View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
MONDAY, DECEMBER 10, 1984
6:15 P.M. LOCAL TIME (12:15 P.M. EST)

THE FOREIGN IMPACT OF THE U.S. BUDGET DEFICIT

Summary of remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
to the
Swiss-American Society Basel
Basel, Switzerland
December 10, 1984

THE FOREIGN IMPACT OF THE U.S. BUDGET DEFICIT
Summary of remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
to the
Swiss-American Society Basel
Basel, Switzerland
December 10, 1984

1.

The strong performance of the U.S. economy has brought important benefits
also to other countries.

Rapid growth of economic activity, stimulated

by a large budget deficit and favorable tax changes, has increased U.S.
imports.

The large budget deficit, by raising dollar interest rates, has

caused the dollar to appreciate, firrther stimulating imports.

2.

High dollar interest rates have to some extent counteracted these
beneficial effects in the rest of the world.

But the importance of

U.S. interest rates for interest rates abroad can easily be exaggerated.
Major countries have been able to uncouple from U.S. interest rates.

Many

countries, moreover, have had reasons of their own for high domestic
interest rates, such as large budget deficits and some degree of infla­
tion.

One piece of evidence of this is that, as U.S. interest rates have

come down recently, interest rates abroad have declined much less if at
all.

3.

The inflationary effect for other countries of a high dollar also can
easily be overrated.

Prices quoted in dollars are not necessarily prices

determined by U.S. supply and demand but often, as in the case of oil, by

-2
world supply and demand.

A high dollar means downward pressure on such

world market commodities, as can be observed by the behavior of the prices
of oil and of many internationally traded commodities.

4.

It has been argued that the United States is draining much-needed capital
from the rest of the world through its external deficit which must be
financed by corresponding capital imports.

This would be a serious matter

if the rest of the world were close to full employment.

In that case, there

would be no room for expanding the supply of savings through a rise in income.
At present very high levels of unemployment and excess capacity, savings
would increase if income rises, for instance, as a result of higher exports.
A capital flow to the United States means that other countries are obtaining
an export surplus (or a reduction in their external deficits) which helps
generate the savings that they transmit to the United States. Most countries
seem to welcome this improvement in their current account.

Of course, such

an improvement necessarily implies an export of capital.

5.

The high dollar has been a cause of widespread concern.

By all the theories

and behavioral rules of the exchange market, it is difficult to explain the
level of the dollar in terms of economic fundamentals.

Current purchasing-

power parity has long been left behind by the dollar; otherwise, the U.S.
current-account deficit would not be anywhere near as large as it is.
Superior inflation performance does not explain the dollar's level, since
countries like Japan and Germany have performed even better and some others
have performed not much worse.

Such a large external deficit in any other

country probably would mean a weak rather than strong currency.

Interest-

rate differentials have been substantial and the dollar's behavior has been

-3broadly in accordance with movements in these differentials.

Neverthe­

less, when interest-rate differentials diminished significantly in recent
months, the dollar remained high and even advanced against some major
currencies.

It is not surprising that some market participants, unable

to discern visible sources of support, speak of a levitation act.

6.

The good investment climate of the United States has often been cited as
a reason for the strong capital inflow into the United States and for the
resultant high dollar.

The inflow indeed has overfinanced the deficit that

would have come about had the dollar not appreciated, and so has driven up
the dollar.

A smaller inflow would have been sufficient to finance the

external deficit at a constant exchange rate.

7.

It seems apparent that the United States does indeed have a good investment
climate.

Important tax changes were made in 1981 to raise the return on

business investment, although some of these were modified in 1983 and others
might be removed under the Treasury's late-1984 tax reform proposal.

The

dynamism of the economy is generally recognized; a pro-enterprise spirit
prevails, labor markets are flexible, wage trends moderate.

8.

Nonetheless, corporate profits, although much inproved, especially in
economic terms (i.e., after adjustment for inventory profits and under­
depreciation), are lower, as a share of GNP, than they were, for instance,
during a good part of the 1950's and 1960's.
ment —

Gross business fixed invest­

although at a historical high of 12-1/2 percent of GNP —

in net

terms, i.e., after depreciation, at 3-1/2 percent is not significantly
above longer term experience.

Because a larger part of gross investment

than formerly takes the form of short-lived equipment, depreciation

therefore is higher and growth of net business fixed investment as a
share of GNP is not much above the historical average.

9.

Examination of the U.S. capital account reveals, furthermore, that the
bulk of the recorded inflows are not what one would normally think of as
investment type.
banking flows.

Much of them essentially takes the form of short-term
Corporate flows reflecting U.S. corporate borrowings through

the frequently cheaper Eurobond market also seem to have more a financial
than an investment character.

Inflows reflecting an investment purpose,

especially direct investment and purchases of equities, have not been
overly strong.

10.

Certainly they have not dominated the totality of the flows.

The particular form of an investment does not necessarily reflect its
purpose.

Most securities, even long-term, have a high degree of liquidity

and positions can readily be reversed.

On the other hand, the item "errors

and omissions," which in some years has been substantial, may contain
investment-type flows.

All in all, however, examination of the U.S.

capital account suggests that the great bulk of the flows has been of
a financial rather than investment nature, including particularly banking
flows.

This suggests that the main driving force behind the high dollar

has been a difference in real interest rates, even though month by month
that differential does not seem decisive.

11.

The size of total capital inflows appears understated if recomputed on
the basis of cumulative current-account deficits instead of recorded
capital transactions.

On the other hand, certain discrepancies in inter­

national payments statistics imply that aggregate world deficits may have

-

been overestimated.

5

-

Thus, it is possible also that the U.S. current-

account deficit is exaggerated, resulting in an overestimate of the
capital inflow.

12.

The safe-haven aspects of the American economy seem to be viewed by the
market as an important feature of strength for the dollar.

So does the

greater ease of all forms of investment in dollar assets, thanks to the
wide range of available assets and their relative liquidity.

The perplexed

and possibly apprehensive portfolio manager, particularly when placing
highly liquid funds, may find the U.S. dollar the most convenient parking
lot for his assets.

13.

Continuation of large U.S. external deficits would produce a rapidly
mounting accumulation of dollar holdings in foreign portfolios.

The

additional interest due each year would raise the current-account deficit.
So would the widening gap, in absolute terms, between U.S. imports and
exports even if both grew at the same percentage rate.

14.

Such an increase in world dollar holdings, however, would come on top of
already very sizable international asset and liability positions of the
United States.

At the present time, allowing for uncertainties surrounding

these statistics, U.S. foreign assets and liabilities (including equity)
probably balance each other at about $1 trillion.

A $100 billion current-

account deficit, while it would make the United States a net debtor country,
would not grossly imbalance the relation of assets and liabilities.

15.

Moreover, the world's portfolio of dollar assets and dollar liabilities
probably exceeds the world's claims on and liabilities to the U.S. economy

-

6

-

by hundreds of billions of dollars.

Claims on and liabilities to the

Eurodollar market must be taken into account, as well as the Eurobond
market, claims and obligations arising out of trade and LDC debt in dollars,
and other third-country dollar assets and liabilities.

These additional

amounts do not affect the net position of the United States.

They are

indicative, however, of the world's willingness to hold dollar balances.

16.

The addition of an annual $100 billion or even more to the asset side of
this world portfolio of dollar assets and liabilities does not change
the balance much in the short run.

The rise of the dollar over the last

few years has increased the value, in nondollar currencies, of the world's
dollar portfolio by more than the U.S. current-account deficits of recent
years.

Yet this shift toward a larger dollar component in world assets

and liabilities has not caused dollar owners and dollar debtors to move
out of dollars.

As the world develops a net dollar-asset position, the

probability of such portfolio shifts is bound to increase.

But resting

on so enormous a base of roughly balanced dollar assets and liabilities,
it is very difficult to guess at what point in the evolution of a net
world dollar position investors would begin to regard this position as
excessive.

17.

Investors can be expected to focus, not on the increase in U.S. liabilities
during a single year, but on the prospect of a string of years of possibly
mounting external deficits.

Such expectations could weigh heavily on the

dollar even before the deficits had materialized.

But an investor who

also expects the present favorable interest differential between dollar
and other assets to continue into the indefinite future can accept a

prospect of moderate dollar depreciation so long as it does not, on
average, exceed the interest differential.

18.

It has been argued that greater stability and predictability of exchange
rates would be expected from worldwide progress toward internal price
stability.

Expectations of future inflation as a factor affecting the

dollar and other currencies would then disappear.

But a wide range of

other factors remain, including differences in the mix of national fiscal
and monetary policies, that could destabilize exchange rates even at minimal
rates of inflation everywhere.
distinct probability.

Wide exchange-rate movements remain a

None of these considerations provides a meaningful

basis for a projection of the future of the dollar.

What they do is to

underline the wide margin of uncertainty and the unpredictability of the
influence of any one factor.

#