View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
Wednesday, MAY 9, 1979
7 :30 P.M. EDT




BANK PROFITS, REGULATION, AND MONETARY POLICY
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at a meeting sponsored by the
West Virginia Bankers Association
Charleston, West Virginia
Wednesday, May 9, 1979

BANK PROFITS, REGULATION, AND MONETARY POLICY
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at a meeting sponsored by the
West Virginia Bankers Association
Charleston, West Virginia
Wednesday, May 9, 1979

It is a pleasure to be speaking to the West Virginia Bankers
Association on "Bank Profits, Regulation, and Monetary Policy." Your
program leads me to believe that you would want me to cover a wide range
of topics.

This is a crucial period for bankers, regulators, and monetary

policy makers.

We need to stay in close touch with each other, and with

events, if we are to negotiate this transition safely.
West Virginia is a very special State where banking is concerned.
After spending much of my time in Washington working on bank branching
matters and bank holding company applications, it is instructive to observe
banking in a State where bank branching and multi-bank holding companies are
not permitted.

That banking can be profitable without such features is

attested to by your return on capital of 12.3 per cent in 1977, and by the
recent rate of growth of your assets, which was 11.9 per cent.

These are

achievements upon which West Virginia bankers can look with pride.




-2
Bank Profits During Inflation
Nevertheless, during a severe inflation such as we are experiencing,
banking profits can be seriously distorted.

Properly adjusted for the effects

of inflation, they may be quite different from what "generally accepted
accounting principles" make them appear.

Let me give you some data.

For 1977, profits of all insured banks in the United States amounted
to $8.9 billion or 11.8 per cent of equity capital.

In historical perspective,

this is a good rate of return, although somewhat lower than the early 1970'3.
It reflects a rate of growth of bank profits of 13.2 per cent over 1976, which
is an above-average achievement.

For 1978, preliminary data show indications

of strong further growth, with profits possibly of $10.7 billion, a return of
12.8 per cent and a growth of profits of 20 per cent.

Unfortunately, these

seemingly satisfactory numbers do not take into account the high rate of infla­
tion that has prevailed and what it has done to the capital of the banking
system.
Banks are unique among business enterprises in that almost all of
their assets consist of paper values that are vulnerable to inflation.
Industrial firms and utilities typically have a good part of their assets,
sometimes the great majority, in the form of brick, mortar, and machinery.
During an inflation, these "hard assets" protect the firm's equity to some
degree.

The bank has only its building and some equipment and capital leases

that can perform a similar function.

For the banking system as a whole, real

estate shown on statements averages about one-quarter of equity capital.
In other words, the protection of bank equity by "hard," i.e., nonmonetary,
assets seems to fall short by 75 per cent of full coverage.




-3The market value of this real estate, to be sure, could be
quite different, and perhaps higher.

However, even today not all

commercial real estate has appreciated.
and local experience.
has much increased.

That depends largely on location

The replacement cost of the buildings, of course,
But so has the depreciation that would have had to be

charged to the appreciated replacement cost.

Some very tentative calculations

seem to show that, net of depreciation, the present replacement cost may not
be substantially higher than book value.

In addition to real estate owned

outright, we should probably take capital leases into account.

These are

the economic equivalent of ownership of the underlying property and
are regarded by accountants as "nonmonetary" assets, but aggregate data
on these are not available.
This is of great importance in assessing the impact of inflation on
banks and their earnings.

It is sometimes said that inflation is neutral

with respect to bank earnings, because it affects equally their assets and
their liabilities.
and liabilities.

That statement applies to the great bulk of bank assets
It overlooks, however, two crucial factors -- the bank's

equity capital on the liability side, an<? the bank's building and real estate
and equipment on the asset side.

Bank equity is not a liability.

The erosion,

by inflation, of the value of deposits and of the assets covering them causes
no loss to the bank.
debt.

The loss falls on the depositor cr holder of subordinated

But any erosion of assets that reflects bank equity, i.e., of the

amount by which assets exceed liabilities, falls upon shareholders.




-4This erosion of capital is a crucial part of the bank's over-all
profit situation, even though it is not reflected in any outflow of cash
like other costs.

In assessing the addition that his retained earnings

make to the true net worth of the bank, the banker must take this erosion
into account, except as it is offset by hard assets.

If hard assets

constitute 25 per cent of equity, and 75 per cent, therefore, are unprotected,
and if inflation moves at about 7 per cent, as it did in 1977, the erosion of
capital would amount to about 5 per cent per year*

To get a

realistic picture, i.e., one adjusted for inflation, of the true economic
profits of this hypothetical bank, the 5 per cent erosion needs to be
deducted from the bank's rate of return on capital.

If that rate of return

is equal to that of the entire banking system, it was 11.8 per cent in 1977.
Deducting an inflation-caused erosion of about 5 per cent from this return
would give an inflation-corrected return of a little less than 7 per cent.
I would be the last to claim that the adjustment for inflation
that I have applied here to bank profits — and that seems to reduce a hand­
some return on capital of 11.8 per cent to only about 7 per cent — has any
pretense to accuracy.

It is a highly simplified shortcut, a rule of thumb,

that happens to approximate very roughly a sophisticated technique developed
by the Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) known as General Price
Level Accounting (GPIA).

I might add, however, that an analysis of bank

earnings done in a manner similar to FASB's GPIA technique for the years
1974-76 does indeed produce inflation-adjusted bank earnings quite consistent
with the picture conveyed here by the shorthand rule-of-thumb method.




-5-

There are other techniques of adjusting business accounts for
inflation, such as the current cost method.

FASB presently has under way

a task force whose purpose is to propose methods of making supplementary
statements to the ordinary bank balance sheets and income statements.

You

will, therefore, probably be hearing a good deal about this subject.

We may

take for granted that there is no way of making precise adjustments.

All

that one can hope for is that the valuations arrived at on the basis of
these adjustments are in reasonable accord with the judgment of the market
in which bank stocks are priced and traded.

Conformity to market judgment

should be the test of any method of adjustment for inflation.

There is good

reason to believe that the market is aware of the distortions caused by
inflation and is not seriously deceived by accounting conventions that ignore
economic realities.

Conformity with the valuation of the market can, therefore,

be taken as a test of the appropriateness of an accounting convention.
I would not have ventured to put before you the rough estimate that
I gave if its results were not reasonably well supported by the verdict of
the market.

The stock market's judgment is that bank profits are greatly

overstated.

The stock market places an astonishingly low value on reported

earnings of bank and bank holding company stocks.

The price/earnings ratio

for nine of the largest money market banks runs from not quite five to a
little better than seven timss.
1970's of 10-20 times.

This contrasts with ratios during the early

Ordinarily the stock market accords so low a multiple

only to high-risk situations.

But the condition of our large banks is sound,

and I can see no justification for these low multiples on grounds of banking
risks.




Nor would one ordinarily expect stocks with the rapid growth of

-6eamings and dividends that bank stocks have enjoyed to sell at such low
multiples.

It is difficult to reject the conclusion that the stock market

has analyzed the situation correctly and is capitalizing bank earnings at
a low value because, after adjustment for inflation, bank earnings indeed
are low and growing only slowly.
The conclusion that bank profits are grossly overstated is supported
also by a look at the ratio of market value to book value.
the same story.

That ratio tells

With some notable exceptions, the large money market banks

are selling in the market far below their bool: value.

Book value for banks

is more meaningful than it is for industrial companies, because bank assets,
being monetary, should by and large all be collectible, and should yield
enough to pay off liabilities and leave for the owners the amount referred
to as book value.

For an industrial company, with its typically large

holdings of nonmonetary assets, the liquidation value of which is highly
uncertain, book value is, of course, not very meaningful.
Thus, when banks sell substantially below their book value, the
market is conveying a message.
assets are of poor quality.

That message, in my view, is not that bank

There is no basis for such an interpretation.

The message, rather, is that bank earnings are of poor quality, i.e., that
they need to be adjusted downward for inflation.

The divergence between book

value and market value becomes possible, of course, because banks are not
expected to be liquidated, so that higher liquidating value has only very
limited effect on market value.

Thus, it comes about that our large banks

seem to be worth more dead than alive.




-7
Evolution of the Banking System
From the subject of bank profits I would now like to turn to
matters of bank legislation.

Banking matters have been prominent in this

and last year's session of Congress.

An effort, carried over from last year,

to resolve the membership problem and simultan3ously enhance equity among
financial institutions and prevent further erosion of the Federal Reserve's
ability to conduct monetary policy has been slowed in the House.

This

development reflects the fact that member banks, especially small banks,
have found the financial cost of membership increasingly burdensome.

That

is, of course, a by-product of inflation which has raised interest rates to
levels that make the holding of sterile balances very costly.
that, in a broad sense, membership is nevertheless worthwhile.

I believe
A country

without a strong central bank is not a good country for banks to operate in.
But it is difficult for the Federal Reserve to be a strong central bank
without broadly based reserve requirements.
Meanwhile, Congress will probably turn to other aspects of bank
legislation.

One important area is the effort to help the small saver.

The small saver is being victimized by inflation in a particularly severe
form.

In addition to the damage to his principal, he is subject to interest-

rate ceilings that do not affect large investors.

Proposals have gone forward

for comment that would give the small saver somewhat improved options without
excessively burdening the depository institutions whose solvency must be a
prime concern of the respective regulators.
Related to the same range of problems, a study is going forward by
the Administration on future policy concerning Regulation Q in general.
Based on this study, the President will make recommendations to Congress.




-8Some of the problems posed by Regulation Q in the past during periods
of rising interest rates have been dealt with, as far as the impact
of disintermediation on housing is concerned, by the introduction of money
market certificates.

But there is no denying that this whole set of problems

is made very much more difficult by the ongoing inflation and by the high
interest rates that inflation brings about.

Progress in dealing with the

problems created by Regulation Q is urgently needed.
Another study mandated by Congress that is also going forward is
a review of the McFadden Act.

This was mandat2 d by Congress as part of the

International Banking Act (IBA).

The IBA perpetuates, in limited degree,

the interstate branching privileges enjoyed previously by foreign banks
operating in the United States while also providing more nearly equal
competitive footing in the future.

In Washington, the Federal Home Loan

Bank Board is proposing to experiment with branching across State lines for
savings and loan associations in the Washington Standard Metropolitan Statistical
Area (SMSA).

New ways of handling family accounts, of doing business, and of

applying new technology may call for changes in this area.

But I feel

confident that the ability of well-managed small banks to compete effectively
with larger branch systems has been well established.
Turning to the area of bank regulation, the banking agencies have
been busy with the implementation of the Financial Institutions Regulatory
Act (FIRA).

Last year, Congress passed this omnibus Act, which is a mammoth

piece of regulation running to about 100 pages in length and containii.g 21
separate titles.




At the risk of understatement, this Act does not appear

-9to have been very well received by the banking community, particularly the.
smaller banks.

I would now like to talk about several provisions of this

Act that seem particularly relevant to banks and bankers in West Virginia.
The first provision involves bank loans to directors and companies
they control.
of loans.

In several ways, the new legislation tightens up on these types

First, loans to directors must be made on substantially the same terms

as those prevailing at the time for comparable transactions with other persons
not associated with banks.

Second, all loans to a director that would result

in aggregate outstanding loans exceeding $25,000 must be approved in advance
by a majority of the bank's board of directors, with the interested director
abstaining.

Finally, the statute prohibits a bank from honoring an overdraft

for the acount of a director, subject to certain exceptions.
The purpose of these provisions, of course, is to prevent a director
from inappropriately using the bank's resources for personal purposes.
abuses have occurred to a limited degree in recent years.

Such

Unfortunately,

however, the new legislation is also likely to have an adverse side effect —
it will reduce the ability of banks to attract directors.

Traditionally,

leading businessmen in their communities have been bank directors.

This

has assured banks of the services of men and women who are well informed
and capable.

It has been an advantage to the bank and has enabled the bank

better to serve its community.

But leading businessmen in the nature of

things often are associated with firms that borrow.

It would be unfortunate

if the new Act should make this natural and well-established relationship
difficult to sustain.




-10Under the new Act, a director applying for a loan in excess of
$25,000 would have to wait until the loan is approved at the next meeting
of the bankfs board, unless the directors had already approved a line of
credit from him and companies that he controls.

In contrast, all other

creditworthy borrowers can get speedy approval from the bank.

These borrowers

also can have their overdrafts honored by the bank, whereas a director cannot,
subject to the exceptions provided in the statute and regulation.
These disadvantages associated with being a director may not be
weighty in many cases.
—

However, they do add to a growing list of disadvantages

including increasing director liability —

that are making it more difficult

for banks, especially small banks, to retain existing directors and attract
new ones.

Beyond a certain point, this result could threaten the viability

of small banks.
In writing the regulations for this title of FIRA, the regulatory
agencies have sought to make it possible for directors and their affiliated
institutions to obtain credit from their banks.

Specifically, the agencies

have provided for advance authorization of lines of credit for directors and
their affiliated institutions and by further liberalizing the automatic
transfer and automatic loan provisions of the statute by providing for
inadvertent overdrafts of up to $1,000 for not more than five business days.
In addition to the foregoing restrictions, most of which apply also
to executive officers and principal shareholders, as well as directors, FIRA
imposes an aggregate lending limit of 10 per cent of a batik's capital and
surplus on loans by a bank to each of its executive officers and principal




-11shareholders and their related interests.
happy to say, does not apply to directors.

This lending limit, 1 am
The Board has amended its

Regulation 0 to implement the new statutory provisions and has addressed
the problems raised by the new restrictions to the extent of its statutory
authority to do so.
The Financial Institutions Regulatory Act also puts restrictions
on loans by a correspondent bank to executive officers, directors, and 10 per
cent stockholders of its respondent banks.

Specifically, the correspondent

bank cannot make loans to these parties unless the loan is made on substantially
the same terms as those prevailing for comparable transactions with other
persons, and also does not involve more than normal risks of collectibility.
The purpose of this provision is to prevent an insider of a respondent bank
from obtaining a preferential loan by placing a correspondent balance with
the lending bank.
The Financial Institutions Regulatory Act also contains new
restrictions on interlocking relationships of management officials -- including
officers and directors — among non-affiliated depository institutions,
including banks, savings and loan associations, crcdit unions, bank holding
companies and savings and loan holding companies.

These restrictions relate,

in different ways, to depository institutions in the same SMSA, in identical
or contiguous or adjacent localities, and in certain size categories.
These provisions greatly expand the type of prohibited relation­
ships that were formerly covered by Section 8 of the Clayton Act.

The

principal saving grace is that a 10-year grandfather clause was included




-12for management interlocks that were in effect on November 10, 1978, and
were not in violation of Section 8 of the Clayton Act on that date.

The

Federal banking agencies, the National Credit Union Administration, and
the Federal Home Loan Bank Board are in the process of adopting final
regulations to implement the new statutory prohibitions.
Finally, the Financial Institutions Regulatory Act requires any
person wanting to acquire an insured bank to file an application with the
appropriate bank regulatory authority.

The applicant must furnish the agency

with a personal history, information on his or her business background, a
recent financial statement, information on the terms and conditions of the
proposed acquisition and the source of funds, and certain other relevant
information.

The regulatory authority has sixty days within which to deny

the application.

If no denial is forthcoming, the proposed acquisition may

be consummated.
The Federal Reserve recognizes that this new application requirement
may present problems for certain individuals, particularly those not used to
the regulatory process.

Accordingly, the twelve Federal Reserve Banks and

the other bank regulatory agencies stand ready to aid those individuals in
need of help in making out an application.

Moreover, the three Federal banking

agencies recently agreed to design their information requests to meet the statutory
requirements but at the same time reduce the reporting burden whenever possible.
While several applications recently have been filed with the
Federal Reserve, we have thus far acted on only one application under the
new legislation.

In making its decisions, the Federal Reserve will be guided

by the statutory criteria contained in the Act.




These criteria permit us

-13to deny any acquisition that would be anticompetitive, or would threaten
the financial condition of the bank.

While the Federal Reserve, of course,

will be faithful to these statutory criteria, I can assure you that it will
also attempt to carry on its long-standing policy of trying to facilitate
the transfer of ownership of smaller banks.
Problems of Monetary Policy
Monetary policy is never simple but at the present time it presents
some quite unusual difficulties.

We are now going into the fifth year of

continuous expansion which makes the present business cycle uptrend the
longest in peacetime history since World War II.
From the record of the past, a recession could have been expected
some time ago.

On the present occasion, however, we have been fortunate in

avoiding some of the major economic imbalances that historically have
tended to develop during upswings and that typically have brought these
upswings to an end after no more than two or three years.

In particular,

overexpansion of inventories seems to have been largely avoided on this
occasion.

Business investment in plant and equipment has not been excessive.

Housing, which on past occasions used to drop sharply as soon as interest
rates went up, has resisted much better this time, thanks to the money market
certificate and other institutional developments designed to supply funds for
housing.

Consumer buying has remained quite strong through the expansion and

there is some doubt that it can continue.
Meanwhile, however, pressures on capacity are mounting and our
past cost-push inflation is being aggravated by the addition of demand-pull
forces.




Thus, there are indications that the economy must be, and indeed is,

-14slowing down.

But there Is no evidence that a recession is unavoidable.

It is worth noting that the difference between the very rapid expansion
during the fourth quarter, at a nearly 7 per cent rate, and the moderate
expansion during the first quarter at less than one per cent would
constitute a more significant slowdown than would a subsequent drop from
the first-quarter rate to a moderate negative rate of expansion.

To call

two quarters of negative expansion a recession and treat it as a major
calamity to be avoided at all costs, while £ slowdown from nearly 7 per
cent to less than one per cent is taken as acceptable and indeed beneficial,
does not make much sense.

Whether or not we are moving into something that

statisticians would call a recession matters much less than whether or not
such a recession, if it occurs, is short and shallow or deep and protracted.
We can reasonably believe that the economy is now moving in the
right direction, toward more restraint, to which monetary policy is contributing.
But the setting of monetary policy close to what could turn out to be a cyclical
peak is not easy.
The problems of monetary policy at the present critical juncture
have been compounded by the peculiar behavior of the monetary aggregates.
The Federal Reserve uses M , M , and M

as guides to monetary policy and
3
communicates its one-year target ranges to the Congress. Until about a month

ago, for a period of half a year, the various monetary aggregates showed little
or no growth.

This could have meant that a recession was on its way.

It

also could have meant that the demand for money balances was diminishing,
perhaps owing to rapid inflation.

Now the monetary aggregates have

accelerated once more, signaling either that recession fears were premature,




-15or that shifts in the demand for money balances have come to an end for
the time being.

The episode has, of course, shaken confidence in the

reliability of M^, M^, and

as guides to monetary policy.

As a result,

some observers have proposed that the Federal Reserve pay more attention
to still another variable -- the monetary base.

The monetary base, so

called because it is the basis for the nation's money supply, consists
chiefly of certain liabilities of the Federal Reserve —
and member bank reserves.

primarily currency

It would like to say a few words on this subject,

because it seems to have attracted a certain amount of attention.
The monetary base — which supports the monetary liabilities of
the banking system — as of mid-April consisted of about $100 billion
currency in the hands of the public, $13 billion vault cash of banks, and
$32 billion reserve deposits of member banks.

It is sometimes alleged that

by controlling the base the Federal Reserve can do as good or better a job
of influencing the economy as by controlling the money supply

or M^.

To evaluate this claim, it is necessary to keep in mind the
relationship between the base and the money supply.
in the hands of the public.

Both contain currency

But while the money supply contains bank deposits

(excluding Treasury deposits), the base contains only, broadly speaking, the
deposits with the Federal Reserve that member banks carry against their
reservable liabilities.

Viewing the base as a proxy for the money supply,

currency receives a weight of one while deposits receive a weight of only
1/8, which is the ratio of reserves to




deposits.

-16Treatlng the base as the proper embodiment of the concept of
"money11 comes close to saying that only currency' is money.
count.

Deposits hardly

It means going back to the days of the 19th century, when currency

and gold were the principal media and the monetary role of deposits had not
yet been recognized.

Today, deposits, including time and savings, are

equal to about nine times the public's holdings of currency.

There seems

to be no good reason for ignoring them in measuring the money supply except
that during the last six months the base and the 6NP have moved more or less
in step, whereas the money supply and the GNP have not.
A closer analysis of currency in circulation raises further
questions about the use of the base.

Of the $100 billion in circulation,

probably very little is held by business.

The behavior of business and its

demand for money, therefore, is not at all well reflected by the base.
who holds the rest?

But

If it were all held by American households, each man,

woman and child would, on average, be carrying over $450 in currency on him.
I must confess that I carry my fair share of currency on me only very rarely
and the other members of my family probably even less often.

This leaves a

great puzzle as to where all the money went.
Where could these greenbacks have gone, if not into the wallets
or under die mattresses of the average citizen?
destroyed?

Have they been lost or

Have they gone abroad, through unreported shipments by tourists or

reported bank shipments, to be hoarded as a last reserve by people in countries
with unsympathetic governments or unfriendly economic systems?




Are they

-17-

perhaps being used in the "underground" or *'off-book" economy that some
observers believe to be expanding rapidly in the United States?

Perhaps

all of these extracurricular destinations have contributed to maintaining
a high volume of currency in circulation in an. age of checks and credit cards.
In any event, a monetary variable the magnitude of which is so hard to
explain and that is exposed to such peculiar possibilities invites only
very limited confidence as a guide to monetary policy.
Under present circumstances, monetary policy must be guided
principally by the direct observation of the economy.

It can, for the time

being, receive only very limited assistance from observation of instrumental
variables such as interest rates and the money supply.

In time, I vouj.d

expect, more stable relations between the real economy of output, employment,
and prices on one side and financial variables such as money supply tnc'
interest rates on the other will probably be re-established.

The conduct

of monetary policy will ther. be fraught by less vacertainty than it. Is today.




#