View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

LESSONS WE CAN LEARN

Address by
Lawrence K. Roos
President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Before the
St. Louis Council on World Affairs
Stouffer's Riverfront Towers
St. Louis, Missouri
October 7, 1981

As we have a l l become p a i n f u l l y aware, i n f l a t i o n i s now the most
serious problem facing most nations throughout the world.

For those

i n d i v i d u a l s who have f a i l e d to c o r r e c t l y a n t i c i p a t e the course of
i n f l a t i o n , the r e s u l t has been capricious—and often disheartening—weal t h
losses.

Even f o r those who have attempted to a n t i c i p a t e i t s coming,

i n f l a t i o n has produced s i g n i f i c a n t changes i n economic behavior:

savings

and investment have declined s u b s t a n t i a l l y , p r o d u c t i v i t y has f a l l e n , and
f i n a n c i a l markets have experienced increased i n s t a b i l i t y and
uncertainty.

The general r e s u l t has been lower standards of l i v i n g f o r

the c i t i z e n s of t h i s Nation and f o r much of the r e s t of the w o r l d .
Today I would l i k e to discuss c e r t a i n aspects of the worldwide
r i s e i n i n f l a t i o n t h a t has occurred over the past decade and a h a l f .

In

p a r t i c u l a r , I would l i k e to share some personal observations and
impressions t h a t I gleaned during a recent v i s i t to the United Kingdom,
Switzerland and West Germany.
social and p o l i t i c a l

These observations concern the d i f f e r e n t

forces a f f e c t i n g the conduct of monetary p o l i c y

in

d i f f e r e n t nations.
There are three basic propositions t h a t I wish to stress in my
discussion:




First:

t h a t p e r s i s t e n t i n f l a t i o n whenever i t
occurs i s a monetary phenomenon; i t

results

simply from excessive growth of the money
supply,

- 2 -

Second:

that central banks are the creators of
money and, consequently, in spite of
monetary control techniques that differ
between nations, they are capable of
reducing, even eliminating, inflation if
they so choose,

Third:

that when central banks have chosen not to
contain the growth of money and inflation,
this choice has usually resulted from
pressures exerted by social and political
forces that do not especially desire price
stability.

The first two propositions are most easily demonstrated by
simply comparing the monetary expansions and inflation experiences of
West Germany, Switzerland, the United Kingdom and the United States over
the past fifteen years.
As mature, developed and open economies, each of these nations
has been similarly affected by a host of non-monetary factors, such as
the vagaries of weather, OPEC, and the general expansion of government
activities.

Yet, in spite of the commonality of these influences on

their respective economies, there are discernibly uncommon differences
between the four nations in the manner in which they have conducted
monetary policy and in the associated inflation they have experienced.
During the early 1960s, Switzerland had the highest rate of
money growth (over 9 percent per year) and, consequently, the highest
rate of inflation (about 5 percent per year).




At that time, the United

- 3 -

S t a t e s , i n c o n t r a s t , had the lowest rate of money growth (about 3 percent
per year} and, again, not s u r p r i s i n g l y , the lowest i n f l a t i o n rate (less
than 2 percent per y e a r ) .

Rates of money growth and i n f l a t i o n i n the

United Kingdom and West Germany f e l l somewhere between the United States
and Switzerland.
What a difference the past f i f t e e n years have made 1

Since the

mid-1960s, money growth i n the United Kingdom and the United States has
s t e a d i l y accelerated.

Over the past f i v e y e a r s , U.S. monetary expansion

was more than double what i t was during the early 1960s.

Money growth i n

the United Kingdom more than t r i p l e d i t s pre-1965 growth r a t e .
The patterns of Swiss and West German money growth over the past
f i f t e e n years stand i n sharp c o n t r a s t to those of the United States and
the United Kingdom.

The Swiss rate o f monetary increase has declined

sharply since the mid-1960s.

West German money growth has shown a mixed

pattern—sometimes sharply d e c e l e r a t i n g , sometimes sharply a c c e l e r a t i n g .
However, over the past f i v e years i t was less than i t s rate of growth in
the e a r l y 1960s.
As a r e s u l t of these divergent p a t t e r n s , while i n f l a t i o n has
averaged more than 13 percent per year i n the United Kingdom and over 7
percent per year i n the U.S. f o r the past f i v e y e a r s , Germany has
experienced only a 4 percent average annual i n f l a t i o n and i n f l a t i o n

in

Switzerland averaged a miniscule 2 percent per year.
Of course, over short p e r i o d s , non-monetary f a c t o r s can also
a f f e c t the rate of i n f l a t i o n .

For example, as a r e s u l t of OPEC, rates of

i n f l a t i o n increased dramatically i n a l l four nations from 1973 to 1975.
A f t e r 1975, however, the fundamental r e l a t i o n s h i p between changes i n the




- 4 -

growth of money and changes in the rate of inflation was reasserted.
Inflation declined in West Germany and Switzerland and increased in the
United Kingdom and the United States reflecting the different patterns of
monetary expansion in these countries.
This brief description of the interaction of money growth and
inflation demonstrates one point quite clearly.

Because West Germany and

Switzerland have maintained fairly tight control over the direction of
growth of their money.stocks, they have achieved relatively low average
rates of inflation.

This, unfortunately, was not the case in the United

Kingdom and the United States.

The important question to be answered is

"why the differences?"
I believe that the answer can be found in social and political
pressures that arise in response to temporary economic "discomforts"
which affect certain segments of the econonjy in times of monetary
restraint.

These discomforts, though painful, are a necessary part of

the process essential to winding down inflation.

They arise in the

following ways.
Monetary restraint designed to reduce inflation usually produces
some initial, but temporary; adverse impacts on employment and
production.

Higher unemployment and slow economic growth, however

temporary, inevitably generate sentiment to abandon policies of restraint.
For monetary restraint to prevail, policymakers must be prepared
to permit interest rates to fluctuate freely in accordance with market
influences.

Unanticipated fluctuations in interest rates have adverse

effects on interest rate sensitive sectors of society such as the housing
and financial industries.




They may also produce movements in foreign

- 5 -

exchange rates which can have a disturbing effect on export and import
industries..

These groups can be expected to react to their discomfort by

exerting political pressure upon monetary policymakers to retreat from
restraint.
Finally, stable monetary control subjects the government to
increased financial discipline.

It forces government to finance i t s

expenditures through higher taxes or through borrowing directly from the
public.
scrutiny.

Either way, the expenditures become subject to greater public
And such scrutiny and consequent discipline may not be

politically acceptable to those in government.
These social and political forces, arising as consequences of
monetary r e s t r a i n t , place enormous pressure on monetary policymakers to
abandon attempts to control and reduce inflation.

If, through the

political process, temporary economic protection of certain sectors of
society takes precedence over price s t a b i l i t y , the central bank,
irrespective of its independence, will find i t increasingly difficult to
maintain s t r i c t monetary control.
How these social and political pressures influence the conduct
of monetary policy is dramatically illustrated in the cases of the United
Kingdom, Switzerland and Germany.
The United Kingdom, since World War I, has faced changes in
worldwide economic and political conditions that have rendered some of
i t s economic sectors inefficient.

Instead of permitting these industries

to decline and new ones to arise in their place—a process that would
have entailed a temporary decline in living standards during the
transition—the political decision was made to protect the affected




- 6 -

industries.

Government expenditures and government deficits grew; their

costs burgeoned.

Ultimately, when all else failed, the government i t s e l f

entered directly into the business of producing goods and services via
nationalization of specific industries.
Concurrently, a constituency avolved whose primary goal was to
maintain high rates of employment at all_ times and to maintain the
existing standard of living despite declining demand and productivity.
Over time this constituency grew in political strength and was able to
force monetary policymakers to accelerate money growth.

This expansion

in money growth, and the subsequent higher inflation, did not result from
faulty techniques or perverse intentions on the part of the Bank of
England.

It occurred simply because the central bank responded to

ever-increasing pressures from the public and private sectors that
benefited from inflationary environment.
In Switzerland, the central bank faces significantly
kinds of political and social pressures.

different

For decades, Switzerland has

been willing to tolerate the decline of i t s major industries—agriculture
and watchmaking—as changes occurred in world economic conditions.

For

example, at the s t a r t of the 1970s, Swiss watchmakers produced about 80
percent of all watches made.

Currently, they produce only about 30

percent and this share is continuing to decline, as watchmaking has
shifted to the Orient.

The Swiss, in turn, permitted resources to be

reallocated into manufacturing and financial service industries, and were
willing to endure higher unemployment in the process.
Why do the Swiss place greater emphasis on price stability than
on employment stability?




First, much of the Swiss labor force consists

- 7 -

of s o - c a l l e d "guest-workers" who are c i t i z e n s o f neighboring nations.
Since temporary r i s e s in unemployment f a l l more heavily on "guestworkers", the p o l i t i c a l
lessened.

impact o f unemployment on the Swiss electorate i s

Furthermore, one of the most important Swiss i n d u s t r i e s — t h e

p r o v i d i n g of f i n a n c i a l services to the *rest of the world—owes i t s very
existence to the s t a b i l i t y of the value of the Swiss f r a n c .

Because

Swiss manufacturing r e l i e s almost solely on imported raw m a t e r i a l s , and
t o some e x t e n t , imported l a b o r , short-term f l u c t u a t i o n s i n exchange rates
have l i t t l e net e f f e c t on Switzerland's important export i n d u s t r i e s .
F i n a l l y , the Swiss government sector i s r e l a t i v e l y small and i s engaged
i n v i r t u a l l y no income maintenance endeavors.
Under these circumstances, i t i s easy to see t h a t , although
there are a few sectors o f the Swiss economy t h a t would b e n e f i t from
p r o t e c t i o n from the s i d e - e f f e c t s of monetary r e s t r a i n t , the Swiss
p r o - i n f l a t i o n constituency i s r e l a t i v e l y small.

As a r e s u l t , the c e n t r a l

bank i s free to control monetary growth i r r e s p e c t i v e of short-term
f l u c t u a t i o n s i n i n t e r e s t r a t e s , exchange rates or unemployment r a t e s .
West Germany l i e s somewhere between the United Kingdom and
Switzerland i n terms of f a c t o r s impacting i t s conduct of monetary
policy.

Although, l i k e Switzerland, i t i s a society t h a t is dominated by

the p r i v a t e sector, i t resembles the United Kingdom i n t h a t i t has
numerous income maintenance programs and a large government sector.
A l s o , l i k e the United Kingdom, Germany has i n d u s t r i e s t h a t are highly
dependent on exports and, t h e r e f o r e , b e n e f i t s from a lower f o r e i g n exchange value of i t s currency.

There are also short-run pressures to

maintain low i n t e r e s t rates to favor various
industries.



interest-sensitive

- 8 -

On the other hand, there are important factors in Germany which
contribute to the v i a b i l i t y of a n t i - i n f l a t i o n a r y policies.

The Bundesbank

is legally independent of the federal government; the prevalence of
"guest-workers" mitigates somewhat the concern over higher unemployment,
and Germany has not yet been faced with* the problem of declining
industries.

Most important of a l l , German citizens remember, either

f i r s t or second hand, the ravages of the hyperinflation of the early
1920s.

They are s t i l l w i l l i n g to suffer some temporary economic

dislocations to avoid a repetition of the tragedy of hyperinflation.
Thus, while there are growing demands in West Germany for income
redistribution and, therefore, for income maintenance p o l i c i e s , the
overwhelming p r i o r i t y is s t i l l to prevent an acceleration in i n f l a t i o n .
As a r e s u l t , the Bundesbank is free to pursue monetary r e s t r a i n t and to
disregard most of the transitional problems that may occur as a result.
What lessons can we in the United States learn from these
comparisons?

Can they be applied to our conduct of monetary policy?

F i r s t , the Swiss and West German experiences make i t clear that
monetary policy can be used to control and reduce the rate of i n f l a t i o n .
The Swiss and West German experiences provide good examples of t h i s .
More importantly, however, experience demonstrates that monetary
control is possible only i f the central bank has a clear mandate to
control i n f l a t i o n .

A p o l i t i c a l and social consensus that price s t a b i l i t y

is the primary p r i o r i t y and responsibility of the central bank must
prevail.
Third, i t is obvious that the larger the governmental sector
becomes relative to the private sector, the greater are the p r o - i n f l a t i o n




- 9 -

pressures on monetary policy-makers.
consciously desire inflation.

This is not because governments

Rather, i t is because inflation,

especially if i t is unanticipated, makes i t easier for the government
sector to expand i t s control over national resources and provide
politically desirable services.

The United Kingdom and the United States

are good examples of this phenomenon.
Perhaps the biggest problem that monetary policymakers face
today in the United States is that the constituency for sectorial
protection, the pro-inflation constituency, is growing.

More and more

groups, through their elected representatives, have been demanding
protection from adverse market pressures and interest rate fluctuations.
We protect the unemployed, the elderly and the minorities.

We protect

farmers, the housing industry, the automobile industry, the t h r i f t
industry and the bond dealers.

The l i s t can and, unless we do something

about i t , will go on and on.
Achievement of price level stability implies that all sectors of
the econony must be subject to market forces. It is the fear of these
market forces that produces powerful political pressures for protection
against inflation rather than elimination of inflation.

Once this

protection syndrome becomes embedded in society, the return to price
s t a b i l i t y becomes increasingly difficult.
We in the United States are presently at the crossroads.

As our

inflation-protected constituencies continue to grow, as they encompass an
even greater portion of our society, there will be increased pressures on
the monetary authorities to abandon their attempts to combat inflation.
The events of the past several weeks—the cries of anguish that interest




- 10 -

rates must be forced down immediately and at any cost—are a reflection
of such p o l i t i c a l pressures in action.
In a democratic society, even the t i t u l a r l y "independent"
central bank cannot remain immune from p o l i t i c a l pressures.

As Arthur

Burns has noted, the anguish of central*banking arises not from i t s
i n a b i l i t y to control money growth, but rather from the d i f f i c u l t i e s that
central bankers have in overcoming the p o l i t i c a l pressures associated
with monetary r e s t r a i n t .
I f we pull back now from our current policy of monetary
r e s t r a i n t , we w i l l , once again, have acted to prolong and, perhaps to
i n s t i t u t i o n a l i z e i n f l a t i o n in this nation.

We must now choose between

long-term benefits for all or short-term gains for a few.
decision be?




What w i l l our