View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
SATURDAY , MARCH 18, 1978
2:00 PM
(E.S.T,)




THE FINANCIAL BATTLE LINE

Remarks of
Philip E. Coldwell
Member
Board of Governors
of the
Federal Reserve System

at the

Sixth Annual Conference of
The Committee for Monetary Research & Education
Arden House
Harriman Campus
Columbia University

Harriman, New York
March 18, 1978

THE FINANCIAL BATTLE LINE

In 1977 the economy successfully waged the battle for higher
production, employment, and incomes.

The 5-3/4 percent growth of real

output during the year provided for a decline of more than one per­
centage point in the unemployment rate, despite rapid growth in the
labor force.

In contrast, the fight against inflation was at best a

draw, as the increase in prices for the year remained around 6 percentthe underlying rate for some time now.

The rapid economic growth in

1977 was accompanied by record increases in credit flows relative to
economic activity and basic money supply rose at a faster pace.

Thus,

the ammunition of inflation was stockpiled during the year.
Today I would like to discuss with you the main domestic
financial forces operating in 1977 and those likely this year.

In

addition, I will examine the setbacks in the international financial
arena over the past year, when a sharply widening trade deficit put
the exchange value of the dollar under strong downward pressure.
Finally, I would like to highlight some of the potential tensions
among the economic goals of our nation.
As you will see, I perceive the possibility of conflict
among the objectives themselves.

In fact, I chose the metaphor

"The Financial Battle L i n e ” as the title of my remarks to convey
this idea.




For if financial forces are directed mainly toward

-2-

attaining only one of the nation's economic objectives, other goals
may be imperiled or even inadvertently sacrificed.

The problem of

potentially conflicting objectives arises because all aspects of the
economy are interconnected and an action in one area may cause an
untoward reaction in another.

But if disagreements exist about the

relative importance of the various objectives, the very possibility
of tradeoffs between objectives can lead to disagreements regarding
appropriate tactics.

And differences of opinion about the strategy

for economic policies become political conflicts.

The Federal

Reserve, with the independent responsibility for establishing monetary
policy and influencing financial conditions, is inevitably in the
center of the fray, if not point man in the forward patrol.
To some extent, differences in views surfaced in 1977,
despite the excellent record of economic growth, as the Federal
Reserve took some policy actions designed to restrain growth in the
monetary aggregates in an environment of rapid growth in credit flows.
Indeed, in 1977, total credit demands of nonfinancial sectors, led
by households and businesses, climbed to a record 18 percent of GNP.
Both mortgage and consumer borrowing were at a record pace, with
mortgages accounting for the lion's share.

Besides helping to finance

record sales of new and existing homes, mortgage funds were in­
directly used for non-housing related purposes, as households w i t h ­
drew a portion of their accumulated equity in dwellings.




Active

demands for consumer credit accompanied substantial sales of new
automobiles and other durable goods.
On the business side, the need for financing became more
pressing in 1977 as the step-up in capital outlays outstripped
growth of internally generated funds.

The heightened business

credit demand was reflected in a greater reliance on short- and
intermediate-term borrowing from banks and finance companies, on
the one hand, and in greater mortgage borrowing to finance the
expansion of multi-family and commercial building activities on
the other.
In contrast, the urgency for equity and long-term debt
financing was reduced following the restructuring and strengthening
of balance sheets achieved during 1975 and 1976, but the expansion
in short- and intermediate-term corporate borrowing was accompanied
by further accumulation of financial assets.

In general, it would

appear that corporations in the aggregate last year acted to retain
their strengthened balance sheets.
In the public sector, State and local governments issued
securities at a record pace, while simultaneously running large
operating surpluses.

Together with the large volume of advance

refundings, this sector thus made sizable acquisitions of financial
assets, especially U.S. Government securities.

Indeed, in 1977,

State and local governments acquired an amount equal to about 25 percent




-4-

of total new Treasury borrowing from the public.

While deficit

financing of the Federal Government declined for the second year
in a row, it still remained sizable.
Supplies of credit from more traditional sources were
ample in 1977.

While credit supplies by households and U.S.

Government-related sources increased, lending by private financial
institutions, as usual, accounted for three-fourths of the total
provided to non-financial groups.

At commercial banks total loans

and investments picked up substantially.

Strength was evident in

all major loan categories, with business loans rebounding briskly
from the depressed 1975-76 levels.

With the surge in loans, banks

increased their reliance on large time deposits and other borrowings,
particularly in the fourth quarter, when inflows of deposits
subject to Regulation Q ceilings slowed.

At thrift institutions,

continued high mortgage demands were accommodated by substantial
deposit inflows, although these institutions increasingly turned to
larger non-deposit sources of funds near year-end and into 1978
when deposit inflows slackened.
While credit supplies were adequate to finance the con­
tinued economic expansion last year, the higher demands bid up the
costs of credit.

The surge in short-term credit demands, together

with the Federal Reserve's resistance to excessive growth in the
monetary aggregates, were associated with increases in short-term
interest rates of about two percentage points over the year.




However,

-5-

rates on longer-term corporate and Treasury securities rose by
substantially less while rates on municipal bonds edged slightly
downward, reflecting heavy institutional and individual demand.
This demand arose from improved profit performance of banks and
fire and casualty insurance companies and from the effects of
rising marginal tax rates for individuals.
Thus far in 1978 uncertainty in foreign exchange markets,
the continuing coal strike, and unusually severe weather have
muddied the economic battlefield obscuring the underlying currents.
In terms of real activity, much of the recent disappointing
statistics in the non-financial area--such as reports of declines
in retail sales, industrial production, and housing starts--were
probably related to adverse weather and strikes.

On the brighter

side, employment and earnings gains have remained quite strong.
In addition, recent trends of equipment orders and inventories
suggest underlying strength in business investment spending.
O n the financial side, total flows of credit in early
1978 appear to be remaining at about the average of last year's
pace.

While short-term rates moved up a notch in January, as the

discount rate and Federal funds rate were raised for international
purposes, they have since remained unchanged or edged slightly lower.
Long-term rates, including mortgage rates, have generally increased
a little, reflecting heavy Federal borrowing and the continued
slowing of funds into deposits at thrift institutions.




Stock

-6-

prices began to decline in early January apparently in response to
uncertainty about the dollar and U.S. policy responses.
International factors played an increasingly important
role in the development of U.S. economic and financial conditions
in 1977.

The U.S. trade deficit widened from $9 billion in 1976 to

an unprecedented $31 billion in 1977.

The expectation that the deficit

might continue at that level through 1978 became a major source of
pressure on international financial markets and the foreign exchange
value of the dollar.
The enlarged trade deficit reflected several developments.
Imports grew rapidly during 1977 in association with the further
strong domestic economic growth.

Oil was of considerable importance

in 1977, accounting for about one-third of the increase in imports
as oil consumption rose and stocks were built to record levels, while
domestic oil production stayed flat.

With the volume of oil imports

nearly twice as high as five years ago and prices five times as high,
oil imports have soared from less than $5 billion in 1972 to $45
billion in 1977.
The expansion of non-oil imports in 1977 was also of major
significance and was spread over most commodity groupings.

Increases

in certain categories of industrial materials, like steel, and con­
sumer goods, such as color television sets, reflected more aggressive
selling efforts by foreign producers who were facing slack demand







-7-

at home.

This gave rise to protectionist pressure in the U.S.

which threatened our relatively free trading system.
While imports rose strongly in 1977, exports were only
slightly above their 1976 level, with most of the gain accounted
for by price increases.

The lackluster performance of exports

reflected the substantially slowed economic growth of our major
industrial trading partners.

The rate of expansion of activity

in Japan and Germany last year was about one-third of the rate
in 1976.
last year.

U.S. exports to these two countries rose only slightly
With a more rapid expansion on the import side, our trade

deficit with Germany widened to more than $1 billion, and with Japan
to more than $8 billion.

This exceptionally large deficit with

Japan led to negotiations which culminated in an agreement by the
Japanese to take steps to stimulate their imports from the United
States and other countries.
Private international capital transactions recorded by
U.S. banks, securities dealers, and corporations continued to show
a net outflow in 1977, though down somewhat from the year before.
The decline in the net outflow reflected a slower growth in inter­
national credit demand and a greater reliance by U.S. b a n k s 1
branches abroad on funds raised directly in foreign money markets.
However, unrecorded private capital flows, which enter in the
residual item in our international accounts, showed a substantially
larger net outflow in 1977, particularly late in the year when

-8-

speculation against the dollar increased.

Some of this may have

reflected changes in international payments patterns--the leads
and lags effect.
The net outflow of funds due to the trade deficit and
private capital transactions was about matched by a large increase
in foreign official purchases of securities in the United States,
principally obligations of the U.S. Treasury.

About half of this

increase reflected the rebuilding of reserve holdings by the United
Kingdom and Italy.

Other countries adding to their dollar assets

in the United States included Germany, Japan, and Switzerland,
all of whom engaged in large scale exchange nuirket intervention
purchases of dollars late in the year.
The dollar came under strong downward pressure in foreign
exchange markets in 1977, primarily in the fourth quarter.

It

declined over the year by 7 percent against a weighted average of
ten major foreign currencies, including

depreciations of about 20

percent against both the yen and the Swiss franc, and more than 10
percent against the mark.

This downward pressure has continued

during the first three months of this year.

Pressure on the dollar

emerged from the growing concern over the rapid expansion of U.S.
oil imports and the trade deficit, from uncertainty about U.S. policy
toward the dollar's exchange rate and from the reappearance of
stronger inflationary trends in the U.S.




The behavior of exchange markets has at times evidenced
very large rate fluctuations, unusually wide spreads between buying
and selling rates, and even one-sided markets.

It has been the

policy of the United States to intervene in exchange markets to an
extent necessary to counter such disorder.

In recent months the

Federal Reserve in cooperation with the U.S. Treasury has drawn on
our swap lines with foreign central banks to obtain sizable amounts
of foreign currency with which to intervene in the exchange markets.
In addition to the inflationary impact of the deteriorating
dollar exchange rate, the degree of fluctuation in that rate has
created a sizable uncertainty in business and political expectations.
In making plans concerning long-term sales contracts and investments,
firms must increasingly be concerned with protecting against foreign
exchange losses.

Similarly, the economic and political uncertainties

are exacerbated by potential reactions of foreign government and
business decisions, especially on oil prices.

Even the U.S. consumer

is faced with a new uncertainty, impacting upon disposable income.
Down the road, the dollar's depreciation may prove to have
been excessive in view of the underlying productivity of our economy
and our relatively favorable growth, compared with many other
countries.

There has been no fundamental deterioration in our

international competitive position.

In fact, the recent depreciation

of the dollar has improved the competitiveness of U.S. exports and




-10-

will help to reduce the trade deficit in the future.

Other factors

too may help stem further deterioration in the trade deficit.

A

pickup in foreign economic expansion would stimulate U.S. exports
and the growth in value of oil imports could moderate somewhat
because the OPEC countries may continue present oil prices in
reaction to the present surplus and because the Alaskan oil pro­
duction has come on full stream.
In order to assess the prospects for the economy in 1978
and beyond one needs to step back from the details of the recent
experience and survey the larger picture with all its interconnecting
elements, including the role of governmental policies.

From this

vantage point, what comes into clearer focus is the problem of
conflicting objectives that I alluded to earlier.
Domestic and international objectives are clearly inter­
twined.

Any major depreciation of the dollar, while tending over

time to reduce the trade deficit, adds to inflationary pressures
fairly promptly.

Imports become more expensive and domestic

competitors find it easier to raise prices.

If financial conditions

in the U.S. were to tighten, capital might be attracted from abroad
and the dollar would strengthen, but higher interest rates could also
diminish domestic investment spending and run the risk of retarding
the recovery.




Conversely, easier financial conditions might provide

-11-

some short-term impetus to the U.S. economic expansion, but could
worsen inflation, exacerbate the trade deficit, and weaken the
dollar.
Over the next year the actual resolution of the tension
between domestic and international objectives will depend importantly
upon governmental policies.

Minimum wage hikes and Social Security

tax raises have already begun to push up wages and prices.

We will

have to wait and see the Congressional outcome of the Administration's
tax and energy proposals.

As for monetary policy, the Federal Reserve

hears contradictory views regarding both technical questions and policy
expansiveness.

On the technical level, for example, monetarists

advise the Federal Reserve to concentrate upon monetary aggregates
as the intermediate guide to monetary policy.

Keynesians, on the

other hand, suggest setting such policy in terms of the level of a
short-term interest rate, like the Federal funds rate, judged to
be consistent with economic goals.
made more forcefully

This Keynesian argument has been

since money demand apparently became less stable.

Because economics is an inexact science, the evidence on
such issues is rarely decisive.

Federal Reserve operations actually

include a role for both monetary aggregates and the funds rate.
Rather than satisfying either camp, however, Federal Reserve policy
has straddled both positions and thus has become the target of criticism
from both.




-12-

While not a shooting war presently, this conflict could
become a major battle in 1978, particularly if the pace of the
expansion produces intensified demands for money and credit.

The

substantial needs of the U.S. Treasury for funds on top of strong
private credit demands could put further upward pressure on interest
rates.

At the same time, the public's demands for money for

transactions purposes could be generating growth of money at a fast
clip.

Such developments would set the stage for renewed debate as

to whether the Federal Reserve should make reserve provision more
accommodative to resist upward interest rate pressure or less
accommodative to resist faster Mj growth.
A more widely contended issue regarding monetary policy
concerns the Federal Reserve's relative emphasis on fighting inflation
versus unemployment.

The Federal Reserve has argued that exclusively

stressing either goal endangers the attainment of the other.

Our

prudent course of promoting a solid recovery while attempting to
restrain further inflationary pressures has not met with complete
success for either nor full agreement among the public.
There is a strong case for adhering to this moderate
course.

While present unemployment can fall further without making

labor markets overly tight, nonetheless at some point remaining
unemployment will be largely structural, impervious to policies
affecting aggregate demand.




Even current inflation is, over the

-13-

short run, stubbornly unresponsive to changes in aggregate demand.
Monetary policy can only provide an environment conducive to the
gradual unwinding of these problems.

A more rapid solution probably

awaits innovative micro-oriented initiatives.
In the meantime, the Federal Reserve has to resist a
built-in bias in most of our governmental structure which leads
to political pressure for a more expansionary monetary policy.
Congress wisely established an independent Federal Reserve to pro­
vide a counter-balance to the possible temptation to undertake
short-term monetary policies that are inappropriate over the long run.
The Federal Reserve is uniquely capable of representing the longerterm public interest, while resisting short-term expedients.

To

some degree, some tension between an independent Federal Reserve
and other governmental bodies is inevitable.

It is a part of the

over-all system of checks and balances incorporated into our
governmental structure which has served the nation well.
Returning to our battlefield analogies, there are some
who believe that the Federal Reserve has been forced into a purely
defensive position like drawing its wagons into the traditional
circle, while its policies are being out-flanked by both the internal
inflationary moves of government and the external mercantilist tactics
of competitors abroad.

Some even see a threat of insidious

infiltration in the rising interdependence of nations and their




-14-

economic policies, which will be difficult to counter if the Federal
Reserve adopts a provincial strategy.

And finally, some see the

Federal Reserve out-gunned by the sophisticated forces of credit
mobility and rate competition in a world of steadily tighter policy
and growth interlocks.
If our defenses in economic and financial policy, theory,
and practice were outmoded like the arrows and lances of tribal
warfare while the war is fought with jets and cruise missiles, the
problems would be manifest.

But the Federal Reserve has its own

arsenal of m o d e m weaponry.

It can reinforce its lines of defense

with strategic stockpiles of swap agreements, probing repurchase
and sales-purchase transactions, a sophisticated intelligence
gathering network, and a response-oriented policy environment.

Thus,

even though some skirmishes have gone badly, it is far from clear
that the war is lost.

Backed by a strong economy, an independent

and free enterprise-oriented populace, and an innovative business
leadership, the U.S. has the staying power for eventual victory.




*********