View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The SecnefaRy of the Trzeasuny

£ui

A—*~tk
C>onK


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

aoA)

.

DepartmentofthcTREASURY
WASHINGTON, D.C. 20220

TELEPHONE 566-2041

FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY
Expected at 10:00 a.m.
February 5, 1980

Testimony of the Honorable G. William Miller
Secretary of the Treasury
Before the
Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs

Mr. Chairman and members of this distinguished Committee:

It is a pleasure to present the views of the Administration on
S. 353 and amendments and on related bills, amended S. 85 and H.R. 7,
to improve the conduct of monetary policy.
As you know, I worked
closely with the Congress on this legislation as Chairman of the
Federal Reserve Board, and am prepared to render whatever assistance
I can on behalf of the Administration.
The importance of monetary
policy in our efforts to control inflation means that the continued
attrition of member banks from the Federal Reserve System is of
grave concern.
It is imperative that the Congress take appropriate
action now to ensure the viability of our country's mechanism for
conducting monetary policy.

One year ago, before the House Committee on Banking, Finance
and Urban Affairs the Administration outlined its three basic
objectives regarding monetary improvement legislation.
They
continue to be:
1) to give the Federal Reserve the best possible tools
with which to administer monetary policy,
2)

to provide an eguitable competitive environment for
depository institutions doing the same types of business,
and

3)

to limit the annual cost of a monetary improvement program
to $200 million or less net of income taxes.

As presently written, amended S. 85 would meet all the objectives
we consider essential to an effective monetary policy mechanism.
H.R. 7, as passed by the House, was a step in the right direction

M-315

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2

and is very close to meeting each of our goals.
But amended S. 85
would build on the initiative of H.R. 7 both by broadening the reserve
coverage and by reducing substantially the cost to the taxpayer.
For reasons which I will discuss below, S. 353 has the potential of
achieving our objectives only if the amending emergency provisions
are operative. Then its deposit coverage and its cost would come
closer to, but would still fall short of, meeting our targets.
Universal Required Reserves
The use of reserves in this country has been a tradition since
active management of the money supply began.
Consequently, all the
proposals on this subject now before the Congress are concerned with
designing a reserve structure which is effective, equitable, and
affordable.
Indeed the search for the "ideal" reserve system for
this country has become especially important since the Federal Reserve's
October 6 announcement that it would henceforth pay more attention
to monetary aggregates rather than interest rates in conducting
open market operations.
Thus, it is even more important that there
be a precise connection between the monetary aggregates and the
reserve base which is altered through open market sales and purchases.
From the central bank's point of view, an effective reserve
structure requires universal, uniform reserves, imposed on balances
constituting the monetary aggregates, and set at sufficiently high
levels to ensure adequate control.
The reserve structure should be
universal because, in the absence of such universality, uncontrollable
shifts of funds from reservable deposits to non-reservable ones act
to weaken the linkage between the reserve base and the money supply.
Similarly, the reserve structures should be uniform as to each
class of deposit at all depository institutions, to minimize the
effects of uncontrollable shifts of funds among depository institu­
tions, subject to differing reserve ratios.

Indeed, universality of reserves is the key to our solution to
the problem of effective monetary control.
If we are to use reserves
in the management of monetary policy for the benefit of everyone in
society, the cost of holding such reserves should be regarded as
a price or franchise tax for participation in the monetary system.
Like any tax, the cost of holding reserves should be set at the lowest
level consistent with their intended purpose, and that cost should
be distributed as equitably as possible.
At the same time that such
costs are distributed universally, so should the benefits of the
monetary system.
Thus, as I will discuss in greater detail below,
universal reserve requirements ought properly to be accompanied
by universal access to Federal Reserve System services and, on an
equal basis, to the Federal Reserve discount window.
In our opinion,
only a mandatory reserve structure coupled with universal access
to System services is likely to achieve these objectives.
It
would minimize the cost of running the monetary system by distribu­
ting the cost among the greatest number of institutions and institu­
tional customers.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

3

Not only should reserves be universal, but reserve ratios should
be set at a sufficient level so that the "multiplier" is not too
large.
If the multiplier is too great, then small errors in managing
the reserve base will be magnified into large changes in the monetary
aggregates.
Of course, universal reserve ratios must not be set at a
level so high as to create artificial pressures for the growth of'-money
substitutes entirely outside the traditional banking system, thus im­
pairing the base upon which the Federal Reserve conducts its monetary
policy.
Therefore, an important objective in devising the new reserve
structure is to give the Federal Reserve the confidence to raise or
lower reserve requirements within specified ranges without a concern
that an increase in reserve ratios will induce reliance on non-deposit
substitutes and,•therefore, reduce reserve coverage. The present
reserve system, so much in need of reform, has the opposite effect.
It
encourages member banks to withdraw from the System in order to be on
a competitive parity with non-members, and such departures tend to
accelerate when interest rates are high or reserve ratios are raised,
just when the sensitivity of monetary policy may be most important.
In fact, the two largest banks ever to withdraw from the System —
both with over one billion dollars in deposits -- are doing so in the
present inflationary and high interest rate environment.
In our view,
only a mandatory reserve system would either stem or lessen such
attrition.
The reserve structure should not make an institution's participa­
tion in the system dependent on criteria other than those related to
the effective conduct of monetary policy.
Other criteria,‘such as
the choice of a supervisor, or the desire to do correspondent banking
business by reselling System services, which are available only to
members, should not affect decisions to hold reserves on which manage­
ment of the money supply is contingent. Nor should the Federal Reserve
be persuaded to conduct its supervisory responsibilities, price its
services, or engage in businesses that compete with private vendors
in order to induce institutions to join or remain within the System.

Competitive Equality
In the last few years the Congress has been extending the use
of Negotiable Order of Withdrawal accounts to increased numbers of
insured depository institutions. Therefore, this is a proper time
to consider extending reserve coverage to all depository institutions
doing the same types of business -- that is, to all institutions pro­
viding transactions accounts.
This would also insure that reserve
coverage is uniform on these new and fast growing accounts except-for
some forebearance for smaller institutions.
Each of the proposals
before us attempts to provide some measure of competitive equality
in its coverage.
One amendment of S. 353 would include NOW accounts,
but only the proposed amendment providing for emergency supplemental
reserves is likely to cover NOW accounts at any significant number
of thrift instutitions.
That is, it is unlikely that thrift institu­
tions would voluntarily hold reserves, especially those that are
members of the Federal Home Loan Bank Board System.
Under amended

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

4

S. 85 all depository institutions would hold reserves against transac­
tions accounts.
In contrast, virtually all thrift institutions would
be exempted initially from reserve requirements in H.R. 7 (because
their transactions balances will be low for years to come) and most
of the thrifts would remain exempted for some time due to the bill's
provision for indexing the exemption level.

We recognize that smaller depository institutions may not be
able to bear the full burden of required reserves as easily as can
larger institutions.
Moreover, monetary control probably would not
be seriously impaired by exempting smaller institutions or by
reducing their reserve burden.
This is because the total reserves
of smaller institutions, in excess of vault cash, would constitute
only a minor proportion of the total manageable reserves on deposit
with the Federal Reserve.
beveral approaches have been advanced
to lessen the reserve burden on smaller institutions, such as an
exemption from reserves, a lower reserve level or an interest
participation program.
We are not committed to any one approach,
but we would support a "two-tier" system for smaller institutions, as
long as such a system does not seriously increase the overall cost
of an improved reserve structure.

Revenue Loss Projections
As I have indicated, the preferable approach to monetary control
is to set reserves universally and uniformly across all institutions,
which would in turn allow some reduction in reserve ratios.
While
universality of reserves on transactions accounts is a provision in
only one of the bills under consideration, each of them would reduce
reserve ratios in such a way as to reduce aggregate reserves held by
all participating institutions.
Under each of the bills, the Federal
Reserve would have fewer reserves and therefore receive less interest
income from the government securities in which it invests reserves -and the Federal Reserve, in turn, would transfer less net income to
the Treasury each year.
In effect, under each of the bills, there is
a specific cost to the taxpayer for the much needed improvement in
monetary control.
The Administration has for some time indicated that a cost of $200
million, when the program is fully effective, is an "acceptable" price
to pay for being able to deal with the monetary control problem.
Mr.
Chairman, I must tell you that, having testified on the 1981 budget
only last week, the limit of $200 million is necessary to maintain
fiscal responsibility.
The $200 million figure would be the net cost
after taking into account any income received by the Federal Reserve
from the pricing of its services or from the pricing of float.
In
addition, the figure would be net of any recaptured income taxes from
current member banks.
That is, it anticipates that members will be
paying additional taxes on increased income from funds no longer held
as reserves, since the proposed new reserve systems provide for gen­
erally lower reserve ratios.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

5

Our joint estimates with the Federal Reserve Board indicate that
amended S. 85, including the proposed amendments, would meet the
objective of universality and involve the lowest cost to the Treasury.
When fully effective, it would cost approximately $74 million annually
in foregone revenues.
By comparison, we estimate that H.R. 7 would
cost about $357 million annually if the mandatory provisions were
effective and about the same under the voluntary provisions.
The
amended S. 353, which would include the income from the pricing of
Federal Reserve services and float, would cost $579 million.
The estimates given above are, of course, somewhat imprecise.
For comparison purposes, however, we believe the numbers are adequate.
They are based on 1977 data on deposits and reserves, and they assume
that there is no transition period (i.e. the new reserve structure
becomes effective immediately).
In actuality, each of the bills
before us has a transition period — a phase-in period — of four
to ten years, during which the reserve ratios of existing Federal
Reserve members are to be reduced and reserves of non-members are to
be gradually increased. We cannot know with any certainty what would
be the growth of deposits subject to reserve requirements and revenues
from pricing of Federal Reserve services during such a phase-in
period.
Thus, we cannot know the true costs of each of the proposals
during a phase-in period.
However, the Federal Reserve has agreed
that any revenue loss during the phase-in will be completely offset
by transfer to the Treasury of funds from the System’s surplus account
I should note that, with respect to phase-in costs, H.R. 7 would
lower reserves for most present member banks sooner than it would
require the accumulation of new balances from institutions entering
the new reserve system.
The transition approach of the other bills
is less costly because the reduction in reserves of existing members
would be timed to coincide more closely with the contribution of
balances from new participants in the system.

S. 353:

The Voluntary Reserve Approach

S. 353 would rely on the payment of interest on reserves to in­
duce depository institutions to keep balances with the Federal Reserve
System.
The interest payments would be set 1/2 percent below the
yield on the System's U.S. Government securities portfolio.
The
problem with this approach is that, depending on a banker's pre­
ference toward risk, the banker might still opt to withdraw from the
Federal Reserve System in order to gain a higher yield on his reserves
elsewhere.
In 1979 the average yield on the Federal Reserve's port­
folio was 8.6 percent; hence the interest payments to reserve holders
would have equalled an annual rate of 8.1 percent if this legislation
had been in force last year.
This compares with an average prime
rate for commercial bank loans during 1979 of about 12-1/2 percent.
Given this disparity in yields it is unclear how many depository
institutions would keep interest-bearing reserves in the System in
lieu of using the funds to make loans or purchase other earning
assets.
Moreover, with the proposed amendment mandating the pricing


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

6

of Federal Reserve services added to S. 353, the benefits to banks of
receiving interest on reserves would be substantially reduced.
Access to and Pricing of Services

Both amended S. 85 and H.R. 7 would require the Federal Reserve
to price its services and make them available to all depository
institutions.
No longer would access to the Federal Reserve System's
services be used as an inducement to membership and thus to hold
reserves — and the universal availability of Federal Reserve
services should benefit the banking system as a whole.
Moreovet,
requiring that the Federal Reserve price services on a basis involving
full allocation of cost, with appropriate allowances for costs unique
to private organizations, such as capital and taxes, should allow
other vendors to compete with the Federal Reserve more effectively.
Traditional market mechanisms will then become more important in
establishing the prices of services and the relative roles of the
competing vendors.
Thus, we are in full agreement with those proposals
which would lead to full access to and pricing of System services.

Conclusion

I'
*
* '
* .
In conclusion, Mr. Chairman, we believe-that the reserve structure
ultimately chosen by the Congress needs to have a fairly universal,
uniform coverage of deposits and depository institutions.
Such
coverage should be sufficient to ensure that the Federal Reserve has
adequate tools with which to conduct monetary policy, and should be
structured to hold the cost to the taxpayer to an acceptable level.
At the same time, the legislation should provide for a more universal
access to the Federal Reserve’s services, and at a realistic price.
This concludes my formal testimony, Mr. Chairman.
pleased to answer any questions the Committee may have.
o 0 o

i


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

•i ■ i

I would be

■ DeporlmenloltheTREASURY
•

WASHINGTON, D.C. 20220

|

TELEPHONE 566-2041

FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY
Expected at 10:00 a.m.
February 5, 1980

Testimony of the Honorable G. William Miller
Secretary of the Treasury
Before the
Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs

Mr. Chairman and members of this distinguished Committee:
It is a pleasure to present the views of the Administration on
S. 353 and amendments and on related bills, amended S. 85 and H.R. 7,
to improve the conduct of monetary policy. As you know, I worked
closely with the Congress on this legislation as Chairman of the
Federal Reserve Board, and am prepared to render whatever assistance
I can on behalf of the Administration. The importance of monetary
policy in our efforts to control inflation means that the continued
attrition of member banks from the Federal Reserve System is of
grave concern.
It is imperative that the Congress take appropriate
action now to ensure the viability of our country's mechanism for
conducting monetary policy.

One year ago, before the House Committee on Banking, Finance
and Urban Affairs the Administration outlined its three basic
objectives regarding monetary improvement legislation.
They
continue to be:
1) to give the Federal Reserve the best possible tools
with which to administer monetary policy,

2)

to provide an equitable competitive environment for
depository institutions doing the same types of business,
and

3)

to limit the annual cost of a monetary improvement program
to $200 million or less net of income taxes.

As presently written, amended S. 85 would meet all the objectives
we consider essential to an effective monetary policy mechanism.
H.R. 7, as passed by the House, was a step in the right direction

Digitized for M-315
FRASER
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2

and is very close to meeting each of our goals.
But amended S. 85
would build on the initiative of H.R. 7 both by broadening the reserve
coverage and by reducing substantially the cost to the taxpayer.
For reasons which I will discuss below, S. 353 has the potential of
achieving our objectives only if the amending emergency provisions
are operative. Then its deposit coverage and its cost would come
closer to, but would still fall short of, meeting our targets.
Universal Required Reserves
The use of reserves in this country has been a tradition since
active management of the money supply began.
Consequently, all the
proposals on this subject now before the Congress are concerned with
designing a reserve structure which is effective, equitable, and
affordable.
Indeed the search for the "ideal" reserve system for
this country has become especially important since the Federal Reserve’s
October 6 announcement that it would henceforth pay more attention
to monetary aggregates rather than interest rates in conducting
open market operations. Thus, it is even more important that there
be a precise connection between the monetary aggregates and the
reserve base which is altered through open market sales and purchases.

From the central bank’s point of view, an effective reserve
structure requires universal, uniform reserves, imposed on balances
constituting the monetary aggregates, and set at sufficiently high
levels to ensure adequate control. The reserve structure should be
universal because, in the absence of such universality, uncontrollable
shifts of funds from reservable deposits to non-reservable ones act
to weaken the linkage between the reserve base and the money supply.
Similarly, the reserve structures should be uniform as to each
class of deposit at all depository institutions, to minimize the
effects of uncontrollable shifts of funds among depository institu­
tions, subject to differing reserve ratios.

Indeed, universality of reserves is the key to our solution to
the problem of effective monetary control.
If we are to use reserves
in the management of monetary policy for the benefit of everyone in
society, the cost of holding such reserves should be regarded as
a price or franchise tax for participation in the monetary system.
Like any tax, the cost of holding reserves should be set at the lowest
level consistent with their intended purpose, and that cost should
be distributed as equitably as possible.
At the same time that such
costs are distributed universally, so should the benefits of the
monetary system. Thus, as I will discuss in greater detail below,
universal reserve requirements ought properly to be accompanied
by universal access to Federal Reserve System services and, on an
equal basis, to the Federal Reserve discount window.
In our opinion,
only a mandatory reserve structure coupled with universal access
to System services is likely to achieve these objectives.
It
would minimize the cost of running the monetary system by distribu­
ting the cost among the greatest number of institutions and institu­
tional customers.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

3
Not only should reserves be universal, but reserve ratios should
be set at a sufficient level so that the "multiplier" is not too
large.
If the multiplier is too great, then small errors in managing
the reserve base will be magnified into large changes in the monetary
aggregates.
Of course, universal reserve ratios must not be set at a
level so high as to create artificial pressures for the growth of money
substitutes entirely outside the traditional banking system, thus im­
pairing the base upon which the Federal Reserve conducts its monetary
policy.
Therefore, an important objective in devising the new reserve
structure is to give the Federal Reserve the confidence to raise or
lower reserve requirements within specified ranges without a concern
that an increase in reserve ratios will induce reliance on non-deposit
substitutes and, therefore, reduce reserve coverage. The present
reserve system, so much in need of reform, has the opposite effect.
It
encourages member banks to withdraw from the System in order to be on
a competitive parity with non-members, and such departures tend to
accelerate when interest rates are high or reserve ratios are raised,
just when the sensitivity of monetary policy may be most important.
In fact, the two largest banks ever to withdraw from the System —
both with over one billion dollars in deposits — are doing so in the
present inflationary and high interest rate environment.
In our view,
only a mandatory reserve system would either stem or lessen such
attrition.

The reserve structure should not make an institution’s participa­
tion in the system dependent on criteria other than those related to
the effective conduct of monetary policy. Other criteria, such as
the choice of a supervisor, or the desire to do correspondent banking
business by reselling System services, which are available only to
members, should not affect decisions to hold reserves on which manage­
ment of the money supply is contingent. Nor should the Federal Reserve
be persuaded to conduct its supervisory responsibilities, price its
services, or engage in businesses that compete with private vendors
in order to induce institutions to join or remain within the System.

Competitive Equality
In the last few years the Congress has been extending the use
of Negotiable Order of Withdrawal accounts to increased numbers of
insured depository institutions. Therefore, this is a proper time
to consider extending reserve coverage to all depository institutions
doing the same types of business —— that is, to all institutions pro­
viding transactions accounts. This would also insure that reserve
coverage is uniform on these new and fast growing accounts except for
some forebearance for smaller institutions.
Each of uhe proposals
before us attempts to provide some measure of competitive equality
in its coverage. One amendment of S. 353 would include NOW accounts,
but only the proposed amendment providing for emergency supplemental
reserves is likely to cover NOW accounts at any significant number
of thrift instutitions. That is, it is unlikely that thrift institu­
tions would voluntarily hold reserves, especially those that are
members of the Federal Home Loan Bank Board System. Under amended


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

4
S. 85 all depository institutions would hold reserves against transac­
tions accounts.
In contrast, virtually all thrift institutions would
be exempted initially from reserve requirements in H.R. 7 (because
their transactions balances will be low for years to come) and most
of the thrifts would remain exempted for some time due to the bill’s
provision for indexing the exemption level.

We recognize that smaller depository institutions may not be
able to bear the full burden of required reserves as easily as can
larger institutions. Moreover, monetary control probably would not
be seriously impaired by exempting smaller institutions or by
reducing their reserve burden. This is because the total reserves
of smaller institutions, in excess of vault cash, would constitute
only a minor proportion of the total manageable reserves on deposit
with the Federal Reserve. Several approaches have been advanced
to lessen the reserve burden on smaller institutions, such as an
exemption from reserves, a lower reserve level or an interest
participation program. We are not committed to any one approach,
but we would support a "two-tier" system for smaller institutions, as
long as such a system does not seriously increase the overall cost
of an improved reserve structure.

Revenue Loss Projections

As I have indicated, the preferable approach to monetary control
is to set reserves universally and uniformly across all institutions,
which would in turn allow some reduction in reserve ratios. While
universality of reserves on transactions accounts is a provision in
only one of the bills under consideration, each of them would reduce
reserve ratios in such a way as to reduce aggregate reserves held by
all participating institutions. Under each of the bills, the Federal
Reserve would have fewer reserves and therefore receive less interest
income from the government securities in which it invests reserves —
and the Federal Reserve, in turn, would transfer less net income to
the Treasury each year.
In effect, under each of the bills, there is
a specific cost to the taxpayer for the much needed improvement in
monetary control.
The Administration has for some time indicated that a cost of $200
million, when the program is fully effective, is an "acceptable" price
to pay for being able to deal with the monetary control problem. Mr.
Chairman, I must tell you that, having testified on the 1981 budget
only last week, the limit of $200 million is necessary to maintain
fiscal responsibility. The $200 million figure would be the net cost
after taking into account any income received by the Federal Reserve
from the pricing of its services or from the pricing of float.
In
addition, the figure would be net of any recaptured income taxes from
current member banks. That is, it anticipates that members will be
paying additional taxes on increased income from funds no longer held
as reserves, since the proposed new reserve systems provide for gen­
erally lower reserve ratios.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

5
Our joint estimates with the Federal Reserve Board indicate that
amended S. 85, including the proposed amendments, would meet the
objective of universality and involve the lowest cost to the Treasury.
When fully effective, it would cost approximately $74 million annually
in foregone revenues.
By comparison, we estimate that H.R. 7 would
cost about $357 million annually if the mandatory provisions were
effective and about the same under the voluntary provisions. The
amended S. 353, which would include the income from the pricing of
Federal Reserve services and float, would cost $579 million.
The estimates given above are, of course, somewhat imprecise.
For comparison purposes, however, we believe the numbers are adequate.
They are based on 1977 data on deposits and reserves, and they assume
that there is no transition period (i.e. the new reserve structure
becomes effective immediately).
In actuality, each of the bills
before us has a transition period — a phase-in period — of four
to ten years, during which the reserve ratios of existing Federal
Reserve members are to be reduced and reserves of non-members are to
be gradually increased. We cannot know with any certainty what would
be the growth of deposits subject to reserve requirements and revenues
from pricing of Federal Reserve services during such a phase-in
period. Thus, we cannot know the true costs of each of the proposals
during a phase-in period.
However, the Federal Reserve has agreed
that any revenue loss during the phase-in will be completely offset
by transfer to the Treasury of funds from the System’s surplus account
I should note that, with respect to phase-in costs, H.R. 7 would
lower reserves for most present member banks sooner than it would
require the accumulation of new balances from institutions entering
the new reserve system. The transition approach of the other bills
is less costly because the reduction in reserves of existing members
would be timed to coincide more closely with the contribution of
balances from new participants in the system.

S. 353:

The Voluntary Reserve Approach

S. 353 would rely on the payment of interest on reserves to in­
duce depository institutions to keep balances with the Federal Reserve
System. The interest payments would be set 1/2 percent below the
yield on the System's U.S. Government securities portfolio.
The
problem with this approach is that, depending on a banker's pre­
ference toward risk, the banker might still opt to withdraw from the
Federal Reserve System in order to gain a higher yield on his reserves
elsewhere.
In 1979 the average yield on the Federal Reserve's port­
folio was 8.6 percent; hence the interest payments to reserve holders
would have equalled an annual rate of 8.1 percent if this legislation
had been in force last year. This compares with an average prime
rate for commercial bank loans during 1979 of about 12—1/2 percent.
Given this disparity in yields it is unclear how many depository
institutions would keep interest-bearing reserves in the System in
]_i©u of using the funds to make loans or purchase other earning
assets. Moreover, with the proposed amendment mandating the pricing


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

6

of Federal Reserve services added to S. 353, the benefits to banks of
receiving interest on reserves would be substantially reduced.
Access to and Pricing of Services

Both amended S. 85 and H.R. 7 would require the Federal Reserve
to price its services and make them available to all depository
institutions. No longer would access to the Federal Reserve System's
services be used as an inducement to membership and thus to hold
reserves — and the universal availability of Federal Reserve
services should benefit the banking system as a whole. Moreover,
requiring that the Federal Reserve price services on a basis involving
full allocation of cost, with appropriate allowances for costs unique
to private organizations, such as capital and taxes, should allow
other vendors to compete with the Federal Reserve more effectively.
Traditional market mechanisms will then become more important in
establishing the prices of services and the relative roles of the
competing vendors. Thus, we are in full agreement with those proposals
which would lead to full access to and pricing of System services.

Conclusion
In conclusion, Mr. Chairman, we believe that the reserve structure
ultimately chosen by the Congress needs to have a fairly universal,
uniform coverage of deposits and depository institutions.
Such
coverage should be sufficient to ensure that the Federal Reserve has
adequate tools with which to conduct monetary policy, and should be
structured to hold the cost to the taxpayer to an acceptable level.
At the same time, the legislation should provide for a more universal
access to the Federal Reserve's services, and at a realistic price.

This concludes my formal testimony, Mr. Chairman.
I would be
pleased to answer any questions the Committee may have.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

o 0 o