View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

NEWS RELEASE
FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION

PR-32-72 (5-17-72)

FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE

IMPLICATIONS TO THE PUBLIC OF A RESTRUCTURED
SAVINGS BANK INDUSTRY

Address of
Frank Wille, Chairman
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation

May 16, 1972

Before the
52nd Annual Conference
of the
National Association of Mutual Savings Banks

Regency Hyatt House
Atlanta, Georgia

FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION, 550 Seventeenth St. N.W., Washington, D. C. 20429



202-389-4221

Two years ago when I addressed your Golden Anniversary Conference, the
Presidential Commission on Financial Structure and Regulation was just being
organized.

We knew that it would examine questions of mortgage financing,

deposit-rate ceilings and the need of thrift institutions, particularly
savings and loan associations, for greater flexibility to adapt to market
developments such as those that occurred in 1966 and 1969.

We knew that the

Commission was being asked to create a financial and regulatory structure that
would encourage vigorous innovation and competition, that would serve an ex­
panding and increasingly complex economy, and that would respond with sensi­
tivity to changing demands in the future.

What we did not know, insofar as

mutual savings banks and the savings and loan industry were concerned, was
whether the Commission would opt for a solution in which both types of institu­
tions would remain relatively specialized in authorized powers in order to
assist the allocation of credit to particular sectors of the economy like
housing or whether instead it would urge a solution in which both would become
more generalized, full-service institutions like commercial banks, each seeking
to attract lendable funds in an increasingly competitive deposit market.
The Commission’s report, issued last December, takes the second, more
generalized, approach, leaving to individual managements any decision to
specialize.

A number of important differences would remain between commercial

banks, mutual savings banks, and savings and loan associations but it was
obviously the Commission's belief that each institutional type would have a
substantially equal opportunity to compete for lendable funds in an environment
without deposit-rate ceilings.

In order to give deposit thrift institutions

this capability, the Commission recommended a significant enlargement of their
authority to diversity both the liability and the asset side of their




2

operations.

Then, to avoid the possibility that new investment opportunities

would divert funds from traditional levels of investment in residential
housing, the Commission further recommended basic reforms in residential
mortgage lending practices, coupled with the enactment of a special tax credit,
available to all institutional lenders, based on gross interest income from
residential mortgages.
Some of these recommendations have very wide support, whether or not the
Commission’s full package of recommendations is adopted.

I would include among

these (i) the eventual removal of deposit rate ceilings, (ii) authorization
for a wider range of time and savings deposits and certificates of deposit
that would vary considerably as to interest rate, withdrawal power and maturity,
and (iii) the reforms suggested in residential mortgage lending practices.
The removal of interest rate ceilings on time and savings deposits, if
accomplished in such a way that the financial soundness of each institutional
type is protected, would be of obvious benefit to depositors, especially those
who are unsophisticated or whose savings are limited in amount.

As we know,

rates of interest paid on money market instruments and corporate obligations
during periods of tight money can exceed by substantial proportions the deposit
rate ceilings which may be imposed to protect the liquidity positions of
financial intermediaries.

Knowledgeable and substantial customers, however,

can invest in such higher-rate instruments directly, and they appear increas­
ingly likely to do so the longer a period of tight money continues, thus
contributing to the exact liquidity strains deposit rate ceilings are in part
intended to ameliorate or avoid.

When the ceilings differentiate further

between large savers and small savers in a manner unfavorable to the latter,
basic inequity is added to long-run ineffectiveness.




- 3 -

The removal of rate ceilings would encourage all deposit institutions to
approximate the rates available through direct investments in the market if
they are to attract new deposits or avoid the loss of existing deposits.
Assuming that their rate patterns would not discriminate against small savers
(and the vigorous competition likely to exist for deposits makes this unlikely),
both large and small savers should experience benefits of convenience and higher
interest payments when rates are rising generally in the money markets.

When

market interest rates are declining, the same forces of competition are likely
to keep deposit rates as high as possible —

possibly even higher than money

market conditions would dictate because institutions which invested long at
relatively high rates can afford to pay such rates and are willing to do so to
maintain a steady inflow of deposit funds.

The deposit experience of mutual

savings banks over the past year in the face of market uncertainties and some
reduction in commercial bank deposit rates makes this point quite clearly —
and it is the general public which has had the benefit of your continued high
rates.
The Commission's recommendation that thrift institutions be allowed to
offer a wider mix of maturities, interest rates and withdrawal restrictions
should benefit both the thrift institutions and their savers.

This has been

the experience in many savings bank States where longer-term certificate
accounts have been authorized, with the highest rates of interest reserved for
those of longest maturity and the most restrictive withdrawal provisions.

An

institution whose earnings or surplus position might not be conducive to paying
a competitive rate on all its accounts uniformly would than have the option of
paying such a rate at least to those depositors willing to share with it the
longer term risks of reinvestment upon maturity.




The evidence we have on

- 4 -

disintermediation indicates that the major problem faced by financial
intermediaries during periods of rising market rates is the loss of exist­
ing deposits.

To prevent withdrawals by rate-conscious depositors, such

institutions should in my judgment be allowed to diversify their liability
structure by (i) segmenting the market for deposits, (ii) creating a deposit
structure built on marginal rate differentials, and (iii) lengthening the
average maturity of deposits to encourage stability over the business cycle.
Such authority in a world without ceilings, would, for example, permit
institutions to develop in addition to the usual certificate accounts, "bonusat-maturity" accounts under which a depositor would commit his funds for a
given period of time at a fixed rate of return plus a bonus of some specified
amount, payable only at maturity and forfeited in the case of early with­
drawal.

The owners of such special deposit accounts would benefit by receiving

the competitive rate, or a bonus rate, without the inconvenience of withdrawing
their funds and making a new investment in the market, while the institution
would succeed to some extent in stabilizing its deposit structure within its
own revenue limitations.
Each of these basic liability reforms should smooth out the flow of
savings to deposit and share accounts in thrift institutions and many small
commercial banks.

If sizeable percentages of their combined assets continue

to be invested in residential housing loans, the flow of funds into housing
should be significantly more even than in the past, thereby avoiding the
peaks and valleys that have traditionally accompanied swings in the business
cycle.




5

The Commission’s recommendations for reforms in mortgage lending
practices are also designed to smooth the flow of funds into the housing
market.

These include such items as authorizing variable rate mortgages,

allowing interest rates on FHA, VA and conventional mortgages to be
determined by market forces rather than by statutory or administered
ceilings, removing unreasonable restrictions on loan-to-value ratios, per­
mitting loans to be made on properties anywhere within the United States or
its territories, simplifying the legal work in mortgage origination and
foreclosure work including the development of a standardized conventional
mortgage form, and abolishing the ’’doing business" barriers which some
States place on out-of-State institutions lending mortgage money on or
holding real property within their borders.

All of these are sound recommenda­

tions that should make mortgage loans throughout the United States more
attractive to institutional lenders that have other equally attractive or more
attractive investment alternatives available to them.

To the extent more

funds are made available to the housing market nationwide through these reforms
than would be the case today, the builder and the homeowner benefit from the
assurance that a plentiful supply of funds for their purposes will be available
although the price of such funds, rather than their availability, may actually
be more important to them, a subject to which I shall return in a moment.
Research conducted by the FDIC indicates that much of the variation in
the flow of mortgage credit from deposit institutions can be explained by
variations in the flow of funds to these institutions.

It appears, for example,

that the speed with which these institutions commit funds to conventional
mortgages depends primarily on three factors: (i) the variations in the flow
of savings over the preceding three or four quarters, (ii) the stability




6

associated by the institution’s management with the various components of its
deposit structure, and (iii) the interest rates available on mortgages
relative to those available on competing market instruments.

While current

deposit flows are significant in explaining an institution's mortgage commitment
and acquisition policy, a greater correlation is found with the long-run
stability or lack of it in the deposit structure.

If inflows appear relatively

stable, the exact pattern is then determined, in great measure, by the alterna­
tive investments available to each type of institution —

those with numerous

short-term investment alternatives being slower to make commitments and to fund
mortgage loans than the institutions with fewer alternatives.

The most

important factor, however, at all institutions in explaining net acquisitions
of mortgages appears to be the variability, long term, of deposit inflows.
The Commission's recommendations to remove deposit-rate ceilings, diversify
the savings deposit structure of thrift institutions and make mortgage loans
more attractive investment alternatives should all result, therefore, in a
greater and more even flow of funds into residential housing in future periods
of tight money periods than occurred in 1966 or 1969.
There appears to be far less correlation between the flow of funds into
residential housing and an institution's increased authority to diversify its
investments and its services.

The average commercial bank, with a broad

capacity to diversify its loans and investments, devotes a far smaller
percentage of its total assets to residential mortgage loans than the average
savings bank, and the latter, which has significant but limited opportunities
to diversify its loans and investments, devotes a significantly smaller
percentage of its total assets to such loans than the average savings and loan




7

association - - the institutional type with the least opportunity to
diversify at the present time.

Of the three, the savings and loan industry,

at least in recent years, has been the principal supplier of funds to the
residential housing market, both in dollar volume and as a percentage of total
assets.

Public officials and legislators are quite justified on this basis

in asking what effect the proposals for asset diversification recommended for
thrift

institutions by the Hunt Commission will have on the future supply of

funds for residential housing.
As I understand it, mutual savings banks in the various States have one
or more of the investment powers recommended by the Commission for deposit
thrift institutions, but no savings bank has all of them.

Savings and loan

associations, on the other hand, are much more generally restricted today,
and the new powers if utilized would have much greater impact on their
operations individually and collectively than they would on savings banks.
I am prepared to accept the argument, based on the savings bank experience in
a number of the States, that the powers to make consumer loans up to 10 percent
of total assets, to invest without limitation in municipal obligations and
corporate debt instruments, to invest up to 10 percent of total assets in
equity securities listed on a rational exchange, and to invest up to 3 percent
of assets in "leeway" investments are unlikely to vary with any perceptible
effect on the housing market and 63 percent of your total assets presently
devoted to residential mortgage loans.

But if the nation’s much larger savings

and loan industry, in utilizing these same powers, were to reduce the percentage
of their total assets committed to residential housing to the same 63 percent
of total assets, the effect on residential housing could over time be noticeably
adverse despite the improved deposit flows likely to accrue to both types of
institutions from other Commission recommendations.




-

8

-

There are some excellent reasons, not directly related to residential
housing flows, why the various proposals for asset diversification proposed
by the Commission would benefit the public as well as deposit thrift
institutions.

Consumer credit markets, for example, are demonstratively

imperfect, resulting in higher than necessary rates for many borrowers.
Additional competitors, conveniently available in the form of mutual savings
banks and savings and loan associations, would markedly increase the number
of credit sources available to borrowers, and the increased competition
sure to result would encourage the lowest possible interest costs
consistent with efficient operation.

Consumer credit services, as well as

checking account services, may be a special convenience for people who
don't use commercial banks at all, and leeway investments subject to the asset
limitation proposed can benefit the public by permitting loans to perfectly
credit-worthy applicants whose collateral is unusual or not technically in
compliance with the requirements of statutory or administrative policy.
For the institution, each of these powers can contribute to the higher earnings
or surplus necessary in periods of rising interest rates to pay market rates
for deposits rather than some lower deposit rate ceiling.

Greater short­

term cash flows could be generated by consumer loans that mature on average in
one year rather than the eight or ten years which mark the life of the average
residential mortgage, thereby improving liquidity and making some additional
funds available to meet prior loan commitments when money tightens.

Finally,

to the extent the new services attract customers who will be savings depositors
at some future date, the stability of the institution's deposit structure
would be enhanced, and this as I have noted earlier appears to be the necessary
prerequisite for net increases in the mortgage account at all Institutions'.




9

These new services and investment powers then, are likely to bring
benefits of competition and convenience to the public, but it overstates
the matter to assume some beneficial effect on residential housing flows
as a direct result.

At best such an effort can only be indirect, through

increased earnings, through the ability thereby to pay competitive market
rates on deposits, and through increasingly stable and predictable deposit
inflows.

A beneficial effect on housing further assumes a management deter­

mination to commit new funds to residential housing in a proportion at least
equal to the percentage of its total assets presently invested in such loans
an assumption which is particularly dubious in the case of the savings and
loan industry.
They, like you, will be under significant pressure when deposit rate
ceilings are removed to maximize earnings.

Such earnings will be necessary

either to pay market rates for deposits on a current basis or to accumulate
reserves for future use so that market rates can be followed upwards
whenever tight money and very high interest rates prevail.

If a swing away

from residential mortgage financing is to be avoided as deposit thrift
institutions struggle to maximize earnings, the interest cost on a home
mortgage may well go up until it becomes just as attractive earnings-wise
to an institutional lender as other available investments like corporate
bonds or consumer loans.
The special tax credit recommended by the Commission on interest
income from residential mortgages becomes a key recommendation at this
point for two reasons.

First, such a credit may be essential if the

mortgage interest rates charged to homeowners in the future are to be




10

held even to today's historically high levels.

Secondly, such a credit may

be essential if generalized lenders, including thrift institutions with the
investment options proposed by the Commission, are to continue the high
levels of investment in residential mortgage loans likely to be needed in
this growing country in the future.
It is for these reasons that I believe the political acceptability of
the Hunt Commission recommendations as to the asset powers of your industry
and the asset powers of the savings and loan industry is so intimately
connected with the tax credit only briefly mentioned by the Commission.

How

the details of that tax credit are worked out, how much impact it will have
on the cost of mortgage credit to homeowners and what sort of an incentive it
will actually provide for lending institutions to stay in the residential
housing field may well determine the fate of the Commission's entire report.




//

|

#

|

|