View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

CURRENT BANK AND THRIFT ISSUES

STATEMENT BY

L. WILLIAM SEIDMAN
CHAIRMAN
FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION
WASHINGTON, D.C.

BEFORE THE
COMMITTEE ON BANKING, HOUSING,
AND URBAN AFFAIRS
UNITED STATES SENATE

10:00 a.m
Room SD-538 Dirksen Senate Office Building
January 21, 1987

Mr. Chairman, Members of the Committee:
We appreciate having this opportunity to speak with
issues important to the banking and thrift industries.
We have provided below our
At the outset, we also encourage a
industry with
the
intent of
supervisory balance. We hope such
future.

you

about

these

thoughts on each issue you have raised.
broad review of the financial services
achieving a proper competitive and
a review can take place in the near

FSLIC Recapitalization
The FDIC supports the proposal of the Administration and the Bank
Board to recapitalize the FSLIC. Quick approval by Congress is important
to maintain confidence in our financial system and reduce the ultimate
cost of handling failing savings and loan associations.
Because of limited resources, the FSLIC has not been able to resolve
problems in
a
significant
number
of failing savings and loan
associations. This condition cannot be permitted to continue without
seriously
impairing confidence in the financial system.
Moreover,
delaying the closing of insolvent institutions increases the ultimate
cost of failures. In some instances, imprudent management may succumb to
the temptation to take excessive risks, to roll the dice in the hope that
insolvency can be overcome. In addition, continuing operating losses add
to the extent of insolvency and thus increase the ultimate cost of
disposing of such institutions.
Failing savings and loans consistently pay above market rates for
their funding. This not only adds to their cost, it puts pressure on the
system as a whole, raising funding costs and cutting into earnings for
competing, solvent institutions.
For these reasons, we believe that
delay is imprudent, destabilizing and costly. The FSLIC recapitalization
plan should be enacted quickly; it should, in our view, be given the
highest priority.
Regulators* Bill
The FDIC continues to request the enactment of this proposal.
Emergency interstate acquisition powers will enhance our ability to
handle failed and failing banks with a minimum of disruption to local
economies and a minimum cost to the insurance fund.
Actions with respect to interstate purchases taken by a number of
states have reduced the urgency of this legislation. Currently, 37
states have enacted legislation providing for some form of regional or
national
full-service
interstate banking.
(The current status of
interstate-banking activity is discussed in Appendix A.)
Of particular
significance, several states that have had high failure rates are among




-

2

-

those that have adopted some form of interstate banking.
We applaud
these states’ efforts.
Unfortunately,
several
states with high bank
failure rates have not changed their laws. (Refer to Appendix B.)
In 1986, 138 insured banks failed and another seven were given
financial assistance to prevent failure. We expect a sizeable increase
in the number of failures in 1987. Along with increased failures, the
number of problem banks has also increased significantly. From just 200
banks in the spring of 1981, the number of problem
banks has increased
each year.
The number reached 1,140 atthe start of 1986 and climbed to
1,484 by year-end -- a growth rate of almost one bank a day.
Weaknesses
are likely to persist through next year or longer in energy, agriculture,
and real estate. Parts of the banking system will continue to be hurt by
these strains.
Competitive forces also have made it more difficult for
banks to improve profitability.
Such problems are exacerbated
by
geographic restrictions which limit diversification possibilities for
banks and can lead to excessive exposures to one source of risk.
Whenever possible, the FDIC attempts to arrange a purchase and
assumption transaction (known as a P&A) to handle failed banks. In such
transactions another institution purchases some of the failed bank’s
assets and assumes deposits and other liabilities. An acceptable P&A is
less expensive to the FDIC. It is less disruptive to depositors because
deposit arrangements of the failed bank are generally honored by the
acquiring bank. Also, many assets of the failed bank are retained by the
acquiring bank, minimizing disruption to the borrowers and reducing the
FDIC’s involvement in servicing and liquidating failed bank assets.
Finally, a P&A is responsive to the question of fairness since we protect
all depositors, thus treating all failed banks in a manner similar to
that required in handling very large institutions.
The increased numbers of bank failures, the geographic concentration
of banking problems, and the relatively large size of some troubled banks
are making it increasingly difficult to find purchasers for all failed
banks. As recently as 1984, the FDIC was able to find buyers for P&As in
80 percent of bank failures.
This percentage has declined to only 68
percent in 1986. Not only has the percentage of bank failures handled
through P&As declined but the price paid by the acquiring banks in these
transactions also has dropped. The average premium received in a P&A
transaction has declined from 3.67 percent of deposits in 1984 to 0.87
percent of deposits in 1986.
These trends have significant adverse
implications for the FDIC insurance fund.
Total purchase premiums
received on P&As in 1986 were roughly $22 million less than in 1984
although the volume of failed bank deposits was more than double. The
relative drop in premiums paid for failed banks
translates
into
significant additional costs to the insurance fund.




In order to enhance the FDIC’s ability to handle the growing number
of failing banks, we continue to seek authority that would:
Allow acquisition
failing banks;

by

an

out-of-state

institution

of

failed

and

-3-

.

Extend the scope of interstate acquisition authority to include bank
holding company systems when the failing bank represents a sizable
part of the holding company system; and
Provide the FDIC with authority to run a failed bank for a limited
period of time to facilitate a more orderly disposal of the bank.

Allowing acquisition of a failed bank by an out-of-state bidder
greatly expands the number of potential acquirers and enhances the
chances of finding a purchaser for a P&A. Increased competition among an
increased number of bidders will reduce costs to the FDIC. This is true
regardless of the size of the failed bank. The Regulators’ Bill required
that the
failedor failing bank have at least $250 million in assets
before interstate bidding would be allowed. Today about 95 percent of
problem banks are below that level with significant concentrations in
states that do not allow out-of-state entry. This size requirement was
intended to provide a transition from then current law. We now recommend
that the threshold be eliminated.
It should be noted that
size
limitations are rare among the many states that have enacted interstate
legislation. The asset size of a failed bank is only one measure of
significance -- and not a particularly good one in terms of assessing the
impact on the community served if a P&A cannot be achieved and a payoff
must be
made.The liquidation of any bank reduces banking services in
the community, increases local economic disruption, and increases costs
for the
FDIC.For these reasons our objective is to avoid payoffs of
failed banks whenever possible. We are making progress toward this goal;
the average amount of uninsured deposits in failures handled by payoff
(including insured deposit transfers to another institution) has declined
each of the last three years. (See Table 1.) Still, this is of little
comfort to the unsuspecting depositors with uninsured funds in such
banks.
Since the Regulators’ Bill was first proposed, a number of states
have passed laws which allow entry by out-of-state institutions under
varying
conditions.
Such initiatives have materially expanded our
options. During the past year, out-of-state institutions were invited to
submit bids in 35 failed bank situations, and submitted the best offer in
two instances. However, varying rules among states create administrative
problems and uncertainty for both the FDIC and interested bidders. In
addition, many of the states have incorporated reciprocity restrictions,
expansion restrictions or other constraints that limit the attractiveness
to many potential out-of-state bidders for failed banks.
The Regulators’ Bill also would permit the interstate acquisition of
failing banks.
We support this because, once a bank has failed, its
value to a potential acquirer can be substantially diminished.
In such
instances
the FDIC’s options are reduced and potential costs are
materially increased.
The Bill would also
allow
the
interstate
acquisition of an entire holding company when one of its significant bank
subsidiaries is failing. This is important because the economic reality
is that holding company banks are frequently managed and operated as a
consolidated entity and not as independent individual banks.
When




-4-

institutions
are
operationally and financially intertwined, it is
difficult to separate a single failed institution from the rest of its
family.
Last year’s bill contained provisions that would not permit expansion
in the state by the acquiring out-of-state institution until two years
after the acquisition of the failing bank(s). The FDIC would prefer that
there be no special delay for acquiring banks and that the new banks be
given the same rights as their competitors. In acquisitions involving a
failing bank, we continue to support a preemption of regional compact
provisions that restrict bank expansion outside the compact.
If Congress should decide that the legislation proposed as the
Regulators’ Bill should not be passed then at least the
expired
interstate provision of Garn-St Germain should
be renewed.
This Act
provided for interstate acquisitions of failed banks with assets of $500
million or more.
That provision significantly increased the FDIC’s
options in several bank failures.
For example,- early in
1986 the
interstate provision was used in a Florida failure and saved the FDIC a
substantial sum.
Even with interstate powers there can be situations where options may
still be very limited.
We have encountered situations involving both
larger and smaller banks, where material uncertainties precluded bidders
from making informed and intelligent bids. In these situations, putting
together a satisfactory P&A was very difficult or impossible in the short
time available.
What is needed in these circumstances is a method to "bridge" the gap
between the failed bank and an orderly
purchase and assumption
transaction -- a fallback position for the FDIC.
The FDIC seeks
authority to operate a full-service bank on a transition basis for a
limited period of time.
The objective would be to return the failed
bank’s assets to the private sector in an orderly manner.
Bridge banks
are not intended to be used frequently. The FDIC has no desire to be in
the banking business. However, in exceptional circumstances, this power
could be an invaluable aid in minimizing economic disruption and reducing
FDIC costs, particularly in handling major failures in the banking system.
As a part of the Regulators’ Bill, the FDIC continues to seek
Congressional confirmation that it and the Office of the Comptroller of
the Currency are exempt from budget apportionment by 0MB.
We strongly
urge Congress to include language to that effect in the Regulators’
Bill. Particularly during these troublesome times, we believe the FDIC
must maintain the flexibility to cope speedily and innovatively with the
problems in the banking industry. 0MB is attempting, for the first time,
to apply 36 year-old legislation to control the FDIC’s funds. There is
no justification for suddenly trying to do this now!
On a related issue I would like to strongly recommend passage of
S. 288 recently introduced by Senator Riegle. This bill recognizes the
importance of attracting and maintaining high caliber examiners during
these increasingly challenging times. Comparable legislation was passed
by a large margin (340 to 49) in the House last year and merits a full
hearing and passage by the Senate this year.



-5-

Nonbank Banks
Nonbank banks are the outgrowth of a loophole in the Bank Holding
Company Act, in which Congress narrowed the definition of "bank" to those
institutions that both accept demand deposits and engage in commercial
lending. By offering only one of these services, the nonbank bank can
carry out most of a bank’s principal activities without coming under the
restrictions and regulations of the Bank Holding Company Act.
Such an
institution is eligible for federal deposit insurance.
This is an attractive option for nonbanking firms and for bank
holding companies alike, as they can access new sources of funds and new
lending markets that, within the current regulatory framework, are not
available to banks. Through the use of the nonbank bank, nonbanking
firms can enter the business of banking without becoming a bank holding
company and therefore need not divest themselves of business activities
not "closely related to banking." In addition, bank holding companies
can avoid the Douglas Amendment to the Bank Holding Company Act and
overcome geographic restrictions against interstate banking.
Nonbank banks became increasingly popular in the early 1980s, with
applications for about 400 charters submitted to the Comptroller of the
Currency.
Nonbank banks have become increasingly controversial as well.
There is concern that nonbank banks pose a threat to the safety and
soundness of the banking system. Also, many bankers argue that nonbank
banks create inequities in the financial system because they enjoy an
unfair competitive advantage over "real" banks.
With regard to safety and soundness concerns, we do not believe
nonbank banks, if subjected to prudential regulation and supervision,
should pose any major risks to the system. Our experience is consistent
with this observation. The FDIC began insuring nonbank banks as early as
1969.
None of these institutions has failed and less than two percent
are on our problem bank list. This compares to a problem bank ratio of
about 10 percent for commercial banks.
Nonbanking activities of bank affiliates can bring the benefits of
financial
product
diversification
to
the
system.
Increased
diversification and earning power will reduce risk and increase earnings
in banking organizations, thereby strengthening the overall banking
system.
Such activities also can lead to increased competition in
securities, insurance and other markets, reducing costs to consumers.
Currently nonbank banks do not control a significant proportion of
banking
resources.
Available
data
indicate
that
they play a
comparatively small role in the system.
The total deposits held by
FDIC-insured nonbank banks, using the broadest definition of nonbank
banks, are only about $12 billion, about 0.6 percent of total domestic
deposits.
Thus, at current levels nonbank banks are not a serious
threat.
Nonetheless, we believe that the present statutory system is highly
inequitable and detrimental.
Allowed to grow, nonbank banks can weaken
the real banks by competing in an unfair contest in the market place.
We



-

6

-

believe that, within the financial system, institutions must be treated
fairly. We need a set of ground rules that are consistent and equitable,
not only because this is right but because it will strengthen the
system. The rules should be spelled out clearly, and they should be
enforced.
The question facing us, then, is how a fair and equitable
system can best be achieved.
Closing the nonbank bank loophole may arguably reduce or eliminate
some of the problems and inequities associated with nonbank banks.
However, if that is the only reform adopted, additional problems will
likely arise.
For example, a thrift loophole would still exist, which
will insure that inequities associated with nonbank banks continue to
exist
through
unitary-thrift holding companies.
Indeed, one such
institution, owned by a large automobile manufacturer, has deposits of
approximately $10 billion, a figure that is not substantially less than
the deposits of all FDIC-insured nonbank banks.
Grandfathering of existing nonbank banks also leaves inequities in
place.
As is currently the case, individual ownership of any combination
of bank, nonbank bank or other business would remain possible.
Simply
closing the nonbank bank loophole will not provide us with a financial
system that is both fair and consistent.
With regard to the so-called "South Dakota loophole," we find this
statute
objectionable and paradoxical in that it authorizes banks
chartered in South Dakota to underwrite insurance in any state but South
Dakota.
It should be noted, however, that no banks in South Dakota are
currently underwriting insurance while several major insurance companies
own FDIC-insured depository institutions.
Once again, the solution to
existing inequities may lie in the direction of expanding ownership
relations rather than trying to stamp out loopholes.
If we truly desire to level the playing field, a broader approach is
needed. We must examine more than just the nonbank bank or South Dakota
loophole in isolation.
We must also address the broader questions of
bank ownership and bank powers, in conjunction with a redefinition of the
term "bank."
We believe that all institutions enjoying the privilege of
federal deposit insurance should operate under the same regulatory rules
and ownership restrictions.
If restrictions are appropriate for one,
they are appropriate for all. Only when those who elect to have deposit
insurance also elect to operate under common rules and regulations can
the system operate fairly and efficiently.
New Powers for Banks
This brings us to the subject of additional powers for banks.
Currently a limited set of new bank powers is under discussion. These
powers include the authorization to underwrite and deal in mortgagebacked securities, commercial paper and municipal revenue bonds and to
sponsor mutual funds. If granted, these new powers could improve the
system
and
allow banks to remain, or once again become, viable
competitors in the financial marketplace.




-7-

These activities are not unlike many of the activities pursued by
banks today.
Indeed, they appear to be natural extensions of banking
skills and expertise, and probably would expose banks to less risk than
direct credit transactions.
Underwriting and dealing in mortgage-backed securities is a natural
extension of writing home mortgage loans.
The ability to package and
sell such loans would provide banks with greater flexibility. The power
to underwrite and deal in municipal revenue bonds is increasingly
important as these instruments (which were virtually nonexistent when
Glass-Steagall was written) continue to play a larger role in the
municipal bond market.
At the time Glass-Steagall was adopted, this
market was dominated by general obligation bonds, in which banks were
given permission to deal.
Banks are being increasingly and unfairly
forced from municipal underwriting. Morever, as more creditworthy firms
choose to raise funds by issuing their own commercial paper, banks must
increasingly look for other, perhaps riskier, loan customers. We believe
these new powers pose no significant additional risk, and can be housed
safely within banks.
In addition to these powers, we believe that banks should be
permitted to sponsor mutual funds.
The mutual fund market has seen
considerable expansion in recent years -- expansion from which banks have
been excluded.
Allowing banks to offer and manage mutual funds will
increase their ability to recapture business
lost
to
nonbanking
competitors in recent years.
This activity, too, is a natural fit for
banks.
Their experience with common trust
funds
and
commingled
investment funds has provided them with the necessary skills. And, as in
the case of such trust activities, we see no evidence of excessive risk
or loss associated with the sponsoring of mutual funds.
We believe mutual funds could be housed within the bank, provided
restrictions similar to those currently placed on trust activities are
required.
Banks should be required to provide adequate disclosure that
these funds would not be federally insured and that customers would be
exposed to risk.
In the interests of competitive equity and safety and soundness, it
is essential that banks be accorded new powers. It also is essential
that adequate supervision and safeguards be integrated into the system.
We feel that the list of new powers under discussion today does not
represent a comprehensive list of powers that could safely be granted to
banks.
Activities not permitted for banking organizations in the United
States in securities and other areas have been performed by affiliates of
U.S. banks in the United Kingdom and elsewhere in the world for some
time.
These activities have contributed tq profitability and they
generally have not posed safety and soundness problems.
On the whole, we feel
financial and financially




that banks should be permitted to offer
related services within the bank so long as

-

8

-

such activities can be properly supervised, and do not expose the bank
and the deposit insurer to inordinate risk. Additional activities that
may involve greater risk should be permitted for subsidiaries
or
affiliates of banks and bank holding companies with adequate insulation
of the bank provided by law. As long as regulators can take the actions
necessary to insulate the banks from the operations of a subsidiary or of
the bank’s owners, we feel there is room for greater expansion of the
permissible activities of bank owners and affiliates. A thorough study
of this matter should explore the possibility that any corporation be
permitted to own banks.
Check Holding Practices
The FDIC supports efforts to ensure that bank deposits be made
available within reasonable timeframes. We already have taken action to
achieve this objective.
In early 1984, the FDIC, along with other
federal regulators, issued a
joint
policy
statement
encouraging
depository institutions to review their current policies, to reduce
delays in funds availability where feasible, and to provide adequate
disclosure of their policies.
We also adopted a program for reviewing
and monitoring response to the joint policy statement.
We believe these efforts have proven productive and note that funds
availability account for under two percent of all consumer complaints
processed by the FDIC. Surveys conducted by the FDIC indicate most banks
give immediate credit to established customers, with delayed availability
applied only on an exceptional basis.
Also, a number of states have
passed
or
are considering laws that would require disclosure of
availability policies and/or establish fixed availability schedules.
(See Table 2.)
The FDIC believes considerable progress has been made to address
concerns about funds availability and that abuses are the exception
rather than the rule.
Nevertheless, we support federal legislation in
order to establish a national policy and provide a means for dealing with
abusive practices.
Federal legislation would also reduce inconsistency
caused by varying state laws.
The Fair Deposit Availability Act (S. 1841) proposed in the last
Congress would have required depository institutions to provide written
disclosure to customers of its funds availability policies.
We strongly
support this goal and believe such disclosures would enable market forces
to work more efficiently.
We also support the requirement that a
depository institution must start computing interest on funds deposited
by check or similar instrument to an interest-bearing deposit as soon as
it receives provisional credit for the deposit. We believe this would be
fair and present negligible credit risk to the depository institution.
The proposed law also would have required that deposits of U. S.
Treasury checks by established customers be made available for withdrawal
as soon as the depositing institution received provisional credit for
such checks.
This approach seems fair and reasonable. It would be




-9-

particularly beneficial for persons who must rely upon government checks
as
their
main source of income.
Generally, delayed availability
complaints about government checks involve senior citizens, where the
financial hardship is likely to be the greatest.
We do not agree with all provisions of S. 1841. The proposal would
have required the Federal Reserve Board to impose a precise funds
availability schedule on deposits. Given the diversities in this country
with respect to geographic location, transportation facilities, use of
technology, and structure of financial institutions, imposing a single
uniform availability schedule could prove inequitable and burdensome.
Moreover, the cost of imposing a quick availability requirement on all
deposits would ultimately be borne by all depositors, regardless of the
need for it.
The proposal also would have established an "Expedited Availability
Council" to consult with the Federal Reserve Board on funds, availability
matters.
We see no need for creating another regulatory council or
assigning the Federal Reserve an oversight role.
A more practical and
efficient approach would be to give the responsibility directly to the
respective regulatory agency.
Conclusion
The topics before this Committee are of the utmost importance to the
stability and well-being of the Nation’s financial system. I urge you to
give the highest priority to recapitalizing the FSLIC, providing more
flexibility to the FDIC to deal with current and future problems within
the industry and increasing investment options available to commercial
banks.
Although these are important issues that need to be dealt with
expeditiously, the long-term viability of the Nation’s banking and
financial system is dependent upon a critical and thorough analysis of
the current laws and regulations that govern banks and other financial
institutions. It is clear that current rules were developed in a much
different economic and legal environment and are no longer appropriate.
The FDIC stands ready to assist the Committee, in any way possible, in
developing a sensible and fair set of standards that will guide the
future development of the system.




Appendix A

CURRENT STATUS OF INTERSTATE BANKING
Currently, 37 states have enacted legislation providinq for regional
or national full-service interstate banking. (See Table A-l) Much of the
expansion in geographic authority has occurred during 1986 as nine states
adopted reciprocal legislation, while West Virginia, Oklahoma and Texas
provided for nationwide banking. Texas is the ninth state to have adopted
nationwide banking legislation.
Twenty-eight states have passed regional
banking legislation; nine of these regional laws have triggers authorizing
nationwide banking by a certain date.
Almost all of this expansion has
taken place in the last four years with the exception of Maine's national
legislation adopted in the mid-70s.
State actions represent a recognition of the new competitive environment
challenging banks and the consequent need for banks to diversify and expand
geographically. De facto interstate banking already exists to a large extent
as banking organizations have used nonbank banks, nonbank subsidiaries,
loan production offices, Edge Act subsidiaries, limited-service banks and
industrial banks to establish an interstate presence.
Another avenue of
expansion for commercial banks had been the emergency acquisition provisions
of
the Garn-St Germain
legislation; however, the provisions authorizing
interstate acquisitions expired during 1986.
Continuing economic problems in the agricultural and energy sectors
have also prompted several states to reduce interstate and intrastate barriers
to limit the negative effects of bank failures. Oklahoma, New Mexico and
Utah adopted emergency takeover provisions during 1986, bringing to eight
the number of states permitting nationwide takeovers in emergency situations.
The Texas legislature adopted one
interstate banking laws.
Banks from any
Texas banks as of January 1, 1987.

of the nation's most
state are permitted to

liberal
acquire

In California, recent legislation authorizes regional reciprocal banking
with eleven western states: Alaska, Arizona, Colorado, Hawaii, Idaho, Nevada,
New Mexico, Oregon, Texas, Utah and Washington. The California law triggers
to nationwide reciprocal banking on January 1, 1991.
Several states are expected to consider interstate banking bills when
the state legislatures reconvene in 1987.
In Colorado, the proposed
legislation is anticipated to take the form of a regional reciprocal law
with the seven contiguous states. During 1986, the Vermont House and Senate
passed different versions of regional banking legislation; however, a
conference committee was unable to reconcile the bills.
The regional
legislation will be reconsidered in 1987.
Iowa will also reconsider emer­
gency takeover legislation, which was narrowly defeated during the 1986
session.




TABtfl

Bank Interstate Expansion Opportunities
(January 15, 1987)
Nationwide
Unltd Reciprocal

Regional^
Unltd Reciprocal

Emer. Takeover
Provisions
National Regional

Non-bank
Banks^

Indus
Banks

Limited
Service
Banks

7/871

1/912
CO
CT
DE
DC
FL
GA
HI
ID
IL
IN
IA
KS
KY
LA
ME
MD
MA
MI
MN
MS
MO
MT
NE
NV
NH

7/871
-

X
X

X
X
X
X

-

-

X
X

X
X
X
X
1-

10/882

X
X
X
X
7/881
X

X

X

1/892




X
7/871

X
X

-

X
X
X
X
1/892

X
X

-

X
X
X
X
X

-

X

X
X
X
X
X

X
X

-

X
X
X
X
X

X
X
X

"X®
X
X

X

X
X

TABLE A-l (Page 2,)
Bank Interstate Expansion Opportunities
(January 15, 1987)
Nationwide
Unltd Reciprocal
OH
OK
OR
PA
RI
SC
SD
TN
TX
UT
VT
VA
WA
WV
WI
WY

Regional 3
Unltd Reciprocal
X

10/882
7/872

Emer. Takeover
Provisions
National Regional
X
X

Non-bank
Banks^

Indus.
Banks

Limited
Service
Banks

X

X
3/902
7/882

X
X
X

X
X
X
-

X
X
12/872

X
X
X

-

X

X

X
7/871
1/881

-

X

-

X

X
-

X *

X
X
X

X
X

^Effective date.
^Trigger date for nationwide banking.
^Anti-leapfrogging provisions are generally included in the language of regional banking laws. Only one state
-- Nevada -- of the 28 with regional banking laws does not have an anti-leapfrogging provision.
^These states permit the establishment of non-bank banks.
^Nationwide trigger dependent upon 13 states having nationwide reciprocal laws in effect; four of the 13 states
must be among the largest 10 states in terms of total deposits.




X

TABLE 2

STATES REQUIRING FUNDS AVAILABILITY PROVISIONS

Requirements

Californi a
Connecticut
Del aware
Florida
Maryland
Massachusetts
Montana
New Jersey
New York
Oregon
Rhode Island
Missouri
111inois




Time Limitations

Disclosure of Policy

X
X

X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X

X
X
X
X
X
X

X
X
X
X

TABLE 1
BANK FAILURES HANDLED
BY INSURED DEPOSIT PAYOFF
(INCLUDING INSURED DEPOSIT TRANSFERS)

No.

Total
Uninsured
Deposits

Average
Uninsured

Average
Size*

1984

16

$25.1MM

S1.6MH

J49.5MM

1985

29

S29.9MM

$1.OMM

-19.1MM

1986

40

$22.8MM

$0.6MM

31.2MM

*Deposits




California - 15 failures (8 in 1986, 7 in 1985).
In September 1986, the
governor signed an interstate reciprocal banking law between institutions
in California and 11 Western states beginning July i] 1987.
Nationwide
banking on a reciprocal basis will begin January 1, 1991.
Colorado - 13 failures (7 in 1986, 6 in 1985). Colorado has not authorized
entry by out-of-state banking organizations through interstate banking
legislation or emergency interstate takeover provisions.
During 1986,
the Colorado legislature failed to pass national and regional interstate
banking legislation; these bills died in committee.
In addition, a bill
authorizing emergency interstate acquisitions failed to secure passage.
Wyominq - 12 failures (7 in 1986, 5 in 1985). Wyoming has not authorized
entry by out-of-state banking organizations through interstate banking
legislation or emergency interstate takeover ~ provisions.
In early 1986,
a law was enacted waiving intrastate branching restrictions to permit the
acquisition of a failed bank and its subsequent operation as a branch.
Minnesota - 11 failures (5 in 1986, 6 in 1985).
In early 1986, Minnesota
enacted legislation authorizing regional reciprocal banking with Iowa,
North Dakota, South Dakota and Wisconsin.
In addition, the legislation
contains a provision allowing failing banks to be sold to out-of-state
banking organizations if an in-state purchaser cannot be found.
Louisiana - 8 failures
legislation authorizing
the District of Columbia
The legislation contains
1989.




(8 in 1986). In June 1986, the governor signed
regional reciprocal banking between Louisiana and
and 14 Southeastern states beginning July 1, 1987.
a nationwide reciprocal trigger effective January 1,

Appendix B
ENTRY BY OUT-OF-STATE BANKING ORGANIZATIONS
INTO STATES WITH HIGH BANK FAILURE RATES
Eleven states have accounted for about 80% of bank failures during the
last two years.
Of the eleven states, five — Colorado, Iowa, Kansas,
Nebraska and Wyoming -- have not authorized entry by out-of-state banking
organizations through interstate banking legislation or emergency interstate
takeover provisions.
Kansas, Nebraska and Wyoming do waive intrastate
restrictions in failing bank situations.
The remaining six states all acted in 1986 to authorize entry by out-of-state
banking organizations.
Texas allows entry on a nationwide nonreciprocal
basis.
Oklahoma and Minnesota permit entry by out-of-state organizations
in failing bank situations
if in-state acquirers are unavailable.
California, Louisiana, Minnesota and Missouri adopted regional reciprocal
banking legislation.
Triggers to nationwide banking are included in the
California and Louisiana regional banking laws and Oklahoma's emergency
interstate takeover legislation.
Texas - 38 failures (26 in 1986, 12 in 1985).
In September 1986, the
governor signed legislation permitting the acquisition of Texas banks by
banking organizations on a nationwide basis beginning January 1, 1987.
Reciprocity is not required.
Oklahoma - 29 failures (16 in 1986, 13 in 1985).
enacted legislation permitting out-of-state banks or
to acquire failing Oklahoma banks if no in-state
As part of the legislation, Oklahoma would permit
banking on a reciprocal basis beginning July 1, 1987.

In May 1986, Oklahoma
bank holding companies
buyers are available.
nationwide interstate

Kansas - 27 failures (14 in 1986, 13 in 1985). Kansas has not authorized
entry by out-of-state banking organizations through interstate banking
legislation or emergency interstate takeover provisions.
In March 1986,
the governor signed legislation permitting emergency intrastate acquisitions
of failing and failed banks in small towns.
Iowa - 21 failures (10 in 1986, 11 in 1985). Iowa has not authorized entry
by out-of-state banking organizations through interstate banking legislation
or emergency interstate takeover provisions. A 1986 legislative proposal,
which would have permitted bank holding companies in eight contiguous states
to acquire failing Iowa banks if no in-state buyer could be found, failed
to gain the approval of the legislature.
Nebraska - 19 failures (6 in 1986, 13 in 1985). Nebraska has not authorized
entry by out-of-state banking organizations through interstate banking
legislation or emergency interstate takeover provisions. A 1985 law waives
percentage-of-asset limitations on multi-bank holding company acquisitions
in failing bank situations.
Missouri - 18 failures (9 in 1986, 9 in 1985). In April 1986, the governor
signed legislation authorizing regional reciprocal banking with Arkansas,
Illinois, Iowa, Kansas, Kentucky, Nebraska, Oklahoma and Tennessee effective
August 13, 1986.