View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
8:30 a.m. EDT
June 15,2007

The Financial Accelerator and the Credit Channel

Remarks
By
Ben S. Bernanke
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at a conference on
The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy in the Twenty-first Century
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Atlanta, Georgia
June 15,2007

Economic growth and prosperity are created primarily by what economists call
"real" factors--the productivity of the workforce, the quantity and quality of the capital
stock, the availability of land and natural resources, the state of technical knowledge, and
the creativity and skills of entrepreneurs and managers. But extensive practical
experience as well as much formal research highlights the crucial supporting role that
financial factors play in the economy. An entrepreneur with a great new idea for building
a better mousetrap typically must tap financial capital, perhaps from a bank or a venture
capitalist, to transform that idea into a profitable commercial enterprise. To expand and
modernize their plants and increase their staffs, most firms must tum to financial markets
or to financial institutions to secure this essential input. Families rely on the financial
markets to obtain mortgages or to help finance their children's educations. In short,
healthy financial conditions help a modem economy realize its full potential. For this
reason, one of the critical priorities of developing economies is establishing a modem,
well-functioning financial system. In the United States, a deep and liquid financial
system has promoted growth by effectively allocating capital and has increased economic
resilience by increasing our ability to share and diversify risks both domestically and
globally.
Just as a healthy financial system promotes growth, adverse financial conditions
may prevent an economy from reaching its potential. A weak banking system grappling
with nonperforming loans and insufficient capital or firms whose creditworthiness has
eroded because of high leverage or declining asset values are examples of financial

- 2-

conditions that could undermine growth. Japan faced just this kind of challenge when the
financial problems of banks and corporations contributed substantially to sub-par growth
during the so-called "lost decade."
As the topic of this conference reminds us, financial conditions may affect
shorter-term economic conditions as well as the longer-term health ofthe economy.
Notably, some evidence supports the view that changes in financial and credit conditions
are important in the propagation of the business cycle, a mechanism that has been dubbed
the "financial accelerator." Moreover, a fairly large literature has argued that changes in
financial conditions may amplify the effects of monetary policy on the economy, the socalled credit channel of monetary-policy transmission. In fact, as I will discuss, these
two ideas are essentially related. As someone who (in a former life) did research on both
of these topics, I thought it might be useful for me to provide a somewhat personal
overview of the financial accelerator and credit channel ideas and their common
underlying logic. Along the way I will offer a few thoughts on where future research
might be most productive.
Market Frictions and the Real Effects of Financial and Credit Conditions
Economists have not always fully appreciated the importance of a healthy
financial system for economic growth or the role of financial conditions in short-term
economic dynamics. As a matter of intellectual history, the reason is not difficult to
understand. During the first few decades after World War II, economic theorists
emphasized the development of general equilibrium models of the economy with
complete markets; that is, in their analyses, economists generally abstracted from market
"frictions" such as imperfect information or transaction costs. But without such frictions,

-3-

financial markets have little reason to exist. For example, with complete markets (and if
we ignore taxes), we know that whether a corporation finances itself by debt or equity is
irrelevant (the Modigliani-Miller theorem).
The blossoming of work on asymmetric information and principal-agent theory,
led by Nobel laureates Joseph Stiglitz and George Akerlof and with contributions from
many other researchers, gave economists the tools to think about the central role of
financial markets in the real economy. For example, the classic 1976 paper by Michael
Jensen and William Meckling showed that, in a world of imperfect information and
principal-agent problems, the capital structure of the firm could be used as a tool by
shareholders to better align the incentives of managers with the shareholders' interests.
Thus was born a powerful and fruitful rejoinder to the Modigliani-Miller neutrality result
and, more broadly, a perspective on capital structure that has had enduring influence.
My own first job as an academic was at Stanford University, where I arrived as an
assistant professor in the Graduate School of Business in 1979. At the time, Stanford was
a hotbed of work on asymmetric information, incentives, and the principal-agent
problem; and even though my field was macroeconomics, I was heavily influenced by
that intellectual environment. I became particularly interested in how this perspective on
financial markets could help explain why financial crises--that is, extreme disruptions of
the normal functioning of financial markets--seem often to have a significant impact on
the real economy. Putting the issue in the context of U.S. economic history, I laid out, in
a 1983 article, two channels by which the financial problems of the 1930s may have
worsened the Great Depression (Bernanke, 1983).

- 4-

The first channel worked through the banking system. As emphasized by the
information-theoretic approach to finance, a central function of banks is to screen and
monitor borrowers, thereby overcoming information and incentive problems. By
developing expertise in gathering relevant information, as well as by maintaining ongoing
relationships with customers, banks and similar intermediaries develop "informational
capital." The widespread banking panics of the 1930s caused many banks to shut their
doors; facing the risk of runs by depositors, even those who remained open were forced
to constrain lending to keep their balance sheets as liquid as possible. Banks were thus
prevented from making use of their informational capital in normal lending activities.
The resulting reduction in the availability of bank credit inhibited consumer spending and
capital investment, worsening the contraction.
The second channel through which financial crises affected the real economy in
the 1930s operated through the creditworthiness of borrowers. In general, the availability
of collateral facilitates credit extension. The ability of a financially healthy borrower to
post collateral reduces the lender's risks and aligns the borrower's incentives with those
of the lender. However, in the 1930s, declining output and falling prices (which
increased real debt burdens) led to widespread financial distress among borrowers,
lessening their capacity to pledge collateral or to otherwise retain significant equity
interests in their proposed investments. Borrowers' cash flows and liquidity were also
impaired, which likewise increased the risks to lenders. Overall, the decline in the
financial health of potential borrowers during the Depression decade further impeded the
efficient allocation of credit. Incidentally, this information-based explanation of how the
sharp deflation in prices in the 1930s may have had real effects was closely related to,

-5-

and provided a formal rationale for, the idea of "debt-deflation," advanced by Irving
Fisher in the early 1930s (Fisher, 1933).
The External Finance Premium and the Financial Accelerator

Both real and monetary shocks produced the Great Depression, and in my 1983
paper I argued that banking and financial markets propagated both types of impulses,
without distinguishing sharply between the two. My subsequent research and that of
many others looked separately at the role of financial conditions in amplifying both
monetary and nonmonetary influences.
On the nonmonetary side, Mark Gertler and I showed how, in principle, the
effects of a real shock (such as a shock to productivity) on financial conditions could lead
to persistent fluctuations in the economy, even if the initiating shock had little or no
intrinsic persistence (Bemanke and Gertler, 1989). A key concept in our analysis was the
external finance premium, defined as the difference between the cost to a borrower of
raising funds externally and the opportunity cost of internal funds. External finance
(raising funds from lenders) is virtually always more expensive than internal finance
(using internally generated cash flows), because of the costs that outside lenders bear of
evaluating borrowers' prospects and monitoring their actions. Thus, the external finance
premium is generally positive. Moreover, the theory predicts that the external finance
premium that a borrower must pay should depend inversely on the strength of the
borrower's financial position, measured in terms of factors such as net worth, liquidity,
and current and future expected cash flows. Fundamentally, a financially strong
borrower has more "skin in the game," so to speak, and consequently has greater
incentives to make well-informed investment choices and to take the actions needed to

- 6ensure good financial outcomes. Because of the good incentives that flow from the
borrower's having a significant stake in the enterprise and the associated reduction in the
need for intensive evaluation and monitoring by the lender, borrowers in good financial
condition generally pay a lower premium for external finance.!
The inverse relationship of the external finance premium and the financial
condition of borrowers creates a channel through which otherwise short-lived economic
shocks may have long-lasting effects. In the hypothetical case that Gertler and I
analyzed, an increase in productivity that improves the cash flows and balance sheet
positions of firms leads in tum to lower external finance premiums in subsequent periods,
which extends the expansion as firms are induced to continue investing even after the
initial productivity shock has dissipated. This "financial accelerator" effect applies in
principle to any shock that affects borrower balance sheets or cash flows. The concept is
useful in that it can help to explain the persistence and amplitude of cyclical fluctuations
in a modem economy.
Although the financial accelerator seems intuitive--certainly financial and credit
conditions tend to be procyclical--nailing down this mechanism empirically has not
proven entirely straightforward. For example, empirical studies of business investment in
structures, equipment, and inventories have often found that a firm's cash flow
significantly determines its level of investment and that the link between cash flow and
investment tends to be stronger for firms (such as relatively small firms) that have more
limited access to capital markets. 2 In a "frictionless" capital market in which borrowers
do not face an external finance premium, a firm's cash position would be irrelevant to its
decision to invest because efficient capital markets would supply any necessary funding

-7for investment projects expected to yield a positive net return. Thus, findings of a
positive association between cash flow and investment tends to support the financial
accelerator theory.
These findings also raise issues and questions, however. I will mention two.
First, as a number of researchers have pointed out, the apparent empirical link between
cash flow and investment may arise because cash flow proxies for difficult-to-measure
factors like the prospective return on investment, which would be relevant to the
investment decision even without capital-market frictions. This identification problem is
a difficult one. However, some work that has attempted to correct for this possible
misspecification has still found a role for cash flow (see, for example, Gilchrist and
Himmelberg, 1999). Second, if only the smallest firms have significant external finance
premiums, as implied by some research, then the macroeconomic significance of the
financial accelerator may be questioned. One response to this point, pursued by several
researchers, has been to dispute the claim that small firms do not playa significant role in
business-cycle fluctuations. For example, small firms apparently account for a
significant portion of cyclical changes in employment and inventory stocks. Another
response has been to argue that even large firms with relatively good access to capital
markets may face nontrivial external finance premiums. For instance, using a sample that
included large public companies, researchers at the Board have estimated external finance
premiums of economically significant magnitudes, and they showed that these premiums
rose sharply during the 2001 recession, as predicted by the financial accelerator theory
(Levin, Natalucci, and Zakrajsek, 2004; Levin and Natalucci, 2005).

-8Financial accelerator effects need not be confined to firms and capital spending
but may operate through household spending decisions as well. 3 Household borrowers,
like firms, presumably face an external finance premium, which is lower the stronger
their financial position. For households, home equity is often a significant part of net
worth. Certainly, households with low mortgage loan-to-value ratios can borrow on
relatively favorable terms through home-equity lines of credit, with the equity in their
home effectively serving as collateral. Ifthe financial accelerator hypothesis is correct,
changes in home values may affect household borrowing and spending by somewhat
more than suggested by the conventional wealth effect because changes in homeowners'
net worth also affect their external finance premiums and thus their costs of credit. If
true, this hypothesis has various interesting implications. For example, unlike the
standard view based on the wealth effect, this approach would suggest that the
distribution of housing wealth across the population matters because the effect on
aggregate consumption of a given decline in house prices is greater, the greater the
fraction of consumers who begin with relatively low home equity. Another possible
implication is that the structure of mortgage contracts may matter for consumption
behavior. In countries like the United Kingdom, for example, where most mortgages
have adjustable rates, changes in short-term interest rates (whether induced by monetary
policy or some other factor) have an almost immediate effect on household cash flows. If
household cash flows affect access to credit, then consumer spending may react relatively
quickly. In an economy where most mortgages carry fixed rates, such as the United
States, that channel of effect may be more muted. I do not think we know at this point

-9whether, in the case of households, these effects are quantitatively significant in the
aggregate. Certainly, these issues seem worthy of further study.
Monetary Policy and the Credit Channel

The ideas I have been discussing today have also been useful in understanding the
nature of the monetary policy transmission process. Some evidence suggests that the
influence of monetary policy on real variables is greater than can be explained by the
traditional "cost-of-capital" channel, which holds that monetary policy affects borrowing,
investment, and spending decisions solely through its effect on the level of market
interest rates. This finding has led researchers to look for supplementary channels
through which monetary policy may affect the economy. One such supplementary
channel, the so-called credit channel, holds that monetary policy has additional effects
because interest-rate decisions affect the cost and availability of credit by more than
would be implied by the associated movement in risk-free interest rates, such as Treasury
rates. The credit channel, in tum, has traditionally been broken down into two
components or channels of policy influence: the balance-sheet channel and the banklending channel (Bernanke and Gertler, 1995). The balance-sheet channel of monetary
policy is closely related to the idea of the financial accelerator that I have already
discussed. That theory builds from the premise that changes in interest rates engineered
by the central bank affect the values of the assets and the cash flows of potential
borrowers and thus their creditworthiness, which in tum affects the external finance
premium that borrowers face. For example, according to this view, a tightening of
monetary policy that reduces the net worth and liquidity of borrowers would increase the

- 10effective cost of credit by more than the change in risk-free rates and thus would intensify
the effect of the policy action.
In the interest oftime I will confine the remainder of my remarks to the banklending channel. The theory of the bank-lending channel holds that monetary policy
works in part by affecting the supply of loans offered by depository institutions. This
concept is a cousin of the idea I proposed in my paper on the Great Depression, that the
failures of banks during the 1930s destroyed "information capital" and thus reduced the
effective supply of credit to borrowers. Alan Blinder and I adapted this general idea to
show how, by affecting banks' loanable funds, monetary policy could influence the
supply of intermediated credit (Bernanke and Blinder, 1988).
Historically, monetary policy did appear to affect the supply of bank loans (at any
given level of interest rates). In the 1960s and 1970s, when reserve requirements were
higher and more comprehensive than they are today, Federal Reserve open market
operations that drained reserves from the banking system tended to force a contraction in
deposits. Regulation Q, which capped interest rates payable on deposits, prevented banks
from offsetting the decline in deposits by offering higher interest rates. Moreover, banks
had limited alternatives to deposits as a funding source. Thus, monetary tightening
typically resulted in a shrinking of banks' balance sheets and a diversion of funds away
from the banking system, a phenomenon known as disintermediation. The extension of
credit to bank-dependent borrowers, which included many firms as well as households,
was consequently reduced, with implications for spending and economic activity.
Of course, much has changed in U.S. banking and financial markets since the
1960s and 1970s. Reserve requirements are lower and apply to a smaller share of

- 11 -

deposits than in the past. Regulation Q is gone. And the capital markets have become
deep, liquid, and easily accessible, either directly or indirectly, to almost all depository
institutions. Although the traditional bank-lending channel may still be operative in
economies that remain relatively more bank-dependent, as recent research has found for
some European countries (Ehrmann and others, 2003), in the United States today it seems
unlikely to be quantitatively important.
This is not to say, however, that financial intermediation no longer matters for
monetary policy and the transmission of economic shocks. For example, although banks
and other intermediaries no longer depend exclusively on insured deposits for funding,
nondeposit sources of funding are likely to be relatively more expensive than deposits,
reflecting the credit risks associated with uninsured lending (Stein, 1998). Moreover, the
cost and availability of non deposit funds for any given bank will depend on the perceived
creditworthiness of the institution. Thus, the concerns of holders of uninsured bank
liabilities about bank credit quality generate an external finance premium for banks that is
similar to that faced by other borrowers. The external finance premium paid by banks is
presumably reflected in turn in the cost and availability of funds to bank-dependent
borrowers. Importantly, this way of casting the bank-lending channel unifies the
financial accelerator and credit channel concepts, as the central mechanism of both is
seen to be the external finance premium and its relationship to borrowers' balance sheets.
The only difference is that the financial accelerator focuses on the ultimate borrowers-firms and households--whereas financial intermediaries are the relevant borrowers in the
theory of the credit channel. By the way, the existence ofloan sales and the originate-todistribute model of bank lending does not fundamentally change this picture. Loan sales

- 12-

and similar activities are, in essence, another form of nondeposit financing, and the
effective cost of this form of funding to the bank will generally depend on its perceived
financial strength and resources (which may affect recourse and reinsurance
arrangements with the loan purchasers, for example).
Recently, researchers have pursued a number of approaches in search of evidence
of a distinct banking channel. For example, some researchers have focused on smaller
banks, which may have fewer funding alternatives to deposits and whose customer base
may consist disproportionately of bank-dependent borrowers (Kashyap and Stein, 2000).
Of course, these days, even the smallest of banks has ready access to sources of funds
other than retail deposits. Thus, even for the smallest banks, the source of any banklending channel remains the existence of a finance premium on marginal sources of
(uninsured) nondeposit funding, rather than an absolute constraint on the quantity of
available funding. Moreover, for the bank channel to affect economic activity, borrowers
accustomed to relying on banks must be unable to tum to other lenders, at least not
without some cost. For some business borrowers, particularly small business borrowers
that rely on banking relationships, this scenario is plausible. 4 But financial innovation
and deregulation imply that borrowers in the market for a mortgage or consumer credit
have numerous nonbank financing alternatives, blunting any direct impact of changes in
bank lending. I will return to nonbank lending and its implications in a moment.
If relationship borrowing is the key, then--as pointed out in the paper at this
conference by Black, Hancock, and Passmore--a bank with many such borrowers might
defensively invest in deposit capacity, say, by increasing the number of branches. By
actively seeking to finance a high share of loans with insured deposits, such a bank could

- 13 shield its borrowers from the effects of increases in the nondeposit finance premium,
whether the result of monetary policy or some other factor. Consistent with this idea,
these authors find that banks that make a large share of their loans to small businesses
also tend to have a high ratio of deposits to loans.
The recognition that, fundamentally, the bank-lending channel is based on
changes in the quality of bank balance sheets naturally turns our attention to bank capital
and its determinants (Van den Heuvel, 2002). Raising new capital on the open market
can be difficult and costly for many banks, implying that, in the short run, capital is
determined by earnings and changes in asset values. Changes in the value of capital,
particularly when a bank's capital is not much higher than the level demanded by
regulators or the market, potentially affects the bank's cost of funds. In conformity with
this hypothesis, various studies have found evidence that loans provided by banks that are
more capital-constrained seem more sensitive to changes in market interest rates than
loans provided by highly capitalized banks.5 Moreover, changes in the financial
condition of banks may playa role in cyclical developments. I have already mentioned
the cases of Japan's "lost decade." Closer to home, some believe that the U.S.
economy's recovery from the 1990-91 recession was delayed by "financial headwinds,"
which arose from regional shortages of bank capital (Bernanke and Lown, 1991).
One might view the idea that banks are somehow "special" in their ability to
gather information and to screen and monitor borrowers as rather dated. Banks do
continue to playa central role in credit markets; in particular, because of the burgeoning
market for loan sales, banks originate considerably more loans than they keep on their
books. Nevertheless, nonbank lenders have become increasingly important in many

- 14-

credit markets, and relatively few borrowers are restricted to banks as sources of credit.
Of course, nonbank lenders do not have access to insured deposits. However, they can
fund loans by borrowing on capital markets or by selling loans to securitizers. Does the
rise of nonbank lenders make the bank-lending channel irrelevant?
I am not so sure that it does. Like banks, nonbank lenders have to raise funds in
order to lend, and the cost at which they raise those funds will depend on their financial
condition--their net worth, their leverage, and their liquidity, for example. Thus, nonbank
lenders also face an external finance premium that presumably can be influenced by
economic developments or monetary policy. The level of the premium they pay will in
tum affect the rates that they can offer borrowers. Thus, the ideas underlying the banklending channel might reasonably extend to all private providers of credit. Further
investigation of this possibility would be quite worthwhile.
Conclusion

I have taken you on a whirlwind tour of several decades of research on how
variations in the financial condition of borrowers, whether arising from changes in
monetary policy or from other forces, can affect short-term economic dynamics. The
critical idea is that the cost of funds to borrowers depends inversely on their
creditworthiness, as measured by indicators such as net worth and liquidity. Endogenous
changes in creditworthiness may increase the persistence and amplitude of business
cycles (the financial accelerator) and strengthen the influence of monetary policy (the
credit channel). As I have noted today, what has been called the bank-lending channel-the idea that banks playa special role in the transmission of monetary policy--can be
integrated into this same broad logical framework, if we focus on the link between the

- 15 bank's financial condition and its cost of capital. Nonbank lenders may well be subject to
the same forces.
Let me conclude by offering you best wishes for a stimulating and enjoyable last
day of the conference. Policymakers and scholars both will benefit from your efforts.

- 16-

References
Almeida, Heitor, Murillo Campello, and Crocker H. Liu (2006). "The Financial
Accelerator: Evidence from International Housing Markets," Review ofFinance,
vol. 10 (September), pp. 1-32.
Aoki, Kosuki, James Proudman, and Gertjan Vlieghe (2002). "Houses as Collateral: Has
the Link between House Prices and Consumption in the u.K. Changed?" Economic
Policy Review, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, May, pp. 163-77
-----------------------------------------------(2004). "House Prices, Consumption, and Monetary
Policy: A Financial Accelerator Approach," Journal ofFinancial Intermediation,
vol. 13 (October), pp. 414-35.
Avery, Robert B., and Katherine A. Samolyk (2004). "Bank Consolidation and the
Provision of Banking Services: Small Commercial Loans," Journal ofFinancial
Services Research, vol. 25 (April), pp. 291-325.
Bemanke, Ben S. (1983). "Non-Monetary Effects ofthe Financial Crisis in the Propagation
ofthe Great Depression," American Economic Review, vol. 73 (June), pp. 257-76.
Bernanke, Ben S., and Alan S. Blinder (1988). "Credit, Money, and Aggregate Demand,"
American Economic Review, vol. 78, Papers and Proceedings of the 100th Annual
Meeting of the American Economics Association, May, pp. 435-39.
Bernanke, Ben S., and Mark Gertler (1989). "Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business
Fluctuations," American Economic Review, vol. 79 (March), pp. 14-31.
--------------------------------------(1995). "Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of
Monetary Policy Transmission, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 9 (Fall),
pp.27-48.
Bernanke, Ben S., Mark Gertler, and Simon Gilchrist (1999). "The Financial Accelerator in
a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework," in Handbook ofMacroeconomics,
Volume lC, Handbooks in Economics, vol. 15. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 1341-93.
Bernanke, Ben S., and Cara S. Lown (1991). "The Credit Crunch," Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, 1991:2, pp. 205-39.
Black, Lamont, Diana Hancock, and Wayne Passmore (2007). "Bank Core Deposits and
the Mitigation of Monetary Policy," unpublished paper, Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, June.
Calomiris, Charles W., Charles P. Himmelberg, and Paul Wachtel (1995). "Commercial
Paper, Corporate Finance and the Business Cycle: A Microeconomic Perspective,"
Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, vol. 42 (June), pp. 203-50.

- 17 -

Carlstrom, CharlesT., and Timothy S. Fuerst (2001). "Monetary Policy in a World without
Perfect Capital Markets," Working Paper 0115, Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland.
Carpenter, Robert E., Steven M. Fazzari, and Bruce C. Petersen (1998). "Financing
Constraints and Inventory Investment: A Comparative Study with High-Frequency
Panel Data," Review ofEconomics and Statistics, vol. 80 (December), pp. 513-19.
Ehrmann, Michael, Leonardo Gambacorta, Jorge Martinez-Pages, Patrick Sevestre, and
Andreas Worms (2003). "Financial Systems and the Role of Banks in Monetary
Policy Transmission in the Euro Area," in Ignazio Angeloni, Anil K Kashyap, and
Benoit Mojon, eds., Monetary Policy Transmission in the Euro area: A Study by the
Eurosystem Monetary Transmission Network,. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Fisher, Irving (1933). "The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions," Econometrica,
vol. 1 (October), pp. 337-57.
Gambacorta, Leonardo (2005). "Inside the Bank Lending Channel," European Economic
Review, vol. 49 (October), pp. 1737-59.
Gilchrist, Simon, and Charles Himmelberg (1999). "Investment, Fundamentals and
Finance," in Ben S. Bemanke and Julio Rotemberg, eds. NBER Macroeconomics
Annual 1998. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Iacoviello, Matteo (2005). "House Prices, Borrowing Constraints, and Monetary Policy in
the Business Cycle," American Economic Review, vol. 95 (June), pp. 739-64.
Jensen, Michael c., and William H. Meckling (1976). "Theory ofthe Firm: Managerial
Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure," Journal of Financial
Economics, vol. 3 (October), pp. 305-60.
Kashyap, Anil K, and Jeremy C. Stein (2000). "What Do a Million Observations on Banks
Say about the Transmission of Monetary Policy?" American Economic Review, vol.
90 (June), pp. 407-28.
Kishan, Ruby P., and Timothy Opiela (2000). "Bank Size, Bank Capital, and the Bank
Lending Channel," Journal ofMoney, Credit, and Banking, vol. 32 (February), pp.
121-41.
------------------------------- (2006). "Bank Capital and Loan Asymmetry in the Transmission
of Monetary Policy, " Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 30 (January), pp. 25985.
Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and John Moore (1997). "Credit Cycles," Journal ofPolitical

- 18 Economy, vol. 105 (April), pp. 211-48.
Levin, Andrew T., and Fabbio M. Natalucci (2005). "The Magnitude and Cyclical
Behavior of Financial Market Frictions," 2005 Meeting Papers 443, Society for
Economic Dynamics.
Levin, Andrew T., Fabbio M. Natalucci, and Egon Zakrajsek (2004). "The Magnitude and
Cyclical Behavior of Financial Market Frictions," Finance and Economics
Discussion Series 2004-70, Board of Govemors ofthe Federal Reserve System,
December.
Stein, Jeremy C. (1998). "An Adverse-Selection Model of Bank Asset and Liability
Management with Implications for the Transmission of Monetary Policy," RAND
Journal ofEconomics, vol. 29 (Autumn), pp. 466-86.
Van den Heuvel, Skander (2002). "Does Bank Capital Matter for Monetary
Transmission?" Economic Policy Review, Federal Reserve Bank of New York
(May), pp. 1-7.

lOver the past two decades, an extensive theoretical literature has exploited the idea that borrowers'
financial positions affect their external finance premiums and thus their overall cost of credit. See, for
example, Bernanke and Gertler (1989), Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist
(1999), Carlstrom and Fuerst (2001), Aoki, Proudman and Vlieghe (2004), and Iacoviello (2005).
2 Calomiris, Himmelberg and Wachtel,(1995), Carpenter, Fazzari and Petersen (1998), and Gilchrist and
Himrnelberg (1999).
3 See Aoki, Proudman and Vlieghe (2002, 2004), Iacoviello (2005), and Almeida, Campello and Liu
(2006).
4 In recent years, community banks appear to have become increasingly important in lending to small
businesses (Avery and Samolyk, 2004).
5 Kishan and Opiela, (2000), Kishan and Opiela, (2006), and Gambacorta (2005).