View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery

Statement by-

Arthur F, Burns

Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Committee on Banking and Currency

House of Representatives

July 30, 1974

I am pleased to appear before this Committee today to
discuss the six questions posed by Chairman Patman*s letter
of June 19* 1974.

The several areas addressed by these questions

are of great interest, particularly to professional economists.
My comments on them convey the basic thinking of the Board
of Governors, and will - - I believe — be responsive to the
Committee1 s needs.
I must, however, go beyond a narrow or technical interpretation of these questions.

Rapidly rising prices, rapidly

rising wages, rapidly rising interest rates - - these are the
burning economic issues of our time.

My testimony today will

seek to identify the sources of this menacing inflationary problem
and to outline the course that public policy must take to restore
price stability.
The first question raised by Chairman Patman concerns
the reliability of the trade-off between inflation and unemployment the so-called Phillips curve - - as a guide for monetary policy.
The discovery some years ago of a statistical correlation between
the rate of inflation and the rate of unemployment seemed to offer
a straightforward choice to policy makers.

These early studies - -

using data first for the British economy, later for the United
States and other economies - - suggested that unemployment
could be reduced if a nation were willing to put up with more
inflation, and that advances in the general price level could be
slowed down if a higher rate of unemployment were tolerated.
Further research and subsequent developments have
indicated, however, that simple statistical correlations of this
kind are misleading.

The forces affecting economic activity

and prices in a modern economy are far too complex to be
described by a simple mathematical equation.
We found in 1970 and early 1971, for example, that
increases in wage rates and prices may continue - - and even
accelerate - - i n the face of rising unemployment and declining
real output.

The experience of the United States in this regard

was not unique: similar developments occurred at about the
same time in Canada, and the United Kingdom.
We have also come to recognize that public policies that
create excess aggregate demand, and thereby drive up wage
rates and prices, will not result in any lasting reduction in
unemployment.

On the contrary, such policies - - i f long

continued - - lead ultimately to galloping inflation, to loss of
confidence in the future, and to economic stagnation.

The central objective of monetary and fiscal policies
should be to foster lasting prosperity - - a prosperity in which
men and women looking for work are able to find work; a prosperity in which incomes and savings are protected against inflation;
a prosperity that can be enjoyed by all.

Of late, such a prosperity

has eluded us, because we have not yet found a way to bring an
end to inflation.
Let me turn to your second question, concerning the
benefits and risks involved in the Federal Reserve accommodating
increases of the general price level that originate in supply shortfalls and other special events.
Prices in the United States have been affected heavily
in the past several years by a variety of special factors.

Dis-

appointing harvests in 1972 -~ both here and abroad -~ caused
a sharp run-up of food prices in 1973. Beginning in the fall of
last year, the manipulation of petroleum shipments and prices
by oil-exporting countries led to huge increases in the price of
gasoline, heating oil, and related products.
Furthermore, a world-wide boom in economic activity
during 1972 and 1973 led to a bidding up of prices everywhere,
In the United States, larger foreign orders for industrial materials,
component parts, and capital equipment added to growing domestic
demands.

Pressures became particularly intense in the major

-4-

materials industries - - such as steel, aluminum, cement,
paper - - i n which expansion of capacity had been limited in
earlier years by low profits and environmental controls.
The impact of world-wide inflation was especially severe
in the United States because of the decline in the exchange value
of the dollar relative to other currencies.

Besides stimulating

our export trade, and thereby reinforcing the pressures of
domestic demand on available resources, devaluation raised
the dollar prices of imported products, and these effects spread
through our markets.
More recently, the removal of controls over wages and
prices has led to sharp upward adjustments in both our labor
and commodity markets.
It has at times been suggested that monetary policy
could have prevented these special factors from affecting
significantly the average level of wholesale and consumer
prices.

That may well be true, but the cost of such a policy

should not be underestimated.

Last year, about 60 per cent

of the rise in consumer prices was accounted for by food and
fuel; for wholesale prices, the proportion was even higher.
To achieve stability in the average price level, it would therefore have been necessary to bring down very sharply the prices
of other goods and services.

Prices of many commodities « particularly farm products
and industrial raw materials - - are established in highly competitive markets and are therefore capable of declining as well
as rising.

The prices of many other commodities and services

that make up the gross national product, however, are nowadays
rather inflexible in a downward direction, in large part because
of the persistent upward push of labor costs and imperfect business competition.

For these commodities, significant price

declines could be achieved only by drastically restrictive policies - policies that would lead to widespread bankruptcies and mass
unemployment.

A monetary policy that sought to offset completely

the effects on the average price level of the rising cost of food,
petroleum products, and other commodities whose prices were
so heavily influenced during the past two years by special factors,
would clearly have been undesirable.
Nevertheless, monetary policy must not permit sufficient
growth in money and credit supplies to accommodate all of the
price increases that are directly or indirectly attributable to
special factors.

The rise in the price of petroleum, for example,

has increased the costs of energy, plastics, petroleum-based
chemicals, and other materials.

Business firms will endeavor

to pass these higher costs through to consumers.

Workers,

too, will bargain for larger wage increases, in order to
compensate for declines in their real incomes.

To the extent

that wage increases outrun gains in productivity, business
costs - - and ultimately consumer prices - - are driven up.
Thus, in addition to their direct effects on prices, special
factors may have large and widespread secondary effects on
the price level.
A monetary policy that accommodated all of these price
increases could result in an endless cost-price spiral and a
serious worsening of an already grave inflationary problem.
The appropriate course for monetary policy is the middle
ground.

The price rigidities characteristic of modern

industrialized economies must be recognized, but a full passthrough of all the price effects stemming from special factors
must not be permitted.
The middle course of policy we have adopted has resulted
in a growth rate of the narrowly-defined money supply »- currency
and demand deposits - - o f about 6 per cent during the past 12
months.

This rate of growth is still too high for stability of

average prices over the longer term.

But moderation in the

growth rate of money and credit supplies must be achieved

gradually to avoid upsetting effects on the real economy.

This

is particularly true now, when price-cost relations are seriously
distorted.
I turn now to Chairman Patman's third question, which
relates to the positive elements and the risks involved in monetizing deficit spending.

The simple fact is that financing Federal

deficits by printing money involves risks, and the risks are
grave.
Fortunately, since 1951, monetary policy in this country ,
has not been conducted with an eye to providing a ready market
for Treasury securities, or for financing Federal deficits*
Considerations of this kind were an objective of Federal Reserve
policy during World War II, when Treasury borrowing proceeded
on an unprecedented scale in relation to the size of our economy.
1 doubt if such a policy was warranted even under war-time
circumstances, and its continuation in the years immediately
after the war was a very serious mistake*

It led to excessive

increases in borrowing by private firms, consumers, and State
and local governments, and thus fueled the subsequent inflation.
The dangers inherent in this situation became acutely
evident during the Korean War, when Federal deficits once
again threatened*

With the aid of prodding by the Congress^

particularly by Senator Douglas, the Federal Reserve and
the Treasury resolved their disagreements, and monetary
policy returned to its traditional role of regulating the supply
of money and credit in the interest of economic stability.
Since then, the Treasury has financed its deficits at prevailing
market interest rates in competition with other borrowers.
During periods of large Treasury financings, the Federal
Reserve follows the practice of maintaining neven-keel?l in the
money market -~ that is, we refrain from taking overt actions
that market participants might interpret as a change in monetary
policy.
n

On some occasions, therefore, the maintenance of

even-keei n has delayed the timing of changes in monetary policy.

Treasury financijq.g operations thus pose problems for monetary
policy, particularly when they are large and frequent.
Federal deficit financing becomes a major source of
economic and financial instability when it occurs during periods
of high economic activity, as it has in recent years.

The huge

Federal deficits of the past decade have added enormously to
aggregate demand for goods and services, and have thus been
directly responsible for upward pressures on the price level.
Heavy borrowing by the Federal sector has also been an important

contributing factor to the persistent rise in interest rates, and
to the strains that have at times developed in money and capital
markets.

Worse still, continuation of budget deficits has tended

to undermine the confidence of the public in the capacity of our
government to deal with inflation.
If the present inflationary problem is to be solved, and
interest rates brought down to reasonable levels, the Federal
budget must be brought into better balance.

This is the most

important single step that could be taken to restore the confidence
of people in their own and our nation's economic future*
Let me turn, neict, to the Committee's fourth question,
dealing with the benefits and risks of the Federal Reserve's
fighting money-market fires.
As this Committee well knows,* the cardinal aim of
monetary policy is maintenance of a financial environment in
which our national objectives of full employment and price
stability can be realized.

For the most part, this responsibility

is best achieved by striving for appropriate growth rates of
the monetary aggregates, and letting financial markets take
care of themselves.

-10-

The appropriate monetary growth rates will vary with
economic conditions.

They are apt to be higher during periods

of economic weakness, when aggregate spending is in need of
stimulus., than when the economy is booming and inflationary
tendencies threaten economic stability*

Special circumstances

may, however, call for monetary growth rates that deviate from
this general rule.

For example, as noted in my response to

the second question, the special factors giving rise to extraordinary price pressures during the past year or two have
required toleration of a monetary growth rate that has been
relatively high by historical standards.
There are times when responsibility for maintaining
financial and economic stability requires the Federal Reserve
to focus attention primarily on factors other than growth in the
money supply or bank credit.

The oldest and most traditional

function of a central bank is to act as a lender of last resort - that is, to provide liquidity when dislocation of financial markets
threatens serious damage to the economy.

Acting in this capacity,

the Federal Reserve in the summer of 1970 warded off a developing liquidity crisis in the commercial paper market.

This

year, difficulties encountered by a large commerical bank led

-11-

to rumors of widespread illiquidity of the commercial banking
system.

These concerns were reduced by timely Federal Reserve

action at the discount window.
It so happens that in neither of these instances did the
Federal Reserve's intervention result in a significant deviation
of the monetary aggregates from desired growth rates,

But let

there be no mistake about our determination to deal with financial troubles*

In the future, as in the past, we will surely not

stand aloof and permit a crisis to develop out of devotion to this
or that preconceived growth rate of the money supply.
The responsibility of the Federal Reserve for conditions
in the money and capital markets goes beyond its historic function
to act as lender of last resort,

Monetary policies need to be

implemented, 1 believe, in ways that avoid large and erratic
fluctuations in interest rates and money market conditions.
From one month to the next, the public's demand for
money is subject to variations that are usually of a short-run
nature.

For example, a large tax refund, a retroactive increase

in social security benefit payments, or a sizable disbursement
by the Treasury of revenue-sharing funds may produce a temporary bulge in the demand for cash balances.

If the Federal

12-

Reserve tried to maintain a rigid monetary growth rate in the
face of such developments, interest rates could fluctuate widely,
and to no good end*

The costs of financial intermediation would

be increased, and the course of monetary policy might be misinterpreted.

To avoid these harmful effects, the Federal Reserve

seeks to achieve desired growth rates of money and credit over
relatively long periods.

Experience over the past two decades

suggests that even an abnormally large or abnormally small
rate of growth of the money stock over a period of 6 months
or so has a negligible effect on the course of the economy - provided it is subsequently offset.
We recognize, of course, that too much attention to
preventing short-.run fluctuations in interest rates could inadvertently cause the growth rate of money or credit to drift
away from what is appropriate for the longer run.

To guard

against this possibility, the Federal Reserve in early 1972
introduced a new set of procedures for implementing monetary
policy,

These procedures focus more attention on provision

of bank reserves through open market operations at a pace
consistent with, desired growth rates of monetary and banking
aggregates.

-13-

The new procedures have been helpful,, but numerous
problems of monetary control still remain*

For example, a

substantial part of the money supply is in the form of deposits
at nonmember banks* As a consequence of this and other
factors, there is considerable slippage between the supply
of bank reserves controlled by the Federal Reserve and the
nation's money supply.

Monetary control is therefore less

precise than it could or should be.

I would once again urge

the Congress to correct this defect by extending the Federal
Reserve's power over reserve requirements to all commercial
banks*
Let me turn next to Chairman Patman1 s fifth question,
which deals with the relationship that interest rates ? the moneysupply, and the rate of inflation bear to one another.
Most interest rates in the United States are now at the
highest levels in our history*

There are some who believe that

restrictive monetary and credit policies are responsible for
this state of affairs,

This view is erroneous.

The basic

reason why interest rates have risen to their present level is
the accelerating pace of price advances over the past decade,
so that we now find

ourselves in the midst of a two-digit inflation.

-14-

Historical evidence - - from other countries as well
as our own -~ indicates beyond any doubt that inflation and
high interest rates go together.
understand.

The reasons are not hard to

In most countries throughout the Western world,

inflationary expectations have become deeply imbedded in the
calculations of lenders and borrowers.

Lenders now reckon

that loans will probably be repaid in dollars of lesser value,
and they therefore hold out for nominal rates of interest high
enough to assure them a reasonable real rate of return.

Bor-

rowers, on their part> are less resistant to rising costs of
credit when they anticipate repayment in cheaper dollars.
Interest rates at anything like present levels are
deplorable.

They cause hardships to individuals and pose a

threat to the viability of some of our industries and financial
institutions.

But we cannot realistically expect any lasting

decline in the level of interest rates until inflation is brought
under control.
History also indicates that high rates of inflation are
typically accompanied by high growth rates in supplies of
money and credit.

But inflationary tendencies and monetary

expansion are not as closely related as is sometimes imagined.

-15-

For example, the econometric model of the St. Louis Federal
Reserve Bank, which assigns a major role to growth of the
money stock in movements of the general price level, has
seriously underestimated the rate of inflation since the
beginning of 1973, Simulations of the model, using the
actual growth rates of the money supply since the first
quarter of 1972, suggest that the rate of inflation during the
past two quarters should have been a mere 3-1/2 per cent.
Apparently, special factors - - such as 1 mentioned previously -«
have been at work.
Inflationary processes are characterized by rising turnover rates of the existing stock of money as well as by relatively
high rates of monetary expansion.

Recent experience in the

United States illustrates this fact.

Over the past ten years,

the average annual increase in the money stock has been about
6 per cent - - a higher rate than in the previous decade.

Since

1964, however, the income velocity of money — that is, the
ratio of gross national product to the money stock - - has risen
at an average annual rate of about 2-1/2 per cent, thus contributing importantly to the inflationary problem.

-16-

The role of more rapid monetary turnover rates in
inflationary processes warns against assuming any simple
causal relation between monetary expansion and the rate of
inflation either during long or short periods*

Excessive in-

creases in money and credit can be an initiating source of
excess demand and a soaring price level.

But the initiating

force may primarily lie elsewhere, as has been the case in
the inflation from which this country is now suffering.
The current inflationary problem emerged in the middle
1960's when our government was pursuing a dangerously expansive fiscal policy.

Massive tax reductions occurred in

1964 and the first half of 1965, and they were immediately
followed by an explosion of Federal spending.

The propensity

of Federal expenditures to outrun the growth of revenues has
continued into the 1970]s.

In the last five fiscal years, total

Federal debt - - including the obligations of the Federal credit
agencies - - has risen by more than $100 billion, a larger increase than in the previous 24 fiscal years.
Our underlying inflationary problem, I believe, stems
in very large part from loose fiscal policies, but it has been
greatly aggravated during the past year or two by the special

-17-

factors mentioned earlier.

From a purely theoretical point

of view, it would have been possible for monetary policy to
offset the influence that lax fiscal policies and the special
factors have exerted on the general level of prices.

One may

therefore argue that relatively high rates of monetary expansion
have been a permissive factor in the accelerated pace of inflation.
I have no quarrel with this view.

But an effort to use harsh

policies of monetary restraint to offset the exceptionally powerful inflationary forces of recent years would have caused serious
financial disorder and economic dislocation.

That would not have

been a sensible course for monetary policy.
The last question put to me deals with how monetary
policy should be used to check inflation and bring interest rates
down to reasonable levels.
The principal objective of monetary policy since late
1972 has been to combat the inflationary forces threatening our
economy.

To this end, supplies of money and credit have been

restricted at a time when credit demands were booming.
therefore, interest rates have risen.

Inevitably,

This unhappy consequence

has led some observers to conclude that restrictive monetary
policies are counterproductive - - because rising interest rates

-18-

are an added cost to businesses and thus may result in still
higher prices.
There is a grain of truth in this argument, but no more
than that.

For most businesses, interest costs are only a

small fraction of total operating expenses.

The direct effects

of a restrictive monetary policy on costs and prices are therefore small.

The indirect effects of a restrictive monetary

policy on prices are far more important.

When growth in

supplies of money and credit is restrained, some business
firms and consumers are discouraged by the high cost of credit
from carrying through their plans to spend; others find it more
difficult to obtain credit and therefore trim their spending; still
others, reckoning, that monetary restraint will cool off aggregate
demand, curtail their outlays for goods and services even though
they do not depend on the credit markets for spendable funds.
In all these ways, a restrictive monetary policy helps to moderate
aggregate spending and thus to reduce inflationary pressures.
In order to bring interest rates down to reasonable levels,
we shall need to stay with a moderately restrictive monetary
policy long enough to let the fires
out.

of inflation burn themselves

-19-

Progress can still be made this year in slowing the
rate of price increase, and it is urgent that we do so.

Inflation

has been having debilitating effects on the purchasing power of
consumers, on the efficiency of business enterprises, and on
the condition of financial markets,
people is wearing thin.

The patience of the American

Our social and political institutions

cannot indefinitely withstand a continuation of the current inflationary spiral.
We must face squarely the magnitude of the task that
lies ahead.

A return to price stability will require a national

commitment to fight inflation this year and in the years to come.
Monetary policy must play a key role in this endeavor, and we
in the Federal Reserve recognize that fact.

We are determined

to reduce over time the rate of monetary and credit expansion
to a pace consistent with a stable price leveL
Monetary policy, however, should not be relied upon
exclusively in the fight against inflation.
also urgently needed.

Fiscal restraint is

Strenuous efforts should be made to pare

Federal budget expenditures, thus eliminating the deficit that
seems likely in fiscal 1975.

The Congress should resist any

temptation to stimulate economic activity by a general tax cut
or a new public works program.

There may be justification

-20-

for assistance to particular industries - - such as housing - that are especially hard hit by a policy of monetary restraint.
An expanded public-service employment program may also be
needed if unemployment rises further.

But government should

not try to compensate fully for all the inconvenience or actual
hardship that may ensue from its struggle against inflation.
Public policy must not negate with one hand what it is doing
with the other.
There are other actions that may be of some help in
speeding the return to general price stability.

For example,

limited intervention in wage and price developments in pacesetting industries may result in considerable improvement of
wage and price performance.

I would urge the Congress to r e -

establish the Cost of Living Council and to empower it, as the
need arises, to appoint ad hoc review boards that could delay
wage and price increases in key industries, hold hearings,
make recommendations, monitor results, issue reports, and
thus bring the force of public opinion to bear on wage and price
changes that appear to involve an abuse of economic power.
Encouragement to capital investment by revising the structure
of tax revenues may also be helpful, as would other efforts to

-21-

enlarge our supply potential.

For example, minimum wage

laws could be modified to increase job opportunities for teenagers, and reforms are still needed to eliminate restrictive
policies in the private sector - - such as featherbedding and
outdated building codes.
A national effort to end inflation requires explicit
recognition of general price stability as a primary objective
of public policy.

This might best be done promptly through

a concurrent resolution by the Congress, to be followed later
by an appropriate amendment to the Employment Act of 1946.
Such actions would heighten the resolve of the Congress and
the Executive to weigh carefully the inflationary implications
of all new programs and policies, including those that add to
private costs as well as those that raise Federal expenditures.
And they would signal to our people, and to nations around the
world, that the United States firmly intends to restore the
conditions essential to a stable and lasting prosperity.

>]< >\< >!< >]< ^ >;<