View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
5:30 P.M. EST (2:30 P.M. PST)
January 4, 2004

Monetary Policy and the Economic Outlook: 2004
Remarks by
Ben S. Bernanke
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Meetings of the American Economic Association
and the North American Economic and Finance Association
San Diego, California
January 4, 2004

The tum of the year is the traditional time to review the high and low points of the
year just past and to contemplate the challenges that lie ahead in the year just begun. In
that spirit, I will provide a brief progress report on the economic recovery, as well as
some remarks on the evolution of monetary policy. As always, the views I will express
are my own and are not to be attributed to my colleagues on the Board of Governors or
the Federal Open Market Committee. 1
It is beginning to appear that 2003 was a watershed year for the American
economy, following what had been, on many dimensions, a subpar performance for the
better part of three years. Though officially the recession lasted only eight months, from
March to November 2001, a period of economic underperformance began with the sharp
decline in stock prices and business investment in mid-2000 and continued through the
months leading up to the Iraq war this past spring. To a degree that is unusual for
postwar recessions, the economic weakness of the period was most apparent in the
business sector, even as consumer spending and residential construction remained robust.
Businesses radically pared their spending on new capital goods and cut the ratio of
inventory stocks to sales to historical lows. In an effort to restore profitability in an
environment of weak demand and nonexistent pricing power, businesses also worked
hard to improve efficiency and cut costs. These efforts have paid off in terms of
remarkable increases in productivity, but, together with insufficient growth in aggregate
demand, they also contributed to a significant decline in employment. Like the aftermath
of the 1990-91 recession, the two years since the recession trough in November 2001
have been described as a ''jobless recovery." Indeed, the lag between the recovery in

output and the recovery in employment has been significantly greater this time than it
was after the 1990-91 downturn.
Monetary policy was deployed to support the weakening economy, as the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC) aggressively cut rates in 2001 and has continued its
policy of accommodation since then. Fiscal policy, including two rounds of tax cuts, has
also been highly stimulative. However, despite some early promise, initially the upturn
proved halting and erratic. Policymakers and private-sector economists recognized early
on that a balanced recovery would require willingness on the part of the business sector
to begin investing and hiring again, but forecasts of improved business sentiment
repeatedly proved wrong, or at least premature. In some sectors, such as nonresidential
construction and communications, capital overhangs and capital misallocation, the result
of the earlier boom, reduced both the need and the financial capacity to invest.
Importantly, the economy was also hit by a succession of shocks--notably the September
11, 2001, terrorist attacks, the corporate governance and accounting scandals of the
summer of 2002, and the Iraq war in the spring of2003--each of which created new
uncertainties and left its mark on business confidence.
Despite all this adversity, there could never have been any doubt that the
diversified and resilient U.S. economy, assisted by ample monetary and fiscal stimulus,
would eventually stage a comeback. After several false starts, it now appears that that
comeback began in earnest in the summer of 2003. As you know, the third quarter of the
year displayed near-record levels of real economic growth, in the vicinity of 8 percent at
an annual rate, and growth appears to have continued strong in the fourth quarter of 2003.
The most heartening aspect of this vigorous expansion is that, fmally, the business sector

appears to have emerged from its funk. Corporate investment has been strong,
particularly in equipment and software, and there are some recent signs that both
inventory investment and hiring have begun to pick up.
Of course, downside risks to the economy remain: The recovery in capital
investment may prove less durable than it now appears, the moderation of fiscal stimulus
in the latter part of next year could adversely affect household spending, or new
unfavorable shocks--geopolitical or otherwise--may yet appear. Still, the incoming data
have continued for the most part to surprise on the upside, and the odds accordingly have
increased that 2003 will be remembered as the year when this recovery turned the comer.
Private-sector forecasters generally expect real growth to be approximately 4 percent in
2004, and they foresee modest improvements in the unemployment rate this year and
continued reductions in unemployment in 2005. I think these predictions are broadly
reasonable, and indeed I would not be surprised if the pace of real growth next year
exceeded 4 percent.
With this generally upbeat scenario in mind, some observers in the markets and
the media have questioned the appropriateness of the current stance of monetary policy.
Certainly, the policy stance we have today is historically unusual. More than two years
after the recession trough, and following several quarters of strong growth, the
historically normal pattern would be for the Fed to be well into the process of tightening
policy by now. Instead, the FOMC has held its policy instrument rate, the federal funds
rate, at the very low level of 1 percent. I would like to take some time now to explain
why I believe this policy remains appropriate, despite its historically unusual character.
The positive case for maintaining an accommodative monetary policy at this stage

of the recovery has three elements, some of which will be familiar to many of you, at
least in broad outline.
First, core inflation rates in the United States are as low today as they have been
in forty years, and they have been trending downward. For example, the twelve-month
inflation rate as measured by the consumer price index, current-methods basis and
excluding food and energy prices, was 2.7 percent at the recession trough in November
2001. This measure of core inflation fell to 2.0 percent as of November 2002 and to only
1.1 percent as of November 2003. Other measures of core inflation, such as the one
based on the chain price index for personal consumption expenditures, have displayed a
similar pattern. Inflation is not simply low; for my taste, it is very nearly at the bottom of
the acceptable range for (measured) inflation. In contrast, in previous episodes of
recovery, inflation was above the range consistent with price stability, so that a tightening
of monetary policy at an earlier stage of the expansion represented the prudent response
to inflation risks. Because inflation is so low today, monetary policy can afford to be
more patient to ensure that the recovery is self-sustaining.
The second unusual aspect of the current situation relevant for monetary policy is
the truly remarkable increase in labor productivity that firms and workers have achieved
in recent years. Those productivity increases affect the inflation outlook in two related
ways: first, by raising potential output and thus (for given growth in aggregate demand)
the size of the output gap; and, second, by reducing the costs of production, which puts
downward pressure on prices. I will first address the effect of productivity on costs,
returning later to the link of productivity and the output gap.
Labor costs account for the lion's share, about two-thirds, of the cost of producing

goods and services. The labor cost of producing a unit of output depends, first, on the
dollar cost per hour (including wages and benefits) of employing a worker and, second,
on the quantity of output that each worker produces per hour. When the cost per hour of
employing a worker rises more quickly than the worker's hourly productivity--the
historically normal situation--then the dollar labor cost of producing each unit of output,
the so-called unit labor cost, tends to rise. Recently, however, labor productivity has
grown even more quickly than the costs of employing workers, with the result that unit
labor costs have declined in each of the past three years. Indeed, in the second and third
quarters of 2003, unit labor costs in the nonfarm business sector are currently estimated
to have declined by a remarkable 3.2 and 5.8 percent, respectively, at annual rates.
Again, because labor costs are such a large part of overall costs, and because
capital costs have also been moderate, the business sector has enjoyed a net decline in
total production costs. A decline in production costs must result in lower prices for final
consumers, an increased price-cost markup for producers, or both. In practice, both have
occurred in recent years: Firms have passed on part of the reduction in costs on to final
consumers in the form oflower (or more slowly rising) prices, and price-cost markups (as
best we can measure them) have risen well above their historical averages. The high
level of markups is an important and perhaps insufficiently recognized feature of the
current economic situation. To the extent that firms can maintain these markups, profits
will continue to be high, supporting investment and equity values. To the extent that
product-market competition erodes these markups, as is likely to occur over time,
downward pressure will be exerted on the inflation rate, even if, as is likely, the recent
declines in unit labor cost do not persist.2

The third unusual factor is the persistent softness of the labor market. As I
already noted, fully two years after the official recession trough, we are only just
beginning to see significant gains in employment. Of course, the unemployment rate, at
about 6 percent of the labor force, is not exceptionally high by historical standards, and
one can debate the degree to which structural change and other factors may have affected
the level of employment that can be sustained without overheating the economy.
Assessing the amount of slack in the labor market is very difficult and ultimately a matter
of judgment. Reasonable people can certainly disagree.
However, my sense is that, when one looks at the full range of information
available, the labor market looks (if anything) weaker than a 6 percent unemployment
rate suggests. For example, it appears that workers who have lost their jobs in the past
couple of years have been more likely to withdraw from the labor force (rather than
report themselves as unemployed) than were job losers in previous recessions. Indeed,
the labor force participation rate fell sharply between 2000 and 2003, from a little over 67
percent to about 66-1/4 percent. Similarly, the ratio of employment to the working-age
population, a statistic that reflects both those who become unemployed and those who
leave the labor force, has fallen significantly, by 2.8 percentage points between its peak
in April 2000 and its trough this past September. The tendency of recent job losers to

leave the labor force likely masks some of the effects of job cuts on the unemployment
rate, so that the current measured level of unemployment may understate the extent of job
loss or the difficulty of finding new work. Of course, a labor market that is slack and
improving only slowly is likely to produce continued slow growth in nominal wages,
contributing to continued moderate growth in costs.
Why has the labor market remained relatively weak, despite increasingly rapid
growth in output? I addressed the causes of the "jobless recovery" in an earlier talk
(Bemanke, 2003). Although many factors have affected the rate of job creation, I
concluded in my earlier analysis that the rapid rate of productivity growth, already
discussed in relation to unit labor costs, has also been an important reason for the slow
pace of recovery in the labor market. All else equal, strong productivity gains allow
firms to meet a given level of demand with fewer employees. Thus, for given growth in
aggregate spending, a higher rate of productivity growth implies a slower rate of growth
in employment.3
To summarize, then, the current economic situation has three unusual aspects,
which together (in my view) rationalize the current stance of monetary policy. First,
inflation is historically low, perhaps at the bottom of the acceptable range, and has
recently continued its decline. Second, rapid productivity growth has led to actual
declines in nominal production costs, which reduce current and future inflationary
pressures. Finally, the labor market remains soft, reflecting the fact that growth in

aggregate demand has been so far insufficient to absorb the increases in aggregate supply
afforded by higher productivity. A soft labor market will keep a lid on the growth in the
cost of employing workers. An accommodative monetary policy is needed, in my view,
to support the ongoing recovery, particularly in the labor market. At the same time, the
risks of policy accommodation seem low, as inflation is low and inflation pressures seem
quite subdued.
These arguments notwithstanding, I realize that some remain unconvinced that the
FOMC is pursuing the right course. Citing factors such as the rise in commodity prices
and the decline of the dollar, a number of observers have warned that the Federal
Reserve's policies risk re-igniting inflation. I would like to address these concerns
briefly. Naturally, I will try to show why these arguments are not of immediate concern,
given the three points I made earlier in support of the current accommodative policy.
Before I do that, though, I would like to emphasize to those uncomfortable with the Fed's
policy stance that, speaking for myself at least, their views are being heard and taken
seriously. Achieving price stability in the United States was an historic accomplishment,
and preserving that legacy is crucially important. I say that not only because I think that
price stability promotes long-run growth and efficiency, which I do, but also because I
believe that low inflation and well-anchored inflation expectations are critical to
maintaining economic stability in the short run. Price stability is of utmost importance to
the nation's economic health, and I believe that the FOMC will do whatever is necessary
to be sure that inflation remains well contained.
With that preface, I will address briefly a few concerns of those who worry that
inflation is poised to rise, beginning with the recent behavior of commodity prices.

A number of commodity price indexes have indeed risen sharply over the past
couple of years, including a large jump in the past several months. This acceleration has
been broadly mirrored in the behavior of the core producer price indexes (PPIs) for crude
and intermediate materials, probably the best and most comprehensive measures of prices
at early stages of processing. Specifically, over the past two years, the twelve-month
change in the core PPI for crude materials has risen rather dramatically, from -9.4
percent to 17.1 percent, and the twelve-month change in the core PPI for intermediate
materials has risen from -1.3 percent to 1.8 percent. Do these developments imply a
significant increase in inflation risk at the level of the fmal consumer?
The answer is almost certainly not. Two points should be made. First, the recent
movements in commodity prices are hardly surprising; they are in fact quite normal for
this stage of the business cycle. The acceleration in the core PPI for crude materials that
we have seen is about what should have been expected, given the increases that have
occurred recently in both domestic and worldwide economic activity.4 The increase in
the demand for commodities from China alone has been substantial; for example, that
country's share of world copper consumption is estimated to have risen from less than 5
percent in 1990 to 20 percent in 2003. The much more moderate acceleration in
intermediate goods prices can likewise be traced to the increase in economic activity,
with some additional effect coming from the decline in the dollar and the indirect impact
of increases in energy prices.
Second, the direct effects of commodity price inflation on consumer inflation are
empirically minuscule, both because raw materials costs are a small portion of total cost
and because part of any increase in the cost of materials tends to be absorbed in the

margins of final goods producers and distributors. Accelerations in commodity prices
comparable to or larger than the most recent one occurred following the 1981-82 and
1990-91 recessions, as well as in 1986-87 and 1999, with no noticeable impact on
inflation at the consumer level.5 A reasonable rule of thumb is that a permanent 10
percent increase in raw materials prices will lead to perhaps a 0.7 percent increase in the
price of intermediate goods and to less than a 0.1 percent increase in consumer prices.
Thus the recent acceleration in commodity prices, even if it were to persist (and futures
prices suggest that it will not), would likely add only a tenth or two to the core inflation
rate. In short, rising commodity prices are a better signal of strengthening economic
activity than of inflation at the consumer level.
Two specific commodity prices that often command attention are the prices of
gold and crude petroleum. The price of gold has increased roughly 60 percent since its
low in April 2001, from about $255 per ounce to about $410 per ounce. A portion of that
increase simply reflects dollar depreciation, which I will discuss momentarily. Gold also
represents a safe haven investment, however, and I agree that there have been periods in
the past when the fear that drove investors into gold was the fear of inflation. But gold
prices also respond to geopolitical tensions; these tensions have certainly heightened
since 2001 and, in my view, can account for the bulk of the recent increase in the real
price of gold.
Oil prices are relatively high, in the range of$33/barrel, but they have been
elevated for most of the past four years, despite a broadly dis inflationary environment.
According to futures markets, oil prices are expected to decline gradually over the next
two years, despite accelerating economic activity, as new supplies are brought on line.

Of course, there is considerable uncertainty about what the price of oil will do, given the
possibility of supply disruptions. But if it follows the course projected by the futures
market, the price of oil should have a modest disinflationary effect on overall consumer
prices in the next couple of years.
Let me turn now to the recent depreciation of the dollar and its implications for
inflation. The dollar has fallen dramatically against some major currencies, notably the
euro, against which the dollar has declined roughly 30 percent from its recent peak in the
first quarter of 2002. However, looking at movements of the dollar against a single
currency can be misleading about overall trends; broader measures of dollar strength
show somewhat less ofa decline. For example, an index of the dollar's real value against
the currencies of important U.S. trading partners, weighted by trade shares, has fallen
only about 12 percent from its peak in the first quarter of 2002. Notably, this broader
index of dollar value remains about 7 percent above its average value in the 1990s and 17
percent above the low it reached in the second quarter of 1995.
Moreover, the direct effects of dollar depreciation on inflation, like those of
commodity price increases, appear to be relatively small. In part, the small effect reflects
the modest weight of imports in the consumer's basket of goods and services. Perhaps
more importantly, however, the evidence suggests that foreign producers tend to absorb
most of the effect of changes in the value of the dollar rather than ''passing through"
these effects to the prices they charge U.S. consumers. A reasonable estimate of the
portion of changes in the value of the dollar passed through to U.S. consumers is about
30 percent. The extent of passthrough also appears to have declined over time,
suggesting that foreign producers also lack ''pricing power" in the current low-inflation

environment in the United States. Overall, on rough estimates, a 10 percent decline in
the broad value of the dollar would be expected to add between one and three tenths to
the level of core consumer prices (not the inflation rate), spread out over a period of time.
I haven't said anything yet about the rate of growth of the money supply, another
indicator that is sometimes cited by those concerned about inflation, largely because there
is not too much to say. Growth in standard monetary measures such as the base and M2
has been moderate (and declining) in recent years, certainly well within expected ranges
given the growth of nominal GDP and normal variation in velocity. For example, for
2003 as a whole, growth in both the monetary base and M2 should be about equal to
growth in nominal GDP. Even should money growth rates accelerate, however, I would
caution against making strong inferences about the likely behavior of inflation, except in
the very long run. Money growth has not proven to be especially useful for predicting
inflation in the short run, in part because various institutional factors unrelated to
monetary policy often affect the growth rate of money. A striking example of the way
special factors can affect money growth rates is the fact that M2 growth has actually been
sharply negative, at about -5 percent at an annual rate, for the past three months for
which data are available. Factors such as the falloff in mortgage refinancing activity and
outflows from retail money market funds into equities and other investments are the
proximate explanations for the decline in M2. Certainly, this short-term decline in broad
money is not to be taken as evidence of tight monetary policy I6
To summarize, 2003 seems to have marked the turning point for the U. S.
economy, and we have reason to be optimistic that 2004 will see even more growth and
continued progress in reducing unemployment. The remarkable strength and resiliency

of the American economy--an economy that has shown the capacity to grow and become
more productive in the face of serious adverse shocks--deserve most of the credit for
these developments. Highly stimulative monetary and fiscal policies have also played a
role, of course.
The Federal Reserve enters 2004 with monetary policy that is unusually
accommodative in historical terms, relative to the stage of the business cycle. That
accommodation is justified, I believe, by the current very low level of inflation, and by
the productivity gains and the weakness in the labor market, both of which suggest that
inflation is likely to remain subdued. In my view, weighing the relative costs of the
upside and downside risks also favors accommodation; in particular, it is important that
we ensure, as best we can, that the current expansion will become self-sustaining and that
the inflation rate does not fall further.
On the other side, as I have already noted, the achievement of price stability must
not and will not be jeopardized We at the Federal Reserve will closely monitor
developments in prices and wages, as well as conditions in the labor market and the
broader economy, for any sign of incipient inflation. We will also look at the information
that can be drawn from surveys and financial markets about inflation expectations. For
now, I believe that the Federal Reserve has the luxury of being patient. However, I am
also confident that, when the time comes, the Fed will act to ensure that inflation remains
firmly under control.

REFERENCES
Bemanke, Ben (2003). "The Jobless Recovery," At the Global Investment and
Economic Outlook Conference, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania,
November 6.
Kohn, Donald (2003). "Productivity and Monetary Policy," At the Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia Monetary Seminar, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, September 24.

I Thanks are due to Sandy Strucktneyer and members of the Board staff for useful comments and
assistance, but they are likewise not responsible for the views expressed here.
2 As employment begins to pick up and the recovery matures, productivity growth is likely to decelerate,
perhaps markedly. Nevertheless, slow growth in wages and the return to normal of price-cost markups
should help keep inflation low.
3 Of course, all else is not necessarily equal. In general, one would expect strong productivity growth to
expand aggregate demand, for example, by stimulating capital formation. However, the stimulative effect
of productivity growth on demand appears to have been weaker than normal in recent years (Kohn, 2003).
Also, the conclusion that productivity growth has contributed to weakjob growth in the short run is in no
way inconsistent with the view that productivity growth raises wages and living standards in the long run,
when full employment has been restored.
4 A part of the increase in the core crude PPI also reflects indirect effects of energy prices (direct effects of
energy prices are excluded from core inflation measures by construction). The depreciation of the dollar,
discussed below, may also have played some role.
5 Commodity prices are also well below previous peaks--indeed, about 15 percent or more below the peaks
reached in 1977, 1980, 1989, and 1995, when weighted by U.S. import shares.
6 The difficulties with using the monetary base as an inflation indicator are even greater than those with
using M2. The base is nearly all (97 percent) currency, about half to two-thirds of which circulates outside
the United States. Hence, to a significant degree, base growth is determined by the foreign demand for
dollars, rather than by economic conditions in the United States.