View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

9
Speech delivered before
The Economic Club of Chicago
The Palmer House, Chicago, Illinois..., .
April 29, 1936
../''' .

THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYST.Eil AND CREDIT CONTROL
It is now nearly three years since I left Chicago to take up my
present duties in Washington. In those three years the administrative organization and functions of the Federal Reserve System have
undergone important and .interesting changes, mainly brought about by
the Banking Acts of 1933 and 1935.
In general terms, I think the most important accomplishment of
recent legislation so far as the Federal Reserve System in concerned
is that it strengthened and clarified the lines of credit control. A
few changes affecting the organization and functions of the Federal Reserve banks were made, but they were not changes in essentials. The most
conspicuous of these changes was that the title of President was given
to the principal executive officer. Formerly his title was Governor.
The title of Vice President now replaces the former title of Deputy
Governor. As you know, the former titles, Governor and Deputy Governor,
were not mentioned in the Federal Reserve Act. The office of Governor
was originally created under the general authority which the Federal Reserve Act gave the directors of the Federal Reserve banks to arrange for
such officers as were necessary for the administrative work of the banks.
Originally, the only office specifically mentioned by the Act, other than
that of director, was that of Federal Reserve Agent and Chairman, with
assistant agents and deputy chairmen. The Banking Act of 1935 in designating the President of the Federal Reserve bank as its chief executive
officer merely recognized an arrangement that had developed under general
authority and that had proved itself desirable from the point of view of
Federal Reserve bank administration.
The organization of the governing board of the System was changed
considerably by the Banking Act of 1935. In the first place, the old
name "Federal Reserve Board" was changed to "Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System". At the same time, the chief executive officer
of the Board was designated as Chairman. Furthermore, the number of members of the Board was changed from eight to seven and all of these members were made appointive. Formerly, as you know, the Secretary of the
Treasury and the Comptroller of the Currency were ex officio members of
the Board.
The term of office of the members of the Board was formerly 12 years.
Under the new law, the terms of members now in office range from 2 to 1U
years and their successors in office will have terms of 14 years so arranged that the tern of one member will expire every 2 years. Since a
member who has served a full term of 1U years is not eligible for reappointment, there will be a regularly recurring change in membership; one
member leaving the Eoard and a new one being appointed every 2 years,
unless more frequent changes occur from deaths or resignations.
The most important changes effected by the 1935 Act, however, have
not to do with these matters of organization so much as with the function
and authority of the governing Board in the field of credit.

xo
In the course of the twenty-two years that have elapsed since the
Federal Reserve banks were established much experience and knowledge have
been1 accumulated. Some problems which the System was devised to remedy
have now been settled and others have taken their place
At the same time
the conception of central banking functions has changed in many respects.
The net result is that the System presents in certain ways a different
aspect from what it did formerly. ;
Twenty-two years ago the ideas prevailed that the important functions
of the Federal Reserve banks were to furnish an elastic currency, to lend
to member banks which were short of money some of the reserve funds accumulated by other member banks, and to curb the speculative use of credit by
^discounting only paper representing self-liquidating
tions. These ideas now appear quite inaccurate, or at least inadequate.
Furnishing currency is seen to be less important than it was thought to be,
because currency cuts a very small figure in the total
made by people in their dealings with one another. What they use for the
most part is bank credit in the form of deposits. Hie control of bank
credit as a whole is, therefore, of greater importance than the control
merely of the currency supply; it is also incomparably more difficult.
In the second place, the reserve banks do not depend on the deposits
which member banks maintain with them for the ability to make loansand
buy securities. They pay for such assets by entering deposit credits on
their books in favor of the member banks whose paper they discount or
whose investments they buy. If a member bank's reserves are deficient,
it can turn over some of its assets to the Reserve Bank and receive a
credit to its reserve account. The Reserve Bank in such a transaction is
not lending to one bank what it owes to another; it is exercising the
familiar banking power of paying for assets by the entry of deposit credit.
In the third place, it is recognized that there is no necessary connection between the form in which credit is procured from a bank end the
form in which it is used. 'Money may be borrowed on acceptances and yet
b H s e d in the stock market. It may be borrowed on a real estate mortgage
and vet be used to buy merchandise. It may be borrowed on the security of
speculative stocks and yet be used to finance the production and shipment
of commodities. Consequently, any discrimination for or against p e r t a i n
tvpe of paper offered for discount does not mean that speculation is being
controlled or that credit is being supplied for the needs of commerce
The task of controlling the use of credit is far more difficult than such
a supposition would imply.
' • Under various provisions of federal law there arc five principal
means of credit control which the. Federal Reserve banks or the Board of
Governors may use. These are:
, ,.
. ••
••••
Discounts '
,""
Open Market Operations
Direct Action
Reserve Requirements
Margin Requirements

'.. .

..

••

.'• i ' -

Discounts

. „ .

,.

• 'v. ,

The Federal Reserve Act has from the beginning provided that each

11
Federal Reserve bank establish from time to time rates of discount to be
charged by it on various classes of paper; these rates to be subject to
review and determination by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, and to be fixed with a view of accommodating commerce and
business. To this the Banking Act of 1935 added the new requirement
that such rates shall be established "every fourteen days, or oftener
if deemed necessary by the Board". This does not mean that the rates
must be changed every time, but that they must be regularly and frequently reviewed. In general the initiative in making changes in discount rates rests with the Federal Reserve banks, but the Board has
authority to make changes on its own initiative if the public interest
demands.
T

.*Jhen the Federal Reserve Act was adopted the prevailing idea seems
to have been that discount rates were not only the most definite means
of credit control but the most important. This idea was apparently
based upon a belief that member banks would seise the opportunity to
borrow funds from the Reserve banks at a low rate of interest, in order
to relend them to their own customers at a higher rate. This was a
logical supposition and it appears to be widely held even at the present
time. As a matter of fact, it has not worked out that way in practice
at all. Member banks rarely show a disposition to borrow from the Reserve banks for the purpose of relending. They do not like to borrow
and as a general thing they will not borrow unless they have to, no
matter how low the rediscount rate is. Custom appears to exercise a
very imperious control over them in this respect. As a consequence,
they borrow from the Reserve banks as a usual thing only when they have
to augment depleted reserves.
The Federal Reserve Act formerly limited the classes of paper which
Federal Reserve banks could discount for member banks, but the Banking
Act of 1935 eased these limitations. The principle followed in the
original provisions was that a definite preference should be maintained
for short-term credit based on self-liquidating commercial transactions.
The Reserve banks were, therefore, given the power to discount only such
paper, that is notes, drafts, bills of exchange ana bankers' acceptances
arising out of commercial, industrial and agricultural transactions, or
paper becked by United States Government obligations. These were narrowly defined classifications. Advances on a wide range of other assets
vhich made up an important part of the total earning assets of banks
were not authorized.
Moreover, as a result of various financial and economic developments the classes of paper which could be used as a basis for borrowing
from the Reserve banks had for many years constituted a decreasing proportion of the assets of member banks. In 1929 it was only about twelve
percent of their total loans and investments, and in 1934. it was only
eight percent. Consequently, in 1931 and 1932 when the great liquidation occurred, many banks whose assets as a whole were good nevertheless
had very little that was technically eligible for use in borrowing at
the Reserve bank. They therefore had to dump their assets on a falling
market in order to raise the funds they needed.
The new banking act increases the powers of the Federal Reserve
banks so that such a necessity may be avoided. It authorises advances

12
to be made to member banks for periods not exceeding four months on any
security satisfactory to the Reserve bank. This amendment modifies and
makes permanent the emergency legislation which was adopted in 193*.
Beside the foregoing general powers of discount and purchase, special authority was given the Reserve banks in 1934 to discount loans which
member banks and other financing institutions may make to established industrial and commercial businesses for the purpose of supplying them with
working capital.
.*
.
These changes made by recent legislation enlarge very greatly the
kind of credit which the Federal Reserve banks may deal in directly, ana
allow, greater freedom of action in meeting the requirements of the money
market.
Open Market Operations
• It must be obvious, however, that the power of a Federal Reserve
Bank to grant credit at predetermined rates of discount and interest can
be exercised only when credit is asked for. Consequently if the Reserve
bank had no other means of credit control than the power to discount the
paper of member banks at given rates, it might have to wait passively
L d idly until individual member banks decided that they would like to
borrow. Then only would it have opportunity to act and what it might
do then would be far from constituting real credit control
as a consequence of the need of meeting the Federal Reserve System s responsibilities more positively, two other means of credit control have been
developed. These are open market operations and direct action. Both
are outgrowths of experience, primarily.
Open market operations consist of the purchase and sale by the Reserve banks of certain classes of securities, mainly^government obligations for the purpose of increasing or decreasing the supply of credit
a v a i l a b l e in the money market as a whole.
By selling securities the
Reserve banks withdraw funds from the market and less crjdit becomes
available. The reason for this is that in the process of paying for_
the securities that are sold.the reserves of member banks become diminished, because every payment means a debit sooner or later to some member bank's reserve account. And as a member bank's reserves decline
toward the legal minimum it is less able to make extensions of credit.
On the other hand, by purchasing securities the Reserve banks put
• •'funds into the market and more credit becomes available;because the
funds which are released in payment flow directlyorindirectly^into the
reserve accounts of the member banks and enlarge them. And as their rev serves expand, they are in a position to extend more and more Credit.
In principle, therefore, the Reserve banks can increase or decrease
the funds available for lending, accordingly as they.buy or sell securities. Of course, -there are in practice many limitations on the effectiveness of open market operations, but their tendency is to enable the
• Federal Reserve banks to take corrective action with respect to abnormal
credit conditions on their own initiative.
. . . .
The powers of the Reserve banks to buy and sell securities in the

13
open market were granted in general terms in the original Federal Reserve
Act, and at the time were not generally considered to be of very great
importance. The first operations were carried on by the Federal Reserve
banks independently of one another, but it was soon found that action
would have to be coordinated; otherwise the banks would be buying or selling in competition with one another and following different, and perhaps
conflicting, policies. To avoid this, a committee representing several
banks was formed for the purpose of directing the operations. About the
same time the purpose of the operations was clarified. For some time
purchases had been made with the idea of providing income to meet expenses, but it was eventiaally realized that such an objective was in conflict with that of moderating a given condition of the money market, and
must, therefore, be subordinated or even abandoned.
The Banking Act of 1933 gave specific recognition to open market
operations as a System matter and established a Federal Open Market Committee of twelve members, one representing each Federal Reserve bank, to
take the place of the former non-statutory committee. At the same time
the law adopted substantially the statement of purpose which had already
governed open market operations. This was to the effect that they be
conducted "with a view to accommodating commerce and business and with
regard to their bearing upon the general credit situation of the country."
The Banking Act of 1935 made a further change by providing that the
Federal Open Market Committee should comprise the members of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System and five representatives chosen
by the twelve Federal Reserve banks. The law also makes the decisions of
this committee obligatory upon the Federal Reserve banks and provides
that the record of the Committee's actions shall be included in the annual
report of the Board submitted to Congress. Thus an activity which was
barely recognized in the original Federal Reserve Act, and which was
gradually developed in the process of administration of the System, has
come to be emphasized in the law as one of the System's most important
functions.
Direct Action
I also mentioned direct action as a means of credit control. Direct
action means efforts by the Federal Reserve banks or the Board to discourage credit policies of given member banks in given circumstances.
Opportunity for it occurs on various occasions, but particularly when a
member bank is being examined, and when it is seeking to rediscount some
of its paper. In this sense, direct action is aimed at the correction of
specific conditions in particular banks. It may also be resorted to,
however, with reference to general conditions and for the purpose of enforcing general credit policy.
The effectiveness of direct action was specifically strengthened by
the Banking Act of 1933 in several particulars. If a member bank makes
undue use of bank credit for any purposes inconsistent with sound credit
conditions, it may be suspended from recourse to credit facilities of the
Federa.1 Reserve System. Furthermore, authority has been given to the
governing Board of the System to remove from office any officer or director of a member bank who continues to violate the law governing the bank's
operation or who has persisted in unsafe and unsound practices in conduct-

lU
ing the bank's business. The Eoard also has power to limit for each Federal Reserve district the individual bank capital and surplus vhich may
be represented by loans secured by stock or bond collateral.
Power to Change Reserve Requirements
.,
Recent legislation has also established two other new forms of general credit control which previously did not exist. The first of these
is the power given the Board to change the reserve requirements now imposed upon member banks by the statute. For most banks (chiefly those
outside the larger cities) the requirement is and has been for years ohat
they have reserves on deposit, with the Federal Reserve bank equal to at
least 7 percent of their demand deposits, and 3 percent of their time deposits. "" The power to alter these reserve requirements was first given
the Board in 1933, but under limitations which were later removed by the
Banking Act of 1935. The Board is now authorized to change the reserve
requirements "in order to prevent injurious credit expansion or contraction", but it is not permitted to lower them below the present requirements nor increase them to more than twice the present requirements. The
result of raising them - which is the only action that could now be taken,
since the minimum is already in effect - would be to decrease the lending
power of member banks and consequently the amount of available credit.
The effect of lowering them later on would be, of course, to enlarge the
lending power and the amount of available credit.
Margin Requirements
The second new form of general credit control recently authorized
pertains to margin accounts and loans made for the purpose of purchasing
or carrying registered securities. Authority for the Board to issue regulations in this field was granted by the Securities Exchange Act of
1934. This grant of authority was in line with various provisions of the
Federal Reserve Act, such as I have already referred to, aimed at restricting the use of credit for speculative purposes.
Pursuant to these provisions the Board has issued twin Regulations,
T and U
Regulation t / following Sections 7 and 8 ( a ) of the Securities
Exchange Act of 1934, governs the extension and maintenance of credit by
brokerfand dealers in securities for the purpose of purchasing or carrying securi^
Regulation U, following Section 7(d) of the Act, governs
l o L s made by banks for the purpose of purchasing or carrying stocks registered on exchanges. In general, these regulations fix the maximum loan
value of securities subject to their, provisions at 45 percent of their
current market value. This means a margin requirement of 55 percent.
This loan value applies equally to margin accounts with brokers and to
similar loans made by banks.
In the case of brokers who are financing other brokers in order to
enable" them to carry accounts of their customers - as may happen, lor
example^ when a la7ge city broker is financing a -respondent broker in
a small community - loan values of 60 percent are P ® ^ ^ ' ® ^ 0 " ! .
provision is also made to facilitate the financing of securities distribution .
_••.»•
The Board has authority to change the loan value P ^ e n t a g e s as
necessary in order to prevent, in the language of the Act, ^the excessive use of credit for the purchase or carrying of securities .

15

The provisions of the law and of the regulations ere too technical
and too numerous for me to discuss in detail, but I shall mention a few
distinctions and exceptions which are to be observed. To begin with,
Regulation U does not prevent a bank from taking collateral in addition
to that required by regulation; it does not require a bank to have anyoutstanding loan reduced or paid, nor additional collateral put up.
Neither regulation applies to loans on government obligations, nor on a
number of similar types of exempted securities. They do not apply to
loans, however secured, which were not made for the purpose of purchasing
or carrying registered securities. 1 wish to emphasize this last point.
Regulation U does not restrict the right of a bank to extend credit,
whether on securities or otherwise, for any commercial, agricultural or
industrial purpose, or for any other purpose except the purchasing and
carrying of stocks registered on a national securities exchange. In
other words, it does not interfere with the available supply of credit in
general. Instead, it achieves its purpose by imposing restrictions upon
the demand for credit from the speculative quarter.
For example, under the regulation last issued, it is possible to
borrow $4.5 on each £100 of stocks, valued at the market. That obviously
means a very definite restriction upon the extent to which speculators
can expand their holdings. If market prices nevertheless rise so that
the $1 00 worth of securities becomes worth £125, £150, or £200, at the
market, the amount that can be borrowed, namely 4-5 percent, becomes of
course progressively greater, until such time as the Board finds it advisable to reduce the ratio of loan value. As the Board reduces the
ratio, the effective demand is checked. In principle, therefore, the
Board has the power to prevent the use of too much credit for speculation and to prevent an expansion dependent too largely upon the ease with
which money can be borrowed. Moreover it is enabled to do this without
making credit any the less available for commercial, agricultural or industrial purposes, and without raising its cost for such purposes. It
is not the function of the Board to attempt control of security prices
nor to do anything in conflict with the responsibilities of the Securities and Exchange Commission in its supervision of securities exchanges.
The function of the Board is confined to control of credit.
As you will recall, one of the conditions at which the original provisions of the Federal Reserve Act were aimed was the use of bank funds
to finance stock market speculation. It has always been clear that the
Act sought to make credit ample for commercial, industrial, and agricultural purposes without encouraging its speculative use; but the difficulty has been to make measures of control work in one field without producing corresponding but undesired results.in the other. A discount rate
that was advantageous to agriculture was advantageous to speculation, and
a rate that was disadvantageous to speculation was disadvantageous to
agriculture. This difficulty in the way of discriminating between the
possible uses to which credit might be put was characteristic of attempts
to reach the objective by control from the angle of supply. It appears
to be obviated in the new provisions, which, as I have said, attempt to
reach the objective from the angle of demand.
This is because the power which has been given the Board to impose

16
and relax restraints upon the demand for credit for speculative purposes
is definitely selective. It is aimed at a particular use of credit and
at the specific channels through which demand becomes effective. For
this purpose, it extends the powers of the Board outside the Federal Reserve System to reach directly brokers and nonmember banks. It differs
from powers of discount, because while these- powers may be exercised to
discriminate against paper directly involved in speculative uses, they
cannot prevent the speculative use of funds procured by the discount of
paper not directly involved in speculation. Moreover, the discount
power is not of effect until such time as individual banks make up their
minds to dispose of some of their assets.
Open Market Operations are even more general in their effect. They
influence the total amount of funds but not the uses to which they can
be put. The same thing is true of the power to alter reserve requirements. Direct action can be used to discriminate against the speculative use of credit, but only in individual cases. It cannot be applied
comprehensively, uniformly, and simultaneously in all relevant cases as
can the power to fix the loan values of securities.
In the case of margin accounts, the regulation is directed at an
unmistakable objective and cannot miss affecting the speculative use of
credit. In the case of loans by banks for purposes of speculation it
may be felt that the objective is less distinct, since the purpose of
such loans may be disguised. This may appear especially possible since
Regulation U permits a bank to rely upon a signed statement, accepted
in good faith, as to the purpose of a given loan. Of course if means
of evasion develop, they will have to be dealt with, but the Board has
chosen to avoid imposing inquisitorial investigations in the absence
of reason for believing that evasions will be deliberate or of serious
consequence.
I have alluded to the exemptions from these new regulations; I
imagine they are of special interest to you and should be mentioned in
detail. The regulations covering brokers and dealers do not apply to
United States Government obligations, State, county, and Municipal obligations, and such other securities as the Securities and Exchange
Commission may exempt. These regulations also do not apply to credit
extended by a broker for bona fide commercial or industrial purposes or
extended for limited periods to finance bono fide, cash transactions in
securities.
In the case of the regulations covering bank loans made for the
purpose of purchasing or carrying stocks, the following are some of the
transactions to which the regulations ere not applicable:
Any loan made for any agricultural or industrial purpose, even though the loan be collateraled by stocks.
Any loan for the purpose of purchasing or carrying
securities not registered on a national securities exchange.
Any temporary advance to finance the purchase or sale
of securities for prompt delivery which is to be repaid in
the ordinary course of business upon completion of the
transaction.

17
Any loan td a dealer tQ aid in the financing of the
distribution of securities td customers not through the
medium of a national securities exchange.
Any loan to a broker or dealer that is made in exceptional circumstances in good faith to meet his emergency needs.
Conclusion - Limitation on Means of Credit Control
Although the five means I have discussed by which credit control
may be exercised - discounts, open market operations, direct action, reserve requirements, and margin requirements - appear to be very comprehensive and powerful, it would be a mistake to convey the impression
that a perfect control of credit will be effected through them. In the
first place, their application cannot be mechanical nor governed by
simple unvarying rules. Credit and economic relationships a.re extremely
intricate, and the circumstances under which the need for action arises
are always to some extent different and special. Let me mention a few
things that complicate the task of credit control.
For one thing, there has never been a time when the membership of
the Federal Reserve System included as many as half the banks in the
country. It does not now. The majority of banks in the United States
are outside the System. Although it is true that the System includes
most of the large banks and that it, therefore, includes the bulk of the
banking business of the country, still from the point of view of the
communities they serve and of relations with other banks, the importance
of the thousands of small banks which are outside the System is not
negligible.
For another thing, there is always the important consideration that
United States Treasury activities must be taken into account. These
have to do in part with the operations of the Exchange Stabilization
Fund and the issue of circulating media, e.g., coins, silver certificates, and United States notes; and in part with the public debt, and
the government's receipts and expenditures. These operations involve
large sums and intimately affect the banking and credit situation.
Finally there are conditions that arise not only outside the System, but outside the country, and yet affect the domestic banking situation powerfully. There is, for example, the recent great movement of
gold to the United States from abroad - a movement that in the last two
years has added over three billion dollars to the reserves of member
banks and created a quite unprecedented credit situation.
These factors, among others, necessarily limit and modify the exercise of credit control.
In concluding I want to assure you how much I appreciate the opportunity you have given me to discuss these matters with you. In the first
place, it is particularly important to me because I am at home here. I
feel as if I were coming back to report to friends who have more than a
formal interest in what I have to say; certainly in addressing you I feel
more than a formal interest in my subject matter.

18
In the second place, it is important to discuss matters with people
such as yourselves who have, understanding and who are able to enlighten
others. I feel, as I have probably said before, that an administrative
agency cannot function properly without having behind it a well informed
and sympathetic public interest. Credit control unfortunately is a matter which bristles with technical difficulties and abstract ideasj but
it is nevertheless essential, if the important objectives of credit control are to be achieved, that at least their general purpose and philosophy be understood.