View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank
of San Francisco

MAY 9 1977

Pr o s p e r ity ,
\
PRICES AND
x — PUBLIC POLICY
1
REMARKS OF

John J. Balles
PRESIDENT
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF SAN FRANCISCO
Meeting with Phoenix Community Leaders and
Board of Directors, Los Angeles Branch,
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
April 26, 1977







John J. Balles

I’m delighted to be back in Phoenix again,
and I'm glad that the Directors and Officers
of our Los Angeles Office have this oppor­
tunity to meet with Phoenix community
leaders to discuss matters of common inter­
est. Speaking as a resident of the Great
Northern California Desert, I would say we
might have a common interest in the sub­
ject of water. Actually, all I had in mind was
taking a gallon or two home as a present for
my family, but from what I've heard recent­
ly, your interest in the subject is more basic
than that.
Needless to say, I'm no expert on the sub­
ject of the Central Arizona Project, but I
must say that I was impressed with the
recent set of editorials in the Phoenix Ga­
zette which summarized the benefits ob­
tained from Arizona's past efforts in the
field of water development. The editorials,
as you might remember, described how
Federal-local participation in the Salt River



Project early in this century made the desert
bloom like a rose (to coin a phrase), creat­
ing a prosperous metropolis where more
than a million people now live and work.
That project involved a Federal investment
of about $10 million, but in the 20 years
prior to the final payment on the debt in
1955, Valley residents paid more than 60
times that amount in Federal taxes. In more
recent decades, the prosperity made possi­
ble by that investment in water resources
has enriched the national and state treas­
uries by billions of dollars more, providing
an example for all of us in the value of
investment spending.
Most of my comments today concern the
health of the national economy and the
Federal Reserve's attempts to keep the
economy healthy. We are certainly faced
with some major problems, as Wall Street
has been telling us recently. (In fact, gallows
humor is back in vogue on the Street.
Here's a sample: What's the difference
between Wall Street and the Titanic? An­
swer: They had a band playing aboard the
Titanic.) But on Main Street, despite serious
fears of inflation, there's an underlying tone
of strength in the production and employ­
ment statistics, as the business community
builds upon the generally admirable per­
formance of 1976.
Strength in 1976— and 1977

The past year admittedly had its problems,
including the well-publicized "pause." But
not enough publicity has been given to the
fact that total output, in real terms, in­
creased faster in 1976 than at any other time
of the past two decades. Again, the year was
marred by the continuation of a near­
record level of unemployment—yet not
enough attention has been given to the fact
that no other period in recent decades,




except the 1973 boom year, could match
1976 in terms of job expansion. Inflation
also was a difficult problem in 1976, yet
relatively few commentators remarked on
the fact that the inflation rate had been
reduced more than half in a two-year timespan. Unfortunately, their optimism may
have been misplaced, in view of the
double-digit inflation we've experienced in
the last several months.
At any rate, the economy in early 1977
had a pretty strong foundation to build
upon. As a result, my staff economists (like
most others) originally saw the key 1977
estimates coming in at about “ five-andfive/' with real GNP growth of 5 percent or
so, and an inflation rate of about 5 percent.
Today, “ six and six” may be a more realistic
bet. Over the year, real GNP could increase
almost 6 percent, especially in view of the
rapid recovery from the big winter freeze.
But unfortunately, most observers now see
the 1977 increase in prices coming closer to
6 percent than to 5 percent—and some
inflation-watchers foresee much worse. In
contrast to the gradual deceleration of last
year, we have experienced a worrisome
speed-up in prices in early 1977, reflecting
such factors as weather problems, fiscal
problems, and the importing of foreign
inflation. I'll have more to say on that in a
minute.
The unemployment rate meanwhile should
fall below 7 percent sometime this year,
with or without any Administration tax
stimulus, since basic expansionary forces
should boost total employment about 3
percent for the second straight year—a very
strong increase in historical terms. To get a
good fix on the strength of the underlying
economy, we should keep our eye on the
doughnut instead of the hole; that is, on




total employment rather than unemploy­
ment. Over the past two years, an expand­
ing economy has created more than five
million new jobs, roughly equivalent to six
times Arizona's entire workforce. In con­
trast to these hard employment figures, the
unemployment rate is a rather mushy figure
for analysis and (especially) policy pur­
poses. The statistics are inflated— in good
times as well as bad—by women workers
who move in and out of the labor force
seeking temporary jobs, by teenagers who
are priced out of the job market by high
minimum-wage laws, and by some individ­
uals who might not otherwise look for work
but who are induced to apply for benefits
because of liberalized unemploymentcompensation laws. If we want an unem­
ployment figure that reflects the actual
health of the economy, we should look at
the proportion of household heads who are
out of work; that figure declined from an
uncomfortably high 6.2 percent two years
ago to a more reasonable 4.6 percent last
month.
Post-Freeze Expansion

The actual shape of the economy this year
was probably decided several months ago
by the Big Freeze. Now, the Big Freeze of
1977 will be long remembered in folk my­
thology as one of the nation’s most memor­
able physical disasters, but its economic
effects may be short-lived, except for one
thing. The severe winter interrupted and
postponed a strong expansion that was
evident around the turn of the year, and so
it practically guaranteed a sharp rebound
right about now. The recovery from the
first-quarter shortfall, plus the continued
growth of consumer and business demand,
should generate a temporarily high rate of
growth during the current quarter and set
the stage for a healthy advance in late 1977
and early 1978.



The consumer was the hero of the 1975
recovery but for a while looked to be the
villain of 1976’s "awesome pause.” But in
late 1976 consumer spending strengthened
again, and this pace has now been re­
gained. Favorable consumer attitude sur­
veys suggest one reason for further
strength, but the major reason is the recent
improvement in employment and consum­
er income. Homebuilding is another sup­
port of the expansion. Most of the earlier
weakness in this market centered in multi­
unit construction, because of builders’
widespread wariness over rental-unit pros­
pects as a result of overbuilding and the
specter of rent controls. But this sector of
the market has begun to recover recently
with the help of a boost in Federal subsidy
programs, while single-family construction
continues to show boom tendencies.
Business capital spending, a late arrival in
this business expansion, is expected at last
to show some strength this year. There is
still some excess capacity in the economy,
but that factor should be less of a constraint
on spending plans as more and more capac­
ity is called into play by the expansion in
demand. For that matter, businessmen
seem to be concentrating less on expanding
capacity and more on modernizing facili­
ties, as a means of offsetting cost pressures
and improving profit margins. Meanwhile,
business spending for inventories should
expand gradually in line with the growth of
other sources of demand, and thus should
cease being the source of volatility in total
spending that it has been throughout much
of the last several years.
Inflation and Fiscal Policy

Generally, we seem to be faced with a very
favorable situation, except for that one
major fly in the ointment— inflation. The
recent price statistics are indeed sobering,



even allowing for the special circumstances
which pushed up prices at a double-digit
rate in early 1977. Consumer prices have
increased at a 6.5-percent annual rate since
last fall—a full percentage point faster than
in the preceding six-month period. Part of
the problem is the weather-induced sharp
rise in food costs, but the prices of other
consumer goods have also accelerated,
while the prices of services have continued
to outstrip those of other consumer pur­
chases. And households may expect further
difficulties in coming months, since the
wholesale prices of consumer goods have
accelerated recently, rising at an 8.2percent annual rate since last fall.
Many of the fears now expressed on Main
Street and on Wall Street concern the price
implications of the Administration's new
energy program. That program recognizes
the fact that energy has become relatively
more expensive because of major shifts in
basic supply-and-demand factors in the
past decade or so. But we should remember
that inflation does not simply reflect the rise
in price of one single commodity, crucial as
that commodity may be in our industrial
society. Inflation is a rise in the general
price level, and it has to be attacked by
appropriate governmental policies—by
overcoming supply bottlenecks, as the A d­
ministration proposes, and more basically
by adopting moderate fiscal- and
monetary-policy measures.
My own fears center around the long-term
inflation threat created by the proliferation
of Federal programs—and the consequent
unprecedented string of substantial
deficits—over more than a decade. The
$112-billion combined deficit of the 1975-76
fiscal years might be explained in terms of
the need to overcome recession, but how



can we defend a deficit of like size in the
expansionary 1977-78 period? The danger is
that overly expansionary policies will rekin­
dle inflationary expectations among con­
sumers and producers—understandably
enough, in the light of recent history—and
that these inflationary expectations will
distort purchasing decisions and under­
mine the long-run growth and stability of
the national economy. In a word, a policy of
heavy fiscal stimulus is risky and flies in the
face of experience. All the research done
by my research staff shows that with such a
policy, the "good news" comes first in the
form of increased employment and output,
but “ bad news" inevitably follows in the
form of resurgent inflation.
Money and Interest Rates

Excessive fiscal stimulus tends to restrict the
freedom of action of monetary policymak­
ers, for we cannot afford to lean too far in
the direction of short-term ease to stimu­
late economic activity as long as massive
budget deficits still exist to generate new
inflationary pressures. The Federal Reserve
has made several adjustments over the past
year in the long-run growth ranges for the
monetary aggregates, partly to take account
of the many changes in financial technolo­
gy now affecting the financial system, but
also to create the conditions for a return to
general price stability. The latest an­
nounced projections include a growth
range of 4 1/2 to 6 V2 percent for M t (currency
plus bank demand deposits) and a range of
7 to 10 percent for M2 (M-, plus bank time
deposits except large CD's). But as Federal
Reserve Chairman Arthur Burns has argued
in several Congressional appearances, the
long-run strategy calls for a gradual reduc­
tion in these monetary growth ranges in an
attempt to unwind the inflation that still
bedevils the economy.



The carefully fashioned monetary policy
followed during the economic recovery
period helped dampen inflationary expec­
tations, and also helped finance the large
gains in employment and output that I've
already mentioned. Our policy, in addition,
contributed to a general pattern of lower
interest rates during 1975 and 1976. This of
course is contrary to our usual experience
during a period of cyclical expansion.
Vet here again, the Federal budget situation
casts a cloud over the outlook. Federal
demands on credit markets could be
roughly the same this year as in calendar
1976, in contrast to the usual cyclical de­
cline in such borrowing during a recovery
period. That projected demand comes just
at the time when private credit demands
are rising, and thus generates significant
upward pressure on interest rates when
coupled with the demands generated else­
where. On top of that, any inflationary fears
created by continued large Treasury deficits
obviously would cause lenders to try to get
higher inflation premiums for their funds.
These effects have already been reflected in
higher interest rates in the first quarter of
1977, and I have difficulty seeing any rever­
sal of that trend, at least as long as inflation
jitters continue to dominate the money and
capital markets.
An Independent Monetary Policy

Monetary policy, through its impact on the
reserves held against bank deposits, helped
support the growth of the economy during
1975 and 1976, while gradually squeezing
out its inflationary excesses. In this endeav­
or, monetary policy showed itself to be far
more effective than fiscal policy, which has
several important drawbacks even apart
from its creation of inflationary deficits.
Manipulating government spending tends




to be a rather clumsy way of dealing with
rapidly changing economic developments,
while the process of reaching a consensus
on needed tax changes usually turns out to
be complex and time consuming. We've
recently witnessed a vivid demonstration of
that point, with continued discussion of
expansionary programs long after the need
for stimulus has passed.
Fortunately, monetary policy is relatively
free of these shortcomings, because of its
great virtue of flexibility. We can change
monetary policy promptly and (if need be)
frequently. The independent Federal Re­
serve can make the hard decisions that
might be avoided by decision-makers sub­
ject to the day-to-day pressures of political
life. And we've seen that when there are
substantial changes in the supply of money
and credit, the effects are speedily transmit­
ted through financial markets to the na­
tion's factories, farms and commercial en­
terprises.
The founders of the Federal Reserve System
were well aware of the dangers that could
arise from the creation of a monetary au­
thority subservient to the Executive branch
of government, and thus subject to political
manipulation. Consequently, they took
several steps to ensure the independence
of the central bank within the structure of
our Federal Government. For example,
Board members have 14-year terms of of­
fice, long enough to minimize the threat of
political pressure, and they also have stag­
gered terms to avoid Presidential "packing”
of the Board. Again, the Federal Reserve
accounts for its actions to Congress, and not
to the Executive branch of government. But
in this connection, the Fed's operations are
financed from its own internal sources, and
thus protected from the political pressures



that may be exercised through the Con­
gressional appropriations process.
This system of monetary management
seems to be working just the way the foun­
ders of the Federal Reserve intended. Cer­
tainly, the Fed has stumbled on some occa­
sions, but it's hard to imagine that our
problems would have been solved if we'd
followed the suggestion of the Fed’s critics
and turned control of the monetary author­
ity over to the Executive branch or to Con­
gress. Specifically, if the spending propensi­
ties of Federal officials had been given freer
rein through easier access to the “ printing
press," our inflation problem of the past
decade probably would have been aggra­
vated even more.
Every nation in the world has suffered
severely from inflation in recent years. But
it's interesting to note that the two industri­
al nations with the strongest central
banks—Germany and the United States—
are also the two with the strongest records
of curbing inflation. Great Britain, whose
central bank was taken over by the Govern­
ment several decades ago, has recently
suffered from a chronic case of double­
digit inflation, with prices rising at times at a
rate of 20 or 30 percent a year. In some
other countries, in Latin America and else­
where, where the monetary authority has
always been dominated by the executive or
the legislature, triple-digit inflation holds
sway, bringing economic and political
chaos in its wake.
In our democratic society, of course, the
independence of a governmental agency
can never be absolute. The Federal Reserve
is subject not only to the Federal Reserve
Act, but to other statutes as well. The foun­
ders of the System recognized this duty by




requiring the Fed to account for its steward­
ship to the Congress. As you know, we now
have a formal reporting system, with Chair­
man Burns traveling up to Capitol Hill once
every quarter to discuss the course of
monetary policy, including growth projec­
tions for the major monetary and credit
aggregates for the year ahead. The present
system is effective because it provides am­
ple scope for the exercise of Congressional
oversight, yet keeps political pressures away
from day-to-day involvement in the details
of monetary policy.
Concluding Remarks

To sum up, the national economy is in
relatively good shape today, with produc­
tion, employment and retail sales pointing
upward, and with manufacturers' orderbooks growing increasingly bulky. Indeed,
the present solidly-based expansion could
continue for the rest of the decade if only—
and it’s a big if—we could get prices under
control. And as I've suggested, one of the
best ways to stop inflation is to get the
Federal budget under control, thus reduc­
ing the pressure on the Federal Reserve to
finance those deficits through the printing
press, and reducing the pressure on finan­
cial markets induced by heavy Treasury
borrowing.
The Federal Reserve has a major role to play
in the fight against inflation. To help the
economy recover from a serious recession,
we earlier adopted monetary growth ranges
which were considerably higher than they
should be over the long run. Ideally, the
increase in the money supply (along with
the increase in turnover of that money
supply) should approximate the long-term
growth rate of physical output, which is
about 31/2 percent a year. Now that the
recession has been overcome, we are de­




termined to move towards a gradual reduc­
tion in the growth of the money supply. To
do so, however, we must be able to main­
tain our present independent policy stance,
free of short-term political pressures. Oth­
erwise, if those pressures for perpetual
rapid expansion should succeed, we would
have few defenses left against the destruc­
tive inflation that has brought chaos to so
much of the world.