View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Forward Guidance in Extraordinary Times, in Normal Times,
and Betwixt the Two

Loretta J. Mester
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Money Marketeers of New York University, Inc.
New York, NY
November 6, 2014

1

Good evening and thank you very much for the invitation to speak to the Money Marketeers. I
understand that a long line of Federal Reserve presidents and governors have addressed your
distinguished group and I am very honored to follow in their footsteps. Tonight I will discuss the role of
communications in Fed policymaking, focusing on the FOMC’s forward guidance on the future path of
policy. Of course, my remarks will reflect my own views and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve System or my colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee.

The Benefits of Clear Communication in Monetary Policymaking
Eleven years ago today, Alan Greenspan, then Chairman of the Federal Reserve, gave an economic
outlook speech. The next day’s headline in The New York Times read as follows: “Greenspan Hints at
End to Low Rates,” while the headline in The Wall Street Journal read: “Greenspan Suggests Continued
Patience on Rates.”1 That one speech generated such contradictory messages illustrates the challenges
monetary policymakers face when communicating with the public. Yet despite the challenges, over the
past two decades the Federal Reserve has been on a journey to enhance its policy communications. That
journey continues today because there are good reasons to believe that better communication will lead to
better economic outcomes.

Clear communication and transparency can make monetary policy more effective by helping households
and businesses make better economic and financial decisions. When policymakers are clear about the
goals of monetary policy and the economic information that is important in their forecasts and policy
decisions, the public will have a better idea of how monetary policy is likely to change as economic
conditions evolve. Moreover, people will have a better sense of how policy will react not only to
anticipated changes in conditions but also to unanticipated economic developments. Such knowledge
helps households and firms make better saving, borrowing, investment, and employment decisions.
1

These were the original headlines in the November 7, 2003 print editions.

2
Transparency about monetary policy plays another important role: it gives the public the information it
needs to hold the central bank accountable for its policies. After all, in order to evaluate the central
bank’s policy decisions, the public has to know the basis for those decisions. Accountability is essential
in a democracy, and it can also promote better policymaking. In the U.S., Congress has given the Fed a
mandate to promote price stability and maximum employment, and it has given the Fed independence in
making monetary policy decisions in pursuit of those goals. A body of research both here and abroad
shows that when central banks formulate monetary policy free from government interference and are held
accountable for their decisions, better economic outcomes result.

Of course, it has taken some time for central banks, including the Fed, to recognize the benefits of
increased transparency. Twenty years ago the FOMC relied on open market operations rather than policy
statements to signal shifts in the stance of monetary policy. It wasn’t until 1994 that the FOMC began to
explicitly announce changes in its fed funds rate target and added more description about the state of the
economy and the rationale for its decisions. Since then, the Fed has taken a number of additional steps to
improve the public’s understanding of monetary policy. The FOMC now releases the votes of individual
members and the preferred policy choices of any dissenters in its post-meeting statement, and it has
expedited the release of the minutes of its meetings. And I think anyone who has looked at the minutes
over time will notice that they have grown meatier, discussing in more detail the consensus view of
policymakers, the perceived risks to the outlook, and also the range of views expressed around the table.

Over time, the FOMC has increased the information it provides on its economic outlook. Economic
projections, which are now contained in the Summary of Economic Projections, or SEP, are released four
times a year instead of twice a year. The projections include more economic variables and a longer
forecast horizon, as well as the policy paths that underlay participants’ projections.

3
Another important step toward enhanced communications came in 2012 when, for the first time, the
FOMC laid out the guiding principles it follows in setting monetary policy. A key part of those principles
was the establishment of an explicit numerical goal for inflation over the longer run. The goal is 2
percent inflation, as measured by the year-over-year change in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures, or PCE inflation. Being explicit about the inflation objective reflects the FOMC’s desire to
be transparent and communicate clearly to the public. But it also underscores the FOMC’s commitment
to price stability and thereby helps anchor the inflation expectations of households and businesses at the
target. Inflation expectations are an important determinant of actual inflation. So having an explicit
target helps promote price stability.

Perhaps one of the most valuable additions to the FOMC’s communications arsenal is the press briefing
the Chair of the Committee holds four times a year to present the FOMC’s economic projections. The
briefings, which started in 2011, provide a vehicle for the Chair to expand on the information contained in
the FOMC’s post-meeting statement. She can highlight things that are too complex to discuss in the
relatively short FOMC statement, and she can give a sense of alternative views as well. Indeed, the Chair
did that at her September press briefing when she discussed various members’ views on forward
guidance, to which I now turn.

Forward Guidance in Extraordinary Times
The FOMC’s forward policy guidance has received considerable attention. During the unusual economic
circumstances of the past six years, the FOMC has provided forward guidance to help the public better
understand the anticipated future path of interest rates. The formulation of the forward guidance has
changed over time, from qualitative guidance, to calendar dates, to economic thresholds, and to a blend of
state-contingent and date-based guidance. Let’s walk through those changes.

4
In December 2008, the FOMC began with qualitative guidance indicating that it anticipated that weak
economic conditions were likely to warrant exceptionally low levels of the fed funds rate for “some
time.” In March 2009, “some time” became “extended period.” In August 2011, the FOMC changed its
qualitative forward guidance to a calendar date when it said that it anticipated an exceptionally low fed
funds rate at least through mid-2013. That date was later extended to late 2014, and then to mid-2015.

The FOMC changed the formulation of its forward guidance from calendar dates to thresholds in
December 2012. The Committee said that it anticipated that the 0-to-¼ percent target range for the fed
funds rate would be appropriate at least as long as the unemployment rate remained above 6½ percent,
inflation between one and two years ahead was projected to be no more than a half percentage point
above the Committee’s 2 percent longer-run goal, and longer-term inflation expectations continued to be
well anchored.

A year later, in December 2013, the FOMC blended state-contingent forward guidance with an element of
calendar-date forward guidance. First, the FOMC indicated that in determining how long to maintain
highly accommodative monetary policy, it would consider information in addition to the unemployment
rate and PCE inflation, including additional measures of labor market conditions, indicators of inflation
pressures and inflation expectations, and readings on financial developments. The FOMC then translated
this into time, saying that based on its assessment of these factors, the 0-to-¼ percent target range for the
funds rate would likely be appropriate “well past the time that the unemployment rate declines below 6½
percent, especially if projected inflation continues to run below the Committee’s 2 percent longer-run
goal.”

In March of this year, the thresholds were replaced with guidance that linked the path of policy to the
Committee’s assessment of both realized and expected progress toward its dual-mandate objectives. The
guidance continued to provide a time element by indicating that based on the FOMC’s assessment, the

5
funds rate target will likely remain 0-to-¼ percent for “a considerable time after the asset purchase
program ends, especially if projected inflation continues to run below the Committee's 2 percent longerrun goal, and provided that longer-term inflation expectations remain well anchored.”

I note that the recent business cycle was not the first time the FOMC has used forward guidance. In
August 2003, in the midst of elevated perceived risks of deflation, the Committee indicated that it
believed policy accommodation could be maintained for a “considerable period.” As deflation risks eased
and economic conditions changed during that cycle, the forward guidance evolved as well, eventually
indicating that the FOMC would be firming policy.

The common element in both of these forward guidance episodes is that they happened during periods of
unusual economic circumstances: in the earlier instance, a deflation scare; in the later instance, the
financial crisis, ensuing very deep recession, and subsequent slow recovery.

In extraordinary economic times, forward guidance can be thought of as more than a communications
device. It is a tool of monetary policy that has the potential to increase the degree of monetary policy
accommodation, especially when interest rates are essentially at their zero lower bound. By reducing
uncertainty about the future path of policy, forward guidance helps lower interest rates by reducing the
premiums investors demand to compensate them for interest-rate uncertainty.

In addition, in theory, if the central bank indicates that the future path of short-term interest rates will be
low for a long time – perhaps lower and for longer than would have been consistent with the central
bank’s past behavior – this can also put downward pressure on longer-term interest rates, thereby spurring
current economic activity. According to the theory, if people believe that the central bank will keep rates
very low, they will expect higher economic activity and higher inflation in the future. When households,
businesses, and market participants are assured of better economic prospects in the future, they should be

6
more willing to make investments in capital and labor today rather than delaying them, and this will help
the current economy.

Note, though, that for forward guidance to have this effect, the public must believe that the central bank is
setting policy differently than it has in the past and also that the central bank is committed to
implementing this particular policy. If, instead, the public believes that the central bank is behaving as
usual, it could misinterpret a very low policy rate as suggesting a gloomier outlook, and this would work
to depress current activity – the exact opposite of the intended effect. In addition, before they will change
their behavior and start spending today, households and firms have to believe that the central bank is
committed to behaving in this unusual way. How to increase the credibility of such a commitment
continues to be a subject of economic research.2

Forward Guidance in Normal Times
So, in extraordinary economic times, forward guidance can be viewed as an additional monetary policy
tool. But in more normal times, away from the zero lower bound, I view forward guidance more as a
communications device that conveys to the public how policy is likely to respond to changes in economic
conditions. In other words, in normal times, forward guidance will focus less on when policy will be
changed or even the particular path of future policy, and more on the rationale for policy decisions. To
the extent that households and businesses understand how policymakers are likely to react to economic
developments – whether anticipated or unanticipated – their policy expectations will better align with
those of policymakers. As I discussed earlier, this alignment can make policy more effective.

2

The literature has suggested different mechanisms for increasing the credibility of this commitment, including
temporarily increasing the inflation target, targeting nominal GDP instead of inflation, and targeting the price level
instead of inflation. For an excellent discussion of forward guidance, as well as other policies at the zero lower
bound, see Michael Woodford, “Methods of Policy Accommodation at the Interest-Rate Lower Bound,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, WY, 2012
(www.kc.frb.org/publicat/sympos/2012/Woodford_final.pdf).

7
In the late 1980s and 1990s, the public had a pretty good sense of how the FOMC’s policy would respond
to economic developments, the so-called reaction function. They were able to get a handle on the
FOMC’s reaction function because after the great inflation of the 1970s, the FOMC became more
predictable and systematic in how it reacted to changes in economic activity and inflation.3 As a result,
forward guidance was rarely used.

But the Great Recession required the Fed to behave in a way quite distinct from its past behavior, and
consequently, there is less understanding about how policymakers are likely to react to incoming
economic information than there was earlier. So in my view taking steps to enhance the public’s ability
to understand the rationale behind the FOMC’s decisions has value. As our economy returns to normal, I
would like the forward guidance used during the extraordinary times of the past six years to evolve into
our offering a clearer sense of the FOMC’s reaction function.

I believe the FOMC’s Summary of Economic Projections, with suitable amendments, could play a central
role in helping the public better understand how policy is likely to respond to economic developments.
Before I offer three possible avenues for consideration, let me again note that these are my own views and
do not necessarily represent the views of my colleagues on the FOMC, including those who serve with
me on the FOMC’s subcommittee on communications.

Right now, the SEP provides information on the range of projections of real output growth, the
unemployment rate, and inflation across participants, as well as the policy paths that individual
participants view as appropriate for achieving those projections. But there is no linkage across the
variables. For example, there is no way to see whether a person low in the range of unemployment rate

3

For a discussion, see John B. Taylor, “Monetary Policy During the Past 30 Years with Lessons for the Next 30
Years,” luncheon address at the Cato Institute’s 30th Annual Monetary Conference on Money, Markets and
Government: The Next 30 Years, Washington, D.C., November 15, 2012.

8
forecasts is high in the range of inflation projections. Rather than presenting ranges, the SEP could be
enhanced by linking the variables for each participant’s projection so that the public could see what each
policymaker is projecting for growth, unemployment, and inflation, and what policy path he or she
believes will achieve those outcomes. This could be done without revealing the identities of the
participants and would convey information on each individual policymaker’s reaction function.

A second enhancement would be to more plainly communicate the degree of uncertainty around the
projections. Currently, the divergence of views among participants is presented in the SEP. But the
divergence across projections is different from the uncertainty any one individual would put around his or
her outlook. Even if there were no divergence, so that each participant was projecting the same economic
outcome and policy path, it would be incorrect to assume that the participants were therefore certain about
that outcome or policy path. The SEP does give a sense of the number of participants who see balanced
risks around their projections and whether the degree of uncertainty is higher or lower than average. But
giving the public a better sense of the probabilities associated with the projections would be valuable.

That brings me to a third potential avenue to help clarify communications. While the SEP provides
important information on the diversity of views among participants, trying to increase the information we
provide on the consensus view would be worthwhile. It is the consensus view that is reflected in the
policy statement after FOMC meetings. Presenting more information on the consensus economic outlook
that underlies the Committee’s policy decisions would help clarify the statement. I realize this will not be
an easy task. The Committee experimented with developing a consensus forecast in 2012.4 It turned out
not to be the right time because policy comprised several elements, including the funds rate path, asset
purchases, and forward guidance, as well as the fact that there was considerable diversity of views about
the economy’s structure and dynamics during those extraordinary economic times. However, we will

4

See the minutes from the July, September, and October 2012 FOMC meetings
(www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomccalendars.htm#11655).

9
eventually return to a more normal policy-setting environment, and in such an environment, the
Committee might be more successful in developing such a consensus forecast, which could form a basis
for explaining policy decisions and alternative views.

Forward Guidance Betwixt and Between Extraordinary and Normal Times
Of course, we are not there yet. So perhaps the more immediate question is what should forward
guidance look like during the transition from extraordinary times to normal times? After several years of
nontraditional monetary policy, the transition toward a more normal economy is likely to entail some
uncertainty about monetary policy setting. I believe clear policy communications can and should play a
key role in reducing that uncertainty. To that end, I favor the Committee being as clear as it can be that
monetary policy will be contingent on the state of the economy. I favor putting less focus on a particular
calendar date for liftoff. This is why I believe the FOMC’s addition to its forward guidance last week was
an important step in the right direction. It was a clear statement that if incoming information indicates
faster than anticipated progress toward the Committee’s employment and inflation objectives, then
increases in the target range for the fed funds rate are likely to occur sooner than the FOMC currently
anticipates. And if progress is disappointing, then increases are likely to be later. I think this is an
important message to convey to the public.

I believe it would also be helpful over time to provide more information in our statement and other
communications about the conditions we systematically assess in calibrating the stance of policy to the
economy’s actual progress and anticipated progress toward our dual-mandate goals, and to the speed with
which that progress is being made. That is, the FOMC should explain how and why we came to our
assessment that realized and expected progress toward our goals is pointing to a particular policy path.

I realize that there is a plethora of incoming economic data and information, and they can send confusing
signals. Our communications should help the public to better understand policymakers’ consensus

10
assessment of what is signal versus noise in the data. What changes in the data and other economic
information do we view as material enough to change our medium-run economic outlook or the risks
around that outlook? Systematically providing the public with such information will allow people to
anticipate how policy is likely to change in response to economic developments that affect the outlook.

Conclusion
In summary, I have laid out some possible improvements to the Federal Reserve’s policy
communications. Such improvements cannot happen overnight – after all, we have been on a journey
toward better communication for quite some time and I expect us to continue on that journey. Although
there is a diversity of views on the Committee, I believe there is enough common ground to encourage us
to seek progress along the lines I am suggesting. I believe our efforts will be rewarded because clear
communications will lead to better economic outcomes and help make the trip back to normal a smoother
ride.