View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
February 4, 1980
10:00 AM EST

Statement by
Paul A* Volcker
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System




before the
Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs
United States Senate

February 4, 1980

I am grateful for this opportunity to testify once again on
certain proposals this Committee is considering to ensure the
continued capacity of the Federal Reserve System to conduct
effective monetary policy in the years ahead.

I am convinced

that, after long debate and with a final effort by this Committee,
a fully satisfactory legislative solution can be enacted in a
matter of weeks —- legislation that would have broad support
from the interested constituencies, would fall within acceptable
limits of cost to the Treasury, and most important, enable the
Federal Reserve to maintain disciplined control of the money supply
and meet its other responsibilities for protecting the safety and
soundness of the banking system.
The need for legislation is strongly reiruxreed by the decision
of the Federal Reserve to adopt new operating procedures on October 6.
These new procedures —- which are described in a i attaclv -nt to
i
this testimony —

place much greater emphasis on reserves as the

instrument for controlling money growth.
have worked reasonably well.

Thus far, the procedures

But their effectiveness will be

undercut as the share of money not subject to reserve requirements
set by the Federal Reserve increases.

Legislation to keep Federal

Reserve control over the nation's reserve base from atrophying
further is, in that context, an essential element in our antiinflationary program.
As we deliberate, the problem of attrition from Federal Reserve
membership intensifies.




In the three years that Congress has

debated this issue, the proportion of bank deposits held by
member banks dropped from 73 percent to about 70 percent.
That drop occurred despite the fact that many institutions
have been willing to defer withdrawal .from membership while
awaiting legislation that would result in more equitable
conditions.

Now, it is evident that patience has run thin.

During the fourth quarter of 197 9 and the first few weeks of
1930, 69 banks with about $7 billion in deposits have given
notice of withdrawal from membership.

The loss of deposits

in this short period exceeds that of any full year.

The

recent withdrawals by two very sizable banks in Pennsylvania,
with more than $3 billion in deposits between them, seems to
me especially significant.

They show that much larger

institutions than before are now prepared to take the step.
As one banker has put it, the cost of membership is "too high
a price to be a member of anything,"
It is my judgment, and that of many others, that, in the
absence of legislative action, the stream of member banks withdrawing will reach flood proportions. Financial innovation,
shifting competitive patterns, and stx*ong inflationary pressures
with their related high interest rates, all have contributed to
an increasing burden of membership.

It has become progressively

moire costly and more difficult for banks to justify continuing
their membership.

It was not so long ago that, among medium-

sized and larger banks, membership was pretty much taken for




granted-

Now in more and more areas of the country, that

attitude is being reversed; it is continued membership that
has to be justified to the stockholders and customers that
ultimately shoulder the burden.

Even banks conscious of the

importance of a strong central bank and reluctant to give up
a national charter find that justification increasingly difficult
or impossible in the light of the heavy burden involved.
A recent survey by Reserve Banks, based entirely on information volunteered by members in the normal course of business,
found that 320 member banks were considered certain or probable
to withdraw.

Another 350 were actively considering withdrawal.

These 670 banks —
drawal procedures —

some of which have alx,,a^y initiated withrepresent more than n) percent of the System's

membership and have in excess of $71 billion in deposits.

If

these banks, in fact, withdraw, deposits of banks holding Federal
reserves will decline to 64 percent of the deposits of the banking
system.

And there is no doubt in my mind that many more banks

are considering withdrawal than have come to our attention and
that the momentum would build further.
I would remind you that loss of members has several adverse
effects on monetary control, the soundness of the banking system,
and the strength of the Federal Reserve,

As attrition causes

the total amount of reserves held at Federal Reserve Banks to
decline, the "multiplier" relationship between reserves and
money increases and tends to become less stable•




Consequently,

-4-

fluctuations in the amount of reserves supplied —

and these

fluctuations inevitably have a range of uncertainty —

can

cause magnified and unintended changes in the money supply.
As attrition increases the proportion of deposits held by nonmember banks, the possibility of unanticipated (and unpredictable)
shifts of deposits between member and nonmember banks increases,
destabilizing the relationship between reserves and money.
As banks leave membership, they also lose ready access to
the Federal Reserve discount window.

Operation of the window

not only can assist otherwise sound banks to weather unexpected
deposit outflows, but also provide an essential safety-valve
function for the monetary system as a whole by enabling individual
institutions to adjust more smoothly and without disruptions to
changing credit conditions.

At the same time, the Federal Reserve

is losing the intimate supervisory surveillance of individual
institutions important to the administration of the discount
window and effective discharge of our supervisory and regulatory
responsibilities.
Finally, the structural consideration so central to the
formation of the Federal Reserve System would become relevant
again as larger and larger segments of the banking industry
come to hold their entire operating and liquidity reserves at
other commercial banks rather than maintaining balances with
the Federal Reserve Banks.

In this setting localized strains

may more readily be transmitted to other banks, and individual
failures could have more serious repercussions.




• 5-

Among the relevant criteria for evaluating any proposed
legislation are how many banks are covered*, the proportion of
deposits held by those banks, and the size of the reserve base
itself in relation to deposit totals.

We have no formula for

deciding precisely how large reserve balances need be f or how
they should be distributed,, to ensure effective monetary control
and a well-functioning banking system*

I am convinced that

reserve requirements must be more equitably distributed among
the nation's banks., and I also feel quite sure the Federal
Reserve can meet its responsibilities with a smaller reserve
base than we now have.

But I have grave doubts whether coverage

and the reserve base could be reduced as drastically as in the
bill (H.R. 7) passed by the House without se \

adverse

implications for monetary management.
Theorists have put forward arguments that under certain
operating hypotheses required reserves may not be needed at
all, let alone in sizable amounts.

The rather abstruse arguments

may or may not be valid in certain circumstances.

But we at the

Federal Reserve are not prepared ~- least of all at this critical
juncture for our economy —

to commit ourselves to experiments

with monetary policy on the basis of untested theorizing about
operating without sufficient reserve balances.

You will properly

hold us accountable for contributing to progress in dealing with
inflation and the other economic problems that beset us.
part, we must have adguate tools to meet that challenge.




For our

In our opinionf a reduction in reserve balances held at
Federal Reserve Banks (expressed in 1977 terms) to as little
as $10 to $15 billion —
terms —

or about $11.5 to $17 billion in 1979

could prove adequate to conduct monetary policy, provided

it is distributed equitably across depository institutions having
transactions accounts*

But we are not certain of that outcome,,

and that level of balances -- some 4 to 6 percent of transactions
balances and less than

1.5 percent of total deposits in depository

institutions -- might not even adequately support Federal Reserve
operational requirements*

For that reason we would strongly urge

at least standby capacity to obtain somewhat larger balances —
up to $20 billion or more in 1977 terms*

H.R. 7, in contrast,

provides for less than $8 billion of balances (in 1977 terms),
distributed among only 450 banks.
The monetary policy need for an adequate level of reserve
balances creates something of a quandary*

Reduction of reserve

balances of member banks to that level would not be sufficient
to stem attrition in a purely voluntary system, because it
plainly would not eliminate the burden of sterile reserves of
Fed members*

On the other hand, a reduction in reserve require-

ments large enough to stop attrition would not provide a satisfactory level of reserve balances from the viewpoint of monetary
policy,

S. 353 would attempt to resolve this quandary, within

the context of a voluntary system, by paying interest on the
reserves held after some reduction,

S. 85 or H.R. 7 approach

the problem by making lower, non-interest bearing reserve




requirements mandatory for all depository institutions having
transactions types of accounts.

However, H.R. 7 provides too

small a reserve base covering too few institutions.

S. 85

would achieve a much more sizable reserve base than H.R, 7.
But it does so at the expense of sizable requirements on time
deposits —• requirements high enough to burden significantly
covered institutions relative to competing market instruments.
The Federal Reserve Modernization Act (S._353)
As I just indicated, the amended version of S. 353, proposed
by Senator Tower, would deal with attrition from Federal Reserve
membership in the context of a fully voluntary system.

The bill

seeks to eliminate the burden of membership by reducing requirements against most deposits and mandating that all balances held
at the Federal Reserve to meet reserve requirements earn interest
at rates close to, but still somewhat short of, market z&tes.
Access to services would be restricted to members and to other
institutions voluntarily maintaining balances in an amount equal
to those required of a member of the same deposit size and configuration.

Those services would be fully priced.

Senator Tower's bill, unlike H.R. 7 and S. 85, provides
for reserves on all savings deposits and on all time deposits
of less than 18 0 day maturity.

Such reserves would be interest

bearing, and therefore would not have the same "tax" effect
associated with such reserves in a mandatory framework.

Thus,

there would not be so strong an incentive to shift funds from




-8-

these types of accounts because of the reserve requirement,
a phenomenon that has been of great concern to the Board in
the context of mandatory reserves on time and savings accounts.
Nevertheless, it seems apparent that members would still feel
somewhat burdened relative to other institutions.

In that

connection, I would point out that, to maintain an adequate
reserve base, actual reserve requirements imposed within the
framework of S. 353 would need to be in the upper part of the
ranges specified in the bill.
I have examined this approach with care and have sympathy
for its objectives because, as I have indicated to the Committee
before, I understand and share the nostalgia for retaining
elements of voluntarism in the operations of the Federal Reserve
System.

But, we simply cannot rely on nostalgia in conducting

monetary policy.

It is the considered conclusion of the

Federal Reserve Board that the voluntary approach cannot practically be made effective within the framework of acceptable
revenue loss to the Treasury and other objectives.

Indeed, it

is our judgment that membership attrition would probably continue,
although at a much slower rate.
Based on 1977 data, the cost analyses of the basic provisions
of S 9 353 that 1 have attached show that the net cost to the
Treasury of implementing that bill would fall in the range from
$4 50 to $520 million annually.

This appears to be far in excess

of amounts acceptable to the Administration or many members of




the Congress.

The bill also encompasses the possibility of a

mandatory supplemental deposit on transactions balances in an
"emergency."

As the Appendix table indicates, with such sup-

plementary deposits yielding 1% percentage points less than a
market rate (as would be the case under the amendment to
S. 353 supplied to the Board by Senator Tower), the net cost
would still not be reduced to acceptable levels even if the
supplemental provision was to be invoked.
The dilemma is that without payment of interest on reserves
at or very near market rates., a purely voluntary system cannot
stem attrition, but the payment of that interest drives up the
cost.

Moreover, it seems unlikely that

An view of the

highly efficient correspondent banking network throughout the
country —

many nonmember institutions would be prepared to

place equivalent balances with the Federal Reserve to obtain
access to services,

Indeed, under S. 353 the effectiveness of

monetary policy, whether viewed in terms of the size of the
reserve base or ongoing access to the discount window,might
ultimately swing on the extent to which nonmember institutions
maintained balances to obtain "Fed" services.

In any event,

we would be left with the increasingly awkward problem of
discriminating between members and nonmembers in the provision
of certain services,such as automated clearinghouse payments,
which for practical reasons cannot operate efficiently unless
open to all depository institutions.

Indeed, even now non-

members have access to those automated services.




-10-

Therefore, I must conclude that attention should be
directed toward approaches that would apply reserve requirements to depository institutions on a universal and mandatory
basis.

Such a universal approach has the enormous benefit of

equitably applying reserve requirements to comparable accounts at thrifts as well as banksf at members as well as nonmembers.
This is particularly important with respect to rapidly growing
components of the nation's basic money supply, NOW and ATS
accounts, many of which now escape reserve requirements
altogether*
I can readily sympathize with the desire to maintain a
voluntary system wherever possible in the provision of governmental services.

But, it would be ironic indeed to insist

upon that approach for philosophical reasons in an area
control of money —

—

which is clearly a specified constitutional

function of the Federal Government/ even at the expense of
impairing the effectiveness with which that function is
discharged•

It is possible to reconcile the seemingly conflicting
objectives of equity for financial institutions, acceptable
limits en the loss of Treasury revenues, and the provision
of a large enough reserve base to ensure the effective conduct
of monetary policy by use of a standby authority for interest-




earning supplemental deposits at Reserve Banks along the lines
that I suggested to the Committee last fall.

Provision of such

a supplemental would permit us to attempt to operate with a
relatively small reserve base, while providing a "safety net"
should experience prove that base inadequate to obtain sufficiently
precise control over the money supply.

It would entail no added

cost to the Treasury and virtually no cost to the banking system*
And, from a legislative viewpoint, it could easily be made part
of any of the bills before the Congress.
The amendment proposed for S. 353 in fact seems to accept
the general logic of that approach.

However, the pre-conditions

for the imposition and retention of the supplement as specified
in the amendment appear

so restrictive as to impair its value.

The amendment stipulates, for example, that the Board must find
that the supplemental deposit is the only means to maintain
effective control over monetary growth and it requires a unanimous
vote of the Board, provisions that might make it impossible to
use the authority even if the overwhelming majority of the Board
felt it had enormous advantages over any conceivable alternative.
The provision in the amendment that stipulates that the
authority for the supplemental will expire after four years is
perhaps a still more serious flaw.
in four years.

It may or may not be needed

But, if the expiration date came at a time when

supplemental deposits were in place, an obvious problem would
be created for the authority would not be in use at that time




-12-

unless it was needed.

On the other hand, the fact that it

had not been used in four years should not indicate that it
would never be necessary.

We have no dispute with the point

that the authority should not be used lightly and we would
be glad to propose procedural safeguards to reinforce that
point without vitiating its potential usefulness in a time
of need*
Provision of Services and Other Issues
The amendments to S. 353 offered by Senator Tower to
require charges for Reserve Bank services and for float are,
in principle, acceptable to the Federal Reserve, and similar
provisions are in other bills.

We believe that pricing is

a natural corollary to open access —

but I would also emphasize,

however, that open access and pricing are practicable only after
reserve requirements are restructured and applied to all depository
institutions.
Pricing of System services likely will induce major changes
in existing banking relationships.

It may have differential

effects on large and small, or city and rural, institutions.
Overly rigid application of the principles, however sound these
principles are, could cause disruptions in banking markets.
Consequently, I would urge that the pricing provision allow a
degree of flexibility in timing and implementation.




For instance,




-13-

it should be clear that the Federal Reserve need not precisely
match costs and revenues for every service.
I would also urge that the Board be given authority,
similar to that provided in H a R. 7, to permit exceptions to
full cost coverage where required by the public interest,
competitive conditions, or the provision of an adequate level
of services nationwide *

Indeed, the Board questions whether

a charge for the receipt and disbursement of new currency is
appropricite at all.

The government might normally be expected

to provide that service, and in any event, the Treasury already
earns some $7 billion per year from the provision of currency
through the interest earned on securities held by the Federal
Reserve as collateral against that currency
The Committee also should note that S. 3 53 does not address
the technical problem relating to collateralization of Federal
Reserve notes that can arise under legislation that reduces
reserve requirements.

We are prepared to supply an appropriate

amendment that could be attached to S. 353 or to any bill that
would deal with the problem*
Conclusion
1 am convinced the essential elements of legislation to
provide the Federal Reserve with the tools it needs to meet
its responsibilities are at hand.

The Board of Governors

believes these elements should give concrete embodiment to the

-14-

following principles/ and these principles can be achieved
without revenue loss.




Reserves should be applied to all transactions
accounts.

Some relatively low exemption level,

or a system of graduated requirements for the
smallest institutions can be accommodated within
this principle.
-

When and if reserve requirements are imposed on
time deposits, they should be confined to shortterm nonpersonal accounts and be at a relatively
low level.
To establish comparable competitive conditions,
reserve requirements should be equal for all
depository institutions offering comparable
accounts.

- Authority should be provided to ensure that the
reserve base is of adequate size for the efficient
and effective conduct of monetary policy.
Access to Federal Reserve services should be open
to all depository institutions with transactions
accounts, and the Reserve Banks should, in principle,
aim to recover the full cost of those services from
pricing —

provided all institutions have a com-

parable reserve burden.
Consistent with the dual banking system, institutions
should remain free to choose a State or Federal
charter and membership in the Federal Reserve

-15-

System, with its implications for certain supervisory matters and for the election of Federal
Reserve Eank Directors, should remain voluntary.

These principles already are incorporated intof or could
readily be added to two bills that are before you:
H.R. 7.

S. 8 5 and

Last September I testified at length on specific

modifications to improve S. 8 5 or H.R. 7 to bring them more
fully into line with the essential objectives, and I have little
further to add to the comments I made at that time.
In conclusion, let me express again the Board's deep concern
that prompt action be taken tc ensure that the Federal Reserve
has, and for years to come will continue to have, adequate tools
to manage the nation's monetary affairs and to ensure a sound
and safe banking system.

In light of the many new uncertainties

facing our nation both at home and abroad, and the enormous
challenge of dealing with inflation, we cannot responsibly
permit attrition from membership to grow to the stage where it
seriously disrupts monetary management and calls into question
the strength and independence of the nation's Central Bank.
fear we will soon be perilously close to that point.
I have stated are consistent with prompt action.
the opportunity before us to slip away.




* * * * * *

I

The principles

We must not permit

APPENDIX

February 1, 1980

Estimates for Monetary Improvement Legislation
(1977 Data)

Plan
Break-points ($ millions)
Reserve Ratios (percent)
Transactions:
Below break-point
Above break-point
Savings
Time (1)
Time (2)

Actual 1977

S.85
As Amended
5/5 "
3
12

Without Supjglementa^
(High)
(To^T
35/0
35/0
3
10

3
3

With Supplementalli/
TLQWT"
35/0
35/0

THTgiT)
3
10

3
3

0

VJ

VJ

0

0

17.2
3.5
0
20.7

21.7
0
0
21.7

1.0
0
0
1.0

29.8
2.3
0.1
32.1

9.1
2.3
0.1
11.4

6.8

5.7

26.3

( 4.8)

15.9

Revenues ($ millions)
Cost of reserve requirement changes
Interest on reserves
Revenues from service charges and floatS/

428
0
( 657)

368 ,
1 303*/
( 657)

1,713
109^
( 657)

Net cost after taxes (55 percent rate)

', 99)

456

524

3«6

454

5,398

2,239
0
2,239
0

5,663
8,758
14,421
408

5,663
8,758
14,421
408

Reserve Balances ($ billions)-/
Member o
Nonmember
Thrift
Total

27.3
0
0
27.3

Reserves released

Coverage (Reserves at Fed)
Commercial banks
Members
Nonmembers
Total
Thrifts




5,663
0
5,663
0

_ _°-

5~, 398
0

( 3111
1,033
1,8251/
6311/
(
657) ( 657)

Footnotes to Appendix Table
a/ All depository institutions must hold supplementary deposits at Federal Reserve Banks of 3 percent of the
first $35 million of transactions balances plus 5 percent of transactions balances above $35 million,
b/ Nonpersonal time deposits,
— I
c/ Short-term time deposits.
Includes supplementary deposits where applicable.
% /
e/ Interest on required reserves of 1/2 percent below the portfolio rate.
/ Interest on required reserves of 1/2 percent below the portfolio rate; interest on supplementary deposits of
1-1/2 percent below portfolio rate.
Based on float outstanding of $3.8 billion at year-end 1977. Revenue from service charges assumed to be
$410 million.