View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release at 2 p.m.EST
Thursday, March 2, 1972




Financing Rural Economies and Agriculture
Remarks of George W. Mitchell
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Farm Forum
Minneapolis, Minnesota
March 2, 1972

Financing Rural Economies and Agriculture
In appearing at this Farm Forum to talk about financing
rural economies and agriculture, I do so without the pretense that
I know more than my audience about most aspects of farm and rural
finance.

Many of you must be intimately involved in rural credit,

either as borrowers or lenders, and some no doubt as both.

So

while the title of my talk looks general enough to cover just about
anything, I'm going to avoid topics where I think your expertise
outclasses mine and focus on aspects where my credentials are in
better order.
Generally I will be characterizing the operation of our
financjj ! institutions, and the channels through which capital and
credit flows to various economic sectors, including agriculture.
One might infer from the data on the recent growth in farm debt
that present financial arrangements have been effective in providing
adequate rural credit.

However, I would not come to that judgment

unless growth in the use of credit were gauged in terms of growth in
need.

And the inference may be questionable because there are some

characteristics of our financial institutions and certain prevailing
financial practices which obviously impede the flow of rural credit.
These arrangements in the private sector may only amount to adversely
affecting the allocation of private credit to rural areas, any short­
fall being offset by expanding Federal credit programs for rural areas.
But adding to the problems to be solved by Government, those that
might be solved or ameliorated by a better functioning of private
institutions and arrangements hardly seems an optimum policy stance.
I wish to acknowledge the assistance of Emanuel Melichar, Senior
Economist, Business Conditions Section of our Division of Research
and Statistics, in the preparation of material for this paper.




-2I want to make clear the nature of my critique of private
institutions.

I am going to be dealing with the organizational frame­

work— the financial laws, institutions, and practices— within which
rural lenders operate.

To a large extent, lenders themselves appear

to be operating efficiently; efficiently, that is, within the limits
allowed by prevailing practices and institutional structure.

But the

present setup has defects that impose significant disadvantages on
institutions and their customers.

Banks, for example, are often

popularly blamed for lack of lenders' initiative or avoidance of the
effort needed to make rural loans when they may, in fact, be partly
or largely immobilized by internal constraints within the system. If
we can find the faults and improve the system— if, for instance, we
can change things so that rural financial institutions can make more
efficient use of their present resources, or so that they can improve
their access to the nation's main market flows of funds— then the rural
economy will be the winner, at least to the extent its needs are competi­
tive with other demands on the economy's credit resources.

This result

is also likely to be in the long-run benefit of rural financial institutions.
The Financial Mechanism
Basically, we are concerned with the process by which the
nation's savings get allocated along various investment sectors, one
of which is the rural economy.

The nation

continually generates a

flow of savings; one part of the flow is directly invested by the saverplowed back into his enterprise; another part is deposited in banks or
thrift institutions, who then lend it out, generally to their own




-3customers, or make it available in central capital markets; and the
third major part is directly made available in central capital
markets, where it may be purchased either by users or by banks and
other financial institutions who then lend it at the most favorable
terms and rates available.

This financial mechanism, if operating

efficiently, directs funds to the uses that promise the best return
after discount for risk and uncertainty and taking into account
lenders' preferences for terms of repayment.
The financial mechanism serving rural areas has two arms—
the private institutions and the Federally-sponsored institutions.
This ambidextrous characteristic is not unique to rural investment,
but is a feature of many other aspects of our economic life where
private flows of funds are not large enough to satisfy social objectives.
Housing, urban redevelopment, education, export financing, are illus­
trative of activities aided by public intervention.

Conceptually,

one might say, public policy acting through Government may institute
a Federal credit program only when imperfections in the working of
the private financial sector are causing a suboptimal allocation of
funds to a given activity, or when it is socially desirable to
encourage the expansion of that activity beyond the limits of an
efficiently working market system.
Take, for example, the financing of farm investment and
operations.

The credit program serving marginal farm borrowers—

the Farmers Home Administration— can be viewed as having been established




-

4-

primarily on considerations of social desirability, serving mainly
farmers who would be fairly unlikely to secure very much credit
even with an efficiently functioning private credit market.

On the

other hand, it seems unlikely that the Federal credit program
serving commercial agriculture— the cooperative Farm Credit System
consisting of the Federal Land Banks, production credit associations,
and the Banks for Cooperatives— was initially undertaken or periodically
expanded primarily in order to expand farm output.

A better rationale,

in addition to political considerations, is that the private financial
sector serving rural areas was and is sufficiently imperfect so that
farm borrowers were and are at a significant disadvantage when competing
with other economic sectors for funds in national credit markets.

These

Federal credit programs played a very significant role in meeting the
unprecedented credit demands that arose in the agricultural sector
during the last two decades.
That record is worth taking a look at, especially with
the perspectives afforded by some recent studies made by Federal
Reserve Board staff.
1870.

Data on agricultural finance go back to about

The most striking financial fact about most of this period—

during which the West was settled and farming was extensively
mechanized— is not the large amount of credit used, but rather how
little was used.
farmers' savings.

Most capital requirements were met directly through
There was only one brief period during which

borrowings rose sharply and exceeded the amount of internal financing,
and that was during the land speculation boom that accompanied
World War I.




As many can still personally remember, disaster followed

5
quickly for many of these borrowers when farm product and land
prices collapsed after the war.
The recovery from this episode was prolonged by the Great
Depression, and the events together brought into being the Federal
credit programs for agriculture.

But no borrowing spree resulted;

on the contrary, outstanding farm debt was gradually reduced through
a combination of foreclosures and little new capital spending.

Then

in the second World War, farmers adopted a different economic strategy
from that in the previous war.

As they prospered they saved much of

their income, and reduced their debt to a low of $8 billion in 1946.
After the war they financed enormous building and equipment purchases,
mainly from their wartime savings plus their continued high income.
Toward the mid-1950*s, farm finance trends appeared to be
settling down.

Annual farm capital spending had leveled out at about

one-third of farmers' total cash flow.

Farmers were financing 88 per

cent of this spending internally, from their cash flow, and only 12
per cent through increasing their debt.
about 27 per cent of cash flow.

The internal financing took

Farm debt was rising by about

$1 billion annually.
Viewed historically, this high proportion of internal
financing looked like normal farm financial behavior.

But during

the late 1950's a significant change occurred; farmers collectively
reduced their savings rate to a level which still prevails.
dropped from 27 to 22 per cent of cash flow.

Savings

Consequently, internal

financing met only two-thirds of capital requirements, and debt
financing rose to one-third.




Thus, even though capital spending did

-

6-

not rise, average annual increases in outstanding farm debt rose
to over $2 billion.
The new lower savings rate continued through the next
capital spending boom, which occurred in the mid-1960's.

Con­

sequently, in these years, annual increases in farmers' debt rose
to over $4 billion.

More recently, increases in debt have moderated

about in line with reductions in capital spending and reduced activity
in the farm real estate market, so that the reduced savings rate
apparently continues.
Will the unprecedentedly high and sustained reliance on
debt financing of recent years wane or persist?

Emil Melichar,

Agricultural Economist for the Board, has suggested a line of analyses
responsive to this question.

On the one hand, he notes that the

postwar demand for credit appears associated with the rapid reorganiza­
tion of farming into larger units.

For the first 40 years of this

century there was very little change in the size of the average
American farm, but the postwar enlargement of farms has coincided
with the rapid rise in debt.

Another factor noted is that the postwar

land price inflation which, in addition to raising capital requirements
involved in land transfers, may have increased credit demands by making
some farmers wealthier in terms of assets than in terms of current
income.

Still other influences raising credit demands are a higher

proportion of nonfarm heirs and an increased propensity for farmers
to elect a retirement period, for which they must cash in their farm
assets.




Such trends will probably continue.

-7The second aspect of the farm finance record of the last
two decades, Mr. Melichar notes, is perhaps self-evident: namely,
the ability of farmers to raise these unprecedented amounts of funds
in credit markets.

From the low point of $8 billion in 1946, out­

standing farm debt rose to $24.8 billion by 1960 and now stands at
$65.6 billion.

For most commercial farmers the need to incur

additional debt happily largely coincided with the ability to do so;
consequently, reports over most of the period of rapid debt expansion
usually noted that the supply of credit was adequate, and that farm
credit needs were being met.
This record was only achieved, however, because of the
sizable borrowing from sellers of farms, from farm suppliers, and
directly in capital markets through the Federal credit programs.
During the last 10 years (evding January 1, 1971), Federal credit
programs accounted for $10.8 billion, or 30 per cent of the total
increase in farm debt.

Another $6.9 billion increase in real estate

debt was obtained mainly from sellers of farms— a source that was
especially significant in tight money years.

Farm suppliers,

particularly during the machinery buying boom of the mid-1960's,
were an important credit source which used access to money markets
directly or borrowed from large non-agricultural banks.

Non-

real-estate debt owed to suppliers, dealers, and individuals increased
by $7.3 billion.

Life insurance companies increased their farm mort­

gage debt holdings by $2.6 billion.




8Private financing versus Federally-sponsored credit
Over the very long view, agriculture has always been
financed by individuals, suppliers, insurance companies, and banks,
with banks historically the dominant institutional credit source.
The new element on the scene is the Federally-sponsored credit.
These programs exhibited faster growth in credit extension than
did other sources over the last decade.
needed.

They seem to have been

Private lending institutions added $5.4 billion to their

farm mortgage portfolios in the past decade.

Could they have supplied

the additional $6.4 billion in farm mortgage debt provided by Federal
Land Banks and the Farmers Home Administration?
banks have provided the $4.3 billion

Or could commercial

rise in non-real-estate debt

secured from production credit associations and the FHA in addition
to the $6.1 billion they did extend?
There is evidence that banks have been hard put to provide
the farm credit increase that they actually recorded in the past two
decades.

In 1950, farmers' bank deposits totaled $6.6 billion and

their farm loans from banks stood at $3.0 billion, or 45 per cent of
their deposits.

On average, farm loan demand could be viewed as

being met through lending out deposits of the same or other farmers.
By 1971, however, farmers' bank deposits totaled $10.4 billion whereas
their bank loans had risen to $16.2 billion, over 150 per cent of their
deposits.

Banks are thus far from being able to finance agriculture

from farming's own contribution to growth in banking resources.




-

9-

Another farm finance problem involving banks is that the
reorganization of farming into larger units has enlarged individual
farm credit beyond the capacity of individual banking institutions,
especially in those States where banking has not undergone a parallel
reorganization.
With respect to the rural nonfarm economy, statistics on
the performance of the private financial sector relative to credit
demands are limited.

There are, however, some clues.

Since 1962,

when the Farmers Home Administration was put into the business o£
financing nonfarm rural housing, its outstanding loans for this purpose
have risen to $3.4 billion.

Over the same period, outstanding FHA

loans for sewer and water systems, recreational development, and
similar nonfarm enterprises have risen from $12 million to $970 million.
These are significant sums to have been lent over so short a period,
and it seems doubtful that very much of this credit demand would have
been met by the private sector.
Another indication of rural credit needs can be derived
from the apparent rise in the number of people who insist that
Federal credit programs should be extended to other segments of the
nonfarm rural economy.

For instance, in 1970 the President's Task

Force on Rural Development called for creation of a Rural Development
Credit Bank as a new part of the cooperative Farm Credit System,

and

for expansion of the nonfarm lending activities of the Farmers Home
Administration.

Since then, the Farm Credit System has obtained some

nonfarm lending authority, but declined to seek expansion on this
scale into nonfarm lending.




However, several bills that purport to

-

10-

accomplish this in one way or another have been introduced in Con­
gress, and hearings have been held on some of them.
In July 1971, the President's First Annual Report on
Financial Assistance to Rural Areas stated that the principal rural
sector requiring additional Federal financial assistance was the
state and local government sector, and thus the message reiterated
the previously proposed rural revenue sharing plan.

With respect

to nonfarm business, the message argued that while the efficiency
of the existing credit programs of the Small Business Administration
and the Economic Development Act could be improved, "new initiatives
in providing financial assistance in support of rural development
should place major reliance upon private sector lending institutions."
But in the latest presidential rural message of February 1, 1972, the
Administration altered this view to the extent of proposing a Rural
Development Credit Fund that would be administered jointly by State
governments and the Farmers Home Administration.

Given this step by

the Administration and the substantial congressional support evidenced
for various rural development measures, the enactment of some kind of
new Federal credit program

intended specifically to assist in the

financing of rural businesses, industries, and public services may
be regarded as probable.
Making the private sector work better
As noted, the Administration and many other backers of
expanded rural development credit have expressed a philosophical
preference for private sector financing.




There are sound economic

-

11-

reasons for this, mainly in the quickness and flexibility of response
to particular situations.

For instance, the private sector can

usually deal more effectively with novel credit demands or those that
are unique to certain regions, or those that may require some departure
from traditional terms or financing methods.

However, those persons

who prefer private credit, and who at the same time believe that
private credit allocation to rural areas has been suboptimal, have
often dealt only with superficial aspects of the situation.

Thus many

apparently think, for example, that bankers need only to be exhorted
to "do a better job of farm lending," to "take more interest in farm
lending," or to "make more use of their correspondents."
plea

A typical

was that of the President's Task Force on Rural Development,

which said, "we recommend a special effort by banks, financial institu­
tions, and the SBA to lend money...]toJ small businesses in countryside
America."

But nowhere did the Task Force undertake to determine why

bankers now run their banks the way they do, and what institutional
changes might permit or encourage them to expand lending of the type
desired.

Thus, without investigating what might be done to permit

more or all of the prospective rural development credit demands to be
met by the private sector, or recommending that someone else undertake
to determine this, the Task Force merely noted that "the capital needs...
are too great in total, and too large in individual amounts, to be met
in full by existing local banking and financial institutions."

I

would have added that those existing institutions need to be changed
in a number of ways which would enable them to make a greater contri­
bution toward financing those capital needs.




12-

One source of the requisite analyses and reform ideas in
recent years has in fact been the Federal Reserve System.

A number

of reports by officials, committees, and staff members have dealt
with the desirability of changes in rural banking structure, corres­
pondent credit arrangements, usury laws, access to money markets,
and, in particular, with increasing the amount of Federal Reserve
discount credit that is readily available to rural banks.

Several

members of the academic community have also contributed to this
public discussion.
Drawing in part on these various observations, the President's
1971 Report on Financial Assistance to Rural Areas went beyond the
usual exhortations to list several changes that would reduce impedi­
ments in the ability of rural banks to finance agriculture:
— greater use of correspondait banks and increased participation
in loans with non-bank lenders;
— greater use of branch banking and formation of more holding
companies ;
— creation of new institutions or instruments to provide greater
access to money markets;
— liberalization of Federal Reserve discounting restrictions,
as applied to rural banks.
These points cover several impediments to rural bank financing and in
the balance of my remarks I will be examining these and other sug­
gestions for improving the level of bank lending to agricultural and
rural communities.




-13-

A factual base is needed from which one might estimate
the credit dimensions of potential improvements in banking practices
and structure.

This is provided in the accompanying tables con­

taining pertinent available facts about rural bank lending.
The data are taken from the June 30, 1971 Reports of
Condition which all banks file with their primary supervisors.

As

of that date, agricultural loans by all insured commercial banks
amounted to $16,149 million.

Since the focus of our attention is

on banks in rural areas, the tabulation is restricted to banks outside
of SMSA'8.

This exclusion eliminates lenders in large cities but the

remaining banks account for $11,247 million in farm mortgages and
loans to farmers.

The sample, therefore, covers over two-thirds of

total farm loans.

The data are detailed by State, by size of bank,

and by whether or not the bank is a member of the Federal Reserve
System.

Not all States are shown in the tables but the 21 States

included make up 85 per cent of the total of farm loans held by banks
outside of SMSA's.
At such banks in these 21 States, loan-to-deposit ratios range
from 49 to 64 per cent and average 57 per cent (Table II).

Levels of

lending are considerably higher than they were a decade ago but still
fall short of those prevailing in city banks.

There seems to be no

consistent difference in lending by members and nonmembers when similar
sized banks are compared, either as to the level of total loans or
the shares lent to farmers (Table I).




To me the most interesting, and in some respects the most
significant, facts have to do with size and character of cash assets
of rural banks (Tables II and III).

Cash assets are currency and

coin, cash items in the process of collection, demand deposit balances
with banks, and, in the case of Federal Reserve member banks, reserve
balances with the Federal Reserve Bank.

Among the 21 States, for

member banks, cash assets range from 10.2 to 16.9 per cent of deposits
for nonmembers, from 6.4 to 15.9 per cent.

Nonmembers average about

3 percentage points less than members, due mainly to the differences
in reserve requirements.

Using these data, what can one say about

the significance of proposals to modify banking practices?
Correspondent banking. Small banks obtain many services
from other and usually larger banks.

Traditionally the smaller bank

has paid for these services indirectly, by maintaining a demand
deposit account at larger banks.

A portion of rural banking resources

is therefore at all times tied up in balances at city banks, rather
than being available for loans.

The sums involved are significant,

ranging, among the 21 States, from 4.7 to 13.4 per cent of total
deposits in the case of nonmembers to 3.3 to 8.7 per cent in the case
of members (Table III).

Within a given state, this ratio tends to be

higher at the smaller banks (Table IV).
Can banks free up funds for achieving higher loan levels
by reducing correspondent balances?

This simple suggestion is in

line with a steadily growing line of thought in many progressive
banks, on using fees rather than balances as a method of compensation.




-15Thus, where local credit conditions warrant, rural banks would not
place funds with city banks who would put them to work earning the
money that pays for the services received.

Instead, rural banks

would put that part of these funds not needed for clearing purposes
to work themselves, in local loans and investments.

The local

earnings would be used to pay for correspondent services on a fee basis.
Why has this change not been made--why the continued siphoning
off of rural banking resources?

Mainly, I believe, because paying for

banking services through deposit balances has been a standard industry
practice for such a very long time.

Generally, banks condensate each

other in this fashion and they use the same practice for other bank
customers, whether corporations, individuals or governments.

So far

as correspondent banking involving rural banks is concerned', the
practice goes back to an era when rural banks quite properly assigned
a low opportunity cost to a significant share of their deposits; in
general, they had more loanable funds than loan demand and it was con­
venient and equivalent to laying up "treasure in heaven" to have &
valued deposit relationship with a city correspondent.
banks, this era-ended from 5 to 10 years ago.

For many rural

Some banks have responded

by trimming their balances, but what is needed is a basic shift toward
fees as a method of compensation for correspondent services.
The city correspondents, on their part, have generally
preferred to be paid through deposit balances mainly, no doubt, because
that is is the way it has always been done.

There is also a rather

pervasive belief, not necessarily borne out by a cost analysis, that




-16the system results, on the average, in higher prices for services
rendered.

Account analyses will answer the question of who gains

or loses from compensating balance arrangements, but the point at
issue has to do with bank customers.

The rural bank's loan customers

are clearly losers if the city bank's customers get access to the
credit that they might have otherwise had access to.

Now that rural

bankers in many sections of the country are serving credit-short
areas they should be seeking city correspondents who are prepared
to sell their services on a fee basis, thus allowing the rural bank
to keep more of its funds at work in its own community.
Among the correspondent services available are participations
in rural lending by city banks.
ments are very important.

For some rural banks these arrange­

Obviously they can offset, or even more

than offset, the drain of funds to city banks.

Our data-reporting

system does not regularly provide information on such fund flows.
We do know that participations run upstream as well as downstream
and there is evidence that in some States on a net basis the flow
is defying gravity.

We also know that country banks sell Federal

funds and buy certificates of deposit in correspondent banks— the
amounts are now about 4 per cent of total deposits; there is very
little reverse flow in Federal funds or certificates.
Banking structure. Another significant inefficiency in the
utilization of rural banking resources is manifested in the previously
noted lower loan-deposit ratios at which small rural banks generally
operate, as compared with larger unit banks or branching systems.




-17Admittedly these ratios could be higher but there are hazards involved
in reaching for the levels of loan saturation feasible for large and
diversified lenders.
A rural unit bank typically serves a small market area
with relatively undiversified economic activity.

Because many of its

borrowers are engaged in the same enterprise or in related activities,
their economic fortunes are likely to rise and fall in concert.

In

this usual rural environment, the overall lending risk faced by the
bank is necessarily greater than if it had a more diversified loan
market, and under these circumstances and without special liquidity
backup it is no less than prudent to maintain a higher percentage of
secondary reserves.
In largely rural States, only statewide branching' systems
or holding companies can generally achieve the degree of diversifica­
tion necessary to a significant improvement in the relative utilization
of banking resources.

States that continue to restrict or outlaw these

forms of banking organization may be imposing an unnecessary limitation
upon loan accommodations to their rural residents.

For instance,

correspondent demand balances appear to absorb a smaller percentage
of rural bank assets in States where holding companies are active,
as in the Ninth District (Table III).
Also, it is only through statewide branching, or indirectly
through active group banking, that rural borrowers can hope to enjoy
the advantages of being served by larger banks in a position to
realize economies of scale.




Very small banks, with tinder $5 million

-18or so in deposits, have significantly higher unit costs which must
in some way be borne by their customers in the form of less service,
higher loan rates or lower time deposit earnings.

In addition,

small banks are often unable, legally or prudently, to meet the loan
demands of the larger firms in their communities.

These may, of

course, be met by recourse to correspondent participations.

I have

already noted the problems entailed in paying for correspondent
services.
Finally, the larger banks have better access to loanable
funds in the nation's capital and money markets, which is an ad­
vantage few, if any, small banks have been able to match at present.
On the other side there is a deep-seated conviction on the
part of many informed persons that branching and holding company
systems result in a draining away of rural savings for urban or
other remote investment.

In theory, a statewide system will reallocate

resources on the basis of comparative need and effective demand.

If

rural and agricultural demands are less urgent and less able to com­
pete on a market basis the funds should go elsewhere.

Whether the

larger systems tend to shew a preference for non-agricultural
customers has not been established one way or another so far as I
am aware.

The very nature of the banking business argues to the

contrary.

Banks have two masters— depositors and borrowers.

If one

has priority in these times it is the depositor and his community.
It is doubtful to me that any bank would disregard or risk the
allegation it was disregarding the needs of the community which
supports its deposit position and growth.




19
Access to capital markets« The nation's larger banks have
been meeting a growing portion of their loan demand in recent years
by raising funds in national and international money markets.

Within

broad limits during normal monetary conditions, these banks are able
to gear such fund-raising activities to their loan demand, so that
their ability to make loans is freed from sole dependence on growth
in regular demand and savings deposits.

The nature of these markets

is such, however, that small and even medium-sized banks can make
only limited use of them; in consequence their lending ability still
depends primarily on growth in local deposits.

Thus, regions and

sectors that tend to be served by smaller banks— such as rural areas
and agriculture— are handicapped in their access to credit.
I have already mentioned changes in banking structure that
would help remedy this condition.

In addition, it is possible to set

up arrangements through which access of the smaller banks to money
markets can be achieved.

One promising technique is to raise funds

by the sale of existing portfolios of agricultural loans into pools
which are financed by the sale of participations in national money
markets.
Rural bankers are becoming more aware of the possibilities
and are taking the initial steps along this line.

A committee of The

American Bankers Association's Agricultural Credit Task Force,
reporting at last fall's ABA Agricultural Credit Conference,
recommended "that consideration be given to establishing a regional
or national mechanism to provide ready marketability for agricultural




-

20 -

production credit paper and other credit closely related to
agriculture."

The committee suggested that this be accomplished

through an organization of banks, operating either on their own or
with governmental backing.

The agricultural credit corporation thus

created would discount some loans for its member banks, participate
in others, and even purchase some high quality paper without recourse.
It would establish a reserve fund against losses, financed by per­
centage fees from banks utilizing the corporation.

To secure funds

for these activities, the credit corporation would sell negotiable
debt instruments in the money market.

By way of an analogy, it is

clear that in the important respects, this ABA committee of rural
bankers wants to create an organization that would provide rural
banks with credit services similar to those provided to production
credit associations by the Federal Intermediate Credit Banks.

Another Task Force committee reporting at the same ABA
meeting similarly recommended "permissive legislation for banks to
go together in forming an Agricultural Credit Corporation."

But in

addition to using such an organization to tap money markets, this
committee also emphasized that the corporation could be used as the
vehicle through which those rural banks with surplus funds could
purchase instruments from other rural banks at which loan demands
were pressing hard against resources.
To these pool proposals by the ABA committees, I would add
the following suggestions for securing improved access to money
markets:




-

(1)

21-

the possibility of obtaining private insurance for
some agricultural and other loans, thereby making
them more salable to private investors.

In fact,

under the Holding Company Statute one large bank
has applied for and received authority to create
a subsidiary to insure loans of a similar t y p e in this case small businesses.
(2) the possibility that the large money market banks
can endorse and/or market, for a reasonable fee,
acceptances originated by smaller banks.

Some of

the larger banks serving rural areas are already
marketing their own acceptances (mostly representing
credit secured by cattle in feedlots) through dealers
in New York, and this proposal would extend this
avenue to still smaller banks.
Federal Reserve discount credit. The final institutional
.changes to be mentioned relate to the Federal Reserve discount
mechanism.

This is the procedure through which Federal Reserve

member banks can borrow funds for short periods of time from their
Federal Reserve Bank.

Sane time ago, the Federal Reserve System,

considering the altered financial environment in which banks were
operating today, began an intensive review and analysis of the
functioning and role of its discount facility.
The Committee that undertook this task made a thorough
and lengthy investigation of all aspects of the problem and in




-

22-

July, 1968, presented its report and supporting evidence to the
Board of Governors.

Two of the principal recommendation in that

Report would, I believe, significantly improve the ability of rural
banks to serve their communities.

I want to discuss them briefly.

Over the postwar years, a majority of rural member banks
had not used the discount window at all, and others only infrequently.
Many rural bankers got the impression that discounting was a
"forbidden fruit."

This impression was fostered because the Federal

Reserve did not clearly define the difference between appropriate and
inappropriate use of Reserve credit.

To remedy this situation, the

Committee recommended that basic borrowing privilege be established
for each member bank.

Under it a bank could, with no questions asked,

borrow up to specified amount for specified number of weeks in each
year.

Thus the extent to which Federal Reserve borrowing could be

used as a ready source of short-term adjustment credit would be known.
It was anticipated that many more bankers would rely on this source
of funds and thereby enhance their ability to serve their local
communities.
The study Committee also concluded that borrowing by rural
banks to meet seasonal deposit outflows and loan extensions associated
with agricultural production was appropriate and should be encouraged.
Thus, a second major recommendation was that a seasonal borrowing
privilege be instituted.

The specific proposal recommended was of

great significance to those banks exposed to large seasonal variations
relative to the size of the bank.

Under the seasonal borrowing

privilege as outlined, banks could arrange for Federal Reserve funds




-23-

to accommodate all of their seasonal outflow exceeding a certain
percentage— perhaps 5 to 10 per cent— of their average level of
deposits.

Such generous seasonal access to Federal Reserve credit,

we believed, was justified by the demonstrated inability of small
rural banks to obtain seasonal funds in money markets.

Given the

assured seasonal access to Federal Reserve credit, these banks
could begin to make longer term loans for both farm and nonfarm
purposes, using some of the funds that presently must be kept in
liquid instruments in order to be available for the seasonal demands.
Since that Report was completed and made available for
general discussion and examination, I believe that a very large
measure of public and industry support for the recommendations has
become evident.

In fact, many of the more technical specific pro­

posals have been put into practice and I believe that attitudes
toward discounting within and without the System have moved significantly
toward the philosophy of the original recommendation.
One troublesome problem— how to define the limits to
seasonal accommodation— has been under continuing study and I believe
we now have a more workable system than we had two years ago.
It is not surprising that I, as the Chairman of the original
study Committee, regret that the Federal Reserve has not yet fully
implemented the Committee's recommendations.

One difficulty has been

that liberalized access to the discount window should be introduced
during a time of relative neutrality in monetary policy, and such
times have been scarce and brief since 1968.




As I indicated, our

-24staff has been continuously working to refine the proposals,
especially the rules and administration of the seasonal privilege.
The Federal Reserve is a conservative institution which
usually moves deliberately after full study and consideration.

But

I do not think it would be fair to say we would deliberately study
a problem until it became extinct, and for that reason I can hope
we will soon be doing our bit to improve the ability of the private
sector to finance rural economies and agriculture.
those of you concerned to do likewise.




I challenge

Table I.

Loans to Farmers, by Member and Nonmember Banks

Insured Commercial Banks Outside of SMSA's in 21 Agricultural States
June 30, 1971

State*
Iowa
Texas
Nebraska

Farm Loans
(millions of dollars)
Nonmember
Member
Total
Banks
Banks

___________ Farm Loans as Percentage of Total Loans
Deposit Sizfe of Bank (millions of dollars)
5 or Less
5-10
10-25
25-50
M
_M__
N
_M__
N
M
N
N

Over 50
N
M

1,139
747
745

318
434
380

821
313
365

66
45
78

63
34
70

58
34
67

55
33C
61

39
26
54

41
26
54

21
11
33

24
14
—

19
19
—

- -

Kansas
Illinois
Minnesota

740
713
676

371
380
224

369
333
452

63
45
46

62
43
51

58
35
32

47
37
42

37
27
20

32
28
25

20
17
11

12
11
—

16
6 .
—

- -

Missouri
Wisconsin
Indiana

545
460
398

153
128
173

392
332
225

44
26
35

47
36
35

36
22
27

39
31
29

28
17
22

31
21
25

16
6
9

18
10
20

2
4
5

Oklahoma
South Dakota
Kentucky

380
358
345

237
194
121

143
164
224

49
70
50

48
73
39

40
65
33

39
71
33

33
45
24

37
46
17

12
43
12

8
40
6

1
28
12

Ohio
North Dakota
Georgia

316
300
298

218
102
46

98
198
252

33
62
19

28
64
26

24
46
18

27
55
28

14
32
13

13
39
15

7
15
5

6
32
4

- -

—

5
6
36
5

Arkansas
Tennessee
Colorado

280
255
243

104
70
190

176
185
53

22
17
44

35
32
30

31
20
45

37
24
31

24
11
39

29
19
18

14
9
26

18
11
31

2
**
22

--------

Mississippi
Montana
Michigan

241
222
203

48
158
102

193
64
101

24
53
20

34
25
22

18
40
16

35
42
16

15
38
8

24
45
13

7
13
8

- -

14
11

5

9
- -

4

—

--------

4
8
4» mm

14
- -

5

21 States
5,453
9,604
4,151
All States
11.247
* States are ranked in order by the amount of farm loans at banks outside of Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas
(SMSA's). Data are shown for the 21 states in which farm loans at such banks totaled over $200 million. Farm
loans shown are real estate mortgage loans secured by farm land plus other loans to farmers.
** Less than 0.5 per cent.
M“
Member banks.
N«Nonmember banks.



Table II.

Deposits, Loans, and Cash Assets

Insured Commercial Banks Outside of SMSA's in 21 Agricultural States*
June 30, 1971

State and
Class of
Banks

Total Deposits
(millions of dollars)
Banks
All
Outside
Banks
SMSA's

Iowa
Member
Nonmember

6,830

Texas
Member
Nonmember

26,813

Nebraska
Member
Nonmember

3,615

Kansas
Member
Nonmember

5,151

Illinois
Member
Nonmember

36,723

Minnesota
Member
Nonmember

9,409

Missouri
Member
Nonmember

11,471

Wisconsin
Member
Nonmember

10,025

Continued next page.




Selected Assets as
Percentage of Total Deposits
Total
Loans

Loans to
Farmers

Cash and
Demand
Balances

Federal
Funds Sold
and Other
Balances

1,485
2,797

58
59

21
29

13
9

3
2

3,301
1,890

50
57

13
17

17
16

5
3

1,176
904

59
63

32
40

13
9

2
3

1,624
1,435

54
53

23
26

15
11

4
5

3,143
2,063

48
50

12
16

12
9

4
3

1,748
1,938

58
57

13
23

11
7

2
1

1,035
2,045

53
52

15
19

14
10

4
4

1,864
2,258

61
56

7
15

11
8

3
2

Table II.

State and
Class of
_______ Banks

Deposits, Loans,

Total Deposits
(millions of dollars)
Banks
All
Outside
Banks
SMSA*s

Indiana
Member
Nonmember

10,968

Oklahoma
Member
Nonmember

5,806

South Dakota
Member
Nonmember

1,616

Kentucky
Member
Nonmember

5,521

Ohio
Member
Nonmember

22,010

2,219
1,826
1,675
746
700
454
1,060
1,719
3,125
1,076

North Dakota
Menber
Nonmember

1,434

Georgia
Member
Nonmember

7,507

Arkansas
Member
Nonmember

3,200

Tennessee
Member
Nonmember

7,777

Continued next page.




599
750
776
1,880
1,040
993
1,246
1,553

and Cash Assets (continued)
Selected Assets as
Percentage of Total Deposits
Total
Loans

Loan# to
Farmers

Cash and
Demand
Balances

Federal
Funds Sold
and Other
Balances

54
54

12

12
8

5
5

49
52

14
19

16
14

8

63
56

28
36

11
10

1
**

54
52

11
13

15
12

4
4

59
59

7
9

10
8

3
3

60
53

17
26

11

1
**

64
63

6
13

14

10

3
4

51
56

IQ
18

15
14

3
2

55
57

6
12

13
11

4
3

8,




6

8

Table 11.

State and
Class of
Banks

Deposits, Loans, and Cash Assets (continued)

Total Deposits
(millions of dollars)
Banks
All
Outside
Banks
SMSA's

Colorado
Member
Nbnmember

4,580

Mississippi
Member
Nonmember

3,282

Montana
Member
Nonmember

1,656

Michigan
Member
Nonmember

21,932

Selected Assets as
Percentage of Total Deposits
Total
Loans

Loans to
Farmers

Cash and
Demand
Balances

Federal
Funds Sold
and Other
Balances

835
283

64
64

23
18

16
14

2
2

806
1,418

53
54

6
14

16
11

3
5

918
268

60
60

17
24

13
8

2
1

2,019
1,337

62
62

5
8

10
7

4
4

* Except data in first column, which shows total deposits at all insured commercial banks.
** Less than 0.5 per cent.
See notes to Table I.




Table III.

Cash Assets as Percentage of Total Deposits

Insured Commercial Banks Outside of SMSA's in 21 Agricultural States
June 30, 1971

State

Total
Cash
Assets

Member Banks
Cash
Items
in Process
Currency
of
and
Collection
Coin

Demand
Balances
With
Other
Banks

Reserves
With
Federal
Reserve
Banks

Total
Cash
Assets

Nonmember Banks
Cash
Items
in Process
Currency
of
and
Collection
Coin

Demand
Balances
With
Other
Banks

Iowa
Texas
Nebraska

12.9
16.9
13.0

1.4
.8
1.0

1.3
1.8
1.0

5.6
8.7
5.0

4.6
5.6
6.0

9.3
15.9
9.2

.4
.7
.3

1.2
1.8
1.0

7.7
13.4
7.9

Kansas
Illinois
Minnesota

14.7
12.3
11.3

1.5
1.1
1.6

6.7
4.5
3.7

5.3
5.3
4.9

10.7
9.3
7.3

.4
.4
.3

1.1
1.3
1.1

9.2
7.6
5.9

Missouri
Wisconsin
Indiana

14.3
10.8
12.2

1.5
1.6
1.5

5.6
3.4
4.5

5.6
4.1
4.2

10.5
8.0
7.8

.3
.2

1.6

1.5

.6

1.6

8.6
6.3
5.6

Oklahoma
South Dakota
Kentucky

16.4
11.3
15.0

1.0

1.2
1.4
1.1
1.6
1.7
2.0
1.7
1.0
2.4

8.5
4.1
6.9

5.2
5.4
5.3

13.7
10.0
12.4

.5
.3
.4

1.8
1.0
2.0

11.4
8.7
10.0

Ohio
North Dakota
Georgia

10.5
10.7
14.0

.8
1. 8
1.2

2.2

3.8
3.6
5.1

3.7
4.2
5.4

8.2
6.4
10.4

.4
.7

2.1

.5'

2.4

5.7
4.9
7.5

Arkansas
Tennessee
Colorado

15.2
13.4
16.3

1.6
.7
1.5

1.8

6.5
6.1
8.0

5.3
4.0
5.3

14.0
10.7
13.5

.6
.4
.6

1.9
2.0
1.6

11.5
8.3
11.3

Mississippi
15.7
Montana
13.2
Michigan____
10.2
See notes to Table I.

1.2
3.9
.9

2.7
1.2

7.5
3.3
3.5

4.3
4.8
3.6

11.3
7.7
6.9

.5
.5
.3

2.2
1.4
1.9

5.8
4.7




.8
.4

1.1
2.3
2.6

1.5

2.2

.8

8.6

Table IV.

Demand Balances at Other Banks as Percentage of Total Deposits,
by Member and Nonmember Banks and by Deposit Size of Bank

Insured Commercial Banks Outside of SMSA's in 21 Agricultural States
June 30, 1971

State

Member Banks
Total Deposits of Bank (millions of dollars)
5 or Less
25-50
5-10
10-25
Ovér

Iowa
Texas
Nebraska

7
12
7

6
9
5

6
8
5

5
10
5

2
6

Kansas
Illinois
Minnesota

7
7
5

7
5
5

7
4
3

7
4
3

4
3

Missouri
Wisconsin
Indiana

7
5
5

6
4
5

5
4
4

6
3
4

Oklahoma
South Dakota
Kentucky

11
4
4

9
4
8

7
6
7

Ohio
North Dakota
Georgia

5
4
7

4
3
4

15
8
8
6
5
5

Arkansas
Tennessee
Colorado
Mississippi
Montana
Michigan

See notes to Table I.




Nonmember Banks
5 or Less

5-10

10-25

25-50
7
13

9
16
9

8
13
7

7
12
7

10
8
7

10
8
6

3
3
5

10
8
7

9
4
6

9
4
10

3
3
4

4
5
6

5
a» mm

6
7
7

6
6
8

6
6
8

8
4
4

8
3
3

8
3
4

#» mm

Over 50
rnmm
m mm

«■»«»

—

7
7
5

9
7
«■ «
i

a» «•

8
6
7

8
6
6

9
7
5

14
9
9

10
8
9

10
8
8

9
13
5

8
6
9

6
6
7

6
4
7

5
3
6

6
8
12

12
9
13

12
8
12.

11
9
9

12
8
4

7

12
6
6

9
6
6

8
6
5

mm mm

3

10
—

fl» «•

—
9
- -

5
fl» mm
—

27
4
4
5
_ _
—

—
6
- -

4

2