View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

LEARNING FR CM BANK FAILURES

For some time, certainly the whole time of my short tenure in office, I
have teen concerned and the Corporation has teen concerned with a single vexing
and overriding problem.

It appears slightly different to us in October than

it appeared in March; it may appear further altered in December.

But, despite

the fact that it deepens, or changes slightly in appearance as time moves on,
it is, and doubtless will continue to be, paramount in all of our minds for
the immediate future.

Because it also bears most heavily upon the general

welfare of banking, I have chosen to discuss it with you today.
Some weeks ago I stood outside the doors of a small country bank, looking
across the street at a group of weatherbeaten farmers.
me, and at the door of the bank.
closed.

They stared back, at

On that door was a notice the bank had been

It had, simply, failed.

It was a depressing emotional experience, with echoes of the depression
years.

The farmers sat around and watched the bank and insisted to anyone who

asked that theirs was a "good little bank, which opened after the depression,
and which would open again.”
Unfortunately that bank will not open again.
that farming community is ended.

Its career of service to

That bank, like seven others in the past

twenty months, had fallen victim to a new "virus” -- new at least in terms of
the past thirty years.
The bank did not fail because of economic strain in the community it
served, and there was little or no embezzlement in the ordinary sense.

If either

of these causes of failure had occurred, it would have been equally regrettable,




2

but we would have been able to diagnose the disease much earlier and we would
have been able to apply well-known remedies.

Additionally, economic failures

in general suggest that the fault is not primarily the bank's and that the remedy
lies in an improvement of the economy itself.

Where an embezzlement is the cause

of a failure, the mechanics of the institution are at fault, and mechanical and
technical improvements can be used in other banks to stem further occurrences.
Actually, in the past two decades, these corrective methods have been used
by various authorities to help stem the number of bank failures in the country.
Actions on the governmental level, private investment initiatives, monetary
policy, and other facturs have combined to create a healthy economic climate.
Concerted educational campaigns by banking trade groups and the supervisory
authorities, state and federal, have helped the banking system to devise and
implement sounder auditing and operating procedures.
The eight failures of the past twenty months, however, pose a problem
of an entirely different sort.

The problem confronting us is grave, even though

the number of failures is minimal when compared to the nation's over 14,000
commercial banks. These failures should not be dismissed; I believe that they are
symptomatic of some rather unhealthy tendencies, reverting in one form or another
to the excesses of the nineteen twenties.

I feel that we as supervisors must

take the lead in restricting these patterns before they swell into a disaster.
To understand what has been happening in banking, we must learn from
these failures.

Liquidating the banks is not enough; fulfilling insurance

responsibilities is not enough.

We must draw lessons from what has happened, and

we must act as leaders in modifying the environment that allows the virus of
failure to grow.




- 3 -

Eight hanks have failed.

I do not intend to give you a bank-by-bank

review, but I would like to consider several of the prominent factors which
run like a litany through most, if not all, of these cases.
Most immediately notable, of course, is that all these failures were
non-economic in nature.

In seven of the eight cases the communities enjoyed

healthy economic conditions, and in the eighth, while the area was somewhat
depressed, there had been no sudden dislocation of any sort.

There was no

economic reason for these banks not to have continued to flourish and serve
their communities successfully, returning a decent profit to ownership at
the same time.
Each failure was caused by a "raid.”

The banks were looted by promoters

through evasions of the law, aided and abetted in some instances by people
who should have known better.
believe, of significance.

The type of bank selected for raiding.is, I

With one exception, they were isolated.

They

were all small, and the managements were rather unsophisticated.
Five of them were the only banks in town, and there were no other banks
nearby.

Two of the banks were located in communities which had other banks,

but both served tight ethnic groups, and were in effect operating in selfcontained environments.
All eight of the banks were relatively small, with the largest at some
$35 million in assets when it was taken over by the promoters and about

$17 million when it was closed.

All the others ranged from $1 million to

at best $7 million.
All these banks in the past had maintained fairly good liquidity positions
and one an extremely good one, due to the ultra conservative policies of the
old management.




-

k

-

What kind of people took over these small, isolated, liquid institutions?
In seven of the eight cases they were outsiders, men with no experience in
banking, and obviously with little respect for, or understanding of, the
fiduciary role of banking.

The eighth case involved long-term management with

a good reputation, which apparently was the victim of a confidence game by
outsiders.

These were men of much the same stripe as those who actually acquired

control of the seven other banks.
In the banks where change of management took place the use of highly
inflated net worth, as reflected in financial statements, became the tool of
credit acquisition.
status was poor.
indictment.

The assets represented at best marginal holdings.

One individual had a criminal record.

Credit

Another was under

Several of the promoters had firms which were insolvent or nearly

so, and in some instances part at least of their holdings were on the verge of,
or actually in, bankruptcy.

Two different groups had interests in insurance

companies which borrowed from the looted banks.

One of these companies had at

that time been closed by the state; the other closed at about the same time the
bank did.
These are unsavory backgrounds.
In too many instances, acquisition of control of the banks was financed
by larger city banks, eager for correspondent balances, and satisfied by the
bank stock which was pledged as collateral.
were not nearly adequate.

Credit checks in several instances

Premiums paid to purchase stock were excessive, but

the lending banks chose not to question this factor.
I suppose the financing banks depended heavily on the fact that under




normal circumstances bank stock is good collateral, but there ¿g one basic flaw
to that thought:

bank stock is good collateral if the bsrik is soundly run, and

if the bank remains open.

If the bank closes, as these banks did, the bank stock

collateral becomes virtually worthless.
The financing bankers made the error of assuming safety in a piece of
paper, rather than in the individuals behind that paper.

There is still no

guarantee better than the person behind it, and the character of the borrower
is still the single best assurance any lender can have.

It seems that we are

always in the process of relearning this lesson.
Once the people purchased the bank in question, aided in many instances
by bank financing, a standard pattern of seeking funds and of placing them was
started.

Two cases involved the use of "float" mechanism, and one involved a

"kite," among other operations, but essentially the pattern revolved around two
key techniques, the solicitation of funds in the form of time certificates of
deposit from out-of-territory groups willing to skirt existing regulations, and
the placement of these and other funds in unsound out-of-territory and self­
dealing loans.
The unsound loans In every case wiped out capital and caused the demise
of the bank.
the others.

These were the twin causes of failure that each had in common with
These two techniques are the tools of the new breed of bank

raiders.
I would like to turn your attention to some banking practices which I
think fostered these raids.

These practices are reminiscent of unhappier times

we do not want to repeat, and I would suggest should be eliminated from the
system, by discipline in the trade and by supervisory vigilance.




-

6

-

As you all know, the period of the 1 9 2 0 s, which reached an unhappy
climax in the 1931-33 period of bank failures, was an era in which banking was
beset by many speculators.

Many otherwise good institutions were pulled down

by men whose approach was all too similar to today's raider, pyramiding unsound
self-dealing loans, unsafe stock transactions, and other non-bank promotions,
into edifices which had to collapse and did, almost destroying the banking
system in the process.
Not speaking for the Corporation for a moment, but only for myself, I
suggest that the funds secured by the promoters in the I963-6U failures were
secured by an outright evasion of the law,— an evasion of the law condoned and
assisted by other financial institutions, including a few banks, savings and
loan associations, credit unions, insurance companies, union pension funds, and
others.

A hunger for earnings impelled these people to place certificates of

deposit in the banks, when they knew that the bounties paid were illegal,
unsound, and unhealthy.

As you all know, there are other banks, otherwise sound,

which are still looking for this kind of money, and paying the same unsound
bounties.
Evading the law is evading the law, and no amount of pious words will
conceal the illegality and immorality of such an action -- not to mention the
inherent dangers.

Every institution which placed such funds is guilty of

evading the law.
Perhaps as important as anything I discuss with you today is my
conviction that bankers must not jeopardize their public trust by overreaching
themselves.

The competitive urge, the desire for rapid growth and quick




- 7 -

profits lead to corner-cutting and to an unrealistic vandering out of the
known territory.

No banker should make loans in an area far

removed from his

bank unless he possesses the know-how, the resources and the ability to maintain
the necessary credit and economic checks needed for sound operations.
Every one of the eight banks which collapsed did so under the weight
of out-of-territory loans, loans which no prudent banker in the borrowers'
area would have made.

Those loans went out of territory simply because the in­

territory bankers knew they were not bankable and refused to handle them.
as simple as that.

It is

The blocks of mortgages, the sales finance paper, and the

other loans were of a high-risk, marginal nature.
A large bank of national scope can maintain a large and sophisticated
staff to handle out-of-territory business.
smaller scale.

A regional bank does the same on a

But even these banks use the extensive resources of the

correspondent bank system when they are going into new areas.

Why should a small

banker risk all that his bank has when it is obvious that it lacks the expertise
to go outside its own area to make loans?
The purpose and the strength of the smaller independent local bank lies
in its ability to give the best service to its community, to draw its financing,
ownership, and management from that community, to know the community and serve
the community s needs.

The unusual American banking system developed out of a

desire to preserve local control over the capital and credit mechanism of the
community and to provide local service.

Perhaps the single sorriest element

in this whole sorry story of bank raiding is the common pattern of reaching for
loans out of a territory, beyond reason, ability, or size.




We as supervisors, state and national, have a moral responsibility.

We

are charged by the people of our states, and by the nation as a whole, to
maintain a sound banking system.

Bank failure may not have quite the economic

impact it did in the 1920’s and 1930's, largely because of deposit insurance,
but the emotional impact is as great as ever.

Any one of you who ever stood

outside a closed bank, as I have done all to often this year, and looked at the
uncomprehending townspeople, understand this.

We must learn the lessons these

failures teach us.
The FDIC moved this year to try to plug up at least one supervisory
loophole.

With the support of the Administration we secured, as you all know,

a law requiring reports of changes in control to the proper Federal agency.
That law requires additionally that we get reports on loans secured by 25 percen
or more of a bank's stock, with certain exceptions.
FDIC did not, and does not, believe that it can with propriety ask for
a veto over the sale of private property.

But we do believe it is consistent

with our supervisory authority and responsibility to be on notice when a new
control or management enters a bank, so that that new control or management
may be investigated.

If necessary, it can be carefully supervised, not in any

sense as a punitive measure, but both to assure that the management is honest
and trying to live up to its fiduciary responsibilities, and also when and
wherever possible to assist that management, to help develop the expertise to
avoid some of the pitfalls that can come from inexperience.
With regard to that law, I would like to extend to you my pledge
I know I also speak for FDIC Chairman Joseph Barr

and

that the agency will

cooperate in every way with state supervisors through exchanges of information.




- 9 -

After all, the state supervisor is the first line of defense in the case of any
state-chartered institution.

We recognize in this law an implicit acceptance of

the responsibility we jointly share, and an implicit acceptance of your important
role. At the same time we would like to ask you to ponder this question:

Is

this legislation enough, or are there other steps, legislative or administrative,
which you can and should take?
I believe that you may want to take note of the laws of the States of
Oregon and Florida, for example.

Where it is inappropriate for Federal

authorities to exercise a veto power over sales of bank stocks of state
institutions, this power might well be vested in the state chartering authorities
I stress chartering authorities, because I feel that the key to effective action
may be found in that power.
considering such legislation.

As you all know, several states are seriously
It will be interesting to watch the progress

they make.
As chartering authorities, and as the closest supervisory agencies for
the nation s state banks, there may be other tools which you can develop.

Not

the least of the tools you can work on is the improvement of your own departments
through upgrading examiner ability and attracting the best possible people.
Personally, I would favor any steps toward improving the financial abilities
of your departments to maintain good operations, adequately staffed, and able
to make consistent and sound examinations.

Your school, which opened this year,

and which I had the honor to address, is in my mind an outstanding example of
how you can improve your service to your states and upgrade the banking systems
of your states and of the nation.
The American system of banking cannot be any stronger than its grassroots




10

-

membership, as exemplified by the small, locally owned and managed bank.

And

that grassroots strength in turn demands that your state supervisory departments
be healthy, effective, and good teachers of the best in banking.
Another item I would like to discuss deals with cooperation between state
and Federal authorities, a cooperation FDIC prides itself in maintaining.
We want to work with you as partners in this effort to maintain an effective
banking system.

Our first conference this year with the state supervisors

from 10 western states was an exercise in this partnership and we feel, a great
success.

I am pleased to announce that the next such conference involving

the supervisors in the states encompassed by our Districts 1 and 2 is scheduled
for February 2 , 3 , and b } . 1965.
But there is more to cooperation than the ability of FDIC and state super­
visors to sit down and talk together.

We must in our day by day operations

evince a willingness not only to talk together but to act together when action
is necessary.

Above all, we must keep each other informed.

I believe that FDIC and the state supervisors have a good record in this
area.

I believe the same to be generally true of the Federal Reserve and state

authorities.

I know that in most instances FDIC and the Federal Reserve work

well together and keep each other reasonably well informed.
I am sorry that I cannot say the same for the Office of the Comptroller of
the Currency.

At the same time, I urge you not to react to this refusal to

cooperate by "competition toward the minimum."

If standards of safety and prudenc

are not adhered to in actions affecting your own states, by any authority outside
your own states, do not lessen your own standards for the sake of maintaining a
specious "competitive" balance.

Be rigorous in maintaining the soundest possible

local supervision despite any pressures you may feel.
will owe you a great debt of gratitude.




In the end the country

-

11

-

This nation has developed the finest, most flexible, most responsive
banking system of all time; let us all dedicate ourselves to keeping it that
way.