View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on
Saturday, May 13, 1967
at 11:00 a.m. , EDT




Living with Monetary Management
Remarks of George W. Mitchell
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Annual Stockholders Meeting
of the
Federal Home Loan Bank of Greensboro

Washington, D. C.
May 13, 1967

Living with Monetary Management

Financial institutions--commercial banks, savings and loan
associations, mutual savings banks and credit unions--in recent decades
have been developing and exploiting one of the most useful financial
techniques of the century:--intermediation, the art of borrowing short
and lending long.
Though it looks like alchemy and depends to a degree on
financial intuition for its profitable use, the transformation of funds
serving real liquidity needs for depositors into long-term loan commit­
ments for borrowers is not only practicable but is also a sound operation.
Both experience and statistical analysis can be used to show that exposure
to the liquidity demands of small and medium-sized depositors is, under
most circumstances, modest in proportion and predictable in timing and,
therefore, manageable.

The stability of these hoards of funds in the

aggregate is dependable, though to a lesser degree than the stability
of demand deposits at commercial banks.
Commercial banking learned long ago that money claims (withdrawals)
against demand deposits simply roll around the community from one account
to another and if a bank could attract a balanced panel of depositors from
various economic and geographic sectors in its service area it could count
on surprising stability in the aggregate of its demand deposits.

In actual

practice, this stability was further reinforced by a banking tradition of
conservative financial management and by public concern for the safety and
availability of depositors' funds.

Banks, therefore, often held large

stocks of short-term and marketable assets as buffers against potential
and even hypothetical deposit drains.




-2As the U.S> financial economy grew in stability and strength
after the banking reforms of the 1930fs, experience with somewhat less
liquid claims-r-time deposits and share accounts--encouraged inter­
mediaries to work greater and greater transformations of liquidity
promises and attractive yields into long-term loans against which
they extended commitments.

Without a doubt this process has made

saving easier and more profitable, and it has accommodated the interest
and convenience of much broader groups of savers and investors.

It has

had an equally beneficent effect on users of loan funds who have had
the benefit of a more competitive environment and in many cases access
to credit resources heretofore not available.
Increasingly, intermediation became the best of all possible
worlds for everyone--the intermediary, the saver, and the borrower.
But, like all good things, some institutions tried to over-extend their
capabilities by simultaneously promising instantaneous, unlimited
liquidity to depositors under all circumstances, and assured credit
availability to borrowers.

These promises, good in ordinary times,

became onerous and hard to meet in the months of monetary restraint
last year.

In some instances, losses and dislocations were severe.
Subsequently, apprehension about the stability of the whole

intermediation process has arisen.

Today intermediaries are re­

examining more carefully and deliberately than ever before the basis
of this operation and what they need to do to avert or lessen the
strains that might arise in future periods of monetary restraint
and sharply rising interest rates.




-

3-

Several things could be done and a few, in my view, should be
done.

Let me sketch briefly some of the possibilities.
One view, more implicit than explicit in the monetary debates

of 1966, is that monetary restraint should be abandoned as a tool of
economic policy.

This course of action appears in several guises--

one academic observer, for example, believes that the money supply
should be increased at an agreed-on, uniform rate, month in and month
out, regardless of the level or change in interest rates or credit
availability; because, he argues, neither the Federal Reserve nor any­
one else is well enough informed on the linkages and lags in monetary
action to prescribe a policy of deliberate monetary influence on the
economic environment.

Discretionary monetary management, in his view,

is usually destabilizing.

This argument seems to contain the assumption

that the private economy is self-stabilizing--a premise that is hardly
borne out by the nistory of business cycles prior to Keynesian economic
policies.

And if it was self-correcting, it was only at the cost of

such "corrections11 as the Great Depression.
Giving up discretionary monetary management for domestic
objectives has also been urged at times by those who believe that, when
domestic and balance of payments considerations give off conflicting
signals to monetary policy, the balance of payments signal should
prevail.

They propose, in other words, that U.S. monetary policies

should always adapt to those of the other industrial nations of the
world.

It is not at all fanciful that we will one day cede monetary

sovereignty to a world-wide monetary authority, but I doubt that we




-

4-

shall be prepared for many steps in that direction except as existing
extensive barriers to trade and migration are contemporaneously
dismantled or relaxed and fiscal policies are also coordinated.
In 1966 many people objected to rapidly rising interest
rates and a lessened rate of credit growth in the United States because
of the immobilizing effect on their ability to sell existing assets, or
to secure the funds to create more assets--in short, they objected to
the impact of monetary action per se.

What this position ignores is

that the failure to restrain excess demand by monetary and/or fiscal
policy will also limit the ability to satisfy demands--but the restraint
will come from inflation.
I do not believe it would be wise to give up monetary tools
as active instruments of government policy until it has been demonstrated
that fiscal policy can go it alone as a stabilization device.

As useful

and promising as it is, fiscal policy needs more time to develop as a
flexible and timely instrument.

It is, of course, possible that for

increasingly long periods of time monetary policy will be able to perform
its function of serving the evident needs of the community without being
forced into a vigorous reflationary or deflationary posture.
been its role during most of the Sixties.

This has

Nonetheless, for the fore­

seeable future, we are likely to have occasional fluctuations in the
economy and I believe intermediaries should expect in these periods to
see changes in the monetary climate and be prepared to live with them.
A change in the rules of this game is not likely to solve their problem«




-5-

In the past few months, intermediaries have been building their
liquidity resources--repaying debt, liquidating outstanding commitments,
and acquiring short-dated assets.

These policies have been made possible

by the large inflow of funds from savers, by investors turning away from
market instruments toward depository institutions, and by a less than
aggressive expansion of new loans and commitments.
This combination of policies and the patterns of interest rates
and credit flows are consistent with the aftermath one would expect from
a period of credit stringency.

But they are becoming less and less

consistent with, and appropriate to, the fundamental function and
rationale of financial intermediaries.

While this is an appropriate

time for reappraisal of intermediation, the reappraisal should not be
an excuse for drifting into a liquidity trance with its immobilizing
effects on the traditional loan customers of interirediaries.
In the current reappraisal of the intermediation process, then,
and the steps that might be taken to avoid or lessen such difficulties
as occurred in 1966, I would hope that you felt considerable urgency to
get on with your regular business of lending and responding to the
current financial environment.
As an outside observer, may I offer a few suggestions or
comments on the longer-run problem, recognizing your superior expertise
and close knowledge of this branch of the intermediation business.
have to do with (1) a realistic objective in coping with monetary
restraint; (2) possible alteration in your asset structure; and (3)
changes in your liability structure and commitments on liquidity and
credit availability.




They

-6It is quite apparent that intermediaries are giving a good bit
of thought to outmaneuvering monetary restraint in the future while
accepting the evident blessings of monetary ease.

But, in my judgment,

periods of conspicuous ease and vigorous restraint may well be of
shorter duration in the future and may be supplanted by longer and
longer periods when monetary policies have nominal effect on inter­
mediation.

If so, I wonder if this effort to outmaneuver monetary

restraint is worthwhile.
In the past 14 years, monetary restraint of an intensity
sufficient to affect the operations of intermediaries in any degree
has been in effect for a total period of no more than 36 months and
only on three different occasions: early fall of 1956 through October 1957;
January 1959 to January 1960; December 1965 through November of 1966.
Looking ahead, it would be easier to try to spot these events in the
offing, even putting up with a recognition lag of two or three months,
and then to adjust operations to the central bank's interest, rather
than to attempt to over-ride, outmaneuver, or insulate your operations
from a public policy of restraint.
True, some moderation in monetary impact on your business may
be possible, practicable, and desirable.

But avoidance in toto is only

likely to lead to the use of different methods and tools by the monetary
authorities should the need for them be apparent.

I suggest, therefore,

that when the economic climate gets steamy and the central bank has
begun to reflect that fact in its policies, it is better for the inter­
mediaries as a whole, and ordinarily individually, to pass along the




-7restraint in charges and availability rather than trying to follow a
"business as usual11 policy.
Diversification of investment opportunities for mutual savings
banks and savings and loan associations is frequently mentioned as
providing more flexibility in adjusting to a decline in savings inflows
and an increase in outflows.

It is true that lending shorter on a

broader spectrum of assets could help to improve portfolio flexibility.
Earnings could respond more readily to rapid changes in general credit
conditions and lenders could have a broader range of investment choice
at times of savings abundance.

It is true, too, that lending shorter

could allow thrift institutions to operate more as one-stop service
outlets for their many customers.
But the advantages of this kind of approach seem to me rather
marginal.

Investment flexibility could be sacrificed--not enhanced--

if needs to service existing customers preclude on-again off-again
operations.

I question whether any significant sectors of consumer,

agriculture, or business customers today are as easy to put off as are
mortgage borrowers once they have become regular customers.

Aside from

builders, in fact, few mortgage borrowers become customers of one
particular lender more than once in a lifetime.

Most household heads

take on a new mortgage loan relatively few times from any lender as
they pass through the family cycle.

In this sense, you may already

have the most readily interruptible credit service being offered.




-8Admittedly, the grass is greener on the other side of the asset
fence, and there are undoubtedly some potential sectors of unsatisfied
credit demand in the United States, even at currcnt rates and terms.
But none stand out as large or as available on a stop-and-go basis as
mortgage lending.

And most sectors are already deeply penetrated by

existing lenders with considerable expertise, ready to capitalize on
the trend toward a checkless credit-card society.
Another investment possibility is to include more short-term
marketable securities in your portfolio.

Greater liquidity is indeed

a worthwhile objective to a limited degree, and especially for inter­
mediaries that traditionally specialize in borrowing short and lending
long.

But in the short run, of course, excessive liquidity can be gained

only at the immediate expense of earnings which may or may not be improved
over the longer run.

Short-dated assets are more profitable only when

long yields are trailing an upward trend in short rates--and perhaps
not even then at the prices you pay for money.

However, your timing

has to be good to make this game pay in the short run--certain it is that
the differential in yields between short and long debt today makes the
former a pretty expensive loss leader.

This is not to deny--let me

emphasize— that a better cushion of liquid assets may not be desirable
as a structural matter or may not improve long-run earning potentials.
Let me turn to the liability management side of the ledger,
for this aspect of the problem seems to me to offer a greater promise
of success, enabling you to use your particular expertise in attracting
and retaining savings flows and pools.




A longer structured set of

-9liabilities can, of course, provide a better balance for the maturity
range of assets, and can bring the turnover of liabilities closer in
line with the; turnover of assets.

This, in turn, can help to minimize

operational needs for liquidity.
It is well known that many medium-sized regular savers as well
as owners of somewhat larger deposit accumulations, or even debt instru­
ments, are not particularly sensitive to favorable yield differentials
on market instruments.

For some, in fact, liquidity is so important

that the alternative to a time or share account is a demand deposit.
For still others, there is no established or familiar pattern of direct
investment and no promotion of such an alternative.

Thus, there is a

great deal of relative stability in regular savings accounts.
Larger and more sophisticated investors have also become
customers of financial intermediaries because they have found that the
investment convenience and yields offered often constitute a better
package than they can put together themselves by dealing directly in
market instruments.

Most of these customers, however, are highly rate

conscious, and many are acutely responsive to expectational influences
in financial markets.

To give them what is in effect costless instant

liquidity is to incur exposure to sudden and large withdrawals that
are disruptive to the practical operation of most intermediaries.

Such

depositors can only be made a useful source of funds if their rate
sensitivity can be curbed through restrictions on withdrawals, through
incentives not to withdraw, or can be satisfied by maintaining a
close linkage between market rates and depository yields.




-10The large commercial banks have used several credit instruments
to compete aggressively with market yields for a small but often signifi­
cant part of their total resources.

Negotiable certificates of deposit,

Euro-dollars, Federal Funds, repurchase agreements, subordinated notes,
and (in a negative sense) dealer loans have all been more or less
competitive with market instruments.
In the aggregate, these devices have seldom provided more than
five per cent of total commercial bank resources.

But the importance to

individual institutions, and in the aggregate of day-to-day, week-to-week,
or month-to-month change, has, of course, been much greater.
On a limited scale, therefore, some instrument or group of
instruments that enable an intermediary to pull funds out of the market-even at a possible loss in the short run--adds a degree of flexibility
in periods of monetary restraint.

And it is at the margin where

flexibility counts most under these conditions.
What does experience tell us about the erosion in intermediaries'
liability structure due to monetary restraint in recent years?

No doubt

your first-hand experience in 1966 tells you plenty--and rather than
summarize something that you could describe better and with more feeling
than I, it seemed to me it would be useful to cite some statistics from
the experience of commercial banks in this period, recognizing that
ratios of withdrawals to savings balances for commercial banks tend
to run substantially higher than those for savings and loan associations.
For my convenience and because of the great detail in which
the data are compiled, let me refer to time and savings deposit figures




-

11-

collected by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago for 450 commercial banks
in 50 Midwest urban and metropolitan areas since the mid-1950's.

These

data are available for regular passbook savings and, after 1958, for
passbook savings plus time certificates of deposit held by individuals
(consumer-type CD's).

Both rates of inflow and outflow are available,

but I will be referring only to the statistic used to measure the rate
of withdrawal or "turnover."

This withdrawal rate pertains to gross

withdrawals during the period— month, quarter, or year— divided by
average daily balances in the corresponding period.

It contrasts with

the measure widely used by savings and loan associations, which relates
gross savings withdrawals to total gross savings receipts.
From 1959 through 1966, the withdrawal rate on consumer-type
time and savings accounts at this group of banks averaged .52; i.e.,
gross withdrawals in two years were roughly equivalent to the average
balance for the period.
accounts alone.

This relationship also held true for passbook

The surprising thing, however, is the stability in this

rate over a period which included changes in time deposit ceilings and
changes in the differential between passbook and CD ceilings.

In three

years— 1959, 1961, 1962--the rate was .52; in 1963 and 1964 it was .47;
in 1960 it was .50; in 1961 it was .51 and in 1966 it was .63.
If we average rates of outflow in the years 1961-1965 as not
being significantly affected by monetary posture one way or the other,
we come up with a rate of .50 to match against .63 for 1966 and .52 in
1959 and .50 in 1960.

These overall averages suggest monetary restraint

could have affected the outflow rate by no more than about 4 per cent




-12in 1959 but by as much as 25 per cent in 1966.

Incidentally, similar

computations for insured savings and loan associations in the Chicago
Federal Home Loan Bank District show that monetary restraint could have
affected the outflow rate for these institutions by about 3 per cent
in 1959 and by about 15 per cent last year.
For commercial banks, local competitive conditions and practices
in the Midwest have had a marked effect on the level of withdrawal rates
in various localities.

If the data are disaggregated so as to show changes

taking place in the major metropolitan area of each State (Chicago, Detroit,
Milwaukee, Indianapolis and Des Moines) and in all of the other urban areas
combined for each State, the results are reasonably consistent with expecta­
tions.

Michigan rates are high--about .65--and rose most sharply--about

one-third--in 1966.

Rates in smaller cities of Iowa, Indiana and Wisconsin

were lower (.40-.45) and rose least--under 10 per cent.

In Chicago,

Milwaukee and Des Moines rates increased about 20 per cent, from levels
of less than .50.
These data imply that, in many geographic areas, attention
obviously needs to be given to the structuring of liabilities of savingstype institutions so as to curb or offset withdrawals from interestsensitive accounts.

In these Midwestern States, 60 to 75 per cent of

passbook savings are, according to the FDIC's 1966 Survey of Deposits,
in individual accounts of less than $10,000 each.
these accounts is less than $900.

The average size of

Another 20 to 30 per cent of passbook

savings are in accounts of between $10,000 and $25,000 each.

While our

withdrawal data do not pinpoint the accounts from which the 1966




-13acceleration in withdrawals emanated, much of the increased outflow must
have come from these larger accounts.
The practice of making immediate payment on request for time
deposits or share accounts, despite legal notice requirements, works
out well as long as the amount and timing of withdrawals can be antici­
pated and allowed for.

But periods of monetary restraint present special

problems; at such times, in the interest of stability of financial
institutions, further disabilities may need to be brought into play
on withdrawals made for rate advantages.

Rules imposing a greater

loss of interest for certain types of withdrawals, further extended
maturities on deposits or share accounts, and a more careful internal
appraisal of depositors' withdrawal propensities are some of the
techniques that should be explored in assessing the limits of inter­
mediation for our depositary institutions.

Perhaps such exploration

would lead to policies circumscribing intermediaries' growth— curbing
advertising claims of instant liquidity, higher yields and assurances
of ever-ready credit while tranquilizing institutional exuberance and
overconfidence— but I have a feeling that for the institutions involved
these results could be all to the good.