View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
Noon EDT
October 21,2004

Oil and the Economy

Remarks by
Ben S. Bernanke
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Distinguished Lecture Series
Darton College
Albany, Georgia
October 21,2004

If you have regular occasion to fill your car's tank with gas, you know that the
price of gasoline has recently been both high and volatile--a consequence, for the most
part, of similar movements in the price of crude oil. 1 The weekly average price for a
barrel of West Texas intermediate, a standard grade of crude oil, hovered around $30
during the second half of 2003 but began to rise around the tum of the year. The price
per barrel reached $37 in March and nearly $41 in May. Oil prices have continued to rise
erratically since the spring, even as other commodity prices have generally stabilized and
overall inflation has been low. As oflast week, the price of a barrel of West Texas
intermediate stood at about $55. 2
Some perspective is in order. Oil prices are at record levels when measured in
nominal terms, but when adjusted for inflation the price of oil still remains well below its
historical peak, reached in 1981. Measured in today's dollars, crude oil prices in 1981
were about $80 per barrel, and the price of gasoline at the pump was nearly $3 per gallon.
Moreover, energy costs at that time were a larger share both of consumers' budgets and
of the cost of producing goods and services than they are today. Clearly, the surges in oil
prices of the 1970s and early 1980s had much more pronounced economic effects than
the more recent increases have had or are likely to have, barring a substantial further rise.
All that being said, prices of oil and oil products in the United States today are
quite high relative to recent experience. During most of the 1990s, oil prices were
1 Although gasoline prices generally rise and fall with the price of crude oil, in the short run the linkage can
be relatively loose. One reason that oil and gasoline prices do not march in lockstep is that the margins that
refiners and distributors of gasoline can command may vary significantly over time, depending on such
factors as the availability of refinery capacity, seasonal variations in the demand for gasoline, and regional
imbalances in gasoline supply.
2 The price of West Texas intermediate (WTI) is often cited in the media, which is why I have used it as an
example here. For consistency, in the remainder of the talk, when I refer to oil prices I mean the price of
WTI. However, as a particularly desirable grade of "light, sweet" oil, WTI commands a premium price.
The average price of crude oil imported into the United States is currently about $40 per barrel, about $15
less than the price of WTI.

-2roughly $20 per barrel, and for a short period in 1998 (remembered without fondness by
oil explorers and producers) the price of a barrel of crude fell to just above $10. As I
mentioned, only a year ago the price of oil was about $30 per barrel. The recent rise in
oil prices has thus been large enough to constitute a significant shock to the economic
system.
The runup in oil prices raises a number of important questions for economists and
policymakers. Why have oil prices risen by so much and why do they continue to
fluctuate so erratically? What is the outlook for oil supplies and oil prices in the medium
term and in the long term? What implications does the behavior of oil prices have for the
ongoing economic expansion? And how should monetary policy respond to these
developments? I will touch briefly on each of these questions today. Before doing so, I
should note that the opinions I express today are my own and are not to be attributed to
my colleagues in the Federal Reserve System?
Recent and Prospective Developments in Oil Markets

To assess recent developments in the oil market, it would be useful to know
whether the high price of oil we observe today is a temporary spike or is instead the
beginning of an era of higher prices. Although no one can know for sure how oil prices
will evolve, financial markets are one useful place to learn about informed opinion.
Contracts for future deliveries of oil, as for many other commodities, are traded
continuously on an active market by people who have every incentive to monitor the
energy situation quite closely.4 Derivative financial instruments, such as options to buy
or sell oil at some future date, are also actively traded. The prices observed in these
I thank William Helkie and Charles Struckmeyer, of the Board's staff, for their excellent assistance.
Oil futnres and other oil-related derivatives are traded on the New York Mercantile Exchange (NYMEX)
and the Interuational Petroleum Exchange (IPE) as well as over the counter.
3

4

-3markets can be used to obtain useful information about what traders expect for the future
course of oil prices, as well as the degree of uncertainty they feel in predicting the future.
One inference we can draw from recent developments in the oil market, in
particular from the pricing of derivative instruments, is that traders in that market are
unusually uncertain about how the price of oil will evolve over the next year or so. For
example, as of last week, traders assigned about a two-thirds probability that the price of
crude oil as of next June would be between $38 and $60 per barrel. Or, to say the same
thing another way, traders perceived a one-third chance that the price of oil would fall
outside the wide $38-$60 range. That well-informed traders would be so uncertain about
what the price of oil will be only eight months in the future is striking, to say the least.
Uncertainty can in itselfbe a negative factor for the economy; for example, I
would not rule out the possibility that uncertainty about future energy costs has made
companies a bit more cautious about making new capital investments. However,
probably more economically significant than near-term uncertainty about oil prices is the
fact that traders appear to expect tight conditions in the oil market to continue for some
years, with at best only a modest decline in prices. This belief on the part of traders can
be seen in the prices of oil futures contracts. Throughout most of the 1990s, market
prices of oil for delivery at dates up to six years in the future fluctuated around $20 per
barrel, suggesting that traders expected oil prices to remain at about that level well into
the future. Today, futures markets place the expected price of a barrel of oil in the long
run closer to $39, a near doubling. s Thus, although traders expect the price of oil to

5 I should acknowledge that oil futures prices have a less-than-stellar record in forecasting oil price
developments, but they are probably the best guide that we have. Chinn, LeBlanc, and Coibion (2001) find
that futures quotes are unbiased predictors of future spot prices, though not very accurate ones.

-4decline somewhat from recent highs, they also believe that a significant part of the recent
increase in prices will be long lived.
What accounts for the behavior of the current and expected future price of oil?
The writer George Bernard Shaw once said that, to obtain an economist, it was only
necessary to teach a parrot to repeat endlessly the phrase "supply and demand." Well, as
an economist, I have to agree with the parrot. For the most part, high oil prices reflect
high and growing demand for oil and limited (and uncertain) supplies.
On the demand side, the International Energy Agency (lEA), perhaps the most
reliable source of data on world oil production and consumption, has continued to revise
upward its projections of global oil usage. To illustrate, world oil consumption for the
second quarter of this year, the latest quarter for which we have complete data, is now
estimated to have been about 3.7 million barrels per day higher than the IEA projected in
July 2003. 6 (For reference, total global oil consumption this year has averaged about 81
million barrels per day). A significant part of this unexpected increase in oil
consumption, about 2.2 million barrels per day, reflected quickly growing oil demands in
East Asia, notably China. However, an ongoing economic expansion across both the
industrialized and the emerging-market economies has also contributed to the world's
growing appetite for oil.
On the supply side, the production of oil has been constrained by the available
capacity and by geopolitical developments. With oil consumption and prices rising
briskly, Saudi Arabia and other members of the Organization of Petroleum-Exporting
Countries (OPEC) have promised to pump more oil. However, the relatively limited
6 Saudi Arabia and other OPEC members, like the lEA and most participants in the oil markets, did not
anticipate the surge in consumption we have seen this year either. OPEC actually reduced its production
targets in 2003 and again in early 2004 out of concern that weak oil demand would cause price declines.

-5-

increases in production delivered so far by OPEC members, together with non-OPEC
production that has fallen a bit below projections, have raised concerns that the spare
production capacity available in the near term may be severely limited, perhaps below
1 million barrels per day.
Interacting with the limits on capacity, and contributing to the exceptional
volatility in oil prices of recent months, are uncertainties about the reliability and security
of oil supplies. Of course, the oil-rich Middle East remains especially volatile. But
political risks to the oil supply have emerged in nations outside the Middle East as well,
including Russia, Venezuela, and Nigeria. Weather also has taken a toll, as recent
hurricanes affected the production and distribution of oil on the U.S. Gulf Coast.
Because neither the demand for nor the supply of oil responds very much to price
changes in the short run, the recent unexpected rise in oil consumption together with
disruptions to supply can plausibly account for much of the increase in prices. However,
the sharp increases and extreme volatility of oil prices have led observers to suggest that
some part of the rise in prices reflects a speculative component arising from the activities
of traders in the oil markets.
How might speculation raise the price of oil? Simplifying greatly, speculative
traders who expect oil to be in increasingly short supply and oil prices to rise in the future
can back their hunches with their money by purchasing oil futures contracts on the
commodity exchange. Oil futures contracts represent claims to oil to be delivered at a
specified price and at a specified date and location in the future. If the price of oil rises as
the traders expect--more precisely, if the future oil price rises above the price specified in
the contract--they will be able to re-sell their claims to oil at a profit.

-6If many speculators share the view that oil shortages will worsen and prices will
rise, then their demand for oil futures will be high and, consequently, the price of oil for
future delivery will rise. Higher oil futures prices in tum affect the incentives faced by
oil producers. Seeing the high price of oil for future delivery, oil producers will hold oil
back from today's market, adding it to inventory for anticipated future sale. This
reduction in the amount of oil available for current use will in tum cause today's price of
oil to rise, an increase that can be interpreted as the speculative premium in the oil price.
Many people take a dim view of speculation in general, and in some instances this
view is justified. 7 In many situations, however, informed speculation is good for society.
In the case of oil, speculative activity tends to ensure that a portion of the oil that is
currently produced is put aside to guard against the possibility of disruptions or shortages
in the future. True, speculation may raise the current price of oil, but that increase is
useful in stimulating current production and reducing current demand, thereby freeing up
more oil to be held in reserve against emergencies. Speculative traders have no altruistic
motives, of course; their objective is only to buy low and sell high. But speculators'
profits depend on their ability to induce a shift in oil use from periods when prices are
relatively low (that is, when oil is relatively plentiful) to periods when prices are
relatively high (when oil is scarce). Social welfare is likely increased by informed
speculation in oil markets because speculative activities make oil relatively more
available at the times when it is most needed. 8

For example, we know of historical examples of speculators "cornering" a market, leading to wild price
fluctuations unjustified by fundamentals.
8 In addition to helping ensure that oil is used at the socially most valuable time, speculation also reduces
risks for producers and consumers of oil. For example, an oil producer who sells oil for future delivery
receives a guaranteed price today and does not have to bear the risk that the price will drop sharply before
the oil delivery date.
7

-7This discussion suggests three indicators to help us detect the influence of
speculative activity on current oil prices. First, if speculative activity is an important
source of the rise in oil prices, we would expect today's oil price to react strongly to news
bearing on future conditions of oil supply and demand. Second, we should see
speculative traders holding claims to large amounts of oil for future delivery, in the hope
of enjoying a profit by re-selling the oil should prices rise. Finally, corresponding to the
speculative positions held by traders, we would expect to see significant increases in the
physical inventories of oil being held for future use.
The first indicator, rapid swings of oil prices in response to news about the
prospective supplies and usage of oil, does appear to be present and to suggest a
speculative element in pricing. It is thus somewhat puzzling that the other two indicators
of speculative activity do not appear to be present: Our best-available measure of
speculative traders' holdings of contracts for future delivery of crude oil and petroleum
products has decreased from earlier in the year and is not unusually high by historical
standards. 9 And official data imply that physical inventories of crude oil and petroleum
products, at least within the industrial countries for which we have good data, have not
risen to any significant degree and at times have even been below seasonal norms. 10
Perhaps the official data overlook important accumulations of crude oil stocks--in China
and other emerging-market economies, for example--but that remains (if you will excuse
the expression) speculation. My tentative conclusion is that speculative activity may help
9 The measure used here is net long futures positions of noncommercial traders (that is, traders who do not
have a direct hedging need). These data, available from the Commodity Futures Trading Commission, do
not perfectly measure speculative activity, as they do not cover all trading in oil futures, nor do they
necessarily cleanly distinguish speculators from other traders.
10 Oil market data for the United States, including inventories data, are released weekly by the Energy
Information Administration, part of the U.S. Department of Energy. Each month, the International Energy
Agency releases analogous information covering the thirty member countries of the Organization for
Economic Development and Cooperation (OECD).

-8to account for part of the recent volatility in oil prices. However, the available evidence
does not provide clear support for the view that speculative activity has made oil prices
during the past year much higher on average than they otherwise would have been. 11
A rather different explanation of the recent increase in oil prices holds that the rise
is in large part a symptom of inflationary monetary policies. An extensive literature
exists on this topic. The general idea is that, if most prices adjust slowly, the effects of an
excessively easy monetary policy will show up first as a sharp increase in those prices
that are able to adjust most quickly, such as the prices of commodities (including oil). If
this idea were valid, then commodity price movements could be used as a guide for
setting monetary policy.
However, the consensus that emerges from this literature is that the relationship
between commodity price movements and monetary policy is tenuous and unreliable at
best. Moreover, applied to the recent experience, economic models that support the use
of oil prices as a leading indicator of monetary policy make a number of other predictions
that are strongly contradicted by the facts. These predictions include (1) that all
commodity prices should move proportionally in response to changes in monetary policy
(in fact, oil prices have risen sharply since the spring as other commodity prices have
generally stabilized); (2) that the dollar should have rapidly depreciated as the oil price

11 Weiner (2002) surveys the academic literature and concludes that, over the long term, speculative
activity has not much affected the average price of oil. The apparently strong effect on oil prices of recent
hurricanes in the Gulf of Mexico, which led to short-term reductions in production, is a bit of evidence that
high prices reflect a tight supply-demand balance rather than speculative hoarding. If inventories or spare
production capacity had been available, the shortfalls created by hurricanes could have been replaced, and
the price effect would have been more muted.
A somewhat different question is whether future prices for oil contain a significant risk premium.
The finding of Chinn, LeBlanc, and Coibion (2001) that futures prices are unbiased predictors of future
spot prices argues against a large risk premium. Estimates by the Board's staff, based on the methods of
Pindyck (2001), indicate that the risk premium in oil futures was no more than $2 or so even during the
recent spikes in prices.

-9rose (in fact, the dollar has been broadly stable during 2004); (3) that inflation
expectations should have increased substantially (but long-term nominal interest rates,
the level of inflation compensation implicit in inflation-indexed bond yields, and survey
measures of inflation expectations concur in showing no such rise); and (4) that general
inflation, though lagging commodity-price inflation, should also rise over time (but
inflation excluding energy prices remains quite low). Models of commodity-price
"overshooting" also imply that the current surge in oil prices will be almost entirely
temporary, a prediction strongly at variance with market expectations as revealed in the
futures markets. I conclude that an increasingly tight supply-demand balance, rather than
speculation or easy monetary policies, probably accounts for most of the recent run-up in
oil prices.
I have focused on near-term developments in the oil markets. What about the
longer term? In that regard, we can safely assume that world economic growth, together
with the rapid pace of industrialization in China, India, and other emerging-market
economies, will generate increasing demands for oil and other forms of energy. If we
are lucky, growth in the demand for energy will be moderated by continued
improvements in energy efficiency that will be stimulated by higher prices and concerns
about the security of oil supplies. Such improvements are certainly possible, even
without new technological breakthroughs. For example, Japan is an advanced industrial
nation that uses only about one-third as much energy to produce each dollar of real output
as the United States does. 12 Industrializing nations such as China appear to be quite

12 Japan may set an unreasonably high standard: That country's small area reduces the use of energy for
transportation, and the low average size of homes on these densely populated islands reduces heating and
cooling costs. Japan also produces a different mix of goods and services than the United States, a mix that

- 10 inefficient in their energy use; for example, the underdeveloped electricity grid in China
has induced heavy use of inefficient diesel-powered generators. As these countries
modernize, their energy efficiency will presumably improve. Still, if the global economic
expansion continues, substantial growth in the use of oil and other energy sources appears
to be inevitable.
The supply side of the oil market is even more difficult to predict. In a physical
sense, the world is not in imminent danger of running out of oil. At the end of2003, the
world's proved reserves of oil--that is, oil in the ground that is viewed as recoverable
using existing technologies and under current economic conditions---reached more than
1.15 trillion barrels, 12 percent more than the world's proved reserves a decade earlier
and equal to about forty years of global consumption at current rates (BP Statistical
Review of World Energy, 2004, p. 4). Of course, global oil consumption will not remain

at current rates; it will grow. But, on the other hand, today's proved reserve figures
ignore not only the potential for new discoveries but also the likelihood that improved
technology and higher oil prices will increase the amount of oil that can be economically
recovered.
The oil is there, but whether substantial new production sources can be made
available over the next five years or so is in some doubt. Some important fields are in
locations that are technically difficult and time-consuming to develop, such as deep-water
fields off West Africa, in the Gulf of Mexico, or off the east coast of South America. In
many cases, the development of new fields also faces the challenge of recovering the oil
without damaging delicate ecosystems, if indeed the political process allows exploitation

may be less energy-intensive. On the other hand, not even Japan has made full use of the energy
conservation potential of existing technologies, such as hybrid autos for example.

- 11 -

of ecologically sensitive fields at all. I have already noted the uncertainties generated by
geopolitical instability; perhaps it is sufficient here to note that, despite the opening of
fields in a number of new regions in the past decade, about 63 percent of known oil
reserves today are in the Middle East. Oil producers are also aware from painful
experience that oil prices can fall as quickly as they rise; hence, exploration projects
launched when prices are high may come to fruition when prices are much lower. These
risks help to explain why major oil companies have not rushed to increase exploration
activities during this recent period of high prices.
Thus, the supply-demand fundamentals seem consistent with the view now taken
by oil-market participants that the days of persistently cheap oil are over. The good news
is that, in the longer run, we have options. I have already noted the scope for
improvements in energy efficiency and increased conservation. Considerable potential
exists as well for substituting other energy sources for oil, including natural gas, coal,
nuclear energy, and renewable sources such as wind and hydroelectric power. For
example, the world has vast supplies of natural gas that, pending additional infrastructure
development, might be transported in liquefied form to the United States, Europe, Asia,
and elsewhere at BTU-equivalent prices below those expected for crude oil. Given
enough time, market mechanisms (most obviously, higher prices) are likely to increase
energy supplies, including alternative energy sources, while simultaneously encouraging
conservation and substitution away from oil to other types of energy. These adjustments
will not occur rapidly, however. Hence the next few years may be stressful ones for
energy consumers, as stretched and uncertain supplies of oil and other conventional
energy sources face the growing demands of a rapidly expanding world economy.

- 12 Economic and Policy Implications of Increased Oil Prices
What are the economic implications of the recent increase in oil prices? In the
long run, higher oil prices are likely to reduce somewhat the productive capacity of the
U.S. economy. That outcome would occur, for example, if high energy costs make
businesses less willing to invest in new capital or causes some existing capital to become
economically obsolescent. Lower productivity in tum implies that wages and profits will
be lower than they otherwise would have been. Also, the higher cost of imported oil is
likely to adversely affect our terms of trade; that is, Americans will have to sell more
goods and services abroad to pay for a given quantity of oil and other imports. The
increase in the prices of our imports relative to the prices of our exports will impose a
further burden on U.S. households and firms.
Under the assumption that oil prices do not spike sharply higher from their
already high levels, these long-run effects, though negative, should be manageable. As I
have already discussed, conservation and the development of alternative energy sources
will, over the long term, take some of the sting out of higher oil prices. Moreover,
productivity gains from diverse sources, including technological improvements and a
more highly educated workforce, are likely to exceed by a significant margin the
productivity losses created by high oil prices.
In the short run, sharply higher oil prices create a rather different and, in some
ways, a more difficult set of economic challenges. Indeed, a significant increase in oil
prices can simultaneously slow economic growth while stoking inflation, posing hard
choices for monetary policy makers.

- 13 -

An increase in oil prices slows economic growth in the short run primarily
through its effects on spending, or aggregate demand. Because the United States imports
most of its oil, an increase in oil prices is, as many economists have noted, broadly
analogous to the imposition of a tax on U.S. residents, with the revenue from the tax
going to oil producers abroad. Since the beginning of the year, the cost of oil imported
into the United States has increased by about $75 billion (at an annual rate), or about 3/4
percent of the gross domestic product (GDP). Add to this the effects of the rise in natural
gas prices, and the total increase in imported energy costs over a full year--the increase in
the "tax" being paid to foreign energy producers--comes to almost $85 billion.
The impact of this decline in net income on the U.S. GDP depends in large part on
how the increase in the energy "tax" affects the spending of households and firms. For a
number of reasons, an increase of $85 billion in payments to foreign energy producers is
likely to reduce domestic spending by something less than that amount. For example, in
the short run, people may be reluctant to cut non-energy spending below accustomed
levels, leading them to reduce saving rather than spending. Because high energy costs
lower firms' profits, they normally reduce the willingness of firms to purchase new
capital goods; however, if the increase in energy prices looks to be permanent, firms
might decide that it makes sense for them to invest in more energy-efficient buildings and
machines, moderating the decline in their capital spending. If higher energy prices reflect
in part more rapid economic growth abroad--which seems to be the case in the recent
episode--or if foreign energy producers spend part of their increased income on U. S.
goods and services, then the demand for U.S. exports may be stronger than it would have
been otherwise. With these and many other qualifications taken into account, a

- 14 reasonable estimate is that the increased cost of imported energy has reduced the growth
in U.S. aggregate spending and real output this year by something between half and
three-quarters of a percentage point.
At the same time that higher oil prices slow economic growth, they also create
inflationary pressures. Higher prices for crude are passed through, with only a very short
lag, to increased prices for oil products used by consumers, such as gasoline and heating
oil. When oil prices rise, people may try to substitute other forms of energy, such as
natural gas, leading to price increases in those alternatives as well. The rise in energy
costs faced by households represents, of course, an increase in the cost of living, or
inflation. This direct effect of higher energy prices on the cost of living is sometimes
called the first-round effect on inflation. In addition, higher energy costs may have
indirect effects on the inflation rate--if, for example, firms pass on their increased costs of
production in the form of higher consumer prices for non-energy goods or services, or if
workers respond to the increase in the cost of living by demanding higher wages. These
indirect effects of higher energy prices on the overall rate of inflation are called second-

round effects. The overall inflation rate reflects both first-round and second-round
effects, of course. Economists and policymakers also pay attention to the so-called core
inflation rate, which excludes the direct effects of increases in the prices of energy (as
well as of food). By stripping out the first-round inflation effects, core inflation provides
a useful indicator of the second-round effects of increases in the price of energy. 13

In the past, notably during the 1970s and early 1980s, both the first-round and
second-round effects of oil-price increases on inflation tended to be large, as firms freely
13 As discussed earlier, higher energy prices may also lower the economy's productive capacity, by
reducing investment and making a portion of the capital stock un-economical to operate. This decline in
potential output puts additional upward pressure on the inflation rate.

- 15 passed rising energy costs on to consumers, and workers reacted to the surging cost of
living by ratcheting up their wage demands. This situation made monetary policy making
extremely difficult, because oil-price increases threatened to raise the overall inflation
rate significantly. The Federal Reserve attempted to contain the inflationary effects of
the oil-price shocks by engineering sharp increases in interest rates, actions which had the
unfortunate side effect of sharply slowing growth and raising unemployment, as in the
recessions that began in 1973 and 1981.
Since about 1980, the Federal Reserve and most other central banks have worked
hard to bring inflation down, and in recent years, inflation in the United States and other
industrial countries has been both low and stable. An important benefit of these efforts is
that the second-round inflation effect of a given increase in energy prices has been much
reduced (Hooker, 1999). Because households and business owners are now confident
that the Fed will keep inflation low, firms have both less incentive and less ability to pass
on increased energy costs in the form of higher prices, and likewise workers have less
need and less capacity to demand compensating increases in wages. Thus, increases in
energy prices, though they temporarily raise overall inflation, tend to have modest and
transient effects on core inflation; that is, currently, the second-round effects appear to be
relatively small.
Although the difficulties posed by increases in oil prices are less than in the past,
the economic consequences are nevertheless unpleasant, as higher oil prices still tend to
induce both slower growth and higher inflation. How then should monetary policy react?
Unfortunately, monetary policy cannot offset the recessionary and inflationary effects of
increased oil prices at the same time. If the central bank lowers interest rates in an effort

- 16 to stimulate growth, it risks adding to inflationary pressure; but if it raises rates enough to
choke off the inflationary effect of the increase in oil prices, it may exacerbate the
slowdown in economic growth. In conformance with the Fed's dual mandate to promote
both high employment and price stability, Federal Reserve policy makers would ideally
respond in some measure to both the recessionary and inflationary effects of increased oil
prices. Because these two factors tend to pull policy in opposite directions, however,
whether monetary policy eases or tightens following an increase in energy prices
ultimately depends on how policymakers balance the risks they perceive to their
employment and price-stability objectives.
An important qualification must be added, however. The relatively small effects
of higher oil prices on the underlying inflation rate that we have seen in recent years are a
consequence of the public's confidence that the Fed will maintain inflation at a low level
in the medium term. As I have discussed, the public's expectation that inflation will
remain low minimizes the second-round effects of oil price increases, which (in a
virtuous circle) helps to limit the ultimate effect on inflation. Moreover, well-anchored
inflation expectations have been shown to enhance the stability of output and
employment. Maintaining the public's confidence in its policies should thus be among
the central bank's highest priorities. 14 For this reason, I would argue that the Fed's
response to the inflationary effects of an increase in oil prices should depend to some
extent on the economy's starting point. If inflation has recently been on the low side of
the desirable range, and the available evidence suggests that inflation expectations are
likewise low and firmly anchored, then less urgency is required in responding to the
14 As my colleague Edward Gramlich put it in his recent remarks on oil price shocks and monetary policy,
"The worst possible outcome is for monetary policymakers to let inflation come loose from its moorings"
(Gramlich, 2004).

- 17 inflation threat posed by higher oil prices. In this case, monetary policy need not tighten
and could conceivably ease in the wake of an oil-price shock. However, if inflation has
been near the high end of the acceptable range, and policymakers perceive a significant
risk that inflation and inflation expectations may rise further, then stronger action, in the
form of a tighter monetary policy, may well prove necessary. In directing its policy
toward stabilizing the public's inflation expectations, the Fed would be making an
important investment in future economic stability.
I will close by briefly linking this discussion to recent Federal Reserve policy. As
a professor and textbook author, I was accustomed to discussing the effects of a particular
phenomenon, such as rising oil prices, with all other factors held equal. However, as
policymakers know, everything else is never held equal. The increases in oil prices this
year did not take place in isolation. Along with the rise in oil prices, increases in the
prices of other important commodities, such as steel and lumber, as well as higher import
prices resulting from the earlier decline in the dollar, provided supply-side pressure on
inflation in early 2004. Meanwhile, an economic expansion that took hold in the middle
of 2003 resulted in strong output growth but, as of early this year, limited progress in
creating new jobs. As a final complication, the beginning of the year also saw the Fed's
policy interest rate, the federal funds rate, at the historically low level of 1 percent, the
result of the efforts of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) to spark faster
growth and minimize deflation risks in 2003. In January, with inflation low and the job
market still weak, the FOMC indicated that it would be "patient" in removing the policy
accommodation implied by the low value of the federal funds rate.

- 18 The increase in inflation that occurred last spring posed a choice for the FOMC.
Should the Committee remain "patient" in the face of this development, or should it
move more aggressively to meet an emerging inflation threat? The answer, I would
argue, properly depended on both the source of the inflation and the state of inflation
expectations. In particular, if the pickup in inflation had largely resulted from an
overheating economy and a consequent increase in pricing power and wage demands, a
more-aggressive policy would have been appropriate. The FOMC's analysis of the
situation, however, was well described by the statement issued after its June meeting. In
that statement, the Committee suggested that the increase in inflation was due at least in
part to "transitory factors" --a heading under which I include the increases in oil prices,
commodity prices, and import prices--and indicated as well that "underlying inflation"
would likely remain low, which I interpret as saying that, with medium-term inflation
expectations well contained, second-round effects appeared likely to be small. The
implication of this analysis was that the FOMC could remain "patient." Thus far at least,
the FOMC's diagnosis appears to have been correct, as both headline and core inflation
have receded from the levels of last spring.
Looking forward, I am sure that the Committee will continue to watch the oil
situation carefully. However, future monetary-policy choices will not be closely linked
to the behavior of oil prices per se. Rather, they will depend on what the incoming data,
taken as a whole, say about prospects for inflation and the strength of the expansion.
Generally, I expect those data to suggest that the removal of policy accommodation can
proceed at a "measured" pace. However, as always, the actual course of policy will

- 19 depend on the evidence, including, of course, what we learn about how oil prices are
affecting the economy.
As the FOMC evaluates its policy options, retaining public confidence in the
Federal Reserve's commitment to price stability will continue to be essential. If the
public were not fully assured of that commitment, the FOMC would find achieving its
objectives of price stability and maximum sustainable employment to be difficult ifnot
impossible. For that reason, I fully endorse the sentiment in the last few FOMC
statements that" ... the Committee will respond to changes in economic prospects as
needed to fulfill its obligation to maintain price stability."

- 20References

BP (2004). BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2004. London: BP, June.
Chinn, Menzie, Michael LeBlanc, and Olivier Coibion (2001). "The Predictive
Characteristics of Energy Futures: Recent Evidence for Crude Oil, Natural Gas, Gasoline,
and Heating Oil," unpublished paper, University of California, Santa Cruz,
http://neonle.ucsc.edu/~chinn/energvfutures.l2df

Gramlich, Edward M. (2004). "Oil Shocks and Monetary Policy," speech delivered at
the Annual Economic Luncheon, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, September 16.
Hooker, Mark A. (1999). "Are Oil Shocks Inflationary? Asymmetric and Nonlinear
Specifications versus Changes in Regime." Finance and Economics Discussion Series
1999-65. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Pindyck, Robert S. (2001). "The Dynamics of Commodity Spot and Futures Markets: A
Primer," Energy Journal, vol. 22, no. 3, pp. 1-29.
Weiner, Robert J. (2002). "Sheep in Wolves' Clothing? Speculators and Price Volatility
in Petroleum Futures," Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, vol. 42, no. 4, pp.
391-400.