View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

CHARLES J. MONROE SEMINAR ON MONEY AND BANKING
KALAMAZOO COLLEGE
Kalamazoo, Michigan
May 22, 2000

.....................................................................

Monetary Policy in a World of Uncertainty
Thank you for inv iting me to speak here today at the annual Monroe Lecture. It’s terrific to be here
in Kalamazoo. I’m delighted to see that you’ve had so many distinguished economists at this event
over the years. When I heard that I’d be speaking here, I looked into your city’s histor y a bit. I ran
across the theor y, with which I’m sure you are all familiar, that Kalamazoo was named after rapids at
a point in the Kalamazoo River. Well if that’s true, then there is no better place to talk about the
economy than Kalamazoo. Because economic forecasting is anything but smooth sailing.
Indeed, for monetar y policymakers, even expansions are a study in the unexpected. The path of monetar y policy can be like the path a Checker cab takes during rush hour in a large city. Ideally, the
passengers would like to go straight to their destination. But a lot of tur ns have to be made along the
way in response to red lights, traffic jams, and delays due to construction and the like. Today I’d like
to talk with you about how central bankers negotiate similar obstacles to the smooth-steady expansion of the economy.
I’ve been the President of the Federal Reser ve Bank of Chicago since September 1994. In this capacity, I’m a member of the Federal Open Market Committee. During this period, the economic perfor mance of the U.S. economy has been stellar. Unemployment has fallen steadily to 3.9 percent — the
lowest rate in 30 years. By all measures, average rates of inflation have fallen by at least a full percentage point since my arrival in 1994. Over the last four quarters, the core Personal Consumption
Expenditure deflator has risen only 1.6 percent, and we’ve had even better inflation news during this
period. And of course, real GDP growth has been in the v icinity of 4 percent for the last four years
and is on track for more of the same this year.

Michael Moskow Speeches

2000

303

At the same time, during this period of record performance, the FOMC shifted its policy instrument, the federal funds rate, numerous times. As you are probably aware, over the last 11 months, the FOMC has raised
the funds rate from 43⁄4 percent to its current rate of 61⁄2 percent. As I’ve ventured out to speak with numerous groups and individuals, I’ve been reminded of something fairly obvious. Most individuals prefer lower
interest rates over higher ones. It’s not unanimous, but close. In fact, when someone offers me the opinion
that interest rates are too low, I can usually guess their occupation on the first crack: they’re an economist.
Well, they never told me that being a central banker was an easy job.
Today I would like to talk about the difficulties of setting monetar y policy in a continuously-changing economy. There are four distinct elements to a coherent discussion of this subject: (1) the goals
of monetar y policy, (2) the instruments of policy, (3) the characteristics of an ever-changing economy, and (4) an explicit list of the shocks that are typically encountered. I will talk about the goals at
length in just a few minutes. As for the monetar y policy instrument, in my time at the Federal
Reser ve, it has been the federal funds rate. Joined with the committee’s procedure of timely policy
announcements, I believe this policy instrument has ser ved the Federal Open Market Committee
well. As for the third item, the characteristics of an ever-changing economy, it is almost self-ev ident
that the U.S. and global economies are changing constantly.
This topic has received an enor mous amount of scrutiny in recent years, from business press articles
to White House conferences on the “New Economy.” Not surprisingly, understanding structural economic changes is always an uphill battle for policymakers. Although assessing such transfor mations
certainly challenges policymakers, the real test that we face as central bankers is in responding to
shocks. Most of the time these events are unexpected, like the global financial crisis in 1998.
However, as in the case of the Y2K bug, sometimes these events have been known for a couple of millennia.
In developing these first three themes at greater length, I will argue for the following conclusion
about the goals of monetar y policy: Monetar y policy should always focus on its primar y goals of low
inflation and maximum, sustainable economic growth. As unexpected events unfold over time, the
Federal Reser ve’s response must always be placed within the context of pursuing these two goals.
In order to understand these two monetar y policy goals more fully, let’s now look at them in the
broader context of public policy. What should be the goals of public policy? Of course, public policy
is more than simply economic policy. Public policy as for med by elected officials can have many
objectives. Some policies may be designed to defend people’s rights to work and obtain education;
others may allow freedom of expression and the pursuit of ideas; and still others may protect people’s right to accumulate wealth. Other objectives may be redistributive or aim to ensure that all people have equal opportunities. These may include social insurance programs and urban development
subsidies to stimulate growth in underdeveloped regions. With all these different and potentially
conflicting goals, various measures are used to evaluate the effectiveness of public policy.
Some possible measures of success would be maximum employment, equal growth rates of economic activ ity across regions and cities, and equitable income distributions. Of course, monetar y policy
cannot address these many and potentially conflicting goals. In the United States, Congress mandated the goals of the Federal Reser ve through its initial charter in 1913 and subsequent legislation,
such as the Humphrey-Hawkins Act of 1978. The goals of monetar y policy today as enumerated in
the Federal Reser ve Act are “maximum employment, stable prices and moderate long-ter m interest

304

Michael Moskow Speeches

2000

rates.” Far from being able to address the distribution of employment across the regions and income
levels, monetar y policy must be focused on national and aggregate goals.
Even with these more narrowly targeted goals, there are clear limits to what monetar y policy can
accomplish. After all, monetar y policy does not directly create real wealth for society. The Federal
Reser ve does not build factories or inter net start-up companies. Nor can monetar y policy per manently lower the unemployment rate. The 1999 launching of the Euro prov ides a nice indirect observation of this limitation. In the United States, the unemployment rate is 3.9 percent, but in the Euro11 countries the unemployment rate is 9.4 percent. If monetar y policy could keep unemployment
low, why have so many sovereign European nations given up their ability to conduct independent
monetar y policy?
The answer is that monetar y policies cannot, in any substantial manner, per manently lower unemployment or raise economic growth. Instead, attempts to engineer higher growth through expansionar y policies lead to the types of inflation that occurred in the 1970s and are so hard to end. Recall
how monetar y policy works. The current policy instrument is the federal funds rate. This is a shortter m interest rate that banks charge each other to borrow excess reser ves over night. When the
Federal Reser ve lowers the funds rate, banks translate this into lower rates that they offer borrowers. Additional longer-ter m lending in other markets extends these effects to interest rates of all
maturities. Additional financial liquidity is created and more credit is prov ided to borrowers at lower
costs. Consumers finance a higher level of durable goods expenditures than prev iously planned, in
part because it is cheaper to take on more debt. Fir ms also face lower costs of funds, and hence lower
hurdle rates for approv ing new investments. Consequently, they approve more investment projects
that were prev iously considered unprofitable, undertake more risk, and accept lower retur ns. In the
process, more jobs are created and incomes rise. This leads to another round of stronger consumer
expenditures.
But if monetar y policy is overly expansionar y, the monetar y stimulus causes aggregate demand to
outstrip the economy’s productive capabilities, and prices begin to rise faster. From the consumer’s
perspective, the real value of nominal wage growth is eroded by rising inflation. Debt ser v icing
becomes more burdensome as real incomes begin to fall. For businesses, the lower rates of retur n on
investment are no longer perceived as acceptable. Projects are cancelled if possible, and larger debts
ser ve as an overhang on fir ms’ prospective plans. Thus, a patter n of boom gives way to bust.
The bottomline summar y from this example should be quite clear. Excessively expansionar y monetar y policies lead only to higher inflation and not to per manently higher economic activ ity. In this
context, a reasonable goal for monetar y authorities is to pursue policies that keep inflation low and
allow the private economy to maintain its maximum sustainable rate of growth. Because of this, central bankers should be primarily concer ned with doing no har m, like doctors operating under the
Hippocratic oath.
By keeping inflation low, central bankers go a long way toward doing no har m to the economy. Just
think back to the 1970s and early 1980s when inflation was high. High rates of inflation were accompanied by extremely variable rates of inflation. An average annual inflation rate of 8 percent might
have a quarterly patter n like 6 percent, 12 percent, 4 percent and 10 percent. This seems to be an
empirical regularity around the world. When inflation is high, it is variable; when inflation is low,
it varies substantially less.

Michael Moskow Speeches

2000

305

It is almost impossible to confidently evaluate the consequences of high inflation and variable inflation separately. But it seems likely that variations in inflation rates are more costly than a completely steady inflation rate. If — and this is a huge if — inflation were a steady 10 percent each and ever y
year, then prices and wages would adjust by roughly 10 percent each year. The only dev iations from
this 10 percent change would be when the price of a good relative to other goods requires adjustment. That is, relative prices would still require adjustment. In this idealized world, the only cost of
inflation would be the loss of purchasing power from holding non-interest bearing money. Most estimates of this cost are fairly low, although they are primarily bor ne by the unbanked public, that is,
indiv iduals without access to financial ser v ices.
But the costs of highly variable inflation might be considerable. Indiv iduals and fir ms make plans
based upon expectations of what inflation will be. When these expectations don’t come to pass, there
are usually consequences. For example, imagine borrowing money for 30 years at a nominal interest
rate of 10 percent when inflation has been running 7 percent for several years. If inflation then falls
to 2 percent, you’d find yourself paying a real interest rate of 8 percent, rather than the 3 percent
you’d originally bargained for. If refinancing is not possible, that’s a costly difference. Even when
refinancing is available, the lender has lost a good investment opportunity. Maintaining a stable
inflation rate avoids the costs of variable and unexpected inflation. As I mentioned a moment ago,
across time and countries there is ev idence that low inflation rates tend to be associated with low
variation in inflation. Consequently, maintaining a low inflation rate is an excellent goal.
The other primar y goal of monetar y policy must be to allow the private economy to achieve its maximum, sustainable rate of growth. The sustainable rate is the rate that the economy can achieve over
time without seeing an acceleration in inflation. To paraphrase Milton Friedman’s famous AEA
Presidential address three decades ago, it is the rate of growth that the economy would naturally
grind out over time when indiv iduals and fir ms are focusing exclusively on business fundamentals.
In this context, good monetar y policy facilitates growth by reducing distortions. Erratic policy,
excessive money growth, variable inflation all lead to distortions that people must deal with in their
nor mal course of business. By focusing on keeping inflation low, monetar y policy reduces these distortions and allows the marketplace to allocate resources efficiently. After all, prices are a signal to
ever yone about how resources should be allocated. Variable inflation rates distort the infor mation in
the price signals to business people.
The infor mation content in prices is particularly important when we consider that the economy is
constantly changing. When there are technological innovations, like the inter net, how do resources
get redirected to innovative companies from less productive enterprises? Adam Smith wrote about the
inv isible hand more than 200 years ago, and it’s applicable here. When prices are freely set in competitive, unfettered markets, resources flow to their most productive uses. Investors seeking higher
retur ns naturally shift financial resources toward their most productive expected use.
By keeping inflation low and stable, the necessar y infor mation about efficient resource allocations is
revealed in prices and interest rates. If any indiv idual or group was responsible for making these
decisions directly, chaos would break out. Instead, it’s important to allow the price mechanism to do
its job. By now it should be clear that the successful pursuit of the second goal, maximum sustainable growth, is highly dependent on our effectiveness at maintaining price stability, the first goal.

306

Michael Moskow Speeches

2000

Our jobs would be easy if all we had to do was get into the cab and tell the driver our destination.
“Take me to price stability as fast as this cab can go.” And there’s nothing we’d rather do more. After
all, nobody likes a back-seat driver. Unfortunately, as I said earlier, obstacles always pop up along the
way. Indeed, much of a central banker’s job is dealing with the unexpected. How exactly does a central banker respond to economic and financial shocks? The answer is, of course, ver y carefully. In
my remaining time, I would like to discuss several cases.

Shock #1: International financial crisis
The first example is the recent inter national financial crisis. There were two distinct shocks. Let’s
start with the July 1997 currency crisis in Thailand. Many East Asian countries were pegging their
currencies to the U.S. dollar, maintaining a fixed exchange rate system. The management of these
currency-systems left them liable to speculation, and the gover nment authorities were not able to
maintain the credibility of their exchange rate guarantees. As these currencies depreciated dramatically, local interest rates rose and economic distress ensued. Within these countries, banks and
financial concer ns were threatened with bankruptcy. Foreign investors attempted to withdraw financial capital whenever it was possible, fueling further pressure for currency devaluation in these
countries.
In the first year of this crisis, July 1997 to August 1998, there were three primar y implications for
the U.S. First, the market for U.S. exports in the affected countries practically evaporated. This produced a large drag on aggregate demand. Second, the financial uncertainty overseas led to a modest
flight-to-quality. That is, inter national investors moved their funds to U.S. investments, and helped
to keep U.S. interest rates low through mid-1998. Third, import prices fell dramatically, reducing
inflationar y pressures for a time.
How should monetar y policy respond to these developments? The FOMC’s policy action was to hold
the federal funds rate constant during this period. This was consistent with our two goals. After all,
inflationar y pressures were temporarily muted by the import price declines, and the excess of aggregate demand over supply was slightly diminished by the exter nal imbalance. During this period, there
was spirited criticism from many academic and business economists about the growing risk of rising
inflation due to seemingly unsustainable growth. In the end, however, the exter nal situation reduced
these pressures for awhile; and the committee left policy unchanged through the first half of 1998.
In August 1998, the inter national situation became more difficult with the Russian default on its
sovereign debt and the ensuing financial troubles generated by the insolvency of a large hedge fund,
Long-Ter m Capital Management (LTCM). The scramble for liquidity in financial markets generated a
strong capital flight-to-quality. Capital flowed to safe-haven U.S. Treasur y securities, and interest
rates fell dramatically in the fall of 1998. I’m sure you all remember this period, since most home
owners refinanced their mortgages at substantially lower mortgage rates. Unfortunately, other credit-worthy borrowers found it more difficult to obtain funds in this env ironment.
In response to the further global financial difficulties triggered by the Russian default, the FOMC
prov ided additional liquidity and lowered the federal funds rate three times to 4.75 percent.

Michael Moskow Speeches

2000

307

Although we could disagree, in my opinion, the committee’s response to this economic shock was an
appropriate action that was consistent with our two primar y goals. Even though the U.S. economy in
1998 was perhaps expanding at rates of growth that couldn’t be maintained indefinitely, the risk of
spreading financial tur moil was accompanied by the risk of economic distress domestically. In many
financial areas, the market for liquidity to credit-worthy borrowers was in danger of shutting down.
The risk of wide-spread cancellation of investment projects and working-capital funding was sufficiently great to warrant easing on the part of the FOMC. In this context, the outlook for rising inflation was becoming less likely, at least in the fall of 1998.
As long as inflationary pressures remained muted, monetary policy could respond to the global financial
crises and remain true to both of its primary policy goals. The important moral of this experience is this:
Whenever unexpected events occur, monetary policy must always keep in mind its long-term goals. In
some cases, the resulting policy response will be in sympathy with other countries’ difficulties. But at
other times, it may be necessary to take unpopular actions or no actions.

Shock #2: Agriculture or industrial dispute
There are many shocks whose effects monetar y policy cannot remedy. For example, when a drought
hits the cor n-belt and reduces agricultural har vests, there is little that central bankers can do to
change that. I mentioned earlier that monetar y policy does not build factories. We similarly cannot
cause a long-needed rain over the Midwest plains, although we are often accused of raining on Wall
Street’s and Main Street’s parade.
Another example is an industrial dispute, such as the GM strike in 1998 or UPS strike in 1997. Many
of these events have little effect on the national economy, but some do, such as the GM strike. In these
cases, all central bankers take note of the affects on aggregate demand and supply. But there is no
national monetar y policy that is effective or appropriate for addressing these localized events.
Monetar y policy is a blunt instrument. Changing the level of the federal funds rate has an effect on the
entire economy. These effects cannot be channeled directly to a single region of the countr y, nor to a
single sector of the economy. Of course, it wouldn’t be appropriate public policy to favor one industr y
or region over the others anyway. But given the tools available to central bankers, it can’t be done.

Shock #3: Y2K
A slightly different type of shock is represented by the new millennium calendar change, or Y2K
problem. As I alluded to earlier, the calendar change to 2000 had been anticipated for a ver y long
time. After all, Dionysus Exiguus did introduce the AD reckoning in AD 532. But Y2K was a shock
in that its potential effects were underestimated for so long. What can monetar y policy do about this
situation?
Fortunately, the Y2K disruptions around the calendar change were minimal, so little action was necessar y. But if there had been larger disruptions, would it have been consistent with our goals to prov ide additional liquidity? The answer is an unequivocal yes. Additional precautions had been taken
to ensure that all extraordinar y discount-window lending would have been to solvent institutions

308

Michael Moskow Speeches

2000

who were simply illiquid. These loans would have been temporar y, and would have represented no
risk of higher inflation. Without these actions, financial illiquidity could have tur ned into insolvency. Disruptions in the credit-allocation system could easily have led to the loss of valuable job matches and the efficient allocation of funds to credit-worthy borrowers.

Shock #4: New economy productivity growth
As I said at the outset, it is important to understand that the economy continues to evolve ever y day.
My final example concer ns the recent ev idence that productiv ity growth has been rising over the last
few years. For the time being, there can be no clear characterization of this episode: it may be a salutar y productiv ity shock, or simply a striking series of continuous structural changes. In either event,
I think the circumstances warrant additional discussion.
The background is familiar to most of you, I’m sure. Beginning in the mid-1970s, the rate of average
productiv ity growth slowed for the next 20 years. This is commonly referred to as the productiv ity
slowdown, and its origins are almost as mysterious as its recent disappearance. For at least the last
10 years, however, I have had the sense that business productiv ity growth was improv ing. Working
in the private sector and talking with business people daily, I began to hear accounts of efficiency
improvements with increasing frequency.
Of course, there are numerous examples related to computers and the Inter net, but it goes further
than that. For the large part, business management practices are better, companies are more focused
on their business lines and customers, inventor y controls are more efficient, and continued restructuring has added flexibility. In addition, we have deregulated industries and privatized many gover nmental activ ities. In my opinion, this process of improvement has been continual, but only over the
last four years have the measured productiv ity data begun to reflect these greater efficiencies.
Understanding productiv ity growth is at the heart of any assessment of the sustainable growth path
of economic activ ity. Over long periods of time, the underlying growth rate of potential output is
deter mined by labor force growth and productiv ity growth. Typically, labor force growth is limited
by population growth, although immigration, demographic changes, and welfare-to-work programs
also play a role. Although the labor force growth rate is uncertain, the larger uncertainty surrounds
productiv ity growth projections.
And this has important implications for monetar y policy. After all, ever y percentage point increase
in productiv ity translates into a percentage point increase in sustainable economic growth. Or put
another way, higher productiv ity leads to greater cost reductions, fewer inflationar y pressures, and a
higher standard of liv ing for the American people. A key question for all economists, business analysts and central bankers is how long will this higher level of productiv ity growth continue? If productiv ity growth is only temporarily higher, then inflationar y pressures will be diminished only temporarily.
With only four years of higher measured productiv ity growth, I’m afraid that the answer to this question will remain elusive for some time. In part, we can’t say with much certainty that productiv ity
growth will remain high indefinitely because we can’t put our finger on the causes of this steady
growth. I’m confident that the list of improved business practices I mentioned earlier are part of this

Michael Moskow Speeches

2000

309

stor y. And the explosive growth in access to computer technologies, the inter net and e-commerce
will surely continue to contribute to improved business practices and labor efficiencies.
However, an important related question is how we account for these sources of growth. Suppose we
think of the improved business practices as a deepening in management capital. This can also be
thought of as accumulations of more efficient capital in the production of goods and ser v ices. In this
case, the current productiv ity boom may be due to capital deepening in response to a few large technological innovations. If so, the current period of higher productiv ity growth may be temporar y
(although the transitional process of further capital deepening may take some time to play out).
Alter natively, suppose that the new computer and business env ironment has opened up a broad, new
expanse, which is more receptive to the generation and application of new ideas. In this context, the
currently high levels of equipment investment may be the response to many smaller technological
innovations, which are likely to be repeated indefinitely into the future. Over the course of five years
or less, it may be difficult to distinguish these two v iews of productiv ity growth. And for current
monetar y policy, these distinctions are unlikely to be critical in the short ter m. As long as sustainable growth is higher and inflationar y pressures are diminished, it does not matter which of these
stories is correct. But if inflationar y pressures re-emerge unexpectedly, then it is likely that the temporar y explanation is in fact the one.
To conclude, I believe that ever yone’s indiv idual interests, as well as national interests, are best
ser ved by a monetar y policy that is always focusing on its two primar y goals: low inflation and maximum sustainable economic growth. Under these conditions, businesses are able to focus on their
product lines and customers, without being distracted by costly efforts to hedge against inflationar y
volatility. Workers are able to focus on their activ ities and skill acquisition, so that productiv ity can
continue to improve. And the economy can grow as strongly as its resources will allow.
A major challenge for all central bankers is to recognize that the economic landscape will continue
to change substantially over the next several years and respond accordingly. Undoubtedly, the future
holds more complicated scenarios than the simple cases I talked about this after noon. And it’s often
difficult to distinguish unusual shocks from the continuously-changing structure of the economy.
But that will continue to be the challenge in the years to come.

310

Michael Moskow Speeches

2000