View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
3:00 p.m. EST
November 28, 2022

What Can We Learn from the Pandemic and the War
about Supply Shocks, Inflation, and Monetary Policy?

Remarks by
Lael Brainard
Vice Chair
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Prepared for the conference volume of the
21st BIS Annual Conference
Central Banking after the Pandemic: Challenges Ahead
Bank for International Settlements
Basel, Switzerland

Policymakers and researchers have begun reassessing certain features of the economy
and monetary policy in light of recent experience. After several decades in which supply was
highly elastic and inflation was low and relatively stable, a series of supply shocks associated
with the pandemic and Russia’s war against Ukraine have contributed to high inflation, in
combination with a very rapid recovery in demand. The experience with the pandemic and the
war highlights the challenges for monetary policy in responding to a protracted series of adverse
supply shocks. In addition, to the extent that the lower elasticity of supply we have seen recently
could become more common due to challenges such as demographics, deglobalization, and
climate change, it could herald a shift to an environment characterized by more volatile inflation
compared with the preceding few decades. 1
Inflation in the United States and many countries around the world is very high (figure 1).
While both demand and supply are contributing to high inflation, it is the relative inelasticity of
supply in key sectors that most clearly distinguishes the pandemic- and war-affected period of
the past three years from the preceding 30 years of the Great Moderation. 2 Interestingly,

I am grateful to Kurt Lewis of the Federal Reserve Board for his assistance in preparing this text and to Kenneth
Eva for preparing the figures. This text updates the views that I discussed as part of a panel at the BIS Annual
Meeting on June 24, 2022. These views are my own and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve
Board or the Federal Open Market Committee.
2
Research has generated a range of estimates on the contributions from supply and demand factors. For example,
Shapiro (2022) finds that demand factors are responsible for about one-third of the surge in inflation above the prepandemic trend, while di Giovanni and others (2022) find a number closer to two-thirds. See Adam Shapiro (2022),
“How Much Do Supply and Demand Drive Inflation?” FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-15 (San Francisco: Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco, June), https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/june/how-much-do-supply-and-demand-drive-inflation; and Julian di Giovanni, Sebnem Kalemli-Ozcan,
Alvaro Silva, and Muhammed Yildirim (2022), “Global Supply Chain Pressures, International Trade, and Inflation,”
paper presented at the ECB Forum on Central Banking 2022, Sintra, Portugal, June 27–29,
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/conferences/ecbforum/shared/pdf/2022/Kalemli-Oezcan_paper.pdf.
1

inflation is broadly higher throughout much of the global economy, and even jurisdictions that
began raising rates forcefully in 2021 have not stemmed the global inflationary tide. 3
In the United States, as a result of significant fiscal and monetary support, the level of
private domestic final purchases recovered extremely rapidly in 2020 and 2021 to levels
consistent with the pre-pandemic trend before moving below trend in 2022 (figure 2). Although
demand came in near the pre-pandemic trend on an aggregate level, the pandemic induced a shift
in composition that concentrated large increases in demand in certain sectors where the supply
response was constrained. The shift in consumption from services to goods was so pronounced
that—despite plunging at the onset of the pandemic in March 2020—real spending on goods had
already risen nearly 4 percent above its pre-pandemic trend by June of that year. While a very
slow rotation back toward pre-pandemic patterns of consumption has been under way for over a
year, it remains incomplete more than two and a half years after the initial shutdown: In the
most recent data, the level of goods spending remains 6 percent above the level implied by its
pre-pandemic trend, while services spending remains a little more than 2 percent below its prepandemic trend (figure 3).
The supply shocks to goods, labor, and commodities have been accompanied by
unusually high volatility in monthly inflation readings since the beginning of the pandemic.
Since March 2020, the standard deviation of month-over-month core inflation has been 0.22
percentage point—a level of variation not seen in a 31-month period since the 1970s and more
than double the standard deviation in monthly core inflation from 1990 to 2019. The initial
The median year-to-date total policy rate hike within the group of Brazil, Hungary, New Zealand, Norway, Peru,
Poland, and South Korea is 6 percentage points. All of these countries began forceful rate hikes in 2021, and the
cumulative hikes have taken policy rates in some of these countries above 10 percent. Despite this, through
September 2022 core inflation in these countries was 9.5 percent year-over-year, rising 3.5 percentage points since
March. See Economist (2022), “Even Super-Tight Policy Is Not Bringing Down Inflation,” October 28,
https://www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2022/10/23/even-super-tight-policy-is-not-bringing-downinflation.
3

drivers of this high variation in monthly core inflation readings were a sharp drop in prices and
subsequent bounceback in the first months of the pandemic, followed by a couple of bursts
lasting three to four months each. The first burst occurred around reopening in the spring of
2021, and the second occurred amid the effects of the Delta and Omicron COVID-19 variants in
the autumn of 2021 (figure 4). 4
The evidence suggests that high concentrations of demand in sectors such as appliances,
housing, and motor vehicles—where supply was constrained by the effects of the pandemic—
played an important role initially in generating inflationary pressures. Acute constraints on
shipping and on the supply of nonsubstitutable intermediate inputs like semiconductors were
compounded by acute constraints on labor supply associated with the effects of the Delta and
Omicron variants and later compounded further by sharp commodities supply shocks associated
with Russia’s war on Ukraine.
The standard monetary policy prescription is to “look through” supply shocks, such as
commodities price shocks or shutdowns of ports or semiconductor plants, that are not assessed to
leave a lasting imprint on potential output. 5 In contrast, if supply shocks durably lower potential
output such that the economy is operating above potential, monetary policy tightening is
necessary to bring demand into alignment with the economy’s reduced productive capacity.

Pandemic fiscal measures played an important role in boosting demand, but the rapid deceleration of inflation over
the summer of 2021 and subsequent rebound in inflation from October through the end of the year do not line up
well with the fiscal demand impulse projected by most forecasters. For example, the Brookings Institution projected
a smooth demand impulse from the American Rescue Plan that peaked at the end of last year. See Wendy Edelberg
and Louise Sheiner (2021), “The Macroeconomic Implications of Biden’s $1.9 Trillion Fiscal Package,” Brookings
Institution, Up Front (blog), January 28, https://www.brookings.edu/blog/up-front/2021/01/28/the-macroeconomicimplications-of-bidens-1-9-trillion-fiscal-package.
5
See, for instance, Martin Bodenstein, Christopher J. Erceg, and Luca Guerrieri (2008), “Optimal Monetary Policy
with Distinct Core and Headline Inflation Rates,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 55 (October), pp. S18–33.
4

Importantly, and separately from the implications for potential output, monetary policy should
respond strongly if supply shocks risk de-anchoring inflation expectations. 6
Although these tenets of monetary policy sound relatively straightforward in theory, they
are challenging to assess and implement in practice. It is difficult to assess potential output and
the output gap in real time, as has been extensively documented by research. 7 This is especially
true in an environment of high uncertainty. The level of uncertainty around the output gap varies
considerably over time, and research suggests that more muted policy reactions are warranted
when uncertainty about the output gap is high. 8 The unexpectedly long-lasting global pandemic
and the sharp disruptions to commodities associated with Russia’s war against Ukraine have
contributed to substantial uncertainty (figure 5).
Even so, the drawn-out sequence of shocks to the supply of labor, commodities, and key
intermediate inputs, such as semiconductors, blurred the lines about what constitutes a temporary
shock as opposed to a persistent shock to potential output. Even when each individual supply
shock fades over time and behaves like a temporary shock on its own, a drawn-out sequence of
adverse supply shocks that has the cumulative effect of constraining potential output for an
extended period is likely to call for monetary policy tightening to restore balance between
demand and supply.
Ricardo Reis makes the case that both these factors would have prescribed tighter policy in the current
environment. See Ricardo Reis (2022), “The Burst of High Inflation in 2021–22: How and Why Did We Get
Here?” CEPR Discussion Paper Series DP17514 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, July),
https://cepr.org/publications/dp17514.
7
See Athanasios Orphanides and Simon van Norden (2002), “The Unreliability of Output-Gap Estimates in Real
Time,” Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 84 (November), pp. 569–83.
8
For discussions of the time-varying nature of output gap uncertainty, see Travis J. Berge (2020), “Time-Varying
Uncertainty of the Federal Reserve’s Output Gap Estimate,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2020-012
(Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, February; revised April 2021),
https://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2020.012r1; and Rochelle M. Edge and Jeremy B. Rudd (2016), “Real-Time
Properties of the Federal Reserve’s Output Gap,” Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 98 (October), pp. 785–91.
For a discussion of tempering the policy response to the output gap in response to increased uncertainty, see
Athanasios Orphanides (2003), “Monetary Policy Evaluation with Noisy Information,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, vol. 50 (April), pp. 605–31.
6

In addition, a protracted series of supply shocks associated with an extended period of
high inflation—as with the pandemic and the war—risks pushing the inflation expectations of
households and businesses above levels consistent with the central bank’s long-run inflation
objective. 9 It is vital for monetary policy to keep inflation expectations anchored, because
inflation expectations shape the behavior of households, businesses, and workers and enter
directly into the inflation process. In the presence of a protracted series of supply shocks and
high inflation, it is important for monetary policy to take a risk-management posture to avoid the
risk of inflation expectations drifting above target. Even in the presence of pandemics and wars,
central bankers have the responsibility to ensure that inflation expectations remain firmly
anchored at levels consistent with our target.
In monitoring inflation expectations for purposes of risk management, not only the
median but also the distribution of inflation expectations can provide important information
about how inflation expectations may be changing. 10 Survey measures suggest that the median
of longer-term inflation has remained within pre-pandemic ranges consistent with 2 percent
inflation (figure 6). However, starting in 2021, there has been a greater dispersion than usual of
views about future inflation in survey responses, as shown in figure 6. Although initially the
increased dispersion reflected a rise in expectations for significantly above-target inflation, more

For two recent examples of assessing longer-term inflation expectations, see Michael T. Kiley (2022), “Anchored
or Not: How Much Information Does 21st Century Data Contain on Inflation Dynamics?” Finance and Economics
Discussion Series 2022-016 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March),
https://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2022.016; and Danilo Cascaldi-Garcia, Francesca Loria, and David López-Salido
(2022), “Is Trend Inflation at Risk of Becoming Unanchored? The Role of Inflation Expectations,” FEDS Notes
(Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March 31), https://doi.org/10.17016/23807172.3043.
10
See, for example, Ricardo Reis (2021), “Losing the Inflation Anchor,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
Fall, pp. 307–61, https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2021/09/15985-BPEA-BPEAFA21_WEB_Reis.pdf. The Board’s staff recently updated the Index of Common Inflation Expectations to include
the 25th and 75th percentiles of inflation expectations over the next 12 months from the University of Michigan
Surveys of Consumers.
9

recently, following substantial cumulative monetary policy tightening, the increased dispersion
has also reflected increased expectations of no inflation or even disinflation. About one-fourth
of respondents to the most recent University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers anticipate that
prices are likely to be the same or below their current level 5 to 10 years in the future—roughly
three times the average fraction that reported such expectations before the pandemic.
Finally, it is important to explore whether any features of the inelastic supply response
associated with the pandemic and the war may have implications for potential growth and
macroeconomic stability in the future. 11 In particular, despite the unprecedented pandemic
policy support for businesses of all sizes that was directed at preserving the supply side of the
economy, key sectors struggled to ramp up activity after reopening. The supply response was
particularly impaired in sectors where supply chains are geographically fragmented and recurring
foreign COVID-19 lockdowns have reduced the reliability of foreign supplies. While conditions
have improved dramatically from some of the worst periods in 2021, measures like the Global
Supply Chain Pressure Index from the Federal Reserve Bank of New York indicate that total
supply chain pressures still are elevated relative to pre-pandemic levels (figure 7).
The supply disruptions in key goods and commodities sectors associated with the
pandemic and Russia’s war against Ukraine have highlighted the fragility of global supply chains
and the risks of inelastic supply at moments of stress. Conditions have improved dramatically
over the past year, judging by the return of the ISM Supplier Deliveries index to its prepandemic range of values (figure 8). That said, ongoing discussions about moving from “just in
time” to “just in case” inventory management and from offshoring to “nearshoring” are raising

See, for example, Agustín Carstens (2022), “The Return of Inflation,” speech delivered at the International Center
for Monetary and Banking Studies, Geneva, April 5, https://www.bis.org/speeches/sp220405.htm.

11

important questions about the extent to which businesses are likely to reconfigure global supply
chains based on a reassessment of the tradeoff between cost efficiency and supply resilience.
Similarly, some have conjectured that the slow and incomplete recovery of the workforce
over the course of the pandemic may be the beginning of a longer-term change in labor supply
dynamics (figure 9). 12 In addition, the potential for more frequent and severe climate events, as
we are already seeing, and for frictions in the energy transition could also lead to greater
volatility of supply. Together, a combination of forces—the deglobalization of supply chains,
the higher frequency and severity of climate disruptions, and demographic shifts—could lead to
a period of lower supply elasticity and greater inflation volatility.
To conclude, the experience with the pandemic and the war highlights challenges for
monetary policy in responding to supply shocks. A protracted series of adverse supply shocks
could persistently weigh on potential output or could risk pushing inflation expectations above
target in ways that call for monetary policy to tighten for risk-management reasons. More
speculatively, it is possible that longer-term changes—such as those associated with labor
supply, deglobalization, and climate change—could reduce the elasticity of supply and increase
inflation volatility into the future.

See, for example, Charles Goodhart and Manoj Pradhan (2020), The Great Demographic Reversal: Ageing
Societies, Waning Inequality, and an Inflation Revival (Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan).

12

Figure 1. Headline Inflation for Selected Countries
Monthly

12−month percent change
Canada
Euro area
United Kingdom
United States

12

10

8

6

4

2

0

2015

2016

Note: Data go through October 2022.
Source: Haver Analytics.

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

−2

Figure 2. Real Private Domestic Final Purchases
Quarterly

Billions of dollars

18000

Real Private Domestic Final Purchases
2014−19 trend

17000

16000

15000

2016

2017

Note: Data go through 2022:Q3.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

14000

Figure 3. Real Personal Consumption Expenditures
Monthly

Index
Goods
Services
Goods, 2014−19 trend
Services, 2014−19 trend

125

120

115

110

105

100

95

90

85

80

2018

2019

Note: Data go through September 2022.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

2020

2021

2022

75

Figure 4. PCE Monthly Inflation Less Food and Energy
Monthly

Percent change

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0.0

−0.2

−0.4

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

Note: Data go through September 2022. PCE is personal consumption expenditures.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

2020

2021

2022

−0.6

Figure 5. Diffusion Index of FOMC Participants' Uncertainty Assessments for GDP Growth
Quarterly

Index

1.00

0.75

0.50

0.25

0.00

−0.25

−0.50

−0.75

−1.00
2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

Note: Data go through 2022:Q3. FOMC is Federal Open Market Committee; GDP is gross domestic product.
Source: Federal Reserve Board.

2019

2020

2021

2022

Figure 6. Expected Price Change, Next 5 to 10 Years
Monthly

Percent

6

Median
Upper quartile
Lower quartile
5

4

3

2

1

2012

2013

2014

2015

Note: Data go through November 2022.
Source: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers.

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

0

Figure 7. Global Supply Chain Pressure Index
Monthly

Standard deviation from average value

5

4

3

2

1

0

−1

1998

2000

2002

2004

Note: Data go through October 2022.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

2022

−2

Figure 8. ISM Supplier Deliveries Index
Monthly

Diffusion index

80

Manufacturing
Nonmanufacturing
75

70

65

60

55

50

45

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

2022

Note: Data go through October 2022. The ISM Supplier Deliveries Index is an inverse diffusion index, a reading above 50 percent indicates slower deliveries.
Source: Institute for Supply Management.

40

Figure 9. Labor Force Participation Rate
Monthly

Percent

63.5

63.0

62.5

62.0

61.5

61.0

60.5

2018
Note: Data go through October 2022.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

2019

2020

2021

2022

60.0