View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:30 a.m. EDT
October 12, 2017

Rethinking Monetary Policy in a New Normal

Remarks by
Lael Brainard
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Panel on Monetary Policy
“Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy,” a conference sponsored by
the Peterson Institute for International Economics
Washington, D.C.

October 12, 2017

I enjoyed Ben Bernanke’s paper titled “Monetary Policy in a New Era.” 1 He
presents a compelling diagnosis of the issues facing policymakers and discusses a variety
of policy options. Bernanke proposes an approach to policy that is elegant and
straightforward to communicate. I will focus on those elements that I find particularly
relevant for the challenges faced by policymakers and suggest some implications and
complications. My comments are not intended to address current policy. 2
The New Normal
Policymakers in advanced economies are confronting a different constellation of
challenges today than those that dominated the canon of U.S. monetary policymaking
over the previous half-century, which I refer to as the “new normal.” 3 A key feature of
the new normal is that the neutral interest rate--the level of the federal funds rate that is
consistent with the economy growing close to its potential rate, full employment, and
stable inflation--appears to be much lower than it was in the decades prior to the crisis.
In the Federal Open Market Committee’s (FOMC) most recent Summary of Economic
Projections (SEP), the median FOMC participant expected a longer-run real federal funds
rate, after subtracting inflation, of 3/4 percent, down sharply from the value the first time
the policy projection was published in the January 2012 SEP of 2-1/4 percent--and the
average value in the decades prior to the financial crisis of 2-1/2 percent. 4

1

Bernanke (2017).
I am grateful to John Roberts for his assistance in preparing this text. The remarks represent my own
views, which do not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve Board or the Federal Open Market
Committee.
3
See Brainard (2015, 2016b).
4
The well-known Laubach-Williams model currently suggests an estimate of the longer-run neutral federal
funds rate that is close to zero. The latest estimates are available on the Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco’s website at http://www.frbsf.org/economicresearch/files/Laubach_Williams_updated_estimates.xlsx. Over the 1960-2007 period, the real federal
funds rate--measured as the nominal federal funds rate less trailing four-quarter core PCE (personal
consumption expenditures) inflation--averaged 2-1/2 percent.
2

-2The low level of the neutral rate limits the amount of space available for cutting
the federal funds rate to offset adverse developments and thereby can be expected to
increase the frequency and duration of periods when the policy rate is constrained by the
effective lower bound, unemployment is elevated, and inflation is below target. In this
environment, frequent or extended periods of low inflation run the risk of pulling down
private-sector inflation expectations, which could amplify the degree and persistence of
shortfalls of inflation, thereby making future lower bound episodes even more
challenging in terms of output and employment losses. To the extent it is weighing on
longer-run inflation expectations, the persistently low level of the neutral federal funds
rate may be a factor contributing to the persistent shortfall of U.S. inflation from the
FOMC’s target. 5
Further complicating the ability of central banks to achieve their inflation
objectives in today’s new normal is the very flat Phillips curve observed in the United
States and many other advanced economies, which makes the relationship between labor
market conditions and price inflation more tenuous. For instance, inflation has remained
stubbornly below the FOMC’s 2 percent target for the past five years even as
unemployment has fallen from 8.2 percent to 4.2 percent, a level that most experts
believe is in the vicinity of full employment. 6
Bernanke’s paper provides an excellent review of the Federal Reserve’s efforts to
operate in this new environment and makes some interesting new proposals. Reflecting
on the Fed’s available “policy toolbox,” Bernanke concludes that the available tools are

5
6

See, for example, Brainard (2017b), Kiley and Roberts (2017), and Nakata and Schmidt (2016).
The inflation information refers to core PCE inflation measured on a 12-month average basis.

-3not likely to be sufficient and proposes a framework that relies on forward guidance with
commitment to help central banks achieve their inflation and employment objectives.
The Makeup Principle
The academic literature on monetary policy suggests a variety of prescriptions for
preventing a lower neutral rate of interest from eroding longer-run inflation expectations.
The paper argues convincingly that many of these proposals present practical difficulties
that would create a very high bar for their adoption. For instance, raising the inflation
target sufficiently to provide meaningfully greater policy space could engender public
discomfort or, at the other extreme, risk unmooring inflation expectations. The transition
to a notably higher target is likely to be challenging and could heighten uncertainty.
As I have noted previously, the persistence of the shortfall in inflation from our
objective is an important consideration for monetary policy. 7 The makeup principle, in
which policy would make up for past misses of the inflation target, is not reflected in
most standard monetary policy frameworks, although it is an important precept in
theory. 8 Some of the proposals that have been advanced to implement this principle
present some difficulties. For example, while price-level targeting would be helpful in
the aftermath of a recession that puts the economy at the effective lower bound, it could
require tightening into a negative supply shock, which is a very unattractive feature, as
Bernanke points out. 9

7

See Brainard (2017b).
See, for example, Eggertsson and Woodford (2003) or Reifschneider and Williams (2000).
9
As Bernanke notes, one way to avoid this feature is to adopt “flexible price-level targeting,” in which
policy takes into account resource utilization as well as the deviation of the price level from its target.
Kiley and Roberts (2017) examine a form of flexible price-level targeting—which they refer to as a
“shadow rate rule”—and find that it performs well.
8

-4Bernanke proposes a framework that avoids this undesirable possibility by
implementing a temporary price-level targeting framework only in periods where
conventional policy is constrained by the lower bound. Bernanke’s proposal thus has the
advantage of maintaining standard practice in normal times while proposing a makeup
policy in periods when the policy rate is limited by the lower bound and inflation is
below target. His proposed temporary price-level target would delay the liftoff of the
policy rate from the lower bound until the average inflation over the entire lower bound
episode has reached 2 percent and full employment is achieved. This type of policy,
which would result in temporary overshooting of the inflation target in order to make up
for the previous period of undershooting, is designed to, in Bernanke’s words, “calibrate
the vigor of the policy response . . . to the severity of the episode.”
The Normalization Bias
The proposed temporary price-level targeting policy is designed to address what I
see as one of the key challenges facing policymakers. Following deep recessions of the
type we experienced in 2008-09, there appears to be an important premium on
“normalization.” This was apparent in 2010, for instance, when there was substantial
pressure among Group of Twenty officials to commit to timelines and targets for
reducing fiscal support and to articulate exit principles for monetary policy. 10 This
inclination proved premature, as was evident from the subsequent intensification of the
euro-area crisis.

10
The 2010 G-20 Toronto communiqué indicated that advanced economies “committed to fiscal plans that
will at least halve deficits by 2013 and stabilize or reduce government debt-to-GDP ratios by 2016.” The
document is available on the U.S. Department of the Treasury’s website at
https://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/international/Documents/The%20G20%20Toronto%20Summit%20Declaration.pdf.

-5Moreover, the benchmark for “normal” tends to be defined in terms of pre-crisis
standards that involved policy settings well away from the lower bound, at least initially,
because it may take some time to learn about important changes in underlying financial
and economic relationships. For example, the factors underlying what we now
understand to be the new normal of persistently low interest rates were in many cases
initially viewed as temporary headwinds. In these circumstances, a standard policy
framework calibrated around the pre-crisis or “old” normal may be biased to
underachieving the inflation target in a low neutral rate environment. The kind of policy
framework that Bernanke proposes, which pre-commits to implementing the makeup
principle based on the actual observed performance of inflation during a lower bound
episode, could guard against premature liftoff and help prevent the erosion of longer-term
inflation expectations.
Monetary policymakers operate in an environment of considerable uncertainty
and therefore have to weigh the risks of tightening too little or too late against those of
tightening too much or too soon. While past experience has conditioned U.S.
policymakers to be highly attentive to the risks associated with a breakout of inflation to
the upside, as in the 1970s, they balance these risks against those associated with
undershooting the inflation target persistently, as in Japan in the late 1990s and the 2000s.
In weighing these risks, the standard approach is typically designed to achieve
“convergence from below,” in which inflation gradually rises to its target. Given the lags
in the effects of monetary policy, convergence from below would necessitate raising
interest rates preemptively, well in advance of inflation reaching its target. Moreover,
particularly in the early stage of a recovery, this kind of preemptive approach tends of

-6necessity to rely on economic relationships derived from pre-crisis observations, when
policy rates were comfortably above the lower bound.
During a period when the policy rate is limited by the lower bound, Bernanke’s
proposal would represent a substantial departure from the standard approach. While a
standard policy framework would tend to prescribe that tightening should start
preemptively, well before inflation reaches target, Bernanke’s temporary price-level
target proposal would imply maintaining the policy rate at the lower bound well past the
point at which inflation has risen above target. In principle, policymakers would have to
be willing to accept elevated rates of above-target inflation for a period following a
lengthy period of undershooting.
Just as policymakers could run a risk of low inflation becoming entrenched in the
standard preemptive framework, so, too, there are risks in the temporary price-level target
framework. One risk is that the public, seeing elevated rates of inflation, may start to
doubt that the central bank is still serious about its inflation target. It is worth noting that
the policy is motivated by the opposite concern--that convergence from below, following
an extended lower bound episode, may lead to an unanchoring of inflation expectations to
the downside. Still, a conscious policy of overshooting may be difficult to calibrate,
especially since the large confidence intervals around inflation forecasts suggest that the
risks of an undesired overshooting are nontrivial. A related risk is that the central bank
would lose its nerve: Maintaining the interest rate at zero in the face of a strong economy
and inflation notably above its target would place a central bank in uncomfortable
territory.

-7One additional challenge of the proposed framework is specifying a path for the
policy rate immediately following liftoff that smoothly and gradually eases inflation back
down to target and facilitates a gradual adjustment of the labor market. In the proposed
framework, once the cumulative average rate of inflation during the lower-bound period
has reached the target of 2 percent, policy would revert to a standard policy rule. 11 This
implies that a standard policy rule would kick in at a point when inflation is above target
and the economy is at or beyond full employment. Even with a smoothing (inertial)
property, a standard policy rule could result in a relatively sharp path of tightening, and
the anticipation of the steep post-liftoff rate path itself could undo some of the benefits
associated with the framework. Thus, there would likely need to be a transitional
framework to guide policy initially post-liftoff that might make both communications and
policy somewhat more complicated.
Integrating the Policy Rate and the Balance Sheet
The temporary price-level targeting framework proposed by Bernanke is
appealing on a conceptual level because it proposes a simple and clear mechanism to help
policymakers deal with the challenges posed by the lower bound on the policy rate in an
environment of uncertainty. The reality is more complicated, however, especially if, as
the paper suggests, many central banks in advanced economies are likely to operate with
an additional tool when the policy rate is constrained. In the paper, Bernanke cites Chair
Yellen’s 2016 Jackson Hole speech, which suggests that in a recession, the FOMC could
be expected to turn to large-scale asset purchases as well as forward guidance after the
federal funds rate is lowered to zero. 12

11
12

In the paper, this rule is specified as an inertial Taylor rule.
See Yellen (2016).

-8Today, when many central banks in advanced economies are operating with two
distinct tools, policymakers consider the effects of the balance sheet as well as the policy
rate in their assessment of the extent of accommodation provided by monetary policy. In
the United States, from the time tapering was first discussed to the September 2017
meeting, when the path for balance sheet runoff was adopted, FOMC minutes and
statements suggest that participants considered the degree of accommodation provided by
both policy tools in their discussions of the sequencing and timing of changes to policy
settings. Discussions about the sequencing of “normalization” and the delay of balance
sheet runoff “until normalization of the level of the federal funds rate is well under way”
effectively consider the extent to which maintaining the balance sheet may continue to
provide makeup support for the economy while enabling the policy rate to escape the
lower bound earlier than otherwise in a low neutral rate environment.
As Bernanke acknowledges, now that many central banks have developed
playbooks specifying the operational modalities associated with asset purchases, and
there is some familiarity with their effects on asset prices and financial conditions, there
is a greater likelihood that asset purchases would become a part of the policy reaction
function, along with forward guidance, during lower-bound episodes. Yet, as I have
noted previously in the international context, asset purchases can complicate policy
frameworks and communications, because their deployment and withdrawal has tended
to be discontinuous and discrete and thus may be associated with greater uncertainty
about the policy reaction function. 13 It appears the public closely follows statements
about both the policy rate and asset purchases to glean possible information about the

13

See Brainard (2015).

-9future overall stance of monetary policy. This suggests there may be benefits in
communications and predictability of a unified policy framework across the tools that is
more predictable and continuous. Relatedly, one helpful elaboration of the framework
Bernanke proposes might be to incorporate a unified measure, or shadow rate, that would
capture the degree of policy accommodation provided through the combined settings of
both asset purchases and the policy rate. 14
Greater Cross-Border Spillovers
Moving away from the policy proposal in the paper, there are two other aspects of
a low neutral rate world that I want to touch on briefly: cross-border spillovers and
financial imbalances. The new normal appears to be characterized by low neutral rates
and a weak relationship between overall inflation and unemployment not only in the
United States, but also in many other advanced economies with lower-bound episodes
likely to be more prevalent. The current environment appears also to evidence intensified
cross-border feedback into financial conditions. 15 In this kind of environment, it is
conceivable the kind of committed forward guidance associated with the temporary pricelevel targeting framework proposed by Bernanke, by helping rule out anticipation of a
standard preemptive tightening, could help avoid unwarranted premature tightening
through the exchange rate.
Given available data, it is difficult to disentangle whether the heightened crossborder feedback effects are attributable to the low level of neutral rates, particular
features of today’s lower-bound episodes, or the interaction of the policies adopted by
many central banks. In any case, recent Federal Reserve staff analysis suggests that

14
15

See, for instance, Krippner (2016) and Wu and Xia (2016).
See Brainard (2016a, 2016b).

- 10 cross-border spillovers have increased notably since the crisis and are quite large. For
instance, European Central Bank policy news that leads to a 10 basis point decrease in the
German 10-year term premium is associated with a roughly 5 basis point decrease in the
U.S. 10-year term premium; by contrast, these spillovers were smaller in the years
leading up to the crisis. 16
Moreover, news about policy rates and term premiums appears to have quite
different effects on exchange rates, such that the ordering of policy normalization can
have important implications for exchange rates and associated financial conditions, as I
discussed earlier this year. 17 Recent staff estimates suggest that news about expected
changes in the policy rate tends to have a large spillover through the exchange rate,
whereas news about changes in term premiums tends to lead to corresponding crossborder changes in term premiums, as discussed previously, with much smaller effects on
the exchange rate. Moreover, the exchange rate effect of changes in short-term rates is
much greater than it was pre-crisis. For instance, policy news that leads to a 25 basis
point increase in the expected interest rate portion of the 10-year Treasury yield is
associated with a roughly 3 percentage point appreciation in the dollar, which is three
times greater than the response pre-crisis. By contrast, policy news surrounding a change
in U.S. term premiums has a muted effect on the exchange rate both now and pre-crisis.
Financial Imbalances
Finally, a low neutral rate environment may also be associated with a heightened
risk of asset price bubbles, which could exacerbate the tradeoff for monetary policy
between achieving the traditional dual-mandate goals and preventing the kinds of

16
17

See Kamin, Li, and Rodriguez (forthcoming).
See Brainard (2017a).

- 11 imbalances that could contribute to financial instability. Standard asset-valuation models
suggest that a persistently low neutral rate, depending on the factors driving it, could lead
to higher ratios of asset prices to underlying income flows--for example, higher ratios of
prices to earnings for stocks or higher prices of buildings relative to rents. If asset
markets were highly efficient and participants had excellent foresight, this would not
necessarily lead to imbalances. However, to the extent that financial markets extrapolate
price movements, markets may not transition smoothly to asset valuations that reflect
underlying fundamentals but may instead evidence periods of overshooting. 18 Such
forces may have played a role in both the stock market boom that ended in the bust of
2001 and the house price bubble that burst in 2007-09.
The risks of such financial imbalances may be greater in the context of the kind of
explicit inflation target overshooting policies proposed in the paper. Again, if market
participants were perfectly rational, overshooting policies would not likely pose financial
stability risks. But the combination of low interest rates and low unemployment that
would prevail during the inflation overshooting period could well spark capital markets to
overextend, leading to financial imbalances.
Macroprudential tools are the preferred first line of defense to address such
financial imbalances, which should in principle enable monetary policy to focus on price
stability and macroeconomic stabilization. But the development and deployment of
macroprudential tools is still relatively untested in the U.S. context, and the toolkit is
limited. Although important research suggests that the situations under which monetary
policy should take financial imbalances into account are likely to be very rare, some

18

See, for example, Case, Shiller, and Thompson (2012) and Greenwood and Schleifer (2014).

- 12 recent research has pointed out that the case in favor of taking financial imbalances into
account is strengthened when the consequences of financial crises are long lasting. 19 In
this case, another complication of a persistently low neutral rate may be a sharper
tradeoff between achieving the traditional dual-mandate objectives and avoiding financial
stability risks, which may make it even more difficult to achieve our price-stability
objective.

19

See, for example, Svensson (2016). See Gourio, Kashyap, and Sim (2016) and Gerdrup and others
(2016).

- 13 References
Bernanke, Ben S. (2017). “Monetary Policy for a New Era,” paper prepared for
“Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy,” a conference held at the Peterson Institute
for International Economics, Washington, October 12.
Brainard, Lael (2015). “Normalizing Monetary Policy When the Neutral Interest Rate Is
Low,” speech delivered at the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research,
Stanford, Calif., December 1,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20151201a.htm.
-------- (2016a). “What Happened to the Great Divergence?” speech delivered at the
2016 U.S. Monetary Policy Forum, New York, February 26,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20160226a.htm.
-------- (2016b). “The ‘New Normal’ and What It Means for Monetary Policy,” speech
delivered at the Chicago Council on Foreign Affairs, Chicago, September 12,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20160912a.htm.
-------- (2017a). “Cross-Border Spillovers of Balance Sheet Normalization,” speech
delivered at the National Bureau of Economic Research’s Monetary Economics
Summer Institute, Cambridge, Mass., July 13,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20170713a.htm.
-------- (2017b). “Understanding the Disconnect between Employment and Inflation with
a Low Neutral Rate,” speech delivered at the Economic Club of New York, New
York, September 5,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20170905a.htm.
Case, Karl E., Robert J. Shiller, and Anne K. Thompson (2012). “What Have They Been
Thinking? Homebuyer Behavior in Hot and Cold Markets,” Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, Fall, pp. 265-98, https://www.brookings.edu/wpcontent/uploads/2012/09/2012b_Case.pdf.
Eggertsson, Gauti B., and Michael Woodford (2003). “The Zero Bound on Interest Rates
and Optimal Monetary Policy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring,
pp. 139-233, https://www.brookings.edu/bpea-articles/the-zero-bound-on-interestrates-and-optimal-monetary-policy.
Gerdrup, Karsten R., Frank Hansen, Tord Krogh, and Junior Maib (2017). “Leaning
against the Wind When Credit Bites Back,” International Journal of Central
Banking, September, www.ijcb.org/journal/ijcb17q3a8.htm.
Gourio, Francois, Anil K. Kashyap, and Jae Sim (2016). “The Tradeoffs in Leaning
against the Wind,” paper presented at the 17th Jacques Polak Annual Research
Conference, sponsored by the International Monetary Fund, Washington,

- 14 November
3, https://www.imf.org/external/np/res/seminars/2016/arc/pdf/Kashyap_et_al_Ses
sion1.pdf.
Greenwood, Robin, and Andrei Shleifer (2014). “Expectations of Returns and Expected
Returns,” Review of Financial Studies, vol. 27 (March), pp. 714-46.
Kamin, Steven B., Canlin Li, and Marius D. Rodriguez (forthcoming). “International
Spillovers from Conventional and Unconventional Monetary Policy,” IFDP
Notes. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Kiley, Michael T., and John M. Roberts (2017). “Monetary Policy in a Low Interest
Rate World,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2017-080. Washington:
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
August, https://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2017.080.
Krippner, Leo (2016). “Documentation for Measures of Monetary Policy,” Reserve Bank
of New Zealand Working Paper. Wellington, New Zealand: Reserve Bank of
New Zealand, July, https://www.rbnz.govt.nz//media/ReserveBank/Files/Publications/Research/Additional%20research/Leo%2
0Krippner/5892888.pdf?la=en.
Nakata, Taisuke, and Sebastian Schmidt (2016). “The Risk-Adjusted Monetary Policy
Rule,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2016-061. Washington: Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, July,
https://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2016.061.
Reifschneider, David, and John C. Williams (2000). “Three Lessons for Monetary Policy
in a Low-Inflation Era,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 32
(November), pp. 936-66.
Svensson, Lars E. (2016). “Cost-Benefit Analysis of Leaning against the Wind,” NBER
Working Papers Series 21902. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research, January.
Wu, Jing Cynthia, and Fan Dora Xia (2016). “Measuring the Macroeconomic Impact of
Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound,” Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, vol. 48 (March-April), pp. 253-91.
Yellen, Janet L. (2016). “The Federal Reserve’s Monetary Policy Toolkit: Past, Present,
and Future,” speech at “Designing Resilient Monetary Policy Frameworks for the
Future,” a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
held in Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August
26, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20160826a.htm.