View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
THURSDAY, DECEMBER 8 1977
7:30 P.M. P.S.T. (10:30 P.M. E.S.T.)




THE SUPPLY AND COST OF MONEY— AS GUIDES TO MONETARY POLICY

Remarks of

Philip

E. Coldwell

Member
Board of Governors
of the
Federal Reserve System

at the
26th Annual UCLA Business Forecasting Conference

University of California
Los Angeles, California
December 8, 1977

THE SUPPLY A N D COST OF MONEY--AS GUIDES TO M O NETARY POLICY

I am pleased to be with you at this annual forecasting
conference and to share with you some thoughts about the supply and
cost of money and their relation to monetary policy.

You will find

no forecasts of precise monetary aggregates, interest rates, or loan
levels in my remarks.

Nor have I attempted to second guess your

other speakers on the levels of gross national product, unemployment,
or inflation.

Instead I decided to spend my time this evening on

a crucial policy debate, about the appropriate guides to the formu­
lation and execution of monetary policy.
For many years economists, politicians, businessmen, and
the practitioners at the Federal Reserve have discussed this problem.
Fundamentally the debate has centered upon the use of monetary
aggregates as a proxy for the supply of credit or alternatively
interest rates as a reflection of the demand for credit.

Both

measures and subsets to each are, of course, merely intermediate
approaches to the ultimate goal of a growing economy providing new
job opportunities and a dynamic use of resources at a fairly stable
price level.
Events of recent months have accentuated the debate as the
monetary aggregates rose sharply and adherents to these measures







-2-

clamored for a tighter policy.

At the same time those favoring an

interest rate approach began a more insistent campaign for policy
attention.

With the monetary aggregates expanding at rates considered

potentially more inflationary and short-term interest rates advancing
as the Federal Reserve sought to contain the money supply growth,
the elements of confrontation have become more pronounced.

On the

one hand, monetarists insist that the central bank constrain money
supply growth and some even suggest a retrenchment to offset what
they consider excessive growth over the past nine months.

On the

other hand the interest rate advocates say that further increases
in such rates to curtail money supply growth will jeopardize the
economic expansion.
The Federal Reserve is obviously very much in the center
of the controversy and its decisions will have an important impact
upon the future health and vitality of our economy in coming months
and years.
Having highlighted the problem, though without spelling
out all of its ramifications, let me turn to Federal Reserve monetary
policy development and our use of measures on the supply and cost
of money.

Obviously our starting and ending points must be the

economic position of the nation and the way in which monetary policy -however indexed -- can contribute toward improvement in the economic
and financial environment both at home and abroad.

Just as obviously

-3-

the central bank cannot do the whole job of economic stabilization
nor can it control fiscal policy, wages, import prices, or a host of
other factors affecting our economic position.

However, we do

recognize the importance of our actions and accept the responsibility
for them.
Having said this, how do we establish policy and implement
it?

More importantly, in the context of the procedural debate, how

do we use the monetary aggregates and interest rates as guides for
policy?
Let us assume the following: (1) that the national economy
is still growing at a reasonable pace, (2) that credit demands are
rising and will continue upward in 1978, (3) that inflation is a p e r ­
sistent and perhaps growing threat, (4) that unemployment and under­
utilization of resources will remain at unsatisfactory levels, and
(5) that our balance of trade will remain in heavy deficit.
Without all the refinements necessary to create a full forecast but
with this general outline, how should the Federal Reserve set its
policy for the coming months?
In our Federal Open Market Committee meetings we are
provided a staff forecast of the near-term expected rate of growth
in monetary aggregates and the impact of such growth on the economy.
Similarly, we are given the expected level of interest rates from
the forecast of the economy and the monetary aggregate assumptions.
The Committee is given a choice of several different paths of monetary







-4-

growth and several choices concerning the interest rate constraints
within which policy is to be implemented.

If the Federal Reserve were

following a strict monetarist approach it would have no interest rate
constraints and would set its monetary aggregate guides for the
long run expected needs of the economy.

If the Federal Reserve

were following a strict interest rate approach, it would have no
monetary aggregate guides.

Obviously, we are using both, to the

considerable unhappiness of both groups of advocates.

Our policy

development has stressed aggregates at some meetings but interest
rates at others.
In my view the two approaches to monetary policy are
separated primarily by dimensions of time, causal relationships,
and certainty.

The monetarists argue, with some factual grounding,

that inflation persists only if money is furnished in sufficient
supply so as to permit upward price competition for transactions.
The time frame for the monetarist is usually 18 to 24 months before
the full impact of money supply changes is complete.

In a policy

sense therefore, the monetarist wants a money supply growth
objective oriented to the one to two year future and since forecasts
of economic conditions for such a long-term span are extraordinarily
difficult, he suggests provision of money supplies at a steady
non-inflationary long-term rate.
The interest rate advocate looks at the economy in a some­
what shorter time frame of three to twelve months.

To him monetary

-5-

policy should be tied to the relatively immediate prospects for the
economy and policy should react quickly to developing troughs and
peaks.

Such a policy would mean stimulus by lowering interest rates

when the forecast future is uncertain or when the economy is failing
to achieve its full potential without overt inflationary pressures.
Thus the time frame of the two approaches diverges and
while the more moderate advocates of each approach can accept some
deviation of recommended policy for the intermediate period, the
hard line advocates are clearly opposed to such deviations.
A second dimension of difference appears to be in the causal
relationships between excess capacity, money supply, and real growth,
especially when an economy is faced with unacceptably high levels of
unemployment and inflation.

The monetarist stresses the impact of

inflation upon the economy and ultimately upon job creating oppor­
tunities.

Therefore, advocates of the monetary aggregates approach

favor a long-range gradual reduction of inflation by curtailing
money supply growth.

Such a program is expected to lay the foundation

for improved economic gains and reduced unemployment in the future.
In contrast, those favoring a shorter time frame and an
interest rate approach believe that appropriate monetary and fiscal
stimulus, creating prompt job openings, will raise economic activity
and the resulting increases in the supplies of goods and services
will not aggravate price pressures and may over time reduce such
pressures.







-6-

Finally, the two approaches are differentiated by certainty
of data.

The monetary aggregates are subject to very large swings in

projections and great uncertainty of relevance in the short-term.
With the problems of incomplete and untimely reporting, of shifts
in definition of transaction balances, and of the unknowns in
velocity, the monetary aggregates have proved to be a highly unre­
liable and inadequate guide to short- or intermediate-term policy
formulation.

Despite extensive analytical and computerized efforts,

there have been very large unexplained shifts in the rates of growth
of the aggregates.

These have caused increased caution in the use

of the aggregates and a widened band of tolerance for changes between
meetings of the FOMC.
Our staff makes estimates of aggregate growth rates for the
short

and long term.

The short-term forecasts relate to the month

the FOMC meeting is held and one additional month.

Thus, at our

October meeting, estimates for October and November were provided
and the mid-point average of these two estimates formed the reference
point for a range within which policy was to be directed.

At our

November meeting the Committee was given an actual figure for October,
a revised estimate for November, and a new one for December.

Thus

for each month there is an original and revised estimate and eventually
a fully revised actual figure.

Both original and revised estimates of Mj

measured against the actual missed the range of tolerance adopted by the
FOMC of plus or minus 2 percentage points in about half of the 21 months

-7-

from February 1976 to October 1977.

For M 2 , while the original estimate

showed a similar error, the revised estimate showed such wide deviations
about one-fourth of the time.

Given the fact that the staff is dealing

with incomplete data which are seasonally adjusted and annualized and
that there were significant regulatory changes relating to deposits
available for transactions, such estimates are remarkably close.
However, the FOMC is making policy on such highly unreliable data and
is guided by estimates with a 50 percent chance of error of more than
two percentage points.
In contrast, there is a certainty to the interest rates of
the moment and a certainty of Committee control over the short-term rate
for interbank borrowing.

These, coupled with the natural bias of policy­

makers toward factual analysis and the uncertainties of the aggregates,
have led to greater reliance upon the Federal funds rate as a con­
straint on policy reaction to changes in aggregate growth rates.
The monetarists are likely to say that this focus of the
Committee away from reliance upon the aggregates has resulted in
the Committee accepting higher rates of aggregate growth but unrealistically low levels on interest rates.

On the other hand, the money

market advocates are likely to be unhappy because of the rise in
short-term rates.
In point of fact, the Committee has temporized on both
approaches and probably for the best.

Policy is not made in a

vacuum of theory but must respond to a host of pressures including







-8-

recently the impact of the uncertainty in energy and tax legislation,
the high level of trade deficits, the decline in the exchange rate
of the dollar, and the public perception of a marked slowing of
the economy.

It would be a very pleasant life to make policy in

an ivory tower devoid of these day-to-day and month-to-month pressures
but this is not the life of a central banker.

He must blend a healthy

respect for the theoretical structure of policy formulation with both
the immediacy of political and social pressures and the business,
market, and consumer perceptions.

His time fraire must be a continuum,

with some actions aimed at short-run impacts and others \vith an inter­
mediate time frame but still keep a strong sense oi: long-run purpose.
The proper balance to this blend is of course n «natler of individual
perspective.

Some people strongly favor emphasis upon the short run

while others have equally r.tron# preferences for the long run.

I

have a bias toward the shorter time frame but with a strong dose of
caution to ensure that cumulative short-term actions do not cause
an inappropriate long-run result.

This time frame problem separates

many of the current commenters on monetary policy.

It seems clear

that some members of the Joint Economic Committee much prefer
interest rate approach and a short-run focus of policy.

an

But it is also

clear that some leading advocates of the monetarist approach favor
exclusive concentration on the long run.

There seem to be no special

qualifications for participation in either group.

Both have their

-9-

Having laid this groundwork of the policy debate of the
Federal Reserve, what can we say about the policy for 1978 and the
implications of alternative courses of action?

First it seems to

me that if the monetary aggregates continue to grow at rates even
approaching those of the past nine months, there may develop a
crisis of confidence.

Those who follow the monetarist line will

preach a doctrine of incipient double digit inflation and, given
business and market sensitivities to potential inflation, decision­
makers* attitudes could be affected.

If the Federal Reserve resists

such growth rates, short-term interest rates will move up again and
this time long rates may follow and savings flows to thrift insti­
tutions could weaken.

These rate movements could, of course, dampen

capital spending programs and reduce the funds available for housing.
Similarly, with short-term rates advancing, creating an upward cost
pressure on bank non-deposit borrowings,

bank lending rates will

increase and exert a dampening influence on borrowing from banks.
To some banks, this statistical trap reflects the short-term rate
pressures of the central bank rather than an excessive borrowing
demand from customers.

To many others the borrowing pressures

reflecting high levels of economic activity are strong enough
to force rate increases.




The public perception has reflected

-10-

a softening in the rate of advance in recent months but the gains
in credit demand may presage a quickening in the economic pace.
If a new resurgence of economic growth is heralded
by greater credit demands and a swelling of the money growth
rates, then central bank resistance would be entirely appropriate.
If, however, the economic pace remains sluggish and real output,
jobs, and capital spending reflect this sluggishness, then a
trend of rising monetary aggregates growth may only mirror slower
velocity and financial restructuring largely disassociated from
the trends in the real economy.

In such an event policy resistance

would seem much less desirable.
As noted above, one of the principal problems in using
the monetary aggregates as guides to policy is their volatile nature
and their unpredictability over the near-term policy period.

To

remedy these difficulties, I have a number of suggestions:




1)

We need to clarify the nature of the aggregates

and define them so that sudden moves or shifts can be
identified and corrected.

One possibility is to change

the regulations governing transfers from and to demand
and time accounts to eliminate the present indefinite
nature of transactions balances.

Such a move would

require greater emphasis on an aggregate that en­
compasses more than the present M]_.




-11-

2)

Another change of some value might be to

focus policy attention on the quarterly data with
two-thirds weight on known figures.

Such a pro­

cedure would obviously reduce the element of u n ­
certainty but would also orient monetary policy more
toward the past than the future.

Nevertheless, the

change warrants consideration if policymakers remain
alert to the hazards of the use of back data.
3)

Similarly the Federal Reserve might widen

the band of interest rate and aggregate guides thus
reducing the degree of desk intervention in the market
and further de-emphasizing the weekly data.

This change

has a number of attractive features permitting the money
market to fluctuate over a wider spectrum of rates while
retaining to the central bank the flexibility to counter
adverse trends once they are cle.arly identified.
4)

Finally, to reduce market sensitivity to weekly

¿aggregates and lift the horizons of decision-makers, we
should consider the elimination of weekly calculations and
publish adjusted data only on a monthly and quarterly
basis.

It would seem to me that when government publishes

data as uncertain as the weekly money supply figures,

-12-

it has a responsibility to either correct or eliminate
such suspect data.

Since we are unable to provide a

definitive weekly figure, I would favor deletion.
These proposed changes are refinements of the present
system and do not change the fundamental focus of policy guides.
However, they could be helpful in reducing "street n oise11 and
statistical aberrations which presently interfere with both
policy formulation and the public's perception of policy intent.
Regarding 1978, I have little to offer in the way of
forecasting assistance.

I expect monetary policy to react

cautiously to unfolding developments in the real economy as well
as the financial pressures of the domestic and foreign situations,
while keeping a watchful orientation on long-run supply conditions.
Excessive movements in interest rates or monetary aggregate changes
are likely to be resisted but hopefully the trends will be toward a
more stable, less inflationary environment.

It is also m y hope that

all of us pay less attention to questionable data and strongly
resist those who believe in mechanistic policy responses regardless
of the developing situation.
It is of considerable importance for the economic and
financial health of the nation to have an appropriate and balanced
monetary policy, but it is also of great importance to have a fiscal




-13-

policy which is responsive to the needs of the nation.

Recently

there has been talk of tax reform, incentives and reductions.
Reforms are contemplated to simplify the tax structure and re­
distribute the tay load.

Tax incentives are being considered to

stimulate capital spending and accomplish special social priorities.
Tax reductions are being discussed as a way to offset the proposed
tax increases for Social Security and unemployment compensation
and alleviate the tax burden on low income families.

Given the

deficit position of the Federal budget, there seems little leeway for
large-scale tax cuts, so whatever is done should be in small doses
with rifle-shot impact.
In my opinion discussions on broad-scale tax reform have
created ¿m uncertainty which has kept business from planning ahead
for new plant capacity.

On the other hand, an investment tax credit

could stimulate capital spending and might be formulated to provide
for tax credits to be steadily recycled into new plant and equipment.
In other words, investment tax credits could be earmarked for reinvest­
ment into sequential rounds of capital spending.
Another unknown element for 1978 will be the inter­
national position of the dollar.

With the very large deficit in

our trade account the dollar exchange rate has been under some down­
ward pressure.

In the past ten months, the dollar has depreciated

considerably against the Swiss franc and the Japanese yen and has
slipped moderately against the market basket of primary currencies







-14-

worldwide.

The dollar exchange rate in 1978 will be affected by

the rate of increase in foreign economies, the import volume and
prices for oil, consumer electronic items, autos, and foodstuffs
and the willingness of foreigners to continue to hold large dollar
investments.

How all of these and the myriad of other forces

work out next year is a real forecasting challenge.

However, I

suspect that the international factors will have considerable effect
on our domestic position throughout the year.

#############