View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Embargoed until:
7:00 a.m. CDT
June 4, 2008

A Perspective on the U.S. Economy

James Bullard*
President, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Northwest Arkansas Convention Center
Rogers, Arkansas
June 4, 2008

*I appreciate assistance and comments provided by my colleagues at the Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis. Robert H. Rasche, Senior Vice President and Director of Research, and Marcela
Williams, Special Research Assistant to the President, provided assistance. I take full
responsibility for errors. The views expressed are mine and do not necessarily reflect official
positions of the Federal Reserve System.

A Perspective on the U.S. Economy
Introduction
It is a pleasure to be here this morning to talk with you about the state of the U.S.
economy. I am impressed that such a large group is willing to come to breakfast to hear an
economist like me give a talk. By the time this is over, of course, some of you may wish you had
decided to sleep in!
As many of you know, I joined the Federal Open Market Committee at a difficult
juncture for the Committee and for the American economy. Growth in real gross domestic
product, one of our best measures of overall health in the economy, has been sluggish. Financial
markets have been struggling to return to normal operation since the current turmoil began in
earnest 10 months ago. In addition, the housing sector has been extraordinarily weak for some
time, with prices falling and sales of both new and existing homes on the decline. The Federal
Reserve has responded to this situation by instituting an array of new lending facilities and
sharply lowering interest rates through the fall of 2007 and into the first several months of 2008.
My intention this morning is to talk about these developments in the context of mediumand longer-term objectives for monetary policy. My sense is that the U.S. economy will be able
to post stronger growth in the second half of this year despite the ongoing financial crisis and the
drag from the housing sector. As I will make clear, such growth is likely to make the inflation
outlook a more pressing concern for the Fed in the second half of this year.
Let me say before I continue that any views expressed here are my own and do not
necessarily reflect the official views of the Federal Open Market Committee or the Federal
Reserve System.

1

Before saying more about the current situation in the U.S. economy, let me provide some
context for my current views by describing the goals and objectives of monetary policy as I see
them.

A General Perspective on the Objectives of Monetary Policy
Over the past two decades, much has been said about the benefits of transparency and
accountability in the conduct of monetary policy. Much has been achieved, both in the United
States and abroad, to reach these goals. I applaud these developments, and I believe that
progress in this direction can and should continue. Consistent with those principles, in my role
as the newest participant on the FOMC, I want to talk for a few moments about my fundamental
beliefs on the appropriate objectives of monetary policy.
One of the guiding principles from contemporary economic theory is that monetary
policy should be conducted in a systematic and predictable fashion. The expectations of
economic actors are critically important for the nature of equilibrium in the economy. These
expectations evolve in part according to the outlook for future policy itself and the implications
of that policy for the path of the economy. This view, once considered radical, is now widely
accepted in academia and by monetary policymakers around the world. This perspective rejects
an alternative view, common in an earlier era in macroeconomics, that policy actions are most
useful when they surprise participants in financial markets and the public more generally.
Systematic monetary policy must start with a clear statement of the ultimate policy
objectives. The Federal Reserve is commonly characterized as striving to foster price stability
along with maximum sustainable employment. Other central banks, including the European
Central Bank (ECB) and the Reserve Bank of New Zealand, for example, are charged with a

2

single mandate: to maintain price stability. In the 1960s, the dual mandate was perceived to
require a policy tradeoff. Under the then-prevailing Phillips curve hypothesis, lower inflation
could be achieved only at a cost of higher unemployment. Today, the consensus view is that
there is no long-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. Indeed, a succession of Fed
Chairmen—Paul Volcker, Alan Greenspan, and Ben Bernanke—have emphasized the
complementarity of the two objectives: namely, that price stability is a precondition for
maximum sustainable employment. 1 I agree with this perspective.
Moreover, I have been impressed during my 18-year career as a Fed economist in
considering the contrast in the behavior of the U.S. economy between the high inflation period of
the 1970s and the more-recent period of low inflation. Between 1965 and 1984, U.S. inflation
rose to double-digit levels before falling again. Since that time, inflation has remained under
better control. The earlier era was associated not only with higher and more variable inflation,
but also with a more volatile real economy. My sense is that a monetary policy better-focused on
price stability has made an important contribution to the improved stability on the real side of the
economy that we have observed since 1984.
This stability has meant a lot to the average household in our nation: long periods of
uninterrupted growth punctuated by just two mild recessions since the mid-1980s.
Price stability has multiple interpretations. In the late 19th and early 20th centuries, price
stability meant that variations in the general level of prices would be transitory: the price index
would revert to a mean. In recent policy discussions, price stability generally is interpreted as a
small positive rate of inflation. Under these conditions, the level of prices does not revert to a
constant, but trends upward. I accept this latter definition of price stability. There may be

1

See, for example, Ben S. Bernanke, “The Benefits of Price Stability,” February 24, 2006.
<www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20060224a.htm>.

3

theoretical and practical reasons to believe that the best price indexes we have available are
subject to upward biases. While I am not a big fan of the upward-bias argument—after all, the
best-available adjustments are already made to the indexes—I admit that I do not have better
measures myself. My preferred definition of price stability is that trend inflation, correctly
measured, is zero. In practice, this likely converts into a trend in measured inflation on the order
of ½ to 1½ percent, depending on the particular price index referenced.
One important aspect of my definition of price stability, which I will revisit this morning,
is that it concerns only the trend in inflation. Central banks cannot and should not try to control
period-to-period fluctuations in any measured price index. Such fluctuations are largely
transitory and reflect different movements of various relative prices. Price stability as a policy
objective for a central bank must be focused on the longer-run behavior of the inflation rate.
Given the current state of knowledge, a central bank that maintains a low and stable average rate
of inflation over a horizon of two to three years should be judged successful at achieving price
stability.
A sustained era of price stability requires that central banks create an environment in
which financial market participants and the general public maintain the expectation that future
inflation will remain low and stable. Such an environment frequently is characterized as having
an “anchor for inflation expectations”; in some cases, the central bank establishes such an anchor
for the economy by announcing an explicit numeric inflation target. The Reserve Bank of New
Zealand was the first institution to choose this approach. During the 1990s it was followed by
the Bank of Canada, the Bank of England, and the European Central Bank, among others.
The FOMC has chosen not to announce such a quantitative guideline, although many past
and current participants on the Committee have expressed individual preferences or “comfort

4

zones” about ranges of inflation that they personally feel are appropriate objectives for policy.
Within the past year, the FOMC has started publishing the ranges and central tendency of the
inflation forecasts of the participants on a three-year horizon. These forecasts generally have
been consistent with the revealed “comfort zones.” In the media, midpoints of these forecasts
are often associated with an implicit FOMC objective for trend inflation. This represents
important progress concerning the transparency of the FOMC inflation objective. Still, there is
some risk that if the evolving inflation situation appears inconsistent with the inflation objective
that is inferred from the revealed preferences of the individual FOMC participants, the anchor for
inflation expectations may start to drag or come completely loose.
I take some comfort that, even absent an explicit numeric inflation objective, the FOMC
has achieved a nominal anchor for the economy over the past 25 years. The Committee
accomplished this the old-fashioned way—the Fed earned credibility for the expectation of low
and stable trend inflation based on the successful outcome of about 25 years of policy history.
The Volcker disinflation in the early 1980s succeeded in stabilizing inflation around 4 percent
per annum. After a mild and short-lived inflation breakout in the late 1980s, the Greenspan Fed
produced a declining trend in inflation throughout the 1990s and into the first few years of the
21st century.
Despite this past success, it is my judgment that at the present time inflation expectations
are fragile. By many measures, inflation has trended up in recent years. At the same time,
available measures of long-term inflation expectations, whether from survey data or from
Treasury inflation-protected securities spreads, have remained remarkably stable. My sense is
that, absent stabilization or reversal of the recent trend in inflation, those expectations will begin
to move higher. That is, market participants, businesses, and consumers will come to view higher

5

inflation as part of the economic landscape. These expectations will then feed into the
equilibrium of the economy and will be difficult to reverse.
A breakdown in inflation expectations has not occurred yet, to be sure, but the risk is real.
It is possible that a breakdown could happen over a very short horizon. Indeed, in the May 2008
University of Michigan/Reuters survey, the 12-month-ahead median expected inflation rate
jumped to 5.2 percent (from 4.8 percent) and 25 percent of respondents reported expecting
inflation in excess of 10 percent over the next 12 months! My sense is that these extraordinary
readings were driven in part by recent exceptional increases in certain commodities prices,
especially gasoline. Still, the 5-year-ahead median expected inflation has drifted up to 3.3
percent.
Despite these worrisome numbers, I think that the Fed can contain the potential for
inflation expectations to drift higher. It is rule number one in modern central banking that
inflation and inflation expectations be kept under control. Let me repeat that: It is rule number
one in modern central banking that inflation and inflation expectations be kept under control.
After a 10-month period in which the dominant policy concern has rightly been the state of
financial markets, policy can begin to address pressing inflationary concerns during the
remainder of the year. While it is too early to say that the financial market turmoil has
completely abated, the Fed’s new lending facilities combined with an environment of low
interest rates have gone some distance to return markets to more normal operation.

Some Implications for the Current Policy Environment
In August of last year, the FOMC took the first of a sequence of policy actions that
reduced the target for the federal funds rate 325 basis points, from 5.25 percent to 2 percent. The

6

initial actions were motivated by turmoil in credit markets. By the end of last year, evidence of
slowing economic growth emerged. By early this spring, many commentators and some
economic forecasters were predicting that the economy was in or about to enter a recession. The
most recent Blue Chip consensus forecast projects positive growth in real GDP for each quarter
in 2008, though the projected growth in the second quarter is close to zero. The most recent
quarter-by-quarter outlook from the Survey of Professional Forecasters is almost identical to the
Blue Chip consensus. Within the past month, forecasters have generally backed off substantially
in their estimates of the probability that the economy is now in or will soon enter a recession.
These forecasts may have a more optimistic tone than many of you have heard earlier this
year. I think this is because financial market turmoil is waning. A financial crisis is, naturally, a
time of great uncertainty, as market participants are all wondering what will happen next.
Forecasters have to take into account the possibility that the crisis will worsen to the point that a
great deal of harm is done to U.S. financial markets. My sense is that, during the first several
months of this year, some forecasts were putting a high probability on such an outcome. As the
probability of especially severe damage to the financial system recedes, forecasts are being
revised upward. This is complicating the inflation outlook for those projecting that significant
economic slack would help to keep inflation in check.
Current consensus forecasts show no sign of relief for the near-term inflation situation.
The Blue Chip consensus forecast for core CPI inflation for 2008 over 2007 is 2.4 percent. The
forecast for 2009, at 2.3 percent, is essentially unchanged. The Survey of Professional
Forecasters puts inflation at 2.3 percent in both years. These forecasts show little change from
the inflation experience in 2007. Forecasts of headline CPI inflation are more disturbing, with

7

both the Blue Chip and the Survey of Professional Forecasters current forecasts in excess of 3
percent. This inflation outlook is not consistent with my view of price stability.
Still, given the current economic environment and the outlook for the next 18 months, my
view is that policy is appropriately calibrated at this time. I see several reasons why maintaining
the current policy is a good option for now.
First, the FOMC has already reduced the target federal funds rate by 325 basis points.
These policy actions were preemptive and involved more aggressive rate cuts than in previous
episodes, such as 1990-91 or 2001. The rate reductions were based on forecasts that economic
activity would slow in the face of contracting housing activity and substantial turmoil in financial
markets. Growth has indeed been slow, at least for the first half of 2008, but that cannot now be
justification for further rate reductions. Surprises to forecasts of economic activity, if any, have
been to the upside. Acting preemptively means that patience is required when circumstances
play out in a way that is consistent with the forecast. Further action in the absence of substantial
forecast errors would be double counting: in effect, reacting twice to the same concern.
Second, the full impact of monetary policy actions is not realized immediately. It is
likely that additional stimulus to economic activity from the monetary policy actions taken in
January and March will peak in the second half of 2008. In addition, there is a fiscal stimulus
program in place that may shift some spending into the second and third quarters of this year.
Any additional monetary policy actions must be judged by their expected impacts in the future in
light of current forecasts of the evolution of the economy. The best judgment, as incorporated in
current forecasts, is that the pace of economic activity will recover in the second half of 2008 and
throughout 2009.

8

Third, at the current funds rate target of 2 percent, real interest rates are quite low by
historical standards. Short-term real rates computed by subtracting near-term forecasts of
headline inflation from nominal rates are significantly negative. Three- to six-month-ahead
headline CPI inflation forecasts exceed 3 percent; some forecasts for this period exceed 3.5
percent. Three-month Treasury bill and prime nonfinancial commercial paper rates are less than
2 percent. Even when evaluated against forecasts of core inflation rates, these yields are zero to
slightly negative in real terms. Five-year inflation-indexed Treasury note yields are essentially
zero. In short, the Fed has created a low interest rate environment that should allow the economy
to continue to adjust to the drag from the housing sector and the aftermath of financial market
turmoil.

Headline versus Core Inflation
As I mentioned earlier, there are many different ways to measure and discuss inflation.
Since July 2004, the FOMC has focused on inflation measured by the core PCE price index in
the semiannual Monetary Policy Reports. I think everyone in this room is aware of the fact that,
for most of the time since 2003, headline inflation has exceeded core inflation. What are the
relative merits of focusing on core rather than the headline inflation? 2
Core measures of inflation defined as excluding food prices have been constructed by the
BLS at least since 1957. Core measures of inflation excluding both food and energy prices have
been published since 1977. The rationale for these measures is not well documented, but it is
likely that the original intent was to better reveal inflation trends. Historically real food prices
exhibited large transitory movements. Some of the major changes in real energy prices in the

2

For a discussion of this issue, see Mark Wynne, “Core Inflation: A Review of Some Conceptual Issues,” Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Part II, May/June 2008, pp. 205-228.

9

1970s and mid-1980s also proved transitory. Under these conditions, a focus on core measures
gave policymakers a clearer indication of changes in the trend of inflation that was subject to
policy control. Much of the volatility of these prices originated with supply shocks in particular
markets: droughts, crop failures, abundant harvests, OPEC boycotts, political disturbances in
major oil-producing countries, and the collapse of the world oil market. Supply disturbances of
this sort do not produce the persistent spreads between headline and core inflation measures that
have been observed over the past five years.
I believe that consideration has to be given to the hypothesis that different forces have
driven the relative price of food and energy in the recent past—namely, shifts in demand in
world markets. These forces are likely to persist for some time. In particular, I have in mind
rapid increases in standards of living in large emerging-market economies. Associated with
these increases in living standards are higher consumption of calories and higher consumption of
energy and thus increasing demand in the global markets for these products. With low short-run
elasticity of supply for food and energy production, these trends in demand generate trends in
relative prices.
The best forecast is that China, in particular, will continue to grow at a rapid rate for the
next decade. Longer-run elasticities of supply for agricultural products are likely substantially
larger than short-run elasticities, and hence the trend in relative prices of food can be expected to
moderate. Trends in relative energy prices may moderate with the emergence of new
technologies. Nevertheless, a plausible case can be made that current trends in these relative
prices will persist and that, therefore, headline measures of inflation will remain above core
measures.

10

Should policymakers take into consideration persistent differences in headline and core
measures of inflation? I believe that consistency requires attention to such differences in the
formulation of policy. Unless there are compelling reasons to do otherwise, policy has to focus
on the prices actually faced by households and businesses. 3 Persistent and substantial trends in
other relative prices are not factored out in measuring overall inflation trends. The relative prices
of computers, communications equipment, and consumer electronics, for instance, have been
falling for decades. However, no one to my knowledge has argued that we are understating the
fundamental trend in inflation because our core measures do not exclude these items.
Available price indexes may be viewed as reasonably good estimates of consumer
purchasing power. Food and energy are significant components of consumer budgets, as
witnessed by the abundant commentary on recent price changes. Monetary policy aimed at price
stability cannot ignore continuing deterioration of purchasing power, regardless of the source. It
is the overall trend in prices that is the inflation measure on which central bankers must
concentrate. If, under current global market conditions, historical core indexes do not measure
that trend appropriately, then it is necessary to develop filters that produce unbiased measures of
trend inflation.

Conclusions
I appreciate having this opportunity to share with all of you some of my thoughts on the
current state of the U.S. economy. While these are challenging times for monetary policymakers,
I am cautiously optimistic that we can move into the second half of 2008 with reduced financial

3

One recent analysis of this issue is by Bodenstein, Erceg, and Guerrieri (2007), which provides some support for
focusing on core inflation when energy prices are volatile. I think this is a good example of the type of research
required, but I also think that conclusions in this area will depend sensitively on the details of the model used and
that the possibility of a relative price trend has to be addressed.

11

market turmoil, reduced drag from the housing sector, more rapid economic growth, and a
renewed focus on keeping inflation low and stable.

References
Bernanke, Ben S. (2006). “The Benefits of Price Stability,” speech delivered at The Center for
Economic Policy Studies and on the occasion of the Seventy-Fifth Anniversary of the Woodrow
Wilson School of Public and International Affairs, Princeton University, Princeton, New Jersey,
February 24. <www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20060224a.htm>
Bodenstein, Martin, Christopher Erceg, and Luca Guerrieri (2007). "Optimal Monetary Policy in
a Model with Distinct Core and Headline Inflation Rates," unpublished paper, Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
<http://dallasfed.org/news/research/2007/07taylor_erceg.pdf>
Wynne, Mark A. “Core Inflation: A Review of Some Conceptual Issues,” Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis Review, May/June 2008, 90(3, Part2), pp. 205-28.

12