View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release 10:30 a.m.
Eastern Daylight Time
June 27, 1972____




Remarks of J. L. Robertson
Vice Chairman of the Board of Governors
of the
Federal Reserve System
before the
60th Annual
International Consumer Credit Conference
Statler Hilton Hotel
Washington, D. C.
June 27, 1972

Consumers in the 70's

I am pleased to be with you today and to have an
opportunity to discuss developments in the consumer credit
field from the vantage point of a member of the Federal
Reserve Board. However, I was somewhat disconcerted by
one thing in the letter of invitation that was sent to me.
I was told that I had come to be regarded as the Federal
Reserve's expert on consumer credit. I was thought of,
I was told, as Mr. Consumer Credit. Well, if we can have
attractive young ladies bearing such titles as Miss Retail
Merchandising and Miss Environmental Protection, consumer
credit certainly rates a sexy "Miss" instead of a sexa­
genarian "Mister".
However, I do not mind the title so much as long
as I am not labeled an expert. I have been wary of that
ever since one of the sages of my home town, Broken Bow,
Nebraska, gave me a bit of advice as I set out many years
ago to make my career in Washington. He told me that there
were three ways to go to hell: the first was gambling;
the second was women; the third was reliance on experts.
He said gambling was the quickest; women were the pleas­
antest; but reliance on experts was the surest.
One thing that I do not want to do is to try to im­
press this knowledgeable group with my expertise. The best
contribution that I can make is to give you my reaction to
some of the problems that confront all of us now in the
field of consumer credit regulation. I may indulge in a
word of advice as to how some of these problems might be
tackled.
It is said that we are entering into the age of
the consumer, and since all of us are consumers, we can
all take some satisfaction in having an age of our own.
One fear that 1 have is that the age of the consumer may
be superseded by the age of the regulator and the liti­
gator. One should always remember that the main purpose
of protective legislation and regulation is to help the
consumer satisfy his material demands safely and at the
lowest possible cost. One of the great dangers in any
kind of regulation is the tendency of the regulation to




- 2 -

become an end in itself, perpetuated by the vested inter­
ests of the regulators and by inertia.
I recall learning in my study of American history
that one of the American colonists' complaints against
Britain concerned laws and regulations that had been im­
posed in the distant past, partly, at least, in a wellmeaning effort to protect consumers against squandering
their limited means on ill-advised luxury expenditures.
These laws outlived their usefulness and became a hin­
drance to industry and trade. To the extent that they
hindered efficient production and distribution, they in­
jured the consumer. One of the great contributions of
Adam Smith, the father of the classical school of eco­
nomics, was his demonstration that the consumers of Eigh­
teenth Century England were being prevented from enjoying
the fruits of the most efficient possible production. This
was being accomplished both by governmental action and by
private combinations in restraint of trade.
In this respect, I think it is a happy coincidence
that the year 1776 saw the publication of both Adam Smith's
Wealth of Nations - dedicated to the free marketplace - and
our own Declaration of Independence which proclaimed politi­
cal liberty. In this sense, the roots of the consumer age
go back to 1776, for it is precisely the great technologi­
cal developments, combined with relative freedom of enter­
prise and trade, which have enabled the ordinary consumer
to enjoy material satisfactions that were beyond the reach
of royalty in earlier epochs (e.g., Louis XIV did not have
a TV).
It is desirable to look at our present-day problems
in this perspective. We are not on the threshold of any
comparable advance in consumer welfare at the present time.
Essentially, we are simply oiling the engine and polishing
the brass to make the machinery not only look better, but
work better and more smoothly, for the benefit of the con­
sumers. It is desirable that we do this. At the same
time, we must keep our eye firmly fixed on the objective
of keeping the productive machinery operating efficiently.
We must be sure it is oil, not sand, that we are putting
in the bearings.




- 3 -

Since the passage of the Truth in Lending Act in
1968, which everyone must recognize as a landmark, a spate
of new legislation has been passed or proposed that affects
your relations with your customers. In 1970, Congress pro­
hibited the unsolicited distribution of credit cards and
severely restricted card holder liability for lost or stolen
cards. These measures may have reduced somewhat the profit­
ability of credit card operations, but they have gone far
to eliminate consumer complaints about that convenient de­
vice. Credit cards are here to stay, and the measures taken
in 1970 to protect users probably gave the cards a firmer
base of public acceptance.
Last year the Fair Credit Reporting Act became ef­
fective. This gave consumers important new rights to re­
ceive notice from creditors when credit was denied, or its
cost increased, because of an adverse credit report. It
also gave consumers access to the information in their
credit files so that they can correct any errors that may
have crept in. In a sense, this was a logical extension
of the principle underlying Truth in Lending. The borrower
is not only entitled to correct and clear information about
the terms of credit being offered, but he is also entitled
to know the reasons for decisions that denied him credit or
increased its cost to him.
While these measures may add to the costs and head­
aches of the lenders to some degree - and I am not at all
sure that they will - I view them as useful oiling of the
credit machinery. The advantage gained in terms of dimin­
ishing the chance that a serious injustice may be done to a
customer or a shattering loss may be visited upon a credit
card holder is quite substantial. At a time when our eco­
nomic system is under attack on the grounds that it is mind­
less, impersonal, and dehumanizing, it is, I submit, merely
enlightened self-interest to minimize the chance of injus­
tice and introduce as much rationality, due process, and
concern as is reasonably possible in the areas which im­
pinge on the daily lives of so many Americans. Moreover,
and to return to the question of cost, I think these safety
devices, if I may call them that, are virtually indispens­
able accessories to the miraculous data-processing hardware
which itself has afforded such expanded horizons to the




- 4 -

whole credit industry and whose overall costs as accesso­
ries is an infinitesimal portion of the resulting produc­
tivity gains.
Congress now has under consideration a proposal that
is called the "Fair Credit Billing Act" - S . 652. This bill
recently passed the Senate, after having been substantially
altered from the form in which it was introduced by Senator
Proxmire. Some of the provisions taken out by the Senate
may be restored by the House. No one knows precisely the
form this bill may finally take.
As the bill came out of the Senate, it required some
significant changes in the handling of billing statements,
changes that may overcome some of the dehumanization that
has been introduced by computerized billing. The legis­
lation would require creditors to acknowledge promptly
customer queries about billing errors and to investigate
the validity of complaints. It would forbid a creditor to
threaten a customer with an adverse credit report during
the investigation period. Where a billing dispute con­
tinues even after the investigation has been made, the
creditor may not report the account delinquent unless he
also reports that there is a dispute. He must also tell
the customer the name and address of the party to whom he
is reporting the credit information.
This legislative proposal also provides that in ac­
counts involving a "free ride", a finance charge may not
be imposed unless the billing statement is mailed at least
fourteen days before the date by which payment must be made
to avoid the charge. It would also bar the practice of some
merchants in limiting the use of credit for returned mer­
chandise to the purchase of other merchandise in the store.
Such provisions are a little more oil for the ma­
chinery. But there are some larger issues that have been
associated with this piece of legislation. The original
Senate bill provided for a radical reduction in the scope
of the time-honored "holder-in-due-course doctrine".
Under that rule, as you know, a bank or other per­
son that has bought a promissory note from a retailer, for




- 5 -

example, can enforce the obligation against the maker even
if the note was given for a refrigerator that did not re­
frigerate or a car that did not run, provided the bank is
a "holder in due course". If the bank did not know that
the merchandise was faulty when it bought the note, it has
a valid claim on the maker, even though the maker has a
valid defense at law against the dealer who sold the note
to the bank.
While English and American courts have generally
enforced the rule, they have done so in a manner which has
often followed St. Paul's injunction that the letter killeth
and the spirit giveth life. Indeed, judicial sympathies
with the victimized consumer have been obvious in the hard
line that courts have so often taken in requiring financing
institutions to come squarely within the legal definition
of due-course-holding, and the frequency with which they
have denied such standing by reason of the workday incidents
of the bank-dealer relationships. So, as a lawyer, I count
it all to the good when courts and judges will be permitted
to enforce the equities of the situation in response to the
plain letter of the law and not through a process of strained
rationalization, however just the results may be.
The holder-in-due-course rule was developed in order
to promote commercial fluidity. It was the consequence of
a negotiable instrument as a "courier without luggage" which
moved as a money-substitute among relatively small but highly
and equally sophisticated parties in interest. It was thought
that if bankers and other investors had to worry about the
health of a horse, for example, that had been sold to the
maker of the note, they would hesitate to purchase such
paper, and commerce would languish for lack of working capi­
tal. When sued on such a note by an innocent transferee,
the maker was not permitted to defend on the ground that
the horse, warranted to be three years old, actually was
thirty. His remedy, he was told, was against the dishonest
horse trader. By this time, unfortunately, the trader had
changed his name and disappeared, or had gone into bank­
ruptcy.
In my judgment, the holder-in-due-course doctrine
should be changed with respect to consumer transactions




- 6 -

whether installment contracts or credit card purchases.
In this I am far from alone. Indeed, I note that a sur­
vey of the President's Office of Consumer Affairs found
the doctrine under heavy attack in 1971, with thirteen
states now substantially restricting or even outlawing
it in consumer transactions. Moreover, in retrospect,
I am not so sure that the doctrine should have ever been
permitted to creep into consumer transactions in the first
place. Be that as it may, the world is a very different
place than when the doctrine first arose, and while I am
emphatically not suggesting that it be enforced with any
less vigor in commercial dealing between commercial par­
ties, it is surely worth noting that even the Federal Re­
serve has abolished negotiability as a precondition of
eligibility of commercial paper at the discount window.
In the rare situation where the dealer has cheated
all of his customers and is now insolvent, it is more
equitable, I believe, for a financial institution to bear
the loss, rather than helpless consumers. Both are inno­
cent of wrongdoing; both were taken in by the same dishon­
est merchant. And in such cases, there is an old rule of
the common law which may be of some help. It is that where
one of two innocent parties must suffer, let it be the one
most responsible for the loss. While I am far from sug­
gesting it as a rule of universal causation, I think it is
worthy of consideration that in so many of these cases the
defaulting merchant would not even have been in business
had he not had the benefit of an ongoing association with
and the assistance of a financial institution. And quite
apart from this consideration of knowing the originator
of paper and choosing him with care - which will bring a
parity of competition between the careful, concerned, and
ethical financing institutions and those who may be less
so - is it also not better to spare the individual and
leave it to the institution to recoup or to spread the
loss, almost imperceptibly, throughout the community?
You may ask: Why did this mile develop and stand
for hundreds of years if it is unjust and deserves repeal
or modification? The answer is simple: Times change.
The rule was developed when poor people did not sign




- 7 -

notes. In the eighteenth century, the names on commercial
paper were those of merchants, aristocrats, ship owners,
and such. Today, in consumer credit, the maker of a note
and the payee do not trade as equals. The danger of over­
reaching is considerable, and most consumers do not have
the knowledge, time, or means to protect themselves. In
this field, the holder-in-due-course doctrine has outlived
its usefulness, and it should be trimmed back.
There are those who argue that this step would
amount to putting sand in the bearings - that consumers
will try to avoid their obligations by false claims of
merchandise or service defects. I believe that such fears
are exaggerated. One thing that our long experience with
consumer credit has taught us is that the overwhelming ma­
jority of borrowers are honest. The deadbeat problem has
been minimal. The problems in this area are more likely
to arise from the activities of a few unscrupulous busi­
nessmen, and lending institutions are in a better position
than are consumers to right those wrongs.
Another area of controversy associated with this
legislation relates to the means of redress available to
those who are victimized by violations of the Truth in
Lending Act. The legal situation as it now stands is not
satisfactory.
On the one hand, the consumer with a small claim
against a creditor who has violated Truth in Lending is
not likely to go to the trouble and expense of litigation.
True, he may recover his expenses at the conclusion of the
law suit, provided he is successful. But often the dam­
ages would not make it worth his trouble. On the other
hand, we have the excessive exposure for technical Truth
in Lending violations under class actions, when you mul­
tiply the $100 minimum recovery per customer by the vast
numbers of consumers in a given class - for example, credit
card holders. It may be that our existing court system is
simply not the appropriate mechanism for handling such con­
sumer claims, either of a small nature or of an unduly large
class. Alternatives to either of these possibilities need
to be explored. Perhaps some system of flexible and in­
formal proceedings such as the use of hearing examiners




may be the answer. Or possibly there may be some useful
analogies suggested in the recent Brookings Commission
report on the bankruptcy courts where the not dissimilar
problems of cost, time, and formalism were considered.
With reference to class actions under Truth in
Lending, a good deal has been said about the danger of
judgments running into millions of dollars on behalf of
a "class", for an unintentional minor violation of Regu­
lation Z by a credit card issuer. In my view, creditors
should not be subject to liability where they have in good
faith followed Regulation Z and the Federal Reserve Board's
interpretations of that regulation. At present, it is
conceivable that a court might declare the Board's rules
or interpretations invalid and subject a creditor to lia­
bility for failure to follow the Act, where the court con­
strues the Act differently than the Board has. To remedy
this inequitable jeopardy, the Board suggested to Congress
that a "good faith reliance" provision be added to the
civil liability provisions of the Truth in Lending Act,
and such a provision would be added to the Act by S. 652.
It provides that a creditor is not liable for any act done
or omitted in good faith and in conformity with any regula­
tion or interpretation of the Board, even if the regulation
or interpretation is later determined by a court to be in­
valid.
While this "good faith" provision is a necessary
addition to the Act in order to avoid the unfair imposi­
tion of liability, S. 652 would also modify the civil
liability provisions of the Truth in Lending Act in ways
that, in my own view, unnecessarily restrict the ability
of consumers to proceed against creditors who willfully
or negligently violate the Act.
The Senate Committee which reported the bill recom­
mended that liability in a class action be limited to the
lesser of $50,000 or 2 per cent of the net worth of the
creditor. I believe that this remedy is not strong enough
to insure compliance among all creditors and that class
action liability should not be so limited as to remove
the deterrent effect and aagtttacagement to compliance which




£

~

- 9 -

is the product of stiff, but fair, class action provisions.
The stakes must be high for those who cavalierly violate
the Act, in fairness to those of you who have borne the
significant cost of conscientious efforts to comply. Con­
sequently, I recommended, during consideration of S. 652,
that the provision should be changed to allow for such dam­
ages as the court may allow, but not more than the greater
of $50,000 or 1 per cent of the creditor's net worth. With
discretion to impose liability within these limits, the
courts would be free to impose a lesser liability where
a $50,000 judgment might threaten the solvency of the de­
fendant, or where the violation was inconsequential or un­
intentional. Serious violators could be subjected to stiffer
penalties.
However, as it passed the Senate, S. 652 set an upper
limit of $100,000 on class action liability, without any ref­
erence to net worth - a figure that could be catastrophic
for a small lender, but insignificant for a big one. In my
view, this limitation is too low. The possibility of a heavy
penalty, imposed with judicial discretion, is needed to pro­
vide the deterrent effect so necessary if Truth in Lending
is to be effective against lenders with resources running
up into the billions.
The problem, then, is to find a formula that will
provide a meaningful deterrent to large companies but which
will not be so large as to threaten bankruptcy for any de­
fendants. This was the intent - and would be the effect of linking the size of the penalty to the net worth of the
offender. There should be a reasonable upper limit that
recognizes differences in the resources of creditors (and
the often corresponding sizes of classes of affected con­
sumers) .
These are only a few of the legislative issues that
are currently of concern to consumer credit people. Un­
questionably, your field is going to continue to receive
the attention of the consumer activists and of the national
and state legislatures. This is both natural and desirable
because of the important role that consumer credit has come
to play in our economic life. However, if you sometimes




- 10 -

feel that you are being sniped at because of relatively
minor imperfections, let me assure you that I, for one,
am an admirer of the achievements of consumer credit in
this country. We have led the world in developing con­
sumer credit and in pioneering such conveniences as credit
cards. I believe that these accomplishments have added
greatly to consumer satisfaction and to our ability to
distribute the goods that our great industrial machine
is capable of producing.
Sometimes, of course, industry has not been will­
ing or able to apply its own lubricant to the squeaking
parts. It is then that Congress has stepped in. Inter­
vention of this type represents the greatest challenge to
industry - to assure that necessary adjustments will be
made as expertly as possible. Let me offer you, briefly,
my thoughts on how you can assure that the legislative
tune-ups will be truly beneficial.
The first requisite is knowledge of which compon­
ents of the machinery really need attention. That comes
from realistic appraisal of the areas of legitimate con­
sumer concern and industry shortcomings. Congressional
interest in consumer matters should not be underestimated,
or misjudged as political posturing. A false assessment
of public and Congressional concern may cause the industry
to miss its opportunity to participate constructively in
the development of inevitable legislation. As a regulator,
I know firsthand of troublesome problems in the enforce­
ment of statutes that could have been solved at the draft­
ing stage. However, the industry's mechanics - those who
knew the machinery best - simply were not there when the
adjustment should have been made.
Industry's essential participation does not end with
the enactment of legislation. There is a continuing need
for its comments and criticisms during the regulation draft­
ing stage. We at the Federal Reserve Board listened atten­
tively to industry's comments during and after the issuance
of Regulation Z. I urge you to make continued constructive
use of the opportunity to present your views on how to make
regulatory proposals less burdensome, more understandable




- 11 -

to all, and of greater benefit to the public. For example,
one of the most pressing tasks at hand is to find a means
of simplifying Regulation Z. We have not had much suc­
cess. Perhaps some of you can point the way.
There are going to be changes required of the con­
sumer credit industry that will present new challenges as
well as new opportunities. Those who fail to anticipate
the trends and to respond creatively may find the adjust­
ment process painful. Those who fail to recognize and ac­
cept the adjustments, who insist on doing "business as
usual", without the extra effort required to satisfy to­
day's consumers, may fall by the competitive wayside.
However, those who understand and work to shape new consumer-credit regulation, those who respond to the new re­
lationships between creditors and customers, will not only
survive new regulation but will emerge as leaders of the
industry. Responsive credit grantors, attuned to the times,
have an unprecedented opportunity to woo and win today's
more enlightened, more discriminating, more demanding cus­
tomers .
The consumers of the 70's have more bargaining
power, are more knowledgeable about credit, and are more
demanding in what they want for their money. At the same
time, they are more affluent, more comfortable with credit
purchasing, and more sensitive to the importance of main­
taining good credit ratings. They make ideal customers.
By meeting the challenges presented by these new-style
customers, by tuning up this great credit machine of ours,
by systematically and intelligently applying oil to the
machinery to keep it operating smoothly, the consumer
credit industry can continue to point with pride to the
vital role it plays in our economy, and at the same time
provide the most effective defense against those who would
pour sand in the bearings.