View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:15 a.m. EST
February 22, 2013

Discussion of “Crunch Time: Fiscal Crises and the Role of Monetary Policy”

Remarks by
Jerome H. Powell
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
“U.S. Monetary Policy Forum”
A Conference Sponsored by the University of Chicago Booth School of Business
New York, New York

February 22, 2013

The issue of fiscal sustainability and its interaction with monetary policy is
certainly timely.1 Many advanced economies are in an extended period of slow growth
and high deficits, and face long-term fiscal pressures from aging populations.
I agree with much in this broad-ranging paper.2 In particular, the authors join
others in finding that accommodative monetary policy is often associated with successful
fiscal consolidations. They conclude that a “tough love” alternative, which would call for
the Federal Reserve to withhold monetary accommodation until fiscal policymakers enact
legislation to reduce budget imbalances, is likely to be counterproductive. Indeed, I
would argue that the tough love approach also would require the Fed to deviate from the
dual mandate that the Congress has assigned it, while assuming a role in influencing
fiscal policy that the Congress has not assigned it.
I find myself in disagreement, however, with the paper’s assessment that the
current fiscal policy challenges might interfere in the near-term with the conduct of
monetary policy in the United States.
Three important propositions underlie the authors’ argument on this issue:
1. The federal government’s fiscal path is unsustainable under current
policies.
2. If the market concludes that a government either cannot or will not service
its debt, the central bank may be forced to choose ultimately between

1

The views expressed here are my own and not necessarily those of my colleagues in the Federal Reserve
System. I am indebted to members of the Board staff--Eric Engen, Edward Nelson, David Lopez-Salido,
and Jon Faust--who contributed to the preparation of these remarks.
2
See David Greenlaw, James D. Hamilton, Peter Hooper, and Frederic S. Mishkin (2013), “Crunch Time:
Fiscal Crises and the Role of Monetary Policy,” paper written for “U.S. Monetary Policy Forum,” a
conference sponsored by the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, held in New York,
February 22, http://research.chicagobooth.edu/igm/usmpf/download2.aspx.

-2monetization leading to inflation or standing by as the government
defaults--the threat of “fiscal dominance.”
3. The Federal Reserve’s balance sheet is currently very large by historical
standards and still growing. The process of normalizing the size and
composition of the balance sheet poses significant uncertainties and
challenges for monetary policymakers.
I believe all of these statements to be true. They are also widely, if not
universally, accepted. However, based on these points and, importantly, on their
empirical findings, the authors set out to show that fiscal difficulties present a near-term
threat to the conduct of monetary policy. The paper argues that rising fiscal pressures,
exacerbated by Federal Reserve losses on asset sales and low remittances to the Treasury,
could lead the Federal Reserve to delay balance sheet normalization and to fail to remove
monetary accommodation as needed to keep inflation expectations stable and inflation in
check. In that case, the market could perceive the onset of fiscal dominance, thus setting
off a vicious cycle of rising inflation expectations, increasing interest rates, and ever
greater fiscal unsustainability.
In my view, this proposition seems highly unlikely. At a minimum, it is
premature.
U.S. Fiscal Position
The paper led me to look back over the past century of U.S. sovereign debt
history. On two prior occasions, federal debt as a percentage of gross domestic product

-3(GDP) increased significantly--during the Great Depression-World War II era and, to a
smaller extent, the two decades ending in the mid-1990s.3
After each of these high-debt periods, fiscal policy responded by running
sustained primary surpluses and reducing debt to levels below 40 percent of GDP. In a
recent paper, Henning Bohn observed that “the foundation of U.S. debt policy is the
promise of safety for bondholders backed by primary surpluses only in response to a high
debt-GDP ratio.”4 That nicely captures our recent history and suggests a principal reason
why the federal debt of the United States still has the market’s trust.
The Great Recession has generated a third substantial increase in federal debt,
from about 35 percent of GDP in 2007 to around 75 percent at the end of this fiscal year,
an increase that is consistent with other increases in sovereign debt for advanced
economies after severe financial crises during the post-World War II period.5 History
and common sense suggest that the federal government should again run primary
surpluses sufficient over time to reduce debt to pre-crisis levels of perhaps 35 to
40 percent of GDP. That would leave fiscal space to address the coming wave of health
and pension costs, as well as unexpected new shocks.
In the past two years, spending cuts and tax increases totaling about $3.5 trillion
over the next 10 years have been enacted. Assuming these measures are not rolled back-in particular, that the spending sequestration either takes effect or is replaced by
equivalent deficit-reducing measures--a reasonable “current policy” projection is that the
3

Figure 1 shows federal debt held by the public and primary budget surpluses--that is, the difference
between federal revenues and federal noninterest outlays--as a percent of nominal GDP from fiscal year
1912 through fiscal 2012.
4
See quote on p. 290 in Henning Bohn (2011), “The Economic Consequences of Rising U.S. Government
Debt: Privileges at Risk,” FinanzArchiv/Public Finance Analysis, vol. 67 (September), pp. 282-302.
5
See Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff (2009), “The Aftermath of Financial Crises,” American
Economic Review, vol. 99 (May), pp. 466-72.

-4ratio of debt to GDP will be roughly stable at around 75 percent through about 2020.6
After that, under current policy, health-care costs and, to a much lesser extent, pension
costs will produce a sharp, sustained increase in the ratio of debt to GDP.
Fiscal Sustainability and Monetary Policy
The authors review empirical evidence of sovereign borrowing costs for
20 advanced economies. They join others in finding a statistically significant relationship
between sovereign debt levels and borrowing costs.7 They also find nonlinear increases
in borrowing costs beginning at debt-to-GDP ratios of around 80 percent. But the
nonlinearities they find are driven to a great extent by the experience of smaller eurozone nations that, of course, borrow in euros. The United States borrows in its own
currency--the world’s primary reserve currency. That difference is crucial for investors,
along with the fact that the United States economy remains the world’s largest and most
productive. The United Kingdom and Japan are also high-debt countries that borrow in
their own currencies; neither shows any detectable rate increase, let alone a nonlinear
one. These countries present a serious problem for the authors’ case.
Of course, the United States is not exempt from concerns about the potential longterm effects of an unsustainable fiscal path. There is almost certainly a level of debt at
which the United States would be at risk of an interest rate spike. However, we should
6

See Loren Adler, Shai Akabas, and Brian Collins (2013), “Key Takeaways from the 2013-2023 CBO
Budget and Economic Outlook,” Bipartisan Beat Blog, Bipartisan Policy Center, February 7,
http://bipartisanpolicy.org/blog/2013/02/key-takeaways-2013-2023-cbo-budget-and-economic-outlook.
Numbers are modified to assume that the spending sequestration either takes effect or is replaced by
equivalent deficit reducing measures.
7
For example, see Eric Engen and R. Glenn Hubbard (2005), “Federal Government Debt and Interest
Rates,” in Mark Gertler and Kenneth Rogoff, eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2004, vol. 19
(Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press), pp. 83-138; Thomas Laubach (2009), “New Evidence on the Interest Rate
Effects of Budget Deficits and Debt,” Journal of the European Economic Association, vol. 7 (June),
pp. 858-85; and Joseph W. Gruber and Steven B. Kamin (2012), “Fiscal Positions and Government Bond
Yields in OECD Countries,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 44 (December), pp. 1563-87.

-5expect that level to be substantially above one identified based on the experience of
smaller euro-zone nations.
The argument also has a serious timing problem. The Federal Reserve’s balance
sheet likely will be normalized by late this decade, before the federal debt-to-GDP ratio
even increases materially from today’s level. Under the reasonable projection mentioned
above, the debt-to-GDP ratio will remain roughly stable until 2020 before rising
significantly in the next decade.8 That’s not a favorable longer-term forecast, all the
more so because it is importantly the result of demographic changes that have been
expected for decades. But the forecast doesn’t support the authors’ claim that fears of
fiscal dominance could materialize in the United States within the next five to seven
years, during the period when the Fed is normalizing its balance sheet.
No current market signal suggests that the United States is near the point of losing
the market’s confidence. In my view, nothing in the Congressional Budget Office debt
forecasts or the authors’ empirical findings provides grounds for such an event during
this decade. The market has every reason to believe--and apparently still does believe-that the United States will continue the difficult task of fiscal consolidation until the job
is done.
Terribly difficult fiscal adjustments lie ahead. Although there is still time to make
them, delay will sharply increase the pain of adjustment. The time to act is now. In my
view, the problem is not principally one of economics or fiscal policy; it is one of
governance. The real threat to the fiscal standing of the United States is that of inaction
caused by a long period of political polarization and dysfunction. That would be a self8

This is the alternative baseline scenario presented in Adler, Akabas, and Collins, “Key Takeaways,” in
note 6.

-6inflicted wound. And that is a problem that can’t be derived from the traditional fiscal
metrics.
We may have more room than other economies around the globe, but I do not
intend to project any sense of complacency around this topic. The authors’ basic
message seems just right to me: We don’t know where the tipping point is; wherever it
is, we are clearly getting closer to it, and the costs of misestimating its location are
enormous and one-sided. The benefits to long-term fiscal consolidation--conducted at the
right pace, and without jeopardizing the near-term economic recovery--would be
substantial.
Balance Sheet Losses and Remittances
The authors’ work on Federal Reserve income and remittances to the Treasury
overlaps with a paper published last month by Federal Reserve Board staff members Seth
Carpenter, Jane Ihrig, Beth Klee, Daniel Quinn, and Alexander Boote.9 Both papers
provide a basis for public discussion of these matters, which is a highly positive
development. Some of the assets acquired through the Federal Reserve’s large-scale
asset purchases (LSAPs) may be sold at a loss, and it is important to be transparent about
this possibility.
Thus far, the Federal Reserve’s asset purchases have greatly increased our income
and remittances to the Treasury. Indeed, remittances have run at an annual level of about
$80 billion from 2010 to 2012. Both papers show that remittances are likely to decline
substantially from these elevated levels as interest rates rise and the Fed balance sheet
9

See Seth B. Carpenter, Jane E. Ihrig, Elizabeth C. Klee, Daniel W. Quinn, and Alexander H. Boote
(2013), “The Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet and Earnings: A Primer and Projections,” Finance and
Economics Discussion Series 2013-01 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
January), www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2013/201301/201301abs.html.

-7normalizes, and there may be a period of zero remittances. If so, the balance sheet would
show a deferred asset representing a flow of future income to be retained and not remitted
to the Treasury. Nonetheless, we expect that the LSAPs, which began in late 2008, will
result in a net increase in remittances over the life of these programs. Moreover, any
temporary losses should be weighed against the expected social benefits of the increased
economic growth generated by the LSAPs, which would include higher tax revenue from
increased output.
Greenlaw and his coauthors also note that we have the flexibility to normalize the
balance sheet more slowly. For example, a “no asset sale” plan--under which assets
would simply run off as they mature--would push out the date of normalization by only a
year or so. That approach would also address concerns over potential market disruption
from the sale of off-the-run agency mortgage-backed securities. And it would also
smooth remittances.
Remittances averaged about $25 billion per year, or 0.2 percent of GDP, over the
decade before the crisis. After the balance sheet is normalized, these remittances should
return to a similar, modest share of GDP. From the standpoint of the sustainability of
federal fiscal policy, remittances are not a first-order concern. That said, an extended
period of zero remittances could certainly bring the Federal Reserve under criticism from
the public and the Congress. The question is whether the Federal Reserve would permit
inflation and thereby abandon its post in the face of such criticism. There is no reason to
expect that to happen.
The Federal Reserve was created as an independent agency, and a broad
consensus has emerged among policymakers, academics, and other informed observers

-8around the world that better overall economic performance is achieved when the conduct
of monetary policy is free from political control.10 Of course, we are accountable to the
Congress and the American people. The Congress has given us a job to do, and as long
as I am a member of the Federal Reserve Board, I will do my utmost to carry out our
mandate.
Other Observations
The authors note that Federal Reserve asset purchases shorten the duration of debt
held by the public, by the issuance of reserves to fund purchases of long-term securities.
And shortening the maturity of the public debt does make any government more
susceptible, in theory, to fiscal dominance. There is also a general assumption that under
fiscal dominance any government has a strong incentive to allow inflation to reduce the
real value of the debt. In the case of the United States, there is less to that than one might
expect. By shortening the duration of debt held by the public, asset purchases have also
reduced any benefit to the government of an unexpected inflation. More fundamentally,
the liabilities that matter in the long term for the federal budget are those associated with
health care and pension costs. These liabilities are not nominal but real, and cannot be
inflated away.

Conclusion

10

Among many studies, see, for example, Alex Cukierman (1992), Central Bank Strategy, Credibility, and
Independence: Theory and Evidence (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press); Alberto Alesina and Lawrence H.
Summers (1993), “Central Bank Independence and Macroeconomic Performance: Some Comparative
Evidence,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 25 (May), pp. 151-62; and Alex Cukierman,
Pantelis Kalaitzidakis, Lawrence H. Summers, and Steven B. Webb (1993), “Central Bank Independence,
Growth, Investment, and Real Rates,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39
(December), pp. 95-140.

-9I am not suggesting, and I do not expect, that the path ahead for monetary policy
will be an easy one. There are legitimate concerns associated with the costs and benefits
of continuing asset purchases. We may face challenges related to financial stability, as
well as market function and inflation expectations. I do not personally see fiscal
dominance as high on the list of near term risks.
I thank the authors for their interesting work.

Figure 1

Federal Government Debt and Primary Budget Surpluses, 1912‐2012
(percent of GDP)
110.0
100.0

Period
Average primary surplus
1932‐1946
‐7.8%
1947‐1974
1.0%
1975‐1993
‐0.8%
1994‐2002
2.4%

90.0
80.0
70.0
60.0

Federal debt

Percent

50.0
40.0
30.0
20.0
10.0

Primary buget surplus
0.0
‐10.0
‐20.0
‐30.0
1912 1917 1922 1927 1932 1937 1942 1947 1952 1957 1962 1967 1972 1977 1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007 2012
Source: Office of Management and Budget and Congressional Budget Office.

Fiscal years