View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Automotive Electric Asso
Boca Raton, Florida
April 22, 1969

DEALING WITH INFLATION

It gives me great pleasure to be with you today and to be able
to share with you my thoughts on dealing with inflation.
This subject, I am sure, needs little introduction.
Unquestionably, inflation does exist.

And, as the President has

rightly noted, it is the country’s number one economic problem.
We all recognize that prices have increased rapidly.

Last year,

the buying power of the dollar, measured by the consumer price
index, dropped almost 5 percent.

And this year, the buying

power of the dollar has continued to decline.

I might point out

that there is a wide consensus of agreement that inflation is a
major economic problem.

But once you get beyond sheer recogni­

tion of this fact, you run into sharp differences of opinion.
Therefore, I shall discuss briefly three aspects of the
inflation problem, on which different opinions have been expressed
First, how serious is inflation?
exist?

Secondly, why does inflation

What's really behind the rise in prices?

And thirdly,

what is being done about inflation and what should be done?
My answer to the first question--how serious is inflation-is that the problem is_ serious.
that.

Let there be no question about

But let us also keep this problem in perspective.

Rightly

or wrongly, this country is engaged in a war; and, as we all know,
wars cost money.
without inflation.

No country has ever been able to fight a war
That last year's rate of inflation was the

sharpest since the Korean War, I believe, tells us something.




In

2

the past, prices have risen rapidly during every war in which we
have been involved.

And there is no reason why Vietnam should be

an exception.
None of this is meant to brand the current inflation solely
as a wartime phenomenon.

But in many discussions of the current

inflation I have found that the wartime nature of the problem gets
ignored.
Aside from this aspect, two other points are worth noting.
If you look at the longer-run record, say over the last ten years,
you*11 find that prices in the United States have increased less
than in most of the large industrialized countries of the world
and, of course, have increased very much less than in the develop­
ing nations.

This, at least, should give some pause to those who

look at everything in the gloomiest light.
Those who go to the trouble of looking past the general
pattern of inflation have discovered still another fact:

Prices

have not gone up equally for every single product or service.
Indeed, prices of some things have not increased at all during
1968.

For example, there were three major industrial groups--

fuel and power, pulp and paper, and chemicals--whose prices were
stable last year.
Here again, none of this is to signify lack of concern over
the broader problems of inflation.

On the contrary, inflation is

a most serious matter and one which none of us can ignore for
long.




Even if we could ignore it, though, I believe inflation is

- 3 -

something we should very much guard against.

We all know that

inflation can hurt, especially people on fixed incomes and welfare.
Under inflation, everybody whose income rises less than the cost
of living is also adversely affected.
But that’s not all the damage the increase in prices has
brought about.

We are all savers in one form or another.

at what you earned last year as

Look

a saver, when you allow for the

decline in purchasing power. The answer is "nothing at all," or
very close to nothing.

This, by the way, reminds me of a pretty

good definition of inflation:

Those who save for a rainy day get

soaked.
But aren't there ways and means of getting around this
problem?

Certainly!

Some individuals put some of their money

into diamonds, or coins, or valuable paintings, or jewelry, or
whatever other inflationary hedges people put their money in.
This may solve their personal problem.

But let me point out that

once inflation is imbedded, it becomes more than a cruel tax on
those least able to pay.
Well-entrenched inflation can become a force that distorts
our economy.

Suppose people accept the idea that it no longer

pays to save, and they act accordingly.

Where then will our

financial institutions get the money to lend?

Suppose investors

buy chiefly the hot stock issues instead of the blue chips.

How

then will our major corporations raise their long-term capital?
Suppose investors sink their money into inflationary hedges instead




- 4 -

of bonds.

How then will our hard pressed states and municipalities

raise their money?

The point is that if continued inflation becomes

built into our economic fabric, it will have some very damaging
effects on the economy, and all of us, and not merely those on
fixed incomes, will lose in the end.
This may be no more than a bit of blue on the horizon, but, as
I read what is being written about the current inflation, I am
encouraged to find not only a growing recognition of the wider
harmful consequences of rising prices but also the further recogni­
tion that an inflationary psychology feeds on itself.

When people

are' betting on inflation, such a psychology can become a powerful
force in generating even more inflationary pressures.

Expectations

of more inflation, for example, can prompt people to go on a
spending spree.

They can cause businessmen to stockpile goods and

to build facilities, even when they are not needed.

They can

encourage labor to demand higher and higher wages and can cause
investors to demand higher and higher interest rates.

To destroy

the expectation of more inflation in many people’s minds may be
more important in the long run than that prices have gone up.
What I am saying is simply this:
the dollar buying less and less.

We may be unhappy about

But, more importantly, we should

recognize the costs to our economy if inflationary expectations
are duly accepted as a way of life by investors and consumers.
To carry the argument a step further, let me add that the
most important thing, of course, is not just to recognize the




- 5 -

dangers inherent in an inflationary psychology, but to do some­
thing about it.

Now, if you are going to fight a disease

successfully, you first need to know what is causing it.

And

before you can decide how to combat the rise in prices, you
first need to determine why prices are going up.
Unfortunately, as you might suspect, even the experts don’t
see eye-to-eye on the causes for the current inflation.

Labor

has been blamed for pushing up wage demands beyond gains in
productivity.

Business has been blamed for not absorbing more of

the increase in wages and nonlabor costs.

Government has been

blamed for massive spending and deficit financing.

The public at

large has been blamed for spending too much, and the Federal
Reserve has been blamed for the excessive demand by making money
and credit too plentiful.
Going a step beyond, there are some people who try to make
you believe that most, if not the entire, responsibility for the
current inflation rests on one of these groups:

labor, business,

government, the public, or the Federal Reserve.

Yet, to blame

inflation on a single group is to me an oversimplification at
best and utter nonsense at worst.
I don’t believe there is a single explanation for inflation.
Instead, those who offer a simple explanation forget that prices
go up or down because of changes in supply or changes in demand,
or both.

No two prices are affected by the same supply and demand

conditions.




Therefore, to explain price changes it's important to

- 6 -

identify the particular supply and demand forces.

More specif­

ically, changes in physical supply, related to weather or strikes,
may be the main reason for a price change.

Sometimes price changes

may be related to a change in costs for labor or material.

Some­

times they can be traced chiefly to a sharp increase in consumer
demand through changes in consumer income, savings, and credit.
And sometimes they result chiefly from changes in effective business
demand coming from capital spending and inventory building supported
by credit.
All of these forces mentioned have recently contributed in
some degree or another to the current price inflation, though you
should be careful when you try to assess why a specific product
has gone up more than another.
orange juice gone up?

For example, why has the price of

Surely not because of anything the Federal

Reserve has done or not done, but rather because of the freeze in
Florida earlier this year.

I could cite other examples.

But the

essential point is that price increases for different commodities
can be explained either by supply forces, by demand forces, or by
a combination of the two.
I think the same thing can be said about the general price
level.

Here again, prices have increased for a variety of reasons.

One reason almost everything has gone up is that costs have gone
up.

Higher costs, however, are only a partial explanation.

The

other culprit for the current inflation is excessive demand.
After all, costs cannot be passed along in higher prices unless




-

demand is high.

/

-

And demand, or spending, has indeed been extremely

high.
To be more specific, let me cite what I think have been the
real causes of the current inflation.

One important reason,

certainly, has been that most types of labor have been in short
supply.

Unemployment has been under the low 4-percent figure

throughout 1968.

Another cause for the inflation is that workers

have received pay increases that exceeded productivity increases.
Average hourly compensation last year went up 7.5 percent;
productivity went up only 3.3 percent.

Furthermore, manufacturers

and businesses were able to pass on the higher costs of doing
business because total spending was excessive.

With costs rising

and demands straining against the economy's limited resources,
something had to give way.

It is not surprising then that prices

rose.
The huge increase in demand, in turn, was related to heavyspending by practically every sector in the economy.

Moreover, a

substantial portion of this increased demand was financed with
credit.
This brings me to the role that we in the Federal Reserve
have played, especially in the last 15 months.

During the first

half of last year, we thought Congress would pass a tax increase
almost any day.

Consequently, we did not clamp down as hard on

credit last spring as we might have done if Congress had not been
so slow in accepting the need of a tax increase and a hold down




- 8 -

on spending.

Then in mid-year, when Congress finally passed the

tax hike, the Federal Reserve thought the fiscal restraint would
slow down the economy quickly.

Therefore, over the summer and

early fall, the Federal Reserve did let up on its efforts to
dampen inflation.

However, when it became evident that the

economy had slowed down much less than expected and we saw that
the pace of inflation had quickened, we reversed gears last
December and started to tighten our reins on credit once again.
In this connection, let me mention that interest rates were
increasing even before the Federal Reserve came to this decision
to tighten.
since.

Interest rates, of course, have kept rising ever

I don't know whether this should surprise anybody although,

again, the reason for this increase in credit costs cannot rest
entirely on what the Federal Reserve has or has not done.

Interest

rates are a price--a price for borrowing--and any price is influenced
by both supply and demand.

As long as businessmen, consumers,

and government are heavy borrowers, or demanders of credit, and
the supply of loanable funds is limited, interest rates have only
one way to go and that is up.
I think that the intense demands for credit have pushed up
interest rates far more than limits imposed on its supply.

In

fact, there has been no outright reduction in bank credit so far-only a substantial slowing down in bank credit growth.

Consequently,

if you are looking for the chief culprit for the highest interest
rates in 40 years, you should place most of the blame on the




9

insatiable demand for credit.
Let me further emphasize that the Federal Reserve, to my knowl
edge, has not been seeking an increase in interest rates as such.
Instead, what the Federal Reserve actions have been really aimed
at are to get the bankers to say "no” more often to their customers
To put it another way, we are trying to encourage the bankers to
trim the loan requests of their customers so that the customers
postpone some of their spending projects.

This is essential

because the demand for credit by the business community is still
going up too fast.

Moreover, as you know, businessmen recently

have raised their sights on what already x^ere substantial plans
for plant and equipment, and this spending is adding to near-term
inflationary strains.

In seeking to bring about a slowing in bank

lending, monetary restraint is, of course, part of a broader
effort to dampen inflation.
We, in the Federal Reserve, have tried to make it perfectly
clear to everybody that, in seeking to reduce inflationary
pressures in the economy, we mean business.

However, much of the

business community evidently didn't believe us and the economy has
kept booming.

Therefore, we felt obliged to take additional

restraining action two weeks ago when we raised the discount rate
to 6 percent and increased the amount of reserves banks must hold.
Under the circumstances, I feel these moves were absolutely
necessary.




10

But let me also underscore that neither I, nor anyone else in
the Reserve System, wants a credit crunch.

Our actions are

intended to slow down the excessive expansion, not choke it; nor
do we want unemployment to become excessive.

These are self-

imposed restraints that require not only great skill by us in the
Federal Reserve, but support everywhere.
I said before that excessive credit is only one of many
factors contributing to the current inflation.

If your doctor's

or dentist's bills are too high, please don't blame the Federal
Reserve.

We know that less credit is not the way to keep medical

charges from going up; the answer is more doctors.

However,

where we hope to make a contribution is to dispel the idea that
prices have only one way to go.

We must succeed in dispelling

this idea.
But to make inroads against inflation takes more than curbs
on credit.
credit.

There are a lot of things that affect prices besides

I have mentioned some of these before:

labor supply,

productivity, profits, government spending, taxes, and land, wage,
and nonlabor costs.

These have a far more important effect on

the economy and the future buying power of the dollar than credit.
This means that the job of dealing with inflation is not one for
the Federal Reserve alone.
business, and the consumer.

It is a job for government, labor,
It is a job that will be won or lost

not just by what I might help decide, but by your decisions as
well.




Dealing with inflation is everybody's job.