View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
8:00 a.m. EDT
April 8, 2015

Remarks on Monetary Policy

Remarks by
Jerome H. Powell
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
C. Peter McColough Series on International Economics
Council on Foreign Relations
New York, New York

April 8, 2015

Thanks for the opportunity to speak to you today. In these brief remarks, I will
discuss the progress of the economy and the path forward for monetary policy. 1 The
current expansion is almost six years old and is now one of the longest since World
War II. While the pace of improvement has at times been frustratingly slow, by some
measures the recovery is now well advanced. By other measures, there is still room for
improvement. Assessing the scope for further improvement will be important in judging
the appropriate path for monetary policy.
After its most recent meeting in March, the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) modified its forward guidance to say that an increase in the target range for the
federal funds rate will be appropriate when the Committee has seen further improvement
in the labor market and is reasonably confident that inflation will move back to its
2 percent objective over the medium term. Such an increase could come as soon as the
June FOMC meeting. The timing of liftoff and the pace of subsequent rate increases will
depend on incoming data and on realized and expected progress toward our
congressionally mandated goals of stable prices and maximum employment. Monetary
policy works with long and variable lags, so rate increases need to begin well before we
reach those goals.
Let us turn to the two main economic conditions for liftoff that the Committee
articulated. We have already seen a great deal of progress in the labor market, and I
expect that progress to continue. Despite slowing in March, job creation has been
particularly strong over the past two years. The unemployment rate has declined from
10 percent in October 2009 to 5.5 percent in March 2015, a level that is not far above

1

The views I express here today are mine alone and not necessarily those of any other member of the
Federal Open Market Committee.

-2many estimates of its natural rate. But the unemployment rate probably understates the
amount of slack still remaining in the labor market. The labor force participation rate
continues to be unusually low, suggesting that potential workers may be waiting on the
sidelines for further improvements in job opportunities and wages. The number working
part time who want full-time jobs also remains elevated. The low level of wage increases
also suggests additional slack.
The Committee said that it will want to be reasonably confident that inflation will
move back to 2 percent over the medium term. On a 12-month basis, headline inflation
in February, as measured by the personal consumption expenditures price index, stood at
0.3 percent; meanwhile, core inflation, which excludes volatile energy and food
components, was 1.4 percent. These low current readings are partly a consequence of
two transient shocks--the dramatic decline in oil prices and the effect of the appreciation
of the dollar on import prices. Before those shocks, both headline inflation and core
inflation were running at about 1.5 percent. When the effects of these shocks pass, I
expect that inflation will return roughly to those earlier levels and then rise gradually to
our 2 percent objective over the medium term as labor and product markets tighten
further. Despite the current low inflation readings, survey-based measures of inflation
expectations in the United States have been stable. However, market-based readings on
inflation compensation have declined significantly since mid-2014. I view this decline as
more likely reflecting movements in risk premiums and other transitory factors, rather
than shifts in longer-term inflation expectations. Still, it will be important to keep an eye
on the performance of inflation breakevens.

-3I expect that economic conditions will support the first rate increase later this
year. I do not expect that such an increase or the associated market reaction will
materially restrain the progress of the economy. From a macroeconomic perspective, the
precise timing of liftoff is less important than the path of subsequent additional rate
increases. My view is that, if the economy continues on its expected path, it will be
appropriate for a time to increase rates fairly gradually. Of course, if the economy
improves faster or inflation increases more than expected, it will be appropriate to raise
rates faster. And if economic performance disappoints or inflation remains lower than
expected, it will be appropriate to delay liftoff or raise rates more slowly thereafter.
There are several reasons why it may be appropriate to raise rates somewhat
gradually, including the proximity of the zero lower bound for interest rates and
continuing economic headwinds in the wake of the crisis. 2 I would like to explore a
rationale that has received somewhat less attention, which is the unusually high level of
uncertainty today about capacity measures such as the natural rate of unemployment. 3
Uncertainty about the precise level of these indicators becomes more important for policy
as the expansion continues and the economy approaches its potential, defined as the level
of output that is consistent with stable prices.

2

See Janet Yellen (2015), “Normalizing Monetary Policy: Prospects and Perspectives,” speech delivered
at “The New Normal Monetary Policy,” a research conference sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, San Francisco, March 27,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20150327a.htm.
3
The natural rate of unemployment can be thought of as the unemployment rate at which the labor market
is at its long-run equilibrium and inflation is stable. We cannot directly observe the natural rate but must
infer it based on the performance of wages, prices, and labor market indicators. Most FOMC participants
estimate that the longer-run normal rate is currently in the range of 5.0 to 5.2 percent. Confidence intervals
around statistical estimates of the natural rate are routinely estimated to be quite wide. For example,
Staiger, Stock, and Watson estimate a 95 percent confidence range around the natural rate to extend nearly
1½ percentage points on either side of the point estimate. See Douglas Staiger, James H. Stock, and Mark
W. Watson (1997), “How Precise Are Estimates of the Natural Rate of Unemployment?” in Christina D.
Romer and David H. Romer, eds., Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy (Chicago: University of
Chicago Press).

-4All else equal, a decision to return interest rates to more-normal levels implies
that the economy is nearing its capacity. The financial crisis did significant damage to
the productive capacity of our economy, and the damage was of a character, extent, and
duration that cannot be fully known today. Given this uncertainty, it is even more
difficult than usual to assess how much slack remains. It seems plausible that at least part
of this supply-side damage could be reversed if the economy enjoys a period of sustained
growth. 4 To encourage that outcome, as monetary policymakers consider removing
accommodation, we should look for a little more proof than usual that labor markets are
tightening or other supply-side constraints are binding. Of course, if the effects of the
crisis prove difficult to reverse and, as a result, inflation pressures do emerge, the Federal
Reserve will use its tools to contain them.
Let us take a brief look at the implications of severe financial crises for economies
generally. Studies document that severe financial crises around the world have typically
left behind large and sustained reductions in the level of output. 5 The recent crisis is no
exception, and figure 1 shows such an effect for the U.S., U.K., euro-area and Canadian

4

See, for example, Laurence M. Ball (2014), “Long-Term Damage from the Great Recession in OECD
Countries,” NBER Working Paper Series 20185 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research, May); and Robert E. Hall (2014), “Quantifying the Lasting Harm to the U.S. Economy from the
Financial Crisis,” NBER Working Paper Series 20183 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research, May).
5
See Robert F. Martin, Teyanna Munyan, and Beth Anne Wilson (2014), “Potential Output and
Recessions: Are We Fooling Ourselves?” IFDP Notes (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, November 12), www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/notes/ifdp-notes/2014/potentialoutput-and-recessions-are-we-fooling-ourselves-20141112.html; Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S.
Rogoff (2009), This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly (Princeton: Princeton
University Press); Valerie Cerra and Sweta Chaman Saxena (2008), “Growth Dynamics: The Myth of
Economic Recovery,” American Economic Review, vol. 98 (March), pp. 439-57; and Davide Furceri and
Annabelle Mourougane (2009), “The Effect of Financial Crises on Potential Output: New Empirical
Evidence from OECD Countries,” OECD Economics Department Working Papers 699 (Paris:
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, May), available at
www.oecd.org/eco/theeffectoffinancialcrisesonpotentialoutputnewempiricalevidencefromoecdcountries.ht
m. For a different view, see Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer (2015), “New Evidence on the
Impact of Financial Crises in Advanced Countries,” NBER Working Paper Series 21021 (Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, March).

-5economies since 2008. The underlying pattern is an interesting one. Economists and
policymakers have tended at first to view a decline in output as a cyclical shock to
demand and to realize only gradually over time that a crisis has done substantial and
lasting damage to the productive capacity of the economy. 6 As a result, estimates of the
gap between actual and potential output often narrow over time, partly through higher
actual output but also through lower estimates of potential. For example, figure 2 shows
that the Congressional Budget Office has made a series of downward revisions to its
estimates of potential output in recent years. 7
This supply-side damage has typically appeared both in the labor market and in
the capital stock. 8 Long spells of unemployment cause skills to atrophy and make it more
difficult for workers to find new jobs, raising the natural rate of unemployment for those
who do remain in the labor force and causing others to throw in the towel and drop out.
Extended periods of weak demand appear to cause companies to invest less in plant and
technology, which slows the growth of the productivity of the workforce. The number of
new business formations declines sharply, perhaps because of reduced credit availability,
which may depress hiring, productivity, business innovation, and hence trend output. 9

6

For example, Martin, Munyan, and Wilson show that estimates of potential output generated by common
filtering techniques tend to revise down following recessions as actual output grows slower than its prerecession trend; see Martin, Munyan, and Wilson, “Potential Output and Recessions,” in note 5. In other
words, looking backward with many years of hindsight at the evolution of output following a financial
crisis, the negative effect on potential output is clearer than it is when estimating the level of potential
output in real time immediately following the crises. As an example of this type of exercise, see Furceri
and Mourougane, “Effect of Financial Crises on Potential Output,” in note 5.
7
See Congressional Budget Office (2014), Revisions to CBO’s Projection of Potential Output since 2007
(Washington: CBO, February), www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/45150-PotentialOutput.pdf.
8
See Dave Reifschneider, William Wascher, and David Wilcox (2013), “Aggregate Supply in the United
States: Recent Developments and Implications for the Conduct of Monetary Policy,” Finance and
Economics Discussion Series 2013-77 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
November), www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2013/201377/201377abs.html; and Hall, “Quantifying the
Lasting Harm to the U.S. Economy,” in note 4.
9
For evidence regarding the link between fewer start-ups and lower job growth, see Ryan Decker, John
Haltiwanger, Ron Jarmin, and Javier Miranda (2014), “The Role of Entrepreneurship in U.S. Job Creation

-6Corporate spending on research and development has also been strongly procyclical,
which may have similar effects. 10
Turning to the recent U.S. experience, many economists now estimate that
substantially more than half of the shortfall in gross domestic product relative to its precrisis trend represents a reduction of potential output and not just a shortfall in demand. 11
U.S. labor force damage likely accounts for some part of the shortfall. 12 The greater part
appears to have resulted from lower trend labor productivity due to reduced capital
investment and “multifactor productivity,” which is often thought of as capturing the
effects of technological innovation. 13 The employment rebound suggests that strong
measures--such as those the Fed took during and after the crisis--can prevent even sharp
job losses from becoming permanent. But the productivity slowdown suggests that
monetary policy cannot, by itself, avert all of the damage.

and Economic Dynamism,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 28 (Summer), pp. 3-24. For an
estimate of how the latest recession affected aggregate trend productivity growth in the United States, see
Reifschneider, Wascher, and Wilcox, “Aggregate Supply in the United States,” in note 8.
10
See Gadi Barlevy (2005), “Why Don’t Recessions Encourage More R&D Spending?” Chicago Fed
Letter 220 (Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, November),
www.chicagofed.org/digital_assets/publications/chicago_fed_letter/2005/cflnovember2005_220.pdf; and
Diego Comin and Mark Gertler (2006), “Medium-Term Business Cycles,” American Economic Review,
vol. 93 (June), pp. 523-51.
11
See Congressional Budget Office, Revisions to CBO’s Projection of Potential Output, in note 7; Hall,
“Quantifying the Lasting Harm to the U.S. Economy,” in note 4; Ball, “Long-Term Damage from the Great
Recession,” in note 4; and Reifschneider, Wascher, and Wilcox, “Aggregate Supply in the United States,”
in note 8.
12
There is considerable debate about how much of the decline in the employment-to-population ratio and
labor force participation has been due to the recession, how much of that decline is reversible, and,
relatedly, how much of the decline would have occurred regardless in the absence of a recession. For the
argument that much of the decrease in labor force participation would likely have occurred even in the
absence of the recession, see Stephanie Aaronson, Tomaz Cajner, Bruce Fallick, Felix Galbis-Reig,
Christopher Smith, and William Wascher (2014), “Labor Force Participation: Recent Developments and
Future Prospects,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall, pp. 197-275, available at
www.brookings.edu/about/projects/bpea/papers/2014/labor-force-participation-recent-developments-andfuture-prospects; for the argument that most of the decline is related to the severity of the recession and is
likely reversible, see Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin (2013), “Labor Force Participation and
Monetary Policy in the Wake of the Great Recession,” IMF Working Paper 13/245 (Washington:
International Monetary Fund, July), available at www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=41133.0.
13
See Reifschneider, Wascher, and Wilcox (2013), “Aggregate Supply in the United States,” in note 8.

-7This consideration raises the question I mentioned a moment ago. Should we
think of this supply-side damage as permanent or temporary? In many previous episodes
around the world, post-crisis reductions in output have proved permanent. Nonetheless,
it seems plausible that at least part of the damage can be reversed. As business
confidence improves, employers may be more willing to take a chance on someone with
an extended spell of unemployment. A stronger job market and rising wages may
encourage more potential workers to join the labor force. 14 Over a longer period,
stronger demand can produce higher capital investment, driving higher productivity. A
long expansion could also produce higher productivity as companies strive to get more
out of every dollar of capital and hour of work and as the strong economy encourages
entrepreneurship and innovation.
To give us the best chance to recover lost ground, we need policies that support
labor force participation, business and household confidence, hiring and investment, and
productivity growth--policies, I hasten to add, that are, for the most part, outside the remit
of the Federal Reserve. Monetary policy also has a role to play by continuing to support
the expansion as long as inflation expectations remain stable and realized inflation stays
close to our 2 percent objective. Indeed, in the current circumstances, accommodative
policy may not only help restore some of our economy’s potential, but should also help
return inflation to our 2 percent objective more expeditiously.
There is no risk-free path for monetary policy. The biggest risk of tightening too
early or too fast is that the economy may weaken more than expected, forcing the central
bank to reverse course. The record of central banks lifting off from the zero lower bound

14

In fact, as the recovery has progressed, the labor force participation rate and other broad indicators have
moved back toward their longer-run trends.

-8suggests caution in this regard. A second risk is that we could prematurely truncate the
process of healing damage from the crisis, thereby ensuring that the admittedly severe
cyclical effects become permanent.
Overly accommodative monetary policy also poses risks. First, the economy
could overheat, and rising inflation could require the Committee to raise rates faster,
which--if overdone--could produce a damaging recession. For now, I would be more
concerned with a second risk, which is that more-accommodative policy could lead to
frothy financial conditions and eventually undermine financial stability. While I do not
see a troubling buildup of these risks today, tighter monetary policy might eventually be
necessary if such risks do appear.
Conclusion
To wrap up, with the support of extraordinary monetary accommodation, our
economy has made substantial progress. As the FOMC moves to return monetary policy
to a more normal footing, it makes sense to me to move fairly gradually as long as the
incoming data evolve about as expected. Doing so would, among other benefits, give our
economy the best chance to make up lost ground.