View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

INTERMEDIATION SYMPOSIUM ON BANKING IN EMERGING MARKETS
WILLIAM DAVIDSON INSTITUTE JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION
Ann Arbor, Michigan
June 15, 2001

.....................................................................
Financial Infrastructure in Emerging Economies
The theme of this conference, financial intermediation in emerging markets, is a crucial public policy issue
in the current global environment. The Journal of Financial Intermediation has played an important role in
disseminating research on the design of financial contracts and financial institutions. I’m glad that the
Journal is actively encouraging research in the area of economic development. As an official with the
Federal Reserve, I have a strong interest in matters relating to financial stability. Recent events, especially
the financial turmoil in fall 1998, show that, in a world of global financial linkages, the stability of the
financial system can be compromised by financial crises in emerging and transition economies. Academic
research on how best to strengthen financial institutions in these emerging economies can therefore promote stability in countries with developed financial markets as well.
Recent crises in emerging and transition economies constitute a wake-up call. It was not too long ago that
commentators spoke of the economic performance in East Asia as “miraculous”. This hyperbole was perhaps understandable. After all, in the five years preceding the Asian crisis, industrial production in
Indonesia, Malaysia, and the Philippines grew at a rate of over eleven percent per year. Korean output grew
at nine percent per year. This rapid growth was truly unprecedented, and was associated with a dramatic
increase in living standards and quality of life. It gave rise to hopes that other emerging and transition
economies, especially those in the former Soviet Union, would enjoy similar growth as the benefits of free
economic activity took hold.
It is now clear that economic growth is not a matter of miracles. The path to economic development is
steep, precarious, and unpredictable. It may be possible to avoid many of the pitfalls by implementing
appropriate policy measures. But we need to understand what went wrong in the countries affected by
crises. Only then can we understand the role of public policy in avoiding these mistakes.

Michael Moskow Speeches

2001

389

The proximate causes of the recent financial crises are fairly clear. In the case of the Asian crisis, there
was a maturity mismatch between assets and liabilities. Essentially, these countries borrowed short-term
from abroad to finance long-term investment projects. In the case of the Russian crisis of 1998, the government relied on revenues from oil exports to service its sovereign debt. Declining energy prices in 1998
induced a fiscal crisis, resulting in devaluation and default.
But these proximate causes mask deeper structural flaws. Why did the Asian countries rely on short-term
foreign investment? Why was the fiscal position of the Russian government so fragile? Could better public policy have avoided some of these problems?
One place to look is in the financial infrastructure of these countries. By “financial infrastructure,” I mean
the entire set of legal, regulatory, and accounting institutions that support the effective functioning of
financial markets and financial intermediation. Financial infrastructure is intimately tied to financial stability and economic growth. So an important question is “What are the essential elements of financial
infrastructure that are needed to facilitate economic performance in emerging and transition economies?”
I’d like to give my take on this question, and raise some unresolved issues that further research might help
address.

On Financial Infrastructure
One important function of financial infrastructure is to promote growth through the effective mobilization
of savings into productive capital, and to channel this capital to its most productive uses. There are two different ways this can be done. Capital provision can be decentralized or centralized. That is, it can operate
through many small investors in the capital markets, or capital can be provided mainly by large banks and
other large investors.
Now, the distinction between these two approaches is somewhat arbitrary. An economy can combine these
two approaches. But we often see one or the other approach predominant in a given country, so let’s run with
this distinction. Countries that rely on decentralized provision of capital are associated with greater market
discipline, less political interference in regulation, and a more active process of Schumpeterian “creative
destruction.” As a result, business decisions tend to better promote economic efficiency and productivity.
In contrast, countries with poorly developed capital markets rely on more centralized provision of capital,
usually through large banks. Therefore, firms are less subject to market discipline, and political interference
in the regulatory process is more likely. Governments have a greater tendency to extend “too-big-to-fail”
guarantees to large inefficient enterprises. And economic decisions are all-too-often made to promote the
interests of insiders rather than for reasons of economic efficiency.
So there seem to be decided benefits from a decentralized, market-based financial system. Unfortunately, the
centralized form of financial organization is particularly common in emerging economies. So it’s relevant to
the theme of this conference to understand the interaction between a country’s financial infrastructure and
its mode of capital provision.
There are three important elements I’d like to discuss when it comes to financial infrastructure. The first is
strong legal protection of the property rights of shareholders and other small investors. To see why shareholder protection is so important, consider how truly weird an equity contract is: An entrepreneur comes to

390

Michael Moskow Speeches

2001

you and says, “Invest your money with me, and I’ll pay you dividends whenever I feel like it.” Why would
any small investor enter into such a contract? For small investors to participate in capital markets as outside shareholders, they need to be confident that they will be protected from fraud; that they will receive
timely and accurate information; that their rights will be honored in any bankruptcy proceeding; and, more
generally, that the playing field is fair.
While a legal system that protects the rights of small investors is perhaps most important, accounting and
regulatory infrastructures are also vital. These three elements — legal, accounting, and regulatory, act like
three legs of a stool underpinning the financial system. I’d like to consider each of these elements in turn,
and see what lessons we might learn about them from the recent crises in emerging markets.

Role of Legal Infrastructure
First, let’s consider the role of legal infrastructure. A well-functioning legal system allows small claimants,
both creditors and shareholders, to have their rights enforced. Two important elements in such a system
are a well-functioning bankruptcy law, and an efficient litigation system.
Why are bankruptcy procedures so important? Property rights are generally clear when a firm is functioning well. But when the firm can no longer pay its bills, the enforcement of property rights becomes more
critical. Different claimants are trying to divide up an inadequate pie. This is the role of bankruptcy law.
And by overseeing the orderly dissolution of firms, bankruptcy law plays an essential part in the process
of Schumpeterian creative destruction. Capital is recycled from less efficient to more efficient uses.
Bankruptcy procedures were problematic in the countries hardest hit by the recent crises. The Indonesian
bankruptcy law was written in 1905 in Dutch, and had never been translated into the native language. In
Thailand, there was a great deal of uncertainty whether a creditor’s interests would be protected in a bankruptcy proceeding. As a result, creditors refused to provide funds to debtors experiencing temporary liquidity shortfalls. Korea had a business culture that regarded bankruptcy of large corporations as a national embarrassment. As a result, the bankruptcy law was rarely used, and insolvent companies were usually
handled politically. Finally, the Russian bankruptcy code was applied very infrequently. As an anonymous
Russian commentator recently noted, “when an entire country is insolvent, implementing bankruptcy is a
delicate business.”
Of course, an effective legal infrastructure requires that the laws be enforced consistently. And to apply
them the judiciaries must command public confidence. Here again, the countries involved in recent crises
provide instructive examples. The litigation process in Thailand was extremely costly and time-consuming. So it was generally avoided. In Indonesia and Russia, the courts were regarded by many as unreliable,
with bribery and corruption all too common. A former State Enterprises Minister in the Indonesian government even described his country’s judges as “auctioneers who hand down verdicts to the highest bidder.” In many countries of the former Soviet Union, much of the economy has been driven underground,
away from rule of law. Clearly, a legal code does little good if the enforcement mechanism is compromised.

Role of Accounting Infrastructure
The second element in a well-functioning financial infrastructure is a set of accounting rules that give outside investors high-quality information. Obviously, market discipline cannot take place without adequate

Michael Moskow Speeches

2001

391

disclosure of information about a firm’s operations. Indeed, disclosure standards represent the “third pillar” of the Basel Committee’s proposed revision of bank capital standards. When founded on high-quality
standards for disclosure and transparency, accounting systems give investors confidence in the credibility
of financial reporting. Without investor confidence, markets cannot thrive.
Economies with decentralized shareholders are associated with high-quality financial disclosure.
Concentrated ownership is associated with a poorer quality of disclosure. But, it is not clear which causes which. Atomistic investors demand greater disclosure, and vote “with their feet” if it is not forthcoming. Thus, market pressure can force better accounting standards even without government action. As an
example, consider the “Neuer Markt”: Germany’s “New Market”, established by the Frankfurt Stock
Exchange to foster small high-tech companies. This new market imposes stricter accounting standards
than generally required of German businesses. No laws or government regulations required this. The firms
listed in this market voluntarily took on these standards because they wanted to attract investors, and
these investors demanded high-quality information.
In contrast, economies that rely on centralized capital provision generally see less pressure for public disclosure. For example, the typical equity firm in East Asia is a business group characterized by family crossholdings. These firms are funded by bank loans, with little outside equity participation. When information needs to be disseminated about a firm’s performance, it is shared informally among these large shareholders and large creditors. Without outside investors, there is little demand for better public disclosure.
Thus, we have a self-reinforcing cycle: Economies characterized by small investors demand high quality
standards for public disclosure. In turn, this fosters the further development of capital markets conducive
to small shareholders. In contrast, economies with more centralized capital provision do not generate a
demand for standards of public disclosure. This retards the development of open capital markets, further
impeding the participation of small investors.

Role of Regulatory Infrastructure
A final element of financial infrastructure is the system of regulation. How should the regulatory system
be structured to be maximally effective? A first requirement is independence from the political process.
Connected lending thrives when bank examiners are subject to political pressures. A second requirement
is that there be incentives for proactive supervision. This often means allowing regulators to close banks
that still have positive net worth. In the United States, we’ve taken a major step in this direction with the
enactment of FDICIA. It mandates prompt corrective action for inadequately capitalized banks. I’m pleased
to say that the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, through its annual Bank Structure Conference, served as
an incubator of this important policy initiative.
Third, bank supervisors themselves must be accountable. Supervisors and examiners must be seen to be
acting vigilantly in the public interest. Fourth, supervisors must focus not only on a bank’s risk position,
but also on the process of risk management. This new theme is receiving strong support from the proposed
revisions to the Basel capital standards. The proposal contains incentives for banks to improve their riskmanagement technologies.
A final point is that, to the greatest extent possible, financial supervision should exploit the market.
Market prices can be used to enhance regulation. For example, research at the Chicago Fed shows that

392

Michael Moskow Speeches

2001

yields on subordinated debt issued by banks provide valuable information on bank conditions. This information can be used to supplement the data collected during regular bank examinations. In addition, market discipline can promote stability. For example, research presented at our most recent Bank Structure
Conference indicates that countries with more extensive deposit insurance coverage are actually more likely to suffer banking crises.

Is Western-style financial infrastructure necessarily appropriate for all emerging economies?
In the past few minutes, I’ve discussed a number of reasons why decentralized provision of capital is conducive to superior economic performance, and why a well-developed financial infrastructure is important
for decentralized capital provision to take hold. The extensive research that underlies these conclusions
is fascinating to me as a policy maker because it says that policy matters. It says that well-designed public policy affecting financial infrastructure can increase economic growth and standards of living.
However, we must tread lightly when we consider making policy recommendations. There may be some
elements of financial infrastructure that work well in developed economies but are not appropriate for
emerging economies. Developing economies often have vast disparities of wealth. It may be unrealistic to
expect that capital markets composed of small investors could provide a significant amount of capital. It
may be that, at some stages of development, the natural way to mobilize capital is through large financial
intermediaries. Economic historians point out that the United States had a substantial degree of bank
dependence during our period of rapid industrialization in the last half of the 19th century.
More generally, financial institutions may serve rather different functions in emerging economies than
they do in developed economies. Legal, accounting, and regulatory practices should reflect these differences. Let me give an example from a study soon to be published by the Chicago Fed. The study shows
how a large agricultural development bank in Thailand acts both as lender and insurer for small farmers.
Specifically, if a farmer is unable to repay his loan due to circumstances beyond his control, the loan is
extended and interest on the loan is deferred. While the bank has an excellent recovery record on these
deferred loans, it can take up to four years to recover the full principal. As a result, they fully write off
loans only when they are past due for more than four years. In contrast, standard banking practice in the
United States would typically write off a loan if it were only ninety days past due. If this American practice were imposed on the Thai development bank, it might well deter the bank from serving its vital
insurance role.
Attempts to impose Western-style standards on emerging or transition economies may do more harm than
good if important elements of the package are left out. In Russia, for instance, an elaborately designed
“Western” legal code was put in place after the fall of communism. However, the code failed to protect the
rights of property owners: The country lacked a well-functioning judicial system to enforce the laws. To
implement structural reforms in this sort of piecemeal fashion may end up like the old joke about “British
traffic reform”: The British government decides that people should drive on the right side of the road.
But, to implement the reform gradually… they decide to start with only the busses.
So it may be unrealistic to regard Western style financial infrastructure as a one-size-fits-all prescription
for all countries. Any application of the principles of sound financial infrastructure to emerging
economies must take the specific conditions of that country into consideration. Still, there are basic principles that can guide us as policymakers. First, the legal system must clearly define and protect property

Michael Moskow Speeches

2001

393

rights. And these rights must be enforced by a competent, ethical, and politically independent judiciary.
Second, accounting standards should be sufficiently transparent to foster market discipline and efficient
pricing of financial assets. And third, regulation should be independent of the political process, and
should rely to the greatest extent possible on market mechanisms and market incentives.
These recommendations are very broad. They raise a number of questions that call for additional
research. Perhaps most important, to what extent can policy options that are effective in developed countries be transferred to emerging economies? Do countries with stronger legal protection of property rights
necessarily achieve faster economic growth? Similarly, does stronger protection for property rights reduce
a country’s susceptibility to systemic risk? Do stronger disclosure requirements lead to better developed
capital markets, or do stronger disclosure standards emerge endogenously as capital markets develop? To
what extent can market discipline replace regulatory discipline? In particular, does market discipline
actually influence firm behavior, or do market prices merely provide information that can inform regulatory decisions?
These questions are ongoing challenges that are open to further investigation and research. Continuing
work by contributors to The Journal of Financial Intermediation that rigorously explores these areas will
no doubt contribute to the advancement of our knowledge. And such knowledge has very tangible, realworld implications. Because if, as researchers, we can begin to answer some of these difficult questions,
then, as policymakers, we can begin to strengthen financial infrastructures both in emerging economies
and in the global system as a whole.

394

Michael Moskow Speeches

2001