View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1

The Tradition against Rediscounting.
"It is a generally recognized principle that reserve
bank credit should not be used for profit, and tha ^ continu­
ous indebtedness at the reserve banks,

except under unusual

circumstances, is an abuse of reserve bonk facilities.
where individual banks have been guilty of such abuse,

In cases
the

Federal reserve authorities have taken up the natter -.vith officers
of the offending banks and have made clear to them that their
reserve position should

be adjusted by liquidating a part of

their loan or investment account rather than through borrowing.
Abuses of t h e privileges of the Federal reserve systen, how­
ever, have not been general among member banks.

The tradition

against continuous borrowing is well established, and it is the
1.
policy of the Federal reserve banks to m a i n t a i n ! i t ." In these
words the Federal Reserve Board described the tradition against
r ediscounti n g .
The tradition against rediscounting is a new n^me for an
old practice of commercial banks.
of the reserve system,

Long before the establishment

commercial bankers,

striving to accomplish

their two-fold objective of liquidity and profits, developed
certain principles and rules of thumb.

Among these the most

familiar probably is that certain ratios should be maintained
between various assets on the one hand and deposit liabilities
on the other.

A nother old rule which many bankers follow is that

their institutions should not normally be in debt to other
banks on loan account.




With the establishment of the Federal

2

reserve system,

o&nks simply extended this practice and strive

nor;;&iiy to be ’’even” witn the reserve banks,

that is to have

neither excess reserves at nor indebtedness t-: the reserve
oanks.

Most writers agree that the tradition is an extension
3.
of pre-federal reserve practice.
Periodically, as during,
roughly,

the decs-; e of the 2 0 ’s, reserve authorities ha e
4.
encouraged member banks to follow the tradition.
During the

war of 1914-191S and a gain in the 1 9 3 0 fs, however,

the pressure

of the reserve authorities on the member banks was all the
5.
other way, i.e., encouraging them to borrow.
The effects of the tradition are clearly reflected in the
money markets.

Mr. Riefler has shown that whereas "market

rates on acceptances have never varied greatly from the buying
rates established by the r e s e r v e

b a n k s .... other open-market

rates...have frequently ruled at levels sufficiently far above
discount rates to have permitted a wide margin of profit to
member banks if reserve funds had been borrowed for the purpose
of lending in these markets, while at other times they have
fallen well b elow discount frates.

It is obvious that these

rates in the short-term open markets could not have remained
so far above discount rates for such long periods,

if member

banks had borrowed freely fro m the reserve banks whenever tne
6.
operation v/as profitable."
Just because the tradition aids t o an understanding of
market rates,

it does not f o l l o w that the reserve banks may

rely upon it as an adequate instrument to restrict the volume




of reserve tank credit extended to the market.

The fallacy of

such a conclusion nay be illustrated • ith an analogy fron English
banking.

English member banks customarily do not borrow from

tne Bank of England.

Instead, they caLl loans

extended to the bill brokers.

hie); they have

The Bank of England does net

rely upon the custom of the English banks of not borrowing to
control the voluiie of reserve resources or the volume of credit
which it extends to the market, because it knows that the bill
brokers follow no such custom.

They borrov fro:., the Esnk when

borrowing is profitable; and they are d i s c o u r s e d by the Bank
through increases in the rate.

The basic instruments which the

Bank uses to control the volume of reserve resources and the
volume of credit which it extends to the market are the rate
and open-market operations, not the tradition of the banks.
The tradition merely influences who shall borrow, not how much
will be borrowed.

Yet it is the volume -vhich is of greatest

importance.
If one examines the reliability of the tradition as an
instrument of central banking control rather than as a
concept to explain money market rates, he notes a number of
important restrictions in it.

In the first place it is not

uniformly effective against all banks.
against many banks, no one will deny.

That it is effective
3one bankers, whose

institutions are members of the reserve system, take pride
in being able to say that theyfhave '.|ieve^ borrowed from the
reserve bank and insist that they^will never>do so short of
a catastrophe.




But this is not true of ail bankers.

Evidence

RATES

PROFIT

AND

DISCOUNTS

DIS- ••
COUNTS
100000000




MARKET RATE

BANK RATE
SYSTEM
DISCOUNTS

MARKET RATE
MINUS
--------7^ BANK RATE

/V

,'A

/

;

/'AAI

A

/

V,
NEW YORK
DISCOUNTS

1919

1920

1921

V

1922

1923

1924

1925

1926

1927

1928




4

may be cited to show that some banks violate the tradition especially when it is profitable to do so.

The Federal Reserve

Board reported that some member banks borrowed continuously in
excess of three times their basic lines of credit for several years
7.
after the war of 1914-1918.
In other words, some member banks have
not always availed themselves of the opportunity to reduce borrow­
ings instead of expanding loans.

Sometimes \lfrien the latter

8
is more profitable than repayment, some banks expand.

.

Tersely

stated, some bankers will violate the tradition whan borrow ing
is sufficiently profitable.

The concentration of borrowings

even in a few banks, however, is a serious shortcoming of the
tradition as an instrument of control over the total volume
of credit.

The following analysis will make this clear.

If

Bank A violates the tradition and borrows at the reserve bank
to fcxpand, it will presumably suffer adverse clearing balances.
The bank or banks to which it loses funds, however, will receive
them as new deposits and new reserves in due course.

These

banks may now expand without reeourse to the reserve bank.

2fee

expansion of these banks, in turn, will permit other hanks to
expand without recourse to the reserve bank.

Thus the violation

of the tradition by some trnnfcs makes possible a manifold
expansion of loans and deposits throughout the banking system.
All the banks save those which violate the tradition and borrow
» y

say that they never have recourse to the reserve bank; hut

their expansion i a b a s e d upon reserve bank credit waft the l e e s

b e c a u se i t i s l& d lr e e t *




Another nore serious practical difficulty is tLi-t it If
possible for banks to fellow the letter of the tradition (if
one may so speak of it) without abiding by its purpose.

Cer­

tain types of short tine borrowing which are not included in
the tradition but are of real importance in the control of
9.
credit are of this character.
To illustrate:
If bank A,
after being indebted to the Reserve bank for several days,
calls loans to repay the Reserve bank anc
discount;

and bank B,

of a few nore days,

in turn,

thus forces bank B to

calls loans after the lapse

only to force bank C into the Reserve

bank, no single bank will have violated the tradition against
continuous borrowing;

nevertheless, the total volume of dis­

counting may be continuously large.

The same consequences

follow if the action is not deliberate.

Indeed,

it is just

such circumstances which constitute a so-called legitimate
"emergency" which warrants a bank in rediscounting at the
Reserve bank.

It has been said that one of the basic

occasions for so-called legitimate borrowing at the Reserve
bank is the necessity of member bankd to restore inpaired
reserves.

Exc^t in unusual circumstances a banK whicn borrows

to expand its earning assets *111 not remain in good favor at
the Reserve bank.

Mr. Keynes says "...pressure is put on the

member banks to restrain their use of rediscounting facilities
with the Federal reserve banks by enticising them, asking
them inconvenient questions, and creating a public opinion to
the effedt that it is not quite respectable for a member bank




6

or good for its credit, to be using the resources of the
10.

Reserve bank nore than its neighbors.M

borrowing to restore

a reserve, on the other hand, is acceptable to the officials.
Yet the latter p e m i t s member banks a_s a whole to laaintain
an extended condition.

The tradition against rediscounting

does not meet tne problem.

It is also true that discounts and

open-market purchases do not exhaust the avenues of access to
the Reserve banks.

Purchased bi„ls constitute another avenue.

The funds which the Reserve bank withdraws fron the i.rrket
through a sale of securities may be returned to the market by
such purchases of bills at the initiative of the member banks.
Again, the tradition is not even designed to operate against
such transactions.
The tradition would seem to be effective against bankers
in proportion to their temerity and scrupulousness.

V/ithout

the use of other instruments (eg. rationing or threats to ration)
it would appear ineffective against the boldly unscrupulous.
If this be true, however, it tends to penalize those banks which
follow it for the benefit of those which do not follow.

The

followers do not borrow and make less necessajry increases in
the rate; but the advantages of the lower rate accrue to the
borrowers, who do not follow the tradition.
A third Serious limitation to the tradition is that it
is not uniformly effective in time.

As one analysis reserve

policy in the 1920*s it becomes clear that open market opera­
tions, the tradition, and the rate are intimately related,




Indeed, the theory of the tradition was developed to explain the
effectiveness of open mark e t operations.

At first some people

assumed that a sale of securities by the reserve banks would
reduce member banks*

feserves by a c o r r e s p o n d i n g amount.

was soon discovered,

however,

was a corresponding increase
the Reserve banks would

It

that frequently the actual result
in rediscounts.

In effect,

have to lend the funds which w e r e

used to buy the securities.

U nder these c i r c u m s t a n c e s , how

could the policy of contraction be served?

Hr.

Burgess answers

the question as follows:
The importance of the p u rchase or sale of s e c u r i ­
ties Mlies usua l l y in their effect upon the amount of
indebtedness of m e m b e r banks to the R eserve Banks.
By increasing their holdings of government securities
the Reserve Banks lighten the indebtedness of the m e mber
banks, and by selling securities they increase this
indebtedness.
The s ignificance of this operation
ari^ses from the unwillingness of the m e mber banks
to remain c o ntinuously in de b t at t he Reserve Banks.
Their lending and investing policy is very closely r e l a ­
ted indeed to the amount of such indebtedness.
"The principle of open-market operations m $ y be
summarized by saying that purchases of securities by
Reserv e Banks t e n d to relieve m e m b e r banks from debt
to t h e Reserve Banks, a n d lead them t o adopt a m o r e
liberal lending and investing policy.
M o n e y rates
become easier; ban k deposits increase.
S u c h purchases
tend to create a b o r r o w e r fs market.
Conversely, sales
of securities by the R e s e r v e Banks increase neriber
bank borrowing and lead the banks to ad o p t a somewhat
less liberal policy.
M o n e y rates g r o w firmer; bank
deposits tend to decline.
Sales of securi t i e s tend to
create a l e n d e r ’s m a r k e t . "
(11)
If one compares the reserve s y s t e m ’s h o l d i n g s of govern­

ment securities wit h the ra t e of discount, however, he
notes that all fc^preciable changes in t h e s y s t e m ’s holdings




8

In other words, when the systen wishes to tighten the narket,
^supports" the tradition by an increase in the raie.

it

It is also

significant that "Reserve credit is uore costly to nenber
banks when Reserve banks substitute rediscounts for other
12
earning assets."
Diagram 2 relates for the decade 1919-1928 profitableness
of discounting and volume of discounting for the systen and for
the New York member banks v/here orofitableness is measured by
13.
the difference between the market rate as corroiled by Riefler
14.
and the Hew York Bank rate. 'General conditions in the market
may be described as follows: first, there was a large supply
of short term paper in the market in which investments could be
made by banks;

second there was a cluster of money rates around

the bank rate; third, the discount window was active.

At that

time it amounted to around #500,000,000 plus at least $100,000,000
of reserve bank investment in bills.

These facts were related

not only to the tradition but also to the rate.

Had the rate

been higher, the volume of discounting would doubtless have been
less; had it been lower, the volume of discounting would doubt­
less have been greater.
significant.

The general conclusion is clear and

In general the volume of discounts vailed with the

profitableness of discounting.
few strategic periods.

Attention nay be called to a

Practically throughout both periods

(1922 and 1924) when borrowing was unprofitable, the volume of dis­
counts fell appreciably and continuously.

The period of greatest

increase in discounts (1919-1920) was also the period in which




y

discounting w a s most profitable.

None of the conditions of

the 2 0 *s obtained intthe 3 0 *s.
One nay summarise experience with the t r a d i t i o n as an
instrument of policy.

It appears most effective at the very

times that the reserve banks a re reducing rates and are otherwis w interested in expanding credit; a n d it a p p e a r s to be least
effective precisely when the other actions of t h e Reserve
officials indicate t h e y w i s h it we r e most effective.

This

conclusion is warranted from t he fact th a t the volume of d i s ­
counts, the number of banks

borrowing, a n d t h e rate roughly

paralled each other.
Therein lies the mo s t telling criticism against the t radi­
tion.

It is not s ufficiently effective to curb a persistent

demand for credit w h e n pr o f i t a b l e investments a re available.
If rediscou n t i n g is suff i c i e n t l y profitable,
indulge regardless of the tradition.

some banks will

R e l i a n c e u p o n it permits

a situation to develop in w h i c h it is n e c e s s a r y to adopt 110re
vigorous m ea s u r e s to a g r e a t e r extent t h a n might
sary had they been used originally.
the m a t t e r as follows:

have b e e n n e c e s ­

Mr. K e y n e s has expressed

"...measures of c a j o l e r y and m i l d discipline

might prove inadequate against a w i d e s p r e a d move m e n t of e x p a n ­
sion ascribable to the s o o a l l e d

’legitimate*

demands of t rade -

w h i c h are just as i n f l a t i o n a r y as the so - c a l l e d
15.
demands of finance, and m a y be more so."
In periods of depression*
are not anxious for




fIllegitimate*

on the other hand, w h e n bank e r s

examinations,

all t h e inconvenient questions

10

which the Reserve bankers asked t j discourage b o r r owing at other
tines will be recalled; and the m e m b e r
ing than ever to borrow.

At such tines,

that the tradition is effective;
public

baiks wi j.1 b e less w i l l ­
one n a y say,

perhaps,

but thr-t is p r e c isely when the

interest might be served better if the t r a d i t i o n were

violated.

At such times the Reserve banks reduce their rates,

yet such efforts to stimulate borrowing by direct appeal to
profits could hardly be expected to be successful - if the
tradition is effective.

In short,

the tradition has a reverse

effectiveness.
Hr. Burgess seens to r e c o g n i z e this.

A t any rate,

in

1927 he said that the feeling a g a i n s t b o r r o w i n g was encouraged
by the officers of the r e s e r v e s y s t e m (p. 182).

In 1936, he

added the significant q u alifying phrase "at tines"

(p. 220).

These factors indicate the w i s d o m of Mr. H a r r i s ’s sugg e s ­
tion:
"Reserve policy should a llow for the inability of
the member banks in the larger city, subject t o m u l t i p l e x
incomings a nd outgoings, always to b a l a n c e their hooks.
But when the ban'-cs
¡10 t h emselves in de b t for long p e r ­
iods of time a n d wh e n the number of banks in debt is a b ­
normall y large, there is something wrong fundamentally;
the difficulty is n o longer t e m p o r a r y d i s e q u i l i b r i u m of
the balance of payments.
The N e w Y o r k B a n k is will i n g
to discuss m a t t e r s ’.ith the m e m b e r b a n k s out of line;
but w h e n all banks a re borrowing excessively, the si t u a ­
tion is t o be m e t not by refusals but b y a higher rate."(l6)

U n i v e r s i t y of M i s s o u r i




Ka r l R. Bopp

1.

Annual R e p o rt o f th e F e d e r a l R e se r v e B o a rd , 1928, p * 8.

2.

A lthough s i m i l a r in in o o r t a n t w ays, in te r - b a n k l e a n s a r e to
be s h a r p ly d is t i n g u is h e d fr o n in t e r - b a a .: d e p o s i t s in th e
p re sen t d is c u ss io n .

3.

W. IV. R i e f l e r , Money R a te s and Honey M ark ets in th e U n ited
S t a t e s , New Y ork . 1 9 3 6 . P P .""S 9 - j£ ; •'/. R . B u r g e s s , The k e s e r v e
Banks and th e Honey M ark et, New Y o rk , 1 9 3 6 , p . 2 1 9 . K r . Ila rr o d ,
how ever, in Economic J o u r n a l , V o l. 37, p . 2 8 5 , a t t r i b u t e s
th e o r i g i n o f t h e t r a d i t i o n t o "a n i n i t i a l d i s t r u s t o f th e
new sy ste m and th e d e s i r e o f member b an k s n o t t o becon e
in d e b te d t o i t . "

4.

Se e th e open in g q u o t a t io n o f t h i s s e c t i o n . Se e a l s o
R. B u r g e s s , C£. C i t . , p . 220; B en jam in S tr o n g in 6 7 th
C o n g r e ss, 1 s t s e s s i o n , A g r i c u l t u r e 1 I n q u ir y , H e a rin g s on
S e n . Cone. R e s. 4 , /a s h in g to n , 1 9 2 1 , p a r t 1 3 , p p . 50b -5$7;
J . !•:. K ey n es, A T r e a t i s e on H oney, New Y o rk , 1 9 3 0 , V ol.
2, p . 240.

5.

C f. New York T im es. A u gu st 2 1 , 1 9 3 7 , A u gu st 2 2 , 1 9 3 7 ( A r t i c l e
by E l l i o t t V. B e l l ) , A u gu st 2 7 , 1 9 3 7 .

6.

W. W. R i e f l e r , Cp. c i t . » pi>. 2 2 -2 3 .

7.

Annual R e p o rt wf th e F e d e r a l R e se r v e ¿ o a r d f o r 1 9 2 2 « p . 3*

8.

W. W# R i e f l e r , 0 £ . c i t . . o . l 6 i ; S . 15. H a r r i s , C|>. c i t . , p . 1 5 ;
69th C o n g r e ss , 1 s t s e s s i o n , S t a b i l i z a t i o n . H e a r in g s on H# R .
7 8 9 5 . W ash ington, 1 9 2 7 , p p . 6 6 $ , 'ir>2-$73.

9.

69th C o n g r e ss , 1 s t s e s s i o n , Op. c i t . , p . 1 5 0 , te stim o n y o f
P r o f e s s o r S p ra g u e *

10.

J . M. K ey n es, A T r e a t i s e on Ilon ey, New Y o rk , 1 9 3 0 , V o l 2 , 2 4 0 .

11.

0j>• c i t . , p p . 238- 239 .

12.

S . E . H a r r i s , Twenty Y e a r s o f F e d e r a l & 66erve P o l i c y ,
C am bridge, 1 9 3 3 , p . 65T

13.

W. W. R i e f l e r , Money R a t e s and Money M ark e ts in th e U n ite d
S t a t e s . New Y o rk , 1 9 3 $ , PP* 2 3 2 -2 3 6 .

14*

T h is method kn ow in gly ig n o r e s th e f a c t t h a t even a s i n g l e
bank may b e a b l e t o expand i t s l o a n s by a g r e a t e r amount
th an i t s b o rro w in g s f r o n th e r e s e r v e b an k . S e e C. A. P h i l l i p s ,
Bank C redi t , New Y o rk , 1 9 2 4 , p p . 3 2 -1 2 0 ; J . E . R o g e r s ,
S p e c u la t io n and t h e Money M a rk e t. C o lu m b ia, Ho. 1927

15.

1 . J . M. K e y n e s, 0 j). c i t . ,

16.

S . E. H a r r i s , 0j>. c i t . . pp. 18-19.




V o l. 2 , p . 2 4 3 .