View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Tor rellease on delivery
3:00 FM, E.S.T.
March 23, 1984

Opportunities and Dangers
Remarks by
Paul A, Volcker
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System




at the
Broyhill Executive Lecture Series
Babcock Graduate School of Management
Wake Forest University
Winston-Salem, North Carolina
March 23, 1984

It's a special honor to be asked to come to Wake Forest
and to renew the Broyhill Executive Lecture Series that was
started in 1980 by President Ford.

And it's particularly

nice to be introduced by Louise Broyhill, with her special
family and University relationships!

Perhaps I should also

say it's really a necessity for those of us in Washington to
get out once in a while and see how the country really lives,
and what it's really thinking.

In a sensef I suppose that

ability to bridge the reality of your world and the world of
Washington is what the Congress is all about, and it's a
special delight to have members from both sides of the aisle
Jim Broyhill and Steve Neal —

here today.

—

They personify

the Wake Forest, North Carolina, Washington, D. C. axis!
Now, I may be from Washington, but I well understand
there are certain other preoccupations on the campus today.
I'll stick to economics.

I assume there is plenty to talk

about -- but I promise to finish before 10:30.
There is a lot to cheer about as we look back at the
last 15 months.

Unemployment has dropped nearly 3 percentage

points, industrial production is up almost 20 percent, the
inflation rate has slowed appreciably, and —

not unrelated

real wages, on the average, are rising more rapidly and
consistently than for many years.
That's quite a record, but I realize these gains have
followed one of the longest and deepest recessions of the
postwar period; the gains we are seeing have not been won




—

-2without great pain and difficulty, and they are not spread
evenly around the country*

And I am not about to suggest we

can afford to rest on our oars now*
I do think we have a new opportunity -- a kind of
launching pad —

for placing the economy on a more sustainable

orbit of growth and stability.
us for almost two decades —

That's a trend that has eluded

essentially for the lifetime of

those of you in college today.

But there are also obvious

threats and obstacles to that bright prospect.
to talk a bit about both —

And I'd like

the opportunities and the dangers.

We have been in the midst of a battle against an
inflationary momentum, and patterns of thinking and behavior
bred by inflation that became ingrained.

To put the point in

some perspective, something like half of our working population those under age 35 —

have never known price stability during

their working and consuming lifetimes —
to get a taste of it recently.

and only have begun

During the late '60's and

'70's, Americans increasingly began to count on inflation as
part of their everyday life -- they expected it to continue,
and those attitudes came to be reflected in behavior.

Workers

came to think of large wage and salary increases of 10 percent
or so as the norm.
pricing policies.

Businesses anticipated inflation in their
Bonds and other fixed-interest securities

got a bad name as investments, and many people turned to real
estate or gold or diamonds to protect their assets.




The rewards

-3from speculation seemed better than worrying about efficiency
and productivity —

and we began to count on inflation to bail

us out of bad business or investment decisions.
helped to keep the process going —

All that

and, in retrospect, it's

understandable productivity growth practically disappeared,
and as the economy became distorted, unemployment trended
higher.
During that period, we saw several efforts to combat
inflation —

efforts launched with sincerity and real concern.

But those efforts were defeated or abandoned prematurely, in
whole or in part, when they seemed to conflict with other
objectives. The whole inflationary process began to take off
in the mid-1960's when, as a nation, we tried both to fight
a war and to introduce a "Great Society" without facing up to
all the costs.

Policies of restraint in the late 1960's were

not pressed for long.
and price controls.

By 1971 we turned to mandatory wage
The apparent gains from that program

were soon washed away.

The energy crisis —

and for a while

bad crops -- accelerated the process.
There were later examples of policy responses to
inflationary concerns, particularly by monetary policy, but
the hard fact is fiscal and monetary discipline was not
pressed long enough to turn the tide.

Instead, the conviction

grew that each cycle of economic activity would leave us with
a residue of still higher prices.




But it was also true that* by the late 1970 's, the
costs were becoming more apparent.

inflation, after it has

been around awhile, feeds on itself —

as I suggested a moment

ago, expectations of inflation, strongly enough held, are
reflected in behavior that perpetuates and accelerates the
process.

As that happened —

and inflation for a short time

moved to the 15 percent range —• there was a justifiable
sense of alarm,,

The consequences, including historically

high interest rates, became more noticeable,

A lot of people

began to observe that, contrary to much earlier doctrine, as
inflation continued, unemployment tended to rise and economic
growth to slow*
As this decade began, you could sense a growing
commitment among the American people that the time had come
to deal decisively with inflation*

I think there was also a

realistic appreciation that sudden, painless solutions were
not possible, but that failure to face up to the job would
ultimately entail much heavier costs.
Many economists used to argue that "a little" inflation
may be a good thing -- a benign kind of "social solvent"
useful in resolving too many competing claims for a limited
amount of real output, and a kind of stimulant to investment.
And there may have been an element of truth in those propositions
when the norm was stability, and a little inflation was a
surprise*




But the old adage about "you can't fool all the

people all the time" applies in this area, as others*

And

once inflation picked up speed and became ingrained in
thinking, the game was up and we learned the economy doesn't
operate very well without a sound financial yardstick -- a
stable dollar.
What is past is prologue, and I have just described a
rather dismal prologue to the 1980 8 s.

But we can also learn

from experience, and those lessons are one important reason I
can be so hopeful for the future -- why, after a deep and
prolonged recession I believe we have a rare opportunity to
set in train a long period of growth and stability.

To put

the point another way, we can reverse the experience of the
1970Bs -- we can demonstrate that an economy that seemed to
be going downhill, with one adverse shock begetting another,
can go up as well.
I am not about to suggest that happy vision will
somehow come by itself, that we can now sit back and count on
the recent good economic news producing a lasting momentum of
its own.

After all the difficulties and disappointments of

the past decade, that kind of optimism doesn't "wash" today

—

understandably so.
I fully realize there are some new and unprecedented
threats and risks to sustaining progress —• the enormous
budget deficits, the international debt problem, the gaping
and still growing imbalance in our international accounts, the




-6strong forces of protectionism, and, not least, the temptation
to return to behavior patterns bred in the years of inflation.
But those threats are not exactly hidden —
they can be met.

and once understood,

Before addressing those threats directly,

let me emphasize why I think we can build on the progress of
the past year or so.




Most importantly, for the first time in many
years, the rate of inflation has, in fact, been
ratcheted down.

Prices are still rising —

but

at the lowest rate in a decade or more.
-

We paid the price of recession in breaking the
inflation momentum.

But prospects for better

performance as the economy grows are undergirded
by greater restraint on underlying costs in most
sectors, accompanied by signs of more emphasis
on efficiency and productivity.
There is a strong sense that major industries and
markets are and will be under greater competitive
pressures than before, both because of less regulation and the intensity of international competition.
Those pressures are often uncomfortable, to say the
least, but they are also an enormous stimulant to
efficiency and innovation.
-

Meanwhile, as the economy grows, we can see the
beginnings of a rebuilding of corporate balance

sheetsf of a strengthening cash flow, of a return
to levels of profitability more normal historically, and of an improved climate for risk capital
and innovation.
Now, with unemployment declining rapidly for more than
a year and with capacity more fully utilized, we face a
critical period in terms of keeping the process of expansion
going not just in 1984 but in the years beyond.

Stated

another way, we have the challenge of combining growth with
continuing progress against inflation, because without the
latter we will, in my judgment, undermine the former.

Despite

all the recent progress, I know there is a lot of skepticism -even cynicism —

about whether it can be done.

In a few areas capacity is already coming under
pressure.
weather.

Recently, food prices reflected the effects of bad
That, in itself, should be temporary, but a rising

consumer price index for even a few months can affect thinking
and expectations.
To some degree, prices will always reflect the stage
of the business cycle.

An inability in 1984 to repeat the

exceptionally good performance of 1983 should not, at this
stage of expansion, in itself be a cause of great concern

—

so long as change is small.
What will count is whether, over reasonable periods of
time, our policies point toward prospects for greater stability,




-8not less*

In my judgment, we cannot be satisfied until we

have reached the point when people can begin to take for
granted that a strong and persistent acceleration in the
general trend of prices is not in the cards —

that in their

financial planning, they do not constantly have to be "on guard."
The memory of years of inflation and failed antiinflation programs have understandably left deep scars, not
least among those responsible for investing money.

That is

one important reason why interest rates have remained so high
in historical terms*

Assuming we can maintain the progress

against inflation, those interest rates should over time move
lower —

and it's important that they do so if we are to

sustain housing, encourage investment, and contribute to a
strong world economy.

But it is precisely the concern about my

assumption -- that inflation will be kept in check -- that is
at issue in the minds of many investors and savers.
Certainly, I would accept the simple proposition that
monetary policy, in the end, will have a lot to do about the
inflation outlook*

Over time, the lesson of history is that

success against inflation requires appropriate restraint on
the growth in money and credit, year after year.

Ultimately,

money should increase no faster than the needs generated by
real growth at reasonably stable prices.

Given the degree of

price increases still "built in," we are necessarily some
distance from that point.




But the goals we have set for

-9ourselves for 1984 are designed to make further progress in
that direction.
This is not the time or place for a long technical
discussion of exactly how fast money should grow, and all the
influences that bear on our judgments in making monetary
policy from month to month.

Suffice it to say our targets

for money and credit growth this year have been designed to
allow for further significant growth in the real economy
say at a rate of about 4-5 percent —
not accelerate much.

—

so long as prices do

Early in the year, we have been doing

even better, and from what I have seen of the views of others,
there is a wide range of agreement that our goals are
appropriate and feasible.
We will, of course, continue to assess our targets in
the light of what is happening —

most fundamentally in terms

of growth and general price trends, but also keeping an eye
on such factors as the exchange rate, developments in domestic
and international financial markets, and other considerations.
We are conscious that relationships between money and what
we really care about —

growth and prices —

are not invariable;

in fact, they deviated quite widely from historic norms in
1982 and 1983.

But neither can we afford to lose sight of

the need for continuing discipline lest we inadverently
squander the chance to restore stability over the long run,
as too often has happened in the past.




-10Nor can we, through any conceivable manipulation of
the money supply, combine a smooth path of economic growth
and moderate interest rates with progress toward price
stability if other areas of the economy, or economic policy,
are out of balance or unstable.

And we don't have to look

very far to see some points of danger.
Obviously, the state of the Federal budget is one case
in point.

Historically large deficits, currently and

prospectively, are a burden on credit markets.

They absorb

an unprecedented fraction of the savings we are able to
generate domestically.

The threat is that, in the end, with

the government preempting so much of our available capital
and credit, there won't be enough to go around to meet the
needs of housing, of investment, and of consumers.
I observed a few minutes ago that, with nominal
interest rates so far above observed inflation, a natural
expectation should be for interest rates to fall.

Part of

the problem has been skepticism about whether progress against
inflation can persist.

And another major part has been the

fact that Treasury financing works in the opposite direction —
toward keeping interest rates up.

It does so both by the

competition it creates in the marketplace, and by helping to
maintain inflationary expectations at a higher pitch.
We, in all our sophistication, can try to explain to
the American people that in the end it is money creation, not




-11deficits, that feed inflation.

But I am afraid there is a

strong instinct, an instinct reflecting a lot of experience
around the world, that the two —

deficits and money creation —

often go hand-in-hand.
That need not be the case, and it's critically important
that it not be the case now.

We can keep money under control.

What we cannot do is escape other implications of the deficit.
In the end, budget deficits —

like investment

—

have to be financed out of the savings we generate as
individuals and as businesses.

But it is apparent there is

not enough savings generated in the U. S. to finance both
investment and a huge deficit.

On a net basis —

that is,

excluding depreciation allowances -- domestic savings for
many years have been roughly between 6-1/2 and 8-1/2 percent
of the GNP, and it is expected to run in the upper part of
that range this year.

But, with deficits, as now projected,

remaining at over 5 percent of the GNP, not much would be
left over to satisfy the needs of housing and business.
In this situation, we have been forced to increasingly
look abroad for capital to supplement our domestic savings.
Fortunately, for some time we have been able to draw upon
foreign savings relatively easily.

Funds have been attracted

not just by our interest rates and by our strong stock market,
but by relative confidence in our economic and political
stability.




Indeed, those inflows from abroad may total 2

-12percent of the GNP or more this year, supplementing our
domestic savings by about a quarter.

The effect has been to

blunt some of the impact of the budget deficit on our interest
rates, and to help finance both the deficit and investment*
That's the good news*

But there is another side*

Reliance on increasing amounts of foreign capital is a tenuous
and risky way to finance domestic growth and capital formation,
For one thing, when we import capital, we also run a trade
and current account deficit*
exceed $100 billion this year*

Our trade deficit may well
That's why our exporters have

not shared in the growing economy, and deficits of that size
cannot be sustained indefinitely*

Moreover, a steady and

growing flow of foreign capital is dependent on confidence in
our ability to properly manage our economic affairs, on
relatively high interest rates, or both.

To the extent our

monetary or fiscal policies fail to justify that confidence
to the extent inflationary pressures again appear to be
ascendant or our external financial position is weakened by
large foreign borrowings —

the greater the risk that new

capital flows from abroad will come less freely.

Then the

consequences for the dollar, for interest rates, and for
housing and domestic investment would be adverse*
The Treasury is going to get the funds it needs to
cover the Federal deficit.

The question is whether the

private sectors of our economy will get enough funds, at




—

-13reasonable interest rates, to support the balanced expansion,
the investment and the productivity we want.
In essence, the demands of the Federal Government
limit the rate of growth of other credit-absorbing sectors of
the economy.

The rationing device is interest rates held

higher than would otherwise be the case.

Under the circumstances,

the more rapidly the economy grows and generates private
credit demands, the greater the risk of rising interest rates.
That's a situation we don't want to be in.
One clear possibility is that economic expansion will
continue despite historically high interest rates relative to
the inflation rate and financial strains —

after all, that

same deficit that creates pressures in financial markets
pours out a lot of consumer purchasing power.

But it would

be an unbalanced expansion, characterized by high consumption
supported by large deficits, by relatively sluggish investment,
and by a widening trade deficit.

That, in itself, is hardly

desirable in terms of the staying power of the expansion, in
terms of the industrial capacity we need, and in terms of
future growth and productivity.

Some sectors, such as

exporters, farmers, and homebuilders would feel the effects
most strongly.

But, in addition, we also must be conscious

of the added risks strong financial pressures would pose

—

to thrift and other financial institutions, to less developed
countries with heavy debt burdens and their creditors in the




-14U*S, and elsewhere, and to the fabric of international trade*
At some unknown point the sustainability of the expansion
itself would be jeopardized.
It's not a pleasant dilemma.

Nor can we escape from

the problem by "monetizing" the Treasury debt through excessive
expansion of bank credit and the money supply.

Of course,

some might urge the Federal Reserve to take that approach.
But the end result would simply be to inflate all the numbers.
Money creation and inflation will not increase savings; in the
end it would only aggravate the savings-investment imbalance
by undermining confidence.
There is a clear and obvious answer to the dilemma.
We can go to the source of the problem —
deficits.

the excessive

It is already too late to make significant changes

in the budget outcome in this fiscal year 1984.

But action

now affecting fiscal 1985 and later years can only work in
the direction of moderating potential pressures; if sufficiently
forceful, the market could then well anticipate the time the
actions become effective.

At the least, the risks of eroding

confidence and new market pressures should be relieved.
By now, this conceptual analysis is familiar and
broadly accepted, in the halls of Congress and elsewhere.
But none of us should underestimate the difficulty of converting
an intellectual consensus into the hard political reality of
action to reduce specific spending programs or to change




-15specific tax laws —

changes that affect people not in the

abstract but directly.
now.

It is that process which is underway

I cannot help but be encouraged by those efforts of so

many in the Congress and in the Administration to produce a
consensus on action.

But I also sense that if these efforts

are to come to fruition, there will need to be a clear sense
of public support and acceptance.
Federal financial policies are my speciality, and they
are of great importance.
story.

But they are far from the whole

There is, for instance, the critical question as to

whether the strong efforts in the private sector to cut costs
and increase efficiency, first born in recession, will carry
into the expansion process.
Can, in fact, the new sense of discipline survive
prosperity?
On the encouraging side, we can point to significantly
lower average nominal wage increases, and to the fact that
during 1983 large collective bargaining agreements had first
year wage settlements (excluding C.O.L.A.'s) averaging about
2-1/2 percent, the lowest since the data began to be collected
in the mid-1960fs.

On the cost side, that's good news because

wages and salaries, in the aggregate, account for about twothirds of all costs.
As usual, when we look not back but forward, the
evidence is more ambiguous.




About half of the large new

-16settlements, in industries where the recession did not bite
so hard, ran to 6 percent or more, only moderately below the
earlier trend.

If generalized, settlements of that magnitude

would place a rising floor under costs, and would be inconsistent
with progress against inflation.
Concerns of this sort in the past have often led to a
call to impose discipline by an "incomes policy" involving
governmental norms for wage and price increases or outright
controls.

But neither the past record nor the public mood

suggests that is a practical, or desirable, approach.
But I do believe we can see signs that a more competitive
marketplace can produce a more viable sort of "incomes policy"
of its own*
—

As you know, trucking, airlines, communications

each a large growth industry that had been sheltered from

competition —

have had to adjust in a way without parallel

in the postwar period.

Other industries long characterized

by relatively high cost and wage structures have found themselves particularly vulnerable to the ready availability of
goods and aggressive pricing from abroad.
I know some of that competitive pressure is exaggerated
currently by the exceptional performance of the dollar, and
there are dangers of a strong protectionist response.

But I

suspect that such fundamental forces are at work that the
United States is likely to remain a far more open economy
than ever before.




And, there should be no excuse for

-17-

maintaining the barriers to competition that now exist

—

whether reflected in quotas on imports or in domestic
legislation —

in the absence of restraint on costs and wages.

We cannot, of course, expect restraint on wages and
other costs if we permit inflation to get the upper hand
again.

The lower trend of nominal wage increases over the

past two years has, because of the drop in inflation, been
consistent with higher real wages.

That is what the economy

is supposed to produce, and, so long as it does so, restraint
on wage increases is justified*
In the end, those increases in real income will depend
on efficiency and productivity, and all our public policies
need to be conscious of that need.

That is one reason the

impact of the deficit on interest rates and investment is so
important, and why we should welcome competition at home and
from abroad.
But discipline and productivity will also have to be
reflected in attitudes permeating a whole range of private
decision-making approaches rooted in our own market system
and political environment.

To take one example, from my

perspective I welcome the interest in profit-sharing arrangements
or other ways of rewarding workers when things are good,
without building in an inexorably rising floor on costs.
Other initiatives to create more cooperative relationships
between management and labor and to improve productivity --




-18the concept of so-called quality circles used so widely in
Japanf more flexibility in work rules combined with greater
job security, and the like —
the future*

seem to me to carry promise for

Many of those initiatives, born in adversity, can

serve us well in prosperity.
All of this is why I, for one, believe it is within
our grasp to see the 1980 's —

a decade begun in the slough

of recession and uncertainty —

become a decade of growth and

stability.
But I don't want to fall out of character and leave
you on

a note

central banker.

of

undiluted

Somebody

optimism.

After all, I am a

once remarked to me that central

bankers are like puritans.

They have a haunting

fear that

someone, someplace may be happy.
We do have a great opportunity

—

the best

in more

than a decade to put the economy right.
But we will also have to work at it —
to make that vision a reality.
done in Washington —
public understanding

and work hard

—

A lot of that work has to be

but in our democracy that will require
and

support.

And as much will depend

upon how we, individually, go about our business and our work
all over the country.
I believe we have learned, from hard experience, that
no real solution can be found simply by turning on the monetary
valve and seeing inflation renewed.




-19We need
stability.

a monetary

policy consistent with

And other policies —

public and private —

also be consistent with that purpose.
much of the available credit.

restoring
must

Big deficits take too

Rigid labor or product markets,

protectionism at home or abroad, failure to carry through on
the gains

in

efficiency

and

productivity

would

all

work

against growth and stability.
We are all on the firing line.
—

at too much expense —

to turn back now.

we have the vision to see it through.




But we've come too far

*******

And I am convinced