View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FD1

N EW S RELEASE

F E D E R A L D E P O S IT IN S U R A N C E C O R P O R A T IO N

FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY

PR-80-78 (8-4-78)

\ \
M rcposn '® UKl
LOtR c S l'O N

Statement on

Federal Reserve Membership Act of 1978 (H. R. 12706),
and Related Legislative Matters

Presented to
Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs
U.S. House of Representatives

by
Ö

George A. LeMaistre, Chairman
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation

August 4, 1978

FED ER A L DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION, 5 5 0 Seventeenth St. N.W., Washington, D.C. 20429



202-389-4221

Mr. Chairman, I appreciate the opportunity to testify before
this Committee and present the FDIC's views on the Federal Reserve
Membership Act of 1978 (H. R. 12706) introduced by Mr. Stanton and
the amendment to this bill that has been proposed by Chairman Reuss.
During the course of this statement, I shall also discuss the FDIC’s
views on the Federal Reserve Requirements Act of 1978 (H. R. 13476)
and the Interest on Reserves Act of 1978 (H. R. 13477), both intro­
duced at the request of the Federal Reserve System, and the Monetary
Policy Data Improvement Act of 1978 (H. R. 13549).
For the most part, the proposals contained in these bills grow
out of the Federal Reserve's concern with declining membership.
There has been a slow but steady erosion of Federal Reserve member­
ship over the last decade as banks have chosen to leave the System.
Recently, this gradual decline accelerated.

Since the beginning of

1977, 108 banks have withdrawn from membership.

The percentage of

total deposits of commercial banks held by Federal Reserve members
has decreased from 83 percent in 1965 to nearly 73 percent at the
present time.
The Federal Reserve System has become increasingly concerned
about the attrition of membership and the declining proportion of
deposits held by member banks.
membership as a solution.

For many years it proposed mandatory

The proposal never received a serious

hearing in the Congress for various reasons, but primarily because
of the concern expressed by the States about the impact of mandatory
membership on the viability of State banking systems.

More Recently,

the Federal Reserve modified its proposal to provide for mandatory
reserves and membership privileges for nonmembers.




2
Last year, as the problem of membership attrition became more
acute, the System proposed payment of interest on required reserves
and reductions in the minimum statutory reserve requirement limita­
tions.

Those proposals were coupled with the Consumer Financial

Services Act (S. 2055) which would have authorized depository insti­
tutions to offer NOW accounts.

In my testimony before Mr. St Germain's

Subcommittee on Financial Institutions Supervision, Regulation, and
Insurance last year, I stated that payment of interest on required
reserves and reduction of reserve requirements as proposed in S. 2055
would have important implications for the competitive balance between
member and nonmember banks, and for the structure of the banking
system.

I indicated that in my judgment these issues are quite

complex and are not related to permitting interest bearing NOW
accounts on a national basis.

Therefore, I recommended that these

issues be dealt with separately and be subjected to careful and
reasoned study.

These hearings and those scheduled before the

Senate Banking Committee provide the opportunity for the thorough
consideration I think is essential.
Let me begin by stating our view that the legal requirement that
Federal Reserve member banks maintain sterile reserves is inequitable
to them and inequitable to their customers.

In many States, it also

places member banks at a competitive disadvantage vis-a-vis nonmember
banks.

The several bills under discussion propose two solutions:

the first is to establish universal reserve requirements for all banks
or depository institutions; the second is to pay interest on reserves,
to reduce reserve requirements, and to charge banks for Federal Reserve
services now provided free to member banks.




3
For reasons I shall discuss, we strongly oppose the establish­
ment of universal reserve requirements.

The alternate proposal,

however, is attractive on its face and deserves thoughtful and
sympathetic consideration.

However, its implementation will not be

easy because a redressing of the imbalance between member and non­
member banks raises many of the difficult issues with which the
Congress has been wrestling, without resolution, for a number of
years.

These include, notably, the issue of changes in the Federal

regulatory structure, particularly whether the Federal Reserve
should continue to exercise supervisory authority; and the issue of
regulatory reform, particularly whether interest rate ceilings and
the prohibition of interest on demand deposits should be abolished.
In the remainder of this statement I shall explain how we
reached these conclusions by discussing how these two proposals
for dealing with the attrition of Federal Reserve membership bear
on several important public policy considerations:

(1) the capability

of the Federal Reserve System to conduct monetary policy effectively,
(2) the balance between the State and national banking systems, (3)
the efficiency and innovative capacity of the banking system, and
(4) the viability of the banking system under liquidity pressures.
I.

Monetary Policy Effectiveness

According to the Federal Reserve System, the Federal Reserve
Requirements Act of 1978 (H. R. 13476) is intended to provide the
basis for more effective monetary control.

Furthermore, the Federal

Reserve has stated its belief that the decline in the proportion of
deposits held by member banks caused by membership attrition adversely
affects the precision with which monetary policy can be conducted.
The point is that as a larger portion of deposits becomes subject to



4
diverse State reserve requirements the linkage between bank
reserves and the money supply becomes less predictable.
Of course, estimating the impact on the monetary aggregates of a
particular change in reserves becomes more difficult when different
banks are subject to different reserve requirements.

But this problem

would exist even if all banks were subject to universal reserve require
ments or if all banks were member banks.

Under the present reserve

structure of the Federal Reserve, time deposits are subject to differen
requirements than demand deposits and different size classes of member
banks are subject to varying reserve requirements.

Hence, a shift of

funds among member banks has precisely the same effect of blurring the
precision of monetary policy that disturbs the Federal Reserve when
nonmember banks are involved.

It should be noted that H. R. 13476

would not alter this appreciably, nor would the Reuss amendment which
would maintain the present system of varying the percentage of
deposits set aside as reserves based on bank size but which would also
remove the Federal Reserve's power to change reserve requirements.
There have been several studies of the monetary control issue
by economists outside the Federal Reserve.

All of those that I am

familiar with have concluded that increased Federal Reserve member­
ship is not important to the effectiveness of monetary policy.
There have been two major statistical studies which attempted
to ascertain the impact of uniform reserve requirements for nonmember
banks on the implementation of monetary policy.

The first was

conducted by Clark tfarburton for the Commission on Money and Credit.
Warburton concluded that nonmember banks are affected by Federal
Reserve monetary policy actions in approximately the same way that
member banks are.




Another investigation was reported by Dennis

5
Starleaf of Iowa State University.
M

In Starleaf's study the actual

money multiplier for the period 1962-1972 was compared with a

1
money multiplier series simulated under the assumption that all
banks were subject to the reserve requirements of the Federal
Reserve.

The simulation indicated that had nonmember banks been

subject to such reserve requirements there would have been even
greater variations in the money stock.

Starleaf thus rejected

the argument that uniform Federal Reserve reserve requirements
are necessary for the implementation of monetary policy.
There have also been a number of articles that attempted to
analyze the logical arguments and the statistical data that exist
on this issue.

The Hunt Commission concluded that "reserve require­

ments are unnecessary for open market operations to control the
monetary base effectively."

Carter Golembe, after discussing the

difficulties in conducting monetary policy with precision, concluded
that,
...so many factors contribute to the lack of
precision and certainty that simply changing
the proportion of deposits subject to Federal
Reserve requirements from almost 80 percent
to nearly 100 percent would be of relatively
minor importance.
In a 1974 study, Professors Ross Robertson and Almarin Phillips
investigated the argument that nonmember banks behave in a differ­
ent manner from member banks and that such behavior thwarts imple­
mentation of Federal Reserve monetary policy.

They concluded that

these arguments have no validity:
This contention deluded those who are innocent
of money matters and even a few who should know
better. As has been observed, open market
operations are for all practical purposes the
instrument of monetary control. Like the rain
from heaven that falls on us all, regardless of




6

our merits, open market operations affect member
and nonmember banks alike. There is not one
shred of evidence to the contrary.
A study conducted by Gary Gilbert and Manferd Peterson at the FDIC
found results similar to those of Robertson arid Phillips.

They

concluded that,
...the behavior of nonmember banks under varying
degrees of monetary ease or restraint is relatively
similar to that of country member banks. To the
extent that systematic behavior of the demand
deposits components is important for the effective
control of the money supply, there is no indica­
tion from available evidence that the nonmember
banking segment has hampered monetary policy.
Some economists have stressed the caveat that the Federal Reserve
could control monetar y aggregates without member banks or without
reserve requirements.

For example, in a 1973 article Henry and Mable

Wallich stated that,

,

Since intermediation [the function of gathering
funds from various entities and lending them to
others] is a constructive activity, there seems
to be no reason why Congress should place burdens
upon it beyond those that the tax system imposes
on any other form of business. The bulk of com­
mercial banking has been exposed to a special
tax, in the form of reserve requirements.
It
makes no essential difference that the revenues
from the tax reach the Treasury via the Federal
Reserve. There is no particular reason for this
tax, since the Federal Reserve can quite well
conduct monetary policy operations without
required reserves. The requirement could, then,
be phased out to give full effect to the benefits
of intermediation.

Most economists regard reserve requirements as secondary to open market
operations in conducting monetary policy.

The Federal Reserve has made

minimal use of changes in reserve requirements in recent years, in
part owing to its fear of aggravating the membership attrition
problem.




Nonetheless, the limited use of this monetary tool has not

7
had a noticeable impact on the ability of the Federal Reserve to
conduct monetary policy.
Furthermore, several studies have shown that open market
operations have a timely impact on all commercial bank reserves.
These studies indicate that the total impact is felt by banks in
some regions within the first 2 weeks following open market
operations.

In most cases, the impact of open market operations

on reserves is transmitted within 6 weeks.

Moreover, the length

of time for the impact of open market operations to be trans­
mitted is not related to the region's distance from money market
centers.
What the Federal Reserve does need to conduct monetary policy
effectively is information about monetary aggregates.

The Reuss

amendment to H. R. 12706 would authorize the Federal Reserve, as
it deems necessary for the conduct of monetary policy, to obtain
from the appropriate Federal agency summary statistics on assets
and liabilities of all depository institutions.

H. R. 13476 would

require depository institutions to report their deposit liabilities
and required reserves directly to the Federal Reserve.

We support

making such information available to the Federal Reserve and have
no objection to the adoption of either proposal.

We do not believe,

however, that adoption of the Monetary Policy Data Improvement Act
of 1978 (H. R. 13549) is necessary.

This proposal would require

the FDIC to collect data on deposit and cash items each week from
a sample of 1,000 nonmember banks, including all those having
deposits exceeding $100 million, and transmit that information to
the Federal Reserve.




8
Several years ago, the Federal Reserve became concerned about
the adequacy of its data on the money supply and established a
committee chaired by Professor George L. Bach of Stanford University
to recommend changes in money supply statistics.

One of the major

recommendations of the Bach Committee was that better and more frequent
data on nonmember bank deposits were desirable.

Following that report

the FDIC instituted a weekly survey of a sample of nonmember banks to
provide the Federal Reserve with better information on the money supply
This collection was initiated with the spring 1976 Call for Report of
Condition.
A second step, also recommended by the Bach Committee, went into
effect in the first week of July 1977.

A sample of 580 nonmember

banks is reporting deposit and cash items on a regular weekly basis,
the same items as all nonmember banks report four times a year.

The

Federal Reserve has indicated that it expects the data from these two
surveys to enable significant improvements in their estimates of the
nonmember bank component of the Nation's money supply.

The FDIC and

the Federal Reserve have agreed to review this program in mid-1979
to determine whether nonmember bank data are necessary for monetary
policy purposes and, if they are, whether the sample of nonmember
banks is adequate.

In the interest of improving the timeliness of

the survey data to the Federal Reserve, the FDIC intends to request
the 580 banks participating in the program to submit the data
directly to the Federal Reserve, rather than through the FDIC regional
offices, which is the present procedure.
In summary, we believe the need of legal reserve requirements
for monetary control purposes is not supported by the weight of
available evidence.




The evidence to date suggests that monetary

9
policy effectiveness depends on adequate data, proper estimation
procedures and appropriate open market operations decisions, and
not on reserve requirement jurisdiction.
Bank Supervision and the Exercise of Monetary Policy
Representatives of the Federal Reserve System have also argued
that significant supervisory and regulatory responsibilities are
required for the effective conduct of monetary policy.

Chairman

Miller reiterated in his testimony before this Committee the Federal
Reserve’s belief that its activities in the bank supervisory and
regulatory area "cannot be readily separated from its job of
conducting monetary policy."

In the past, representatives of the

Federal Reserve have argued as well that an understanding of the
nuances of monetary policy and of developments in the economy
facilitate bank supervision.
Three major arguments have been advanced by those who believe
bank supervision and regulation and the conduct of monetary policy
should be separated.

First, it has been argued that the Federal

Reserve's responsibility for bank supervision diverts attention
from monetary policy formation and that this diversion may reduce
its effectiveness in implementing monetary policy.

Former Federal

Reserve Governor James Robertson voiced this concern in stating:
As a practical matter, I believe it would be
seriously detrimental to place in the Board
the important additional responsibilities
that would accompany unification. There are
limits to a man's ability effectively to
perform his assigned duties.
In our complex
society, merely keeping informed of what is
going on in the national economy is becoming
more and more difficult. Developing and
implementing appropriate monetary policy at
a given time require consideration and
evaluation of the significance of an enormous




10
volume of available data and their interrela­
tionships. The responsibilities are of such
magnitude that the Board should not be also
burdened with the performance of bank super­
visory functions. Supervision is too
important a function in itself to be the
Federal Reserve's part-time job.
This argument has assumed greater importance today than when first
made by Governor Robertson because of the Federal Reserve’s mush­
rooming responsibilities under the civil rights and consumer protec­
tion laws and because of the ever increasing burdens of holding
company supervision and regulation.
Second, some observers find the existing concentration of power
within the Federal Reserve System disturbing, given the System’s
insulation from the political process.

They would favor separation

of the supervisory and monetary policy functions.
Third, it is argued that when the implementation of monetary
policy goals and bank supervision are combined, the former will
inevitably take precedence leading to inconsistent and inequitable
bank supervision.

For example, it is argued that the monetary

authority would be loath to restrain the aggressive policies of a
group of overextended money center institutions when monetary
policy goals are aimed at credit expansion.

Conversely, it is

argued that the Federal Reserve might move to check bank holding
company expansion on safety and soundness grounds when its actual
reason is to effect a restrictive monetary policy.

Events during

the period 1971-1975 are cited to support this proposition.

Many,

including former FDIC Chairman Frank Wille, believe this combina­
tion of supervision and the implementation of monetary policy goals
to be inappropriate, arguing that bank supervision and regulation
should be based upon an independent appraisal of the condition of




11
the bank and not upon the monetary goals of the moment.

Former

FDIC Chairman W ille concisely stated the case as follows:
The basic problem, of course, is that where the
implementation of monetary policy goals is
combined with bank regulation and supervision,
the former will always be viewed as more
important than the latter and the temptation or
threat is ever present to use the powers of
regulation and supervision to reward banks for
their cooperation or to penalize banks for their
lack of cooperation with the Board’s most recent
view of its monetary policy goals. Since those
goals change with some frequency, the likelihood
of a consistent, evenhanded approach to matters
of bank regulation and supervision over any
length of time is very much in doubt. Whereas
prior to 1970, this was a special concern only of
large State member banks which the Federal Reserve
System actually examined or of member banks forced
to the discount window, it is now the concern of
every bank in a holding company system.
We believe that the first and third of these arguments have
merit.

Yet, we think that the merits of the Federal Reserve’s

contention that it is necessary for it to have supervisory and
regulatory responsibilities to conduct monetary policy effectively
deserve consideration.
The Federal Reserve has stated two reasons.

First, the Board

of Governors has contended that information gained directly from
examination and supervision of banks provides a useful input in
the formulation of monetary policy.

This argument implies that

supervisory responsibilities provide the Board with a tangible feel
for events in the banking system.

Former Governor Holland argued in

testimony before this Committee that "examiner asset evaluations
supply firsthand knowledge of the changing quality of credit....
This provides valuable supplements to the meaning of the quantitative
statistics on monetary and credit aggregates."




12
We do not disagree that information derived from bank examina­
tions and supervision might be helpful to the Federal Reserve.
However, the Federal Reserve does not need to be engaged actively in
supervision to obtain such information.

It could be attained easily

through conversations with supervisory agencies or through participa­
tion on their boards.

Alternatively, the Board could be given

authority to collect information reflecting credit quality by means
that do not involve the full panoply of supervisory responsibilities.
Second, even if monetary policy benefits from information provided
firsthand through direct supervision, which cannot be obtained in
other ways, one still must consider whether the value of such
information outweighs the very substantial costs in terms of time and
resources that are consumed by supervisory and regulatory responsibil­
ities.

Finally, many analysts question whether such information can

possibly be relevant given the lags between changes in credit quality
and the examination and between events in the economy and changes in
credit quality.
The second reason given for the Federal Reserve's retention of
supervisory and regulatory responsibilities is, in effect, that
supervisory and regulatory responsibilities and the conduct of
monetary policy are mutually reenforcing.

Again, testifying before

this Committee, then Governor Holland asserted:




Now more than ever, the Federal Reserve's
role as monetary policymaker and as lender
of last resort interacts with the effects
of prevailing bank supervisory and regula­
tory policies. Each of these policies
increasingly influences the effectiveness
of the other. To divorce them is to weaken
both.

13
Governor Holland argued by way of example that if the bank supervisor
alters bank capital or liquidity standards "at an inopportune moment,
he can dilute or frustrate for a time the thrust of monetary policy."
The difficulty with this position is obvious and it is pointed
up in former Chairman Wille's arguments.

Sometimes objective super­

visory standards will and should run counter to the thrust of monetary
policy and will, therefore, dilute or tend to frustrate it.

This will

be the case whether or not supervision is within or outside of the
Federal Reserve System unless the Federal Reserve is really arguing
that supervision and regulation ought to be used to facilitate the
implementation of monetary policy.

This, of course, would be objected

to by those who believe in consistent and equitable supervision and
regulation and by monetarists who would argue that the attempt to use
such a tool is wholly inappropriate and ultimately an ineffective way
to conduct monetary policy.
Thus far, we are not persuaded by the case put forward by the
Federal Reserve for the importance of bank supervision and regulation
to the effective conduct of monetary policy.

Furthermore, we believe

some benefits will be gained from the functional separation of super­
vision and monetary policy.

Therefore, it is our opinion that the

attrition of members from the Federal Reserve System and, hence, a
lessening of its supervisory and regulatory presence has not inter­
fered with the effective conduct of monetary policy.
In summary, based on the available evidence and experience,
we tentatively conclude that neither control of reserve require­
ments in nonmember depository institutions nor supervisory juris­
diction is critical to the conduct of monetary policy.




In fact,

14
membership might not even be necessary for the Federal Reserve to
conduct monetary policy effectively.
I I Dual Banking System
Historically, our Nation’s banking system has developed within
the unique Federal character of our State and national governments.
Today this is manifested in the ability of both the States and the
Federal Government to charter banks and other kinds of depository
institutions.

The vitality of this dualism is maintained by permit­

ting banks to convert from one chartering authority to another.
While some may disagree, we believe the dual system of State
and national banks has been a positive element in the American
system of government and has contributed to a more innovative and
responsive financial system.

Accordingly, maintaining a balance

between the State and national banking systems is a desirable public
policy.

The attrition in Federal Reserve membership gives some pause

that this balance is more precarious now than it has been in the past
However, despite the decline of Federal Reserve membership, member
banks still hold about three-quarters of domestic deposits.

Moreover

the largest banks which depend on Federal Reserve clearing and money
transfer services represent a hard core of membership and deposits
not likely to leave the system.
Nonetheless, we should not maintain a "balance" for the sake of
balance.

It is clear that Federal Reserve reserve requirements bear

heavily on member banks and result generally in such banks carrying
more cash than they otherwise would.

In direct competition with the

nonmember bank, a member bank might be disadvantaged.

For example,

how can a member bank offer the same rate for a $100 time deposit as




15
a competing nonmember if the member is able to invest less than
its competitor because the law requires it to hold more in cash?
Its deposit customers will tend to be offered lower rates, its
loan customers will tend to be charged higher rates, or its
shareholders will receive lower returns.
One solution to the problem of equity that we believe should be
resisted is the proposal in H. R. 13476 to impose universal reserve
requirements on the transactions balances of nonmember depository
institutions.

As we explained above, extension of universal reserve

requirements to nonmember institutions is not essential to conduct
monetary policy effectively.

While reserve requirements are primarily

responsible for the inequity of Federal Reserve membership, we believe
that equity can be achieved in other ways— such as paying interest on
reserves, permitting reserves to be held in the form of marketable
securities, or reducing reserve requirements— without the necessity of
resorting to universal reserves for all institutions.
Universal reserve requirements are perceived as a threat to the
integrity of State banking systems.

If nonmember banks have to main-

tain reserves at the Federal Reserve just as member banks must do,
but have no access or have limited access to the discount window
and other System benefits, why not become members?

The assumption

is that obligatory universal reserves would not only make nonmember­
ship unattractive, but many institutions would also be inclined to
convert to a national charter.

The result would be an imbalance in

the dual system in favor of membership and the national banking
system.
There is little evidence to substantiate the accuracy of such
a scenario.




The fear may well be a false one.

However, the impact

16
of redressing the reserves imbalance on the dual banking system
cannot be predicted accurately.

It is conceivable that there

would be a massive influx into the State member and national systems.
If this occurred, many State systems would lose their viability, and
the Federal Reserve's and the Comptroller's supervisory authority
would have grown substantially without the benefit of Congressional
consideration.

My point is that the issue of Federal regulatory

structure cannot be isolated from this issue of balance.

The better

of the two proposals— the payment of interest on reserves and lower­
ing of reserve requirements— avoids some serious shortcomings of the
universal reserve requirements proposal, but it holds the potential
of an inadvertant resolution of an issue which the Congress has
conscientiously debated for many years and which deserves conscious
choice for its resolution.
Ill•

Banking System Efficiency and Innovativeness

Market pricing of goods and services is vital to the efficient
allocation and use of those goods and services.

In the words of

Milton Friedman, pricing is highly desirable "...to prevent the
waste that arises from the absence of specific charges for them."
Generally, market pricing encourages competition to improve the
quality of goods and services and to lower their cost.

Presently,

pricing is absent in at least three areas that bear directly or
indirectly upon the legislation under consideration:

(1) the absence

of interest payment on the required reserves of member banks, (2) the
provision of services by the Federal Reserve to member banks, and
(3) the prohibition of interest payments on demand deposit balances
and deposit interest rate ceilings.




I will address each in turn.

17
Interest on Reserves
As a matter of principle, whether to pay interest on reserves
should not be an issue.

Presently, failure to pay interest is

tantamount to the imposition of a tax without calling it that.

A

substantial amount of the revenue foregone by member banks is
passed on to the Treasury Department by the Federal Reserve.

Some

of the revenue is used by the System to offset the cost of providing
"free" services to member banks.

If it were the national policy to

tax banks, it would be preferable to levy the tax directly on all
banks and other depository institutions as well.

Then all would be

treated equally*
Concern has been raised about the adverse impact payment of
interest on reserves would have on Treasury revenues.

This concern

has lead to attempts to structure a procedure for paying interest
while minimizing the loss in Treasury revenues.

However, structur­

ing a procedure for paying interest bogs down in questions about the
appropriate interest rate, concerns about possible windfall gains to
to large banks, and controversy over what percentage of the Federal
Reserve System's revenues should be available for interest payments,
vie submit that none of this is really necessary.

It imposes the

subjective judgment of men in dealing with the cost of membership
when the market system could probably do better.

Why not permit

member banks to invest their reserves in interest bearing securities?
The Federal Reserve could determine what kinds of securities should
be eligible for this purpose based on considerations such as risk.
This approach would permit each bank to make its own choice and
obviate the necessity of having the Federal Reserve establish a rate.
Presently, 36 States allow State nonmember banks to hold at least




18
part of their required reserves in the form of U.S. Government
securities.

To our knowledge, such a change would not have any

significant impact on the effective conduct of monetary policy.
If either the loss of Treasury revenues or subsidization of small
banks were felt to be important problems, we would recommend that
the Congress address these problems directly through national tax
policy.
To the extent that our faith in the efficacy of the market
system might be misplaced, we are willing to endorse the provision
in Section 3 of H. R. 12706 (Stanton bill) that would require the
Board of Governors to prepare a study on permitting member banks to
invest their reserves in securities.
Pricing of Services
Explicitly pricing Federal Reserve services should increase the
efficiency of our financial system by allowing various financial
institutions to purchase the services they desire from the Federal
Reserve or private alternatives.
major services are:

Among the Federal Reserve System's

operation of the payments system, including check

processing and transportation and automated clearinghouse services;
pickup and delivery of coin and currency? wire transfers; purchase,
sale, safekeeping and clearing securities? and operation of the
discount window.
The Federal Reserve has proposed pricing most of these services
except the discount window in a two-phase process.

In the first

phase, pricing of services would be limited to those connected with
the payments mechanism and access would be limited to member banks.
This would permit the Federal Reserve time to develop appropriate




prices before bringing in all depository institutions.

Services

would be priced according to geographic region and whether the
activity in question is processed through a city bank, country bank,
regional check processing center, or interdistrict transfer.

Non­

member institutions would be permitted to deposit intraregional
checks and drafts through regional check processing centers.

In the

second phase, nonmembers could purchase virtually all services the
Federal Reserve has to offer, but would continue to clear checks and
drafts through reserve accounts of member banks.

Charges for services

would not be determined on the basis of membership.
The Stanton bill would require the Federal Reserve to price
each service explicitly, based on all the costs of providing the
service including overhead plus a return on capital.

The Federal

Reserve would be required to offer each service to every depository
institution at the same fee.
If interest were paid on member bank reserves, by whatever means,
pricing of Federal Reserve services would be essential to prevent dis­
criminatory treatment of nonmember depository institutions.

Pricing of

services also is sound policy because it would enhance the efficiency
of the financial system.

This would provide a better opportunity for

the correspondent banking system to compete with the Federal Reserve.
Such competition, in turn, should encourage the Federal Reserve to
eliminate waste, to improve services and to offer new ones.
The Federal Reserve has stated its opposition to the Stanton
bill which would require the System to price each service on the
basis of costs and a return on capital.

Governor Coldwell pointed

out that private competitors would not be required to price services
separately as the Stanton bill would require of the System.




This loss

20
of flexibility would place the System at a significant competitive
disadvantage.

It should be noted, however, that if the Federal

Reserve is not subject to pricing guidelines of some sort, it could
achieve the same advantage that the Stanton bill would provide to
private competitors.

Assuming that it is good public policy to

maintain a significant presence for the Federal Reserve in the pay­
ments mechanism, we are sympathetic to its concern about constraints
on its flexibility in setting prices.

Therefore, we would recommend

that the matter of pricing guidelines receive careful study prior to
the enactment of legislation on the issue of pricing.

Some of the

reasons for favoring such an intermediate approach and some of the
matters that need to be considered are discussed below.
The costs of producing the same service for a variety of
customers may differ in various areas of the country because labor
and capital costs are not equal.

Thus, it may be more efficient to

allow the Federal Reserve to charge different prices according to the
costs of providing services to different customers.

The cost of

providing a certain service to nonmember banks and nonbank depository
institutions could be below the cost of providing the same service
only to member banks.
service were utilized.

This could result from the way in which a
For example, a credit union may not require

daily pickup and delivery of coins or currency, or a savings and
loan association might not complete security transactions as often
as a commercial bank.
To allow the Federal Reserve some flexibility in developing and
implementing a pricing system, the Federal Reserve could be permitted
to price services explicitly by broad service classes.

One price

schedule might be developed for payments services, another for




21
securities services, and another for transportation.

Perhaps a cost-

plus pricing system could be developed for the services now provided
by the Federal Reserve, and the markup over the cost of providing the
service might be limited to a fixed percentage.
There seem to be economies of scale associated with at least some
services that the Federal Reserve now provides.

If these economies are

pervasive, the Federal Reserve will be able to offer the relevant ser­
vice at a lower price than any private competitor.

There is nothing

undesirable about this, but the result should be determined by experi­
ence, not fiat.

It is not unlikely that the Federal Reserve has a

natural monopoly on some services because private competitors could not
attract sufficient volume to offer the same services at as low a price.
According to materials that former Federal Reserve Chairman Burns
submitted to Senator Proxmire on October 4, 1977, in recent years the
per unit costs of conventional check processing, return items, transfer
of funds, and automated clearinghouse activities have declined as
volumes increased.

If these trends continue, the private sector might

not be able to offer competing services at costs that.are as low as
those incurred by the Federal Reserve.

On the other hand, the cash

services offered by the Federal Reserve do not seem to show declining
costs with increasing volumes.

In an electronic banking environment,

it is not clear that several payments systems can compete efficiently.
However, in this regard the private bank wire continues to compete
with the Federal Reserve wire, and networks of correspondent banks
provide payment services that are preferred by some member banks over
Federal Reserve payment services.




22
Interest on Demand Deposits
Payment of interest on reserves of member banks potentially
could place nonmember banks at a disadvantage because the 40-year
old prohibition against the payment of interest on demand deposits
does not permit member banks to pay interest on correspondent
balances.

These balances often serve as reserves for nonmember banks

and serve as well for check clearing operations and compensation for
other correspondent services.

If the principle of explicit pricing

is adopted for member banks, then parallel treatment would dictate
that banks should have the choice of paying interest on correspondent
balances and levying explicit charges for correspondent services.
There can be little doubt that this would increase the efficiency
of the financial system.
As a matter of principle, if the interest prohibition is lifted
for correspondent deposits, it should be lifted for all demand deposits
I have long supported elimination of the prohibition of interest pay­
ments on all transactions balances as well as removal of interest rate
ceilings on other kinds of deposits.

Economists have demonstrated

that there is no merit to the contention that competition for demand
deposits through the payment of interest led to bank failures during
the Depression as some contend.

They have also demonstrated, at least

to our satisfaction, that competition for deposits through the pricing
mechanism would result in a more efficient allocation of resources thaï
competition through indirect means involving the implicit payment of
interest by building more branches, keeping open longer hours, providii
free checking services, offering premiums and free travelers’ checks, a
well as a variety of other services.

Such competition would lead to

substantial benefits for both financial institutions and bank customers




23
Under the present system of implicit interest payments on
checking accounts, depositors are denied the opportunity to
determine for themselves how they wish to spend their portion of
the income the bank earns on their deposits.

If interest were paid,

a depositor might choose to consume the same services that banks
now offer in the course of competing with other institutions for
accounts or a depositor might choose to forego such services and spend
interest income on different goods and services.

This is an important

benefit— consumers would decide how to spend their interest income,
not the banks.
Free- or below-actual-cost checking encourages inefficient use of
resources because depositors have little or no incentive to economize
on check writing, even though check clearance costs are substantial.
Direct charges for checks are likely to prompt depositors to write
fewer checks.
checks.

Such fees should cover a substantial cost of clearing

Management’s adoption of pricing policies more nearly in

line with the costs of providing services to customers will enhance
a financial institution's capability of paying a competitive interest
rate on deposit balances without impairing earnings.
Payment of competitive interest rates will lower some operating
costs by reducing the need for customers to transfer funds from non­
interest bearing checking accounts to savings accounts.

Thus depositors

will no longer find it necessary to maintain separate checking and
savings accounts.

Customers will not need to spend as much time and

effort in managing deposit balances, particularly when interest rates
are high.

Also, existing inequities, whereby some depositors pay less

than the cost of servicing their accounts will be eliminated.




IV.

Banking System Viability and Liquidity Pressures

One of the important functions of the Federal Reserve System
is to serve as the Nation’s lender of last resort.

Through the

vehicle of the discount window, the Federal Reserve is able to
provide liquidity when it is needed.

The discount window acts as

a safety valve by permitting the Federal Reserve to cushion the
impact of a tight monetary policy on individual institutions.
It can also assist member banks in meeting routine but unexpected
loan demand or deposit withdrawals, seasonal liquidity requirements,
and emergency liquidity needs.
expected to be to the market.

A member bank's first recourse is
If sufficient funds are not available

in the market, the Reserve Bank might provide accommodation, but it is
understood that it is temporary.

Each member bank must eliminate its

discount window borrowings within a reasonable period.

Reserve

Banks also require member banks to pledge collateral, typically of
high quality.
The Federal Reserve Act authorizes entities other than member
banks to use the discount window only under "unusual and exigent"
circumstances.

As a result, the Federal Reserve indicates, for

example, that no nonmember bank has borrowed from the discount
window since 1966.
While nonmember banks also face unexpected needs for liquidity,
they ordinarily cope with them with little difficulty by borrowing
from correspondent banks in much the same way that members do from
the Federal Reserve.

Indeed, even when nonmember banks are in

trouble, it is generally possible for them to borrow from corres­
pondents if they have sufficient and acceptable collateral.

To be

sure, the lending bank may also impose special conditions on the




25
borrowing, bank.

But in that regard, the Federal Reserve also behaves

like a careful creditor in accommodating a floundering bank.

It makes

sure such loans are well collaterized, that its interest in the collat­
eral is perfected, and that the borrowing bank is solvent.

Thus, the

fact that nonmembers do not have window accommodation is not seriously
disadvantageous in most circumstances.
The Federal Reserve believes that the ability of the financial
system to handle liquidity "crunches" will weaken if membership
attrition continues unabated.

It should be understood that the

decline in Federal Reserve membership does not impair the ability of
the System to cope with the kind of generalized liquidity crisis most
of us are concerned about, in which the public demands more cash than
the banking system holds.

Aggressive open market operations and

discount window accommodation to members can provide cash sufficient
to meet the public's demand.

The decline in membership does impair

the ability of the system to minister to a localized liquidity squeeze
involving one or a few institutions.

In the past, the Federal Reserve

has sometimes resorted to conduit loans in such circumstances— that is,
loans to a member bank which in turn provide credit to a nonmember
institution.

We think that the Federal Reserve should accommodate a

nonmember bank directly in such special circumstances.
Indeed, we are concerned that membership attrition has contributed
to a narrow interpretation of the words "unusual and exigent" by the
Federal Reserve.

If experience is a guide, these words appear to be

interpreted by the Board of Governors as requiring a national emergency
before a Reserve Bank would be authorized to lend to a nonmember insti­
tution.

The interpretation could be less restrictive, but at the

present time it does not appear that the Board of Governors is willing




26
to interpret "unusual and Exigent" circumstance as extending to
situations that are unique to an inidividual nonmember institution.
The unwillingness of the Federal Reserve to open the discount window
to American Bank and Trust of Orangeburg, South Carolina, in
September 1974 led the FDIC to take the unusual step of providing
short-term liquidity directly to the bank under Section 13(c) of
the FDI Act.

This was the only time the FDIC ever took such action

for temporary liquidity purposes.*
Former FDIC Chairman Frank W ille in a letter to Mr. St Germain
in January 1975 stated:
I believe that the statutory provisions,
regulations and policies surrounding direct
Federal Reserve loans to nonmember banks
need to be reviewed and a procedure adopted
whereby the failure of a nonmember bank will
not be precipitated by a sudden and purely
temporary need for liquidity.
W e share Chairman Wille*s concern.

We believe that emergency

borrowings from the Federal Reserve discount window should be avail­
able to member and nonmember banks alike upon certification by the
FDIC that they are in danger of failing and that such assistance is
♦•
necessary for a temporary period until a merger, a receivership sale
or some other orderly resolution of the bank’s problems is arranged.
The FDIC, in turn, should be authorized to guarantee the repayment
of such borrowings*out of the resources of the deposit insurance
fund.

In connection with this authority, the FDIC should be required

by law to keep the Federal Reserve fully informed with up-to-date
information as to the financial condition of all banks certified to
borrow from the discount window under this provision.

*Two weeks later the bank was closed.