View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
(Approximately 11:30 a.m)
Thursday, February 17, 1966




Key Problems in Maintaining Monetary Stability
Remarks of
George W. Mitchell
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Financial Conference
of the
National Industrial Conference Board
New York City

February 17, 1966

Key Problems in Maintaining Monetary Stability
The concept of "monetary stability" ranks along with that of a "sound
currency" as a moral platitude intended to define a good or proper public policy.
Both ideas convey the subjective satisfactions associated with firmness and
constancy, of a future reward for present behavior, of foreswearing economic
indulgence, and of doing good generally.
Public policy, admittedly, needs a powerful emotional anchor if it
involves results that transitorily or apparently are hostile to identifiable
private or community interests.

But public policy also needs a rational

anchor which distinguishes between ends and means; it needs an analytical
anchor which pins down cause and effect; it needs a judgment anchor which is
aware of the limitations of current analytical techniques and perceptive in
the use of intuition.
To be specific, monetary stability is not a goal of public policy
but a means of achieving some goal such as a rising standard of living, greater
stability of personal incomes, economic growth or a better scale of living for
future generations.

The contribution of monetary stability is limited to its

role in making our economic system function better.

Most of us believe,

looking at the experience of other nations as well as our own, that monetary
stability "works" better than monetary instability.

However, we must admit,

in the light of experience, that the free enterprise system, or some modification
of it, is capable of "living with" a certain amount of monetary instability.
The tolerance of our economic system to the many infringements on
its free functioning is quite remarkable and, I suppose, each of us has some
kind of a priority schedule for what he regards as the greater and lesser perils
involved in artificial constraints on the economy, whether they arise from the
tax system, administered prices, money management> wage guidelines, or whatever.




-2-

The only point I wish to make is that among these infringements, the risk taken
of some degree of monetary instability is, of necessity, a matter of judgment
rather than of precise analysis or blind faith.
Monetary stability implies somewhat more than price stability but
most of the force of the concept is associated with price stability or antici­
pations of price stability.

Only bankers, and central bankers in particular,

could be continuously concerned with "monetary stability" if the incidence of
monetary instability did not have price and output aspects.

It is essential,

therefore, to make a judgment about contemporary or prospective price developments.
The price measurements that are available are found in the indexes of
consumer and wholesale prices.

Both have numerous deficiencies as measures of

monetary stability.
The CPI signaled a steady price creep throughout much of the fifties
and most of the sixties--in fact, it has been stable only in periods when food
prices were falling.

This upcreep reflects to a significant degree the

difficulty of measuring quality changes in goods and services consumed.

The

longer the period covered and the more rapid the rate of technological change
the less reliable the index becomes as a measure of real change in the price
of an unchanging standard of living.
The UPI is a much better index for signaling monetary instability.
However, it suffers from the defect of under-reporting price changes because
of its reliance on quoted prices for some important commodities instead of
actual prices paid, thereby often missing the changing terms and conditions
that obtain in actual transactions.
and, at best, a late warning signal.




As a consequence, this index is sluggish

-

3-

The adequacy or inadequacy of our price measures has been debated so
often and so tediously that, despite its importance, I hesitate even to summarize
the pros and cons before this audience

At the risk of some caricature of the

facts, I think an allegorical treatment may spare us both that rehash
In that vein, then, I start with the well known fact that over the
past few years the United States has had a balance of payments problem.

We

may think of it as a challenge to public policy but some have thought of it as
an exploitable business opportunity.

One such opportunity was a narrowly

circulated, but influentially directed, weekly market letter of a Western
European financial concern which used our balance of payments deficit to iterate
week after week the phrase "The dollar is weak again today."

And in that currency

the dollar was "weak again today," month after month, and year after year.
But the economics of the situation were not in any sense accurately
conveyed by the phrase

The market weakness of the dollar reflected a capital

flow that was revitalizing and infusing European economies with American
production and distribution techniques

Sentiments and judgments inspired by

the phrase "the dollar is weak again today" were inimical to the interest of
that community even more than ours.

Ironically, while this poop sheet pointed

at the dollar as a weakening currency the trading position of its principal's
country was deteriorating steadily and the robust appearance of its currency
long concealed the economic malaise that had set in.
Now, in the United States, the monthly consumers price index has been
rising slightly, but perceptibly, in most of the months of the postwar years.
Its monthly heralding in the press is, in effect, a little like the use of the
phrase "the dollar is weak again today."

Over the years there have been times

when the judgments implicit in the declaration have been justified, but the




-4sustained impression of a steady price creep implies to the public, at any rate,
that Government fiscal and monetary policies have been wrong for a good many
years and should have been geared to retarding growth and investment in the
interest of price stability.
Most of us doubt that monetary policy can be very effective in compelling
the economy to absorb the benefits of technological advances through falling prices,
or that monetary policy can cope with the vagaries of the weather, or the timing
and duration of either the cattle or hog cycle.

And while 1, for one, do not

object to a price index that can be used for a more egalitarian distribution
of wage, salary or retirement income I am deeply concerned that the CPI is being
used to condition a community judgment that will opt for policies injurious to
the public welfare.
As in thé balance of payments analogy, there is irony in the price
situation, too, for as the CPI inflates our fears the WPI deflates our appre­
hensions with its sluggish registering of price developments.
A sensitive reporting system for price changes is primarily to fortify
our knowledge and analysis of the contemporary and prospective price developments
as they unfold at different speeds in different parts of the economy.

Since a

certain amount of price movement is taking place at all times--and desirably so,
for this is how resources get allocated to more productive uses— we need
commodity detail and pricing refinements to distinguish between individual
price adjustments that appear to be related to shifts in resource use and those
that are responding to over-all demand or to expectations of change in over-all
demand.
To a degree the present wholesale price index can be used to measure
the pervasiveness of price change, and from these data some judgments can be




-

5-

made as to the weight of inflationary pressures.

To give the data meaning in

terms of our recent experiences with inflationary developments I have constructed
a table comparing four 12-month periods from the wholesale price index components.
The first period I have labeled "Korea"; it covers April 1950 to
April 1951, a period in which the wholesale price index rose 18 per cent.

I

assume there is no disagreement that the proper label to describe this magnitude
of change is inflation.
The second period which I have called "Cyclical Recovery" is from
June 1954 to June 1955.

It exhibits a typical response of the wholesale price

index to a more or less normal strengthening in industrial prices as output
expands cyclically.

The change in the total index was slight in this particular

instance because of the decline in foodstuff component but industrial prices
rose 1.7 per cent.
The third period I call the Mid-Fifty "Inflation."
is in quotes because at the time, and since, not all analysts

The word inflation
have been in

agreement that this was a period when fiscal and monetary policies should have
been constraining growth and employment.

Nonetheless, in the twelve months

from June 1955 to June 1956 the industrial component of the WPI rose 5 per cent—
clearly enough of a change to give rise to differences in judgment as to its
significance for policy action.
It is interesting in light of many current economic discussions to
note that the Council of Economic Advisors in the 1956 Economic Report published
just ten years ago described the effectiveness of the monetary and fiscal policies
of the time as follows:




Price Changes in Four 12-Month Periods
(Wholesale prices)

KOREA

CYCLICAL
RECOVERY

April 1950
to
April 1951

June 1954
to
June 1955

MID-SIXTY
MID-FIFTY
"INFLATION" "TRADE-OFF"
June 1955
to
June 1956

Sept. 1964
to
Sept. 1965

Per Cent Increase in Weighted Indexes
Total Index
Foodstuffs
Industrial commodities

18.1
20.6
17.1

0.3
-3.7
1.7

3.6
-0.9
4.9

2.3
4.4
1.6

Industrial materials
Sensitive
Other

21.1
38.8
14.0

2.3
5.5
1.3

5.4
5.4
5.4

1.9
3.5
1.4

Industrial products
Consumer
Producer

11.6
11.3
12.6

0.9
0.3
2.0

4.2
2.7
7.8

1.2
1.2
1.2

Distribution <jf Changes in Industrial Commodity Groups
227

228

229

251

Per cent rising

98

61

79

68

Per cent rising 2 per cent or more

96

36

67

35

Per cent rising 5 per cent or more

92

16

44

13

Number of groups




-

6-

"Even now, however, it can be said with confidence that the early
recognition of a need for monetary and fiscal caution, and the gradual
but persistent application of a policy of restraint during the greater
part of 1955, contributed in no small degree to the achievement and
maintenance of prosperity without price inflation.
"The vigorous expansion of economic activity during 1955 was
accompanied by little change in the average level of wholesale or
consumer prices.

To be sure, the substantial stability of the price

level reflected in some degree the opposite movements of industrial
and farm prices in wholesale markets.

However, the increase even in

the average level of industrial prices was not large for a period of
high prosperity."
Considering that the price increases which have taken place recently
are about one-third as large as those of 1955 it would appear that our
"inflation sensitivity" index has risen significantly in the past decade.
I refer to the fourth period, running from September 1964 to
September 1965 as the Mid-Sixty "Trade-Off" because while in dimensions it
resembles the cyclical recovery of 1954-55 it came after over three years of
expansion and in an environment in which significant gains were being made
in economic growth and the reduction in unemployment.

It reflects a period

in which the economy was deliberately--so to speak--being pressed toward
higher and higher levels of resource utilization.
The table shows change in the weighted indexes and in the distribution
of changes in industrial commodity groups.

By any measure the Korea inflation

stands out--the industrial index rose 17 per cent; 98 per cent of 227 commodity
groups were rising; 92 per cent rose 5 per cent or more.




The contrast with the

-7Mid-Sixty rise is sharp--in that period the industrial component rose 1.6 per
cent; 68 per cent of 251 industrial commodities were rising but only 13 per
cent rose 5 per cent or more.
My attention has also been called to a table in the January Survey
of Current Business in which price changes for 1,418 industrial commodities
are compared from October to October in each of the past four years.

The results

for 1964-65 are roughly similar to those in my table— 50 per cent of the
commodities rising, 16 per cent by more than 5 per cent, 30 per cent unchanged,
and 20 per cent decreasing.
In reciting these price statistics and relationships I may appear to
be laying the groundwork for minimizing concern for the potential of price
inflation in 1966

On the contrary— this record shows, within the sensitivity

limitations of the WPI, only what has happened--not what is happening or about
to happen.

Expectational forces today are very strong--probably stronger than

the real economy and certainly stronger than the consumption sector.
When we look at the real economy's performance we find it is setting
records in production and employment considering the levels that the expansion
had already achieved.

Industrial production rose at an annual rate of 13 per

cent in the fourth quarter and on into January; non-agricultural employment
was rising at a 7 per cent annual rate.

GNP rose by $16 billion in the fourth

quarter, almost as much as in the first quarter of the year when the effects
of the automobile and steel strikes shifted output from the past and the future
into a temporary surge.

Inventory accumulation in the past quarter at a rate

in excess of $10 billion set some sort of post-Korea record, considering it
took place as steel stocks were being adjusted downward and strike conditioning
influences were absent.




-8-

In December and January, capacity utilization for manufacturing as a
whole was above the fourth quarter average of 91, and for some of the material
producing industries--specifically, nonferrous metals, paper, and textiles,
the pressure was greater.

These high rates of operation have increased the

risk that price increases will be more pervasive in 1966 and that the industrial
average will rise at a faster pace.
It may be that steel and aluminum prices will be held down and that
would be a significant departure from the mid-Fifties when steel provided
pervasive upward pressure.

It is difficult, in any event, to visualize steel

prices rising'10 per cent as they did from mid-1955 to mid-1956 and again in
the succeeding twelve months.
As I see it, the threat of inflation today is lodged in current
inventory policies and defense spending expectations.

The extent to which

the former continue and the latter are translated into capital spending, or
even capital financing, will measure the pressures of inflation in the coming
months.

The critical judgments are hinged on the degree of economic stimulus

from the war in Vietnam.

As this becomes clear, it will confirm or invalidate

today's expectations.
Among the problems involved in maintaining monetary stability,
evaluating the evidence from economic developments that inflation threatens
is of major importance and, in some circumstances, by far the most difficult.
Once the diagnosis is in, the other matter of high ranking importance is what
to do about it; and, to put it bluntly, what to do about it without unduly
jeopardizing economic stability.
Given a public consensus that stabilizing action is needed, there is
seldom any lack of alternative methods for retarding expansion.




The problem

is to select the one, or the combination of a&ethcds, that will be most effective.
It is widely recognized that monetary tightening is not the only alternative.
In today*s climate, proposals to »aise pe^sciai and corporate taxes, to reduce
non-defense spending, ^r even t~ cut tack cn defense spending, are advanced
as measures to presets menet at v stability
At other times and in different circumstances proposals have been
made for highly selective constraints on sectors of the economy which seem to
be expanding abr c m a A *v under the stimulus cf false expectations, previous
constraints, or just plain speculation

Sc we have had credit restraint by law,

or agreement, for consumer credit, housing credit, stock market credit and
foreign investment

And since we have used taxation to stimulate private

investment and consumption deliberately and, in some degree, selectively-these steps could be reversed for the contrary reason
While it seems clear to me that diagnosis and the prescribed course
of treatment lor monetary instability encompass the key problems for public
policy, there are some other problems of intriguing if not of key significance.
For example, is monetary stability t h r e a t e n e d in some way by recent develop­
ments in financial intermediation, including the spectacular growth in bank
time deposits and the heightened competition a m o n g bank and nonbank inter­
mediaries for savings and rate conscious money and near-money stocks7 Are
our institutions proffering more liquidity than t^ey can deliver or at prices
they cannot afford to p a y 7
Or, tc take another tack, w^ at about U e nation s banking structure?
Does it have the flexibility and dimensions tc perform the tasks expected of it?
Does confining i«divideal barking a^lts to a single locality or region bring
into being cirt ^




eoting practices and policies that have destabilizing implications9

-10There are no clear and unequivocal answers to these questions in
my opinion, but it does make sense to redouble our efforts better to under­
stand the less obvious but broader effects emerging from environmental and
institutional changes in banks and banking.
There is time to mention in these brief remarks one other matter
bearing on the problem of monetary stability.

A month or so ago I spoke

to the American Economic Association on the banking implications of a
"cashless and checkless" society indicating that automation in this field would
have revolutionary effects on banking.

It is appropriate to mention here a

parallel development of improving technology in economic analysis, not likely
in the immediate offing but in longer run prospect, namely, push button
central banking--the millennium for the central banker

and also his functional

demise.
There are, of course, some economists and bankers who feel the push
button era should be with us already--in fact, they've designed the buttons
and the circuits connecting the automated central banker
Their

to the economy.

uttons are variously labeled "money supply, narrow," "money supply, broad,"

"total bank credit," "total bank reserves," "interest rates," etc., etc.

And

there are some other alchemists' preparation said to guide the more intuitive
of us.
All of these monetary analysts, including the pseudo types, have some
theory of monetary causation including an a priori or empirical finding of at
least how much time elapses between monetary action and final spending or
inflation.

Unfortunately, no such theory has been demonstrated to have, in

changing institutional and economic environments, sufficient validity to warrant
its adoption as an unvarying base for policy formulation.




Monetary actions

-11-

continue to require a very large element of intuitively based judgment, trial
and error probings, and constant review in the light of evolving expectations.
It would, of course, be a great boon to monetary policy if analytical
techniques could determine within usable limits the manner in which monetary
restraint or ease works its way through the economy and how long, given the
circumstances, before the degree of tranquilization or stimulation sought is
achieved.

Studies of monetary linkages will, some day, afford better

operating guides than we now have.

And we should press forward as vigorously

as possible to develop scientific substitutes for intuition and judgment
predicated on an eclectic use of monetary magnitudes.
that the scientific know how

When the day comes

is available we can "dial" more or less

monetary stability in the certain knowledge of its influence on the basic
goals of our economic system.