View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release
Sunday, October 29, 1967
6:00 P.M., E.S.T.




INTEREST RATE FLEXIBILITY AND THE BEHAVIOR
OF COMMERCIAL BANKS'
TIME AND SAVINGS DEPOSITS
A Paper Presented
by
Andrew F . Brimmer
Member
Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System

Before the

Executive Savings Seminar
of the
Savings Division,
American Bankers Association
at the
Marriott Twin Bridges Hotel
Washington, D . C.

October 29, 1967

Interest Rate Flexibility and the Behavior
1
of Commercial Banks
Time and Savings Deposits

The marked expansion in time and savings deposits at commercial banks and other financial institutions during this year has been
commented on many times.

This is readily understandable—especially

in view of the sharply lower rates of increase experienced in 1965.
However, beyond these easily recognizable year-to-year changes,
several developments have occurred in the competition for savings
which may have a lasting impact on the banking system in the long-run:




A number of banks (particularly the larger ones) have
demonstrated their ability to moderate or quicken the
inflow of funds through reducing or raising interest
rates paid on time deposits.

It will be recalled that

last winter and spring many observers (including a
number of bankers) were urging bank supervisory authorities to reduce maximum rates payable on time deposits
because banks and other depositary institutions could
not reduce interest rates on their own initiative.
Passbook savings, despite the recovery registered
this year, remain vulnerable to higher yielding
savings instruments.

Nevertheless, while the 4 per

cent interest rate ceiling on such deposits may
appear somewhat out of line, in my personal opinion,
it is still desirable to maintain the existing structure of rate ceilings on time and savings deposits.

-2The competition for business-type time deposits
has become even more sophisticated.

A number of

banks (even some large ones) which recently entered
this market apparently became disenchanted after
the severe attrition experienced in late 1966 and
are now concentrating on somewhat more certain
sources of funds.

Still other banks with European

branches are relying more heavily on Eurodollar
deposits to supplement their domestic sources.
In fact, for these banks, Eurodollar deposits
have become a particularly close substitute for
domestic CD's.

This development also may carry a

number of implications for monetary management in
the long-run.
In the remarks which follow, I shall develop each of the
above points further.

The subsequent discussion would be helped,

however, by a brief re-tracing of the path by which commercial banks
arrived at their present stance with respect to competition for time
and savings deposits.
Revival of Commercial Bank Competition for Savings
Many of us tend to forget just how recently banks were
allowed to re-enter the competitive arena for deposits.

The principal

check on their ability to compete, of course, was the ceiling which
the Federal Reserve Board and the FDXC imposed on the interest rates
payable on time and savings deposits.




It will be recalled that for

-3the maximum legal rate on
21 years (from January 1, 1936 until January 1, 1957) /savings deposits
and time deposits with maturities of 6 months or more were frozen at
2-1/2 per cent.

Time deposits of 90 days to 6 months had a maximum

rate of 2 per cent, and those of 30 to 89 days had a ceiling of 1 per
cent.

In 1957, all of these rates were raised by 1/2 per cent--except

for the 30-to-89-day time deposit rate which remained at 1 per cent.
This new schedule remained intact for five years--until January 1,
1962.

Since the latter date, the maximum rate on some form of time

deposit has been raised each year.

But the passbook rate has remained

at 4 per cent on savings deposits since Jaftu&ry 19-62.

In contrast, the time
deposit ceiling was raised through several steps to reach 5-1/2 per
cent in December, 1965, where it remains for deposits of $100,000 or
more.

In an effort to moderate rate competition among banks and

other institutions for funds, the ceiling was set in September, 1966,
at 5 per cent for time deposits of less than $100,000.

Within this

regulatory framework, the banks' ability to compete for deposits was
f

obviously limited until well into the decade of the 1 9 6 0 s .
But as the scope for competition expanded, the banks
responded vigorously.

Their response was partly stimulated by the

inroads being made by nonbank financial institutions and by the
increasing efforts of corporate treasurers to reduce their nonearning
liquid assets to a minimum.

Many banks apparently decided to buy

money--rather than continue to complain about their declining importance in the evolving financial mechanism.



Just how successful the

-4-

banks

f

efforts have been is known to all of u s , but repetition will

do no harm:

Total demand deposits of banks still exceed their total

time deposits by a small margin.

However, since the end of 1964, the

time deposits of consumers and businesses have been larger than the
demand balances held by this group.

Ten years ago, total time and

savings deposits represented about one-fourth of the total deposits
of banks; today they represent almost one-half.

Moreover, in the

process of restructuring deposit liabilities, time deposits have
accounted for over 70 per cent of the growth of total deposits in
1

the I 9 6 0 s .
The Challenge to Deposit Growth
This vigorous re-entry of the commercial banks in the race
for savings was checked abruptly about a year ago, as inflows of
time and savings deposits in the aggregate virtually ceased.

This

sharp slowdown in inflows reflected a number of factors:
The attractive level of market rates of interest in
1966 which tended to divert savings to other forms
of financial assets.
The unchanged Regulation Q ceiling on large CD's
w h i c h — g i v e n rising market rates--led to a $3.2
billion CD attrition from August to December, and
The September rollback in the maximum rates member
banks could pay on smaller denomination time deposits.
Moreover, during 1966, the composition of inflows changed
rather dramatically.




At all commercial banks, passbook savings accounts

-5declined by $2.5 billion.

At member banks of the Federal Reserve

System, passbook savings declined by about
year.

$3 billion over the

On the other hand, consumer-type time deposits accounted for

essentially all of the growth in interest-bearing deposits at member
banks.

As a result, savings deposits (which had accounted for nearly

nine-tenths of all IPC interest-bearing deposits at member banks a
few years ago) dropped to about 53 per cent of the total in early
1967.

The large denomination negotiable CD's had increased by over

$2.3 billion by August, 1966, but the subsequent attrition led to an
outflow of $600 million in such deposits over the year as a whole.
This composition of inflows in 1966 was very much a
reflection of relative offering rates.

Despite the fact that the

proportion of member banks paying the 4 per cent maximum on savings
deposits increased from less than one-half to about two-thirds, passbook savings accounts declined in relative attractiveness--not only
because of rising market yields but also because of the increasing
attractiveness of consumer-type time deposits.

As the year progressed,

banks began increasingly to offer a wide variety of time deposits to
consumers--savings certificates, savings bonds, CD's, etc.--at rates
considerably above those available on passbook savings deposits.

By

January, 1967, over one-half of member banks were paying the 5 per
cent maximum on at least one form of IPC consumer time deposit, up
from 17 per cent in M a y , 1966.
Not only were passbook savings being shifted out of b a n k s ,
but the more interest sensitive depositors were shifting from passbook




-6-

accounts to time deposits•

Indeed, the decline in passbook savings

accounts was greater at those banks with the largest gap between
their savings and time deposit rates, and the depositor sensitivity
to rate differentials was also greater at the larger banks.
This shifting pattern of inflows and outflows suggests
that many banks were simply competing with themselves--gaining time
deposits at the expense of savings deposits in their own bank.
this was not universally true.

But

Had not many banks offered higher

rates on time deposits, more passbook savings depositors would have
shifted funds away from the banking system.

Indeed, not only is there

ample evidence that banks paying higher rates--other things being equalshad greater inflows, but some banks that did not raise rates actually
had outflows.

Moreover, especially at the larger banks, awareness of

alternatives and interest-sensitivity was generally high among depositors.
The larger member banks, for example, had the largest percentage increase
in consumer-type time deposits--and the largest percentage decrease in
passbook savings accounts.

A n d , on balance, the larger banks had the

smallest percentage increase in total consumer-type interest bearing
deposits.

Had they not offered higher rates on time deposits, their

interest-bearing deposit inflows would probably have been negative.
Although market rates of interest began to decline late in
1966, banks continued, in general, aggressively to seek time and savings
deposits through early 1967, in large part to help rebuild their
liquidity positions.

By early 1967, over one-half of all member banks

were paying the 5 per cent maximum on at least one form of consumer-type




-7-

time deposits, and the proportion of all such deposits in these banks
was about four-fifths of the total.

Since some individual banks were

paying less than the maximum rate on some forms of consumer-type time
deposits, the proportion of total consumer-type time deposits to
which the 5 per cent maximum applied was about three-fourths.
In the passbook area, about two-thirds of all member banks
(holding nine-tenths of all savings deposits) were paying the 4 per
cent maximum in early 1967.

Since the 360 largest member banks were

generally the highest rate paying banks on all forms of IPC interestbearing deposits, it is not surprising that in early 1967 they held
about two-thirds of all consumer interest-bearing deposits (passbook
and time).

Moreover, these banks accounted for about two-thirds of

the increase in consumer-type time deposits in 1966.

B u t , as men-

tioned above, their larger passbook attrition kept their share of
the total growth in member bank consumer-type time and savings
deposits to about one-half.




Interest Rates and Deposit Trends in 1967
During the first half of 1967 (for the first time since
banks generally became aggressive seekers of interest-bearing deposits
in recent years) these institutions operated in a financial environment
of easier monetary policy and fluctuating interest rates.

Moreover,

the saving rate of the oublic rose, loan demands were less frantic,
and the considerably reduced level of market rates over the period-compared with 1 9 C 6 — i n c r e a s e d the relative attractiveness of bank
interest-bearing deposits.
How did banks react to these developments in
framing deposit strategy?
How were inflows, in turn, influenced by bank
policies?
In general, the degree of flexibility observed among banks
in the interest rates they offered on deposits should tend to reinforce
our belief in the efficacy and efficiency of the market mechanism.
From January through A p r i l , time and savings deposits at
member
adjusted
all/banks expanded at a seasonally/annual rate of 14 per cent, nearly
twice as rapidly as in all of 1966.

This accelerated inflow reflected

mainly the high personal saving rate and the increased relative attractiveness of bank deposits during a period of declining market yields.
With inflows enlarged at times of reduced loan demands, some banks
attempted to moderate their deposit inflows by reductions in offering
rates and by other m e a s u r e s — s u c h as limiting the amount they would




-9-

accept from each depositor, restricting eligible purchasers, shortening maximum maturities on attractive rate instruments, and cutting
down on advertising.
As shown in Table 1, about 85 per cent of the 6,000-odd
member banks did not change the maximum rate offered on consumer-type
time deposits in the January-July period of 1967.

But 850 banks did

change such rates over this period, and they make by far the more
interesting study.

The fact that only a minority of banks changed

rates is not the key point.

In almost any market only the marginal

sellers--those more sensitive to shifting pressure--are the price
changers.
In the January-April period, about 5 per cent of the member
banks issuing consumer-type time deposits reduced maximum rates.
These reductions were four times as common among the larger banks
as among the smaller i n s t i t u t i o n s — a development that is readily
understandable since more of the larger banks had been paying higher
rates in 1966.

About one-fourth of the reductions were by 25 basis

points to 4-3/4 and most of the remaining decreases were by 50 basis
points to 4-1/2 per cent.
These rate reductions were not the only rate movements;
about 4 per cent of member banks raised rates on consumer-type time
deposits.

Most of these were smaller banks.

More than one-half of

them raised rates to 5 per cent and most of the remainder to 4-1/2
per cent.

Another 1 # 5 per cent of member banks (again mainly smaller

ones) introduced consumer-type time deposits for the first time.




About

-9aTable 1.

Size of
Bank
(total
deposits in
millions of
dollars)
(1)

Total
Number
of
Banks
(2)

Number
of Banks
Changing
Rates
(3)

Pattern of Changes in Maximum Interest Rates on Consumer-Type
Time Deposits Among Member Banks, by Size of Bank,
January-April and April-July, 1967

Banks that only
Raised Rates
1st.
Qt.

2nd
Qt.

(4)

(5)

Banks that only
Reduced Rates

Not
Specified
(6)

1st
Qt.

2nd
Qt.

(7)

(8)

500 and
over

94

19

.

-

-

2

1

100-500

291

64

7

1

1

9

7

50-100

274

44

3

5

1

7

10-50

2,014

266

54

47

1

under 10

3,351

457

167

77

6,024

850

231

130

Not
Specified
(9)

Total:
•ill Banks

Source:

Raised
Rates in
1st Qt.;
Reduced
Rates in
2nd Qt.
Cll)

No change
in
Rates

(

)

16

_

1

36

2

in

10

-

18

-

230

44

48

4

58

10

1,748

9

48

66

4

65

21

2,894

12

110

132

9

193

33

i

Federal Reserve Board, Quarterly Surveys of Time and Savings Deposits,




Reduced
Rates in
1st Qt.;
Raised
Rates in
2nd Qt•
(10)

75

i

4

-10one-third of these set their highest rate at 5 per cent, and most
of the balance at 4-1/2 or 4 per cent.
These diverse movements lowered average consumer-type
time deposit rates by about 5 or 6 basis points over the JanuaryApril months.

The average of maximum rates declined to 4.82 per

cent and the average of the most common rate to 4.77 per cent.

With

two-thirds of member banks already at 4 per cent, the average rate
on passbook accounts remained unchanged at 3.91 per cent.
Despite the small decline in average consumer time deposit
rates at all member banks in the January-April period, inflows of
such deposits were rapid for all size groups of banks.
in rates paid

Moreover,

despite the larger declines/at the biggest institutions, inflows
were somewhat more rapid at the latter banks.
After mid-February, savings deposits began to increase
again, having declined in 1966--and the increase was more rapid among
the less interest-sensitive small bank depositors.

One category of

particularly sharp growth (although from a relatively small base) was
the small-denomination time deposit-open account, a category that
many
includes the 90-day notice passbook type account which /additional banks
began to introduce in early 1967.

The creation, advertising, and

success of this form of deposit is a clear example of competitive
innovation.

This deposit combines the passbook form (noted for its

ease, convenience, and acceptance) with the time deposit form--the
90-day n o t i c e — a n d permits the issuance of a high rate, relatively
liquid, and hence attractive savings instrument.




-11-

Over the spring and early summer--from April through July-the environment in which banks operated changed substantially, and in
response bank attitudes toward time deposits also changed once more*
With market interest rates rising, with business borrowing for tax
payment purposes expanding, and with increasing bank expectations that
loan demands and interest rates would be higher in future months, some
banks became more aggressive in seeking time and savings deposit funds.
Reflecting this aggressiveness, not only did more banks
advertise more vigorously, but offering rates also began to edge back
up.

While most member banks left unchanged their highest offering

rates on consumer-type deposits, (in contrast to developments over the
preceding three months) more banks increased the highest rates offered
on smaller denomination time deposits than reduced it.

About 5 per

cent of member banks raised such rates, with increases three times as
frequent among large banks as among smaller institutions.

Most of these

increases lifted their highest rates to the 5 per cent ceiling.

As

before, some banks--about 2.5 per cent of the t o t a l — l o w e r e d rates, and
about 1 per cent introduced consumer-type time deposits for the first
time.

Also as before, there was little change in savings deposit rates.
Despite higher rates offered on consumer-type time deposits,

the rate of inflow (while large) moderated somewhat from the earlier
months.

This may have reflected a moderation in the one-time shift

from the securities markets earlier in the year, and perhaps it was
also a reflection of the increasing pull of market yields.




But total

-12inflows of time and savings deposits to all member banks accelerated as
the growth in passbook savings and business-type time deposits more than
offset developments in the consumer time deposit market*
By the end of July, about one-half of all member banks were
paying the 5 per cent ceiling on at least one form of consumer time
deposit; among banks with deposits of $100 million and m o r e , the ratio
was four-fifths.

Nearly two-thirds of all member banks were paying the

4 per cent ceiling on passbook accounts, and these banks held nine-tenths
of such deposits.
In the April - July period, average rates for consumer-time
deposits generally moved back to the January level:

the highest rate on

such deposits averaged 4.87 per cent, and the most common note was 4.83
per cent.

These rates and the passbook average were about 1/8 below

their respective ceilings.

Small banks, of course, had lower average

r a t e s — a s banks with deposits of less than $10 million were paying an
average of nearly 30 basis points less on consumer type deposits than banks
with deposits over $500 million.
No information is yet available for rate movements on bank time
deposits since mid-summer.

However, my expectation is that more banks have

raised rates and increased promotions as market rates have continued to
rise.

Since July, the overall trend of time deposits at member banks has

been dominated by movements in CD's.

Inflows of consumer-type deposits have

moderated somewhat—particularly in the passbook category.
Rate Flexibility and the Behavior of Consumer-type Deposits
This review of 1966-67 developments in time and savings deposit
markets of member banks is indicative of a high level of interest rate
flexibility.



As mentioned above, many observers argued last spring that

ceiling rates should be lowered because banks simply would not reduce
rates on their own.

The evidence simply does not suppdrt this assertion.

In fact, not only did a sizable number of banks reduce r a t e s — b u t the
pattern of deposit flows strongly suggests that they were fully justified
in making the move.

About 4 per cent of member b a n k s — a little less than

one-third of banks changing rates—lowered rates on time deposits in the
January - July period and did not raise them at all.
experience?

What was their

For an answer we can focus on Tables 2 and 3 .

Most of these

banks--about 85 per cent of those that lowered r a t e s — w e r e small banks
with deposits of less than $50 million.
flows paralleled rate movements:

In general, the pace of deposit

those banks that lowered rates on

consumer-type time deposits and did not raise them again had rates of
inflows below the average.

Their consumer-type time deposits expanded

by roughly 10 per cent, about one-half that recorded for all member
banks.

These banks were evidently trying to slow inflows because of the

reduced need for funds or because other deposit inflows were large.
Indeed, among most of these banks that reduced rates and kept
them at the lower levels, the rate of growth of passbook accounts was
considerably above the average for all member banks.

This was partic-

ularly true for those few banks that lowered their time deposit rates
in both quarters.

A very few of the banks that lowered rates also had

rates of consumer-type time deposit inflows considerably above average
and were probably cutting rates to moderate the pace.
On the other hand, despite the higher than average passbook
savings inflows, most of the banks that cut time deposit rates in the
first quarter and did not raise them again had below average growth



-13aTable 2;

Size of Bank
(total
deposits
in millions
of dollars)

Number
of
Banks

Per cent
of total

Member Banks That Only Reduced M a x i m u m Interest Rates,
January - A p r i l 1967 (No c h a n g e , A p r i l - July 1967)
by Size of Bank and Percentage Change in Consumer-Type Time
and Savings Deposits (Amounts in millions of dollars)

Cons.-type time
Outst., 1-31-67
Per cent
A m o u n t of total

Per Cent Change in A m t . Outst., J a n , 31 - July 31
Cons.-type T i m e
Cons.-typ e & S a v g s .
Savings
All
All
All
Banks
Banks
Banks
reducing!, m e m b e r r e d u c i n g member r e d u c i n g member
banks
banks
banks
rate
rate
rate

110

1.8

353

1.4

8.8

19.2

3.7

3.4

4.5

7.5

500 and over

2

2.1

81

0.9

14.5

23.3

1.3

3.2

2.9

7.8

100 - 500

9

3.1

112

2.5

10.7

17.8

4.2

3.4

5.3

6.6

50 - 100

7

2.6

43

2.0

6.8

19.5

6.3

3.5

6.4

7.9

10 - 50

44

2.2

84

1.4

12.0

16.4

5.1

3.5

6.4

7.7

U n d e r 10

48

1.4

34

1.1

-16.8

13.9

6.7

3.5

-0.3

7.8

Total

Source:

Federal Reserve Board, Quarterly Surveys of Time and Savings D e p o s i t s .




-13bTable 3 .

Member Banks That Only Reduced Maximum Interest R a t e s ,
April - July 1967 (No Change, January - April 1967)
by Size of Bank and Percentage Change in Consumer-Type
Time and Savings Deposits (Amounts in Millions of Dollars)
Per Cent Change in Amt. Outst., Jan. 31 - July 31
Cons.-type Time
Savings
Cons.-type & S V R S
Banks
All
All
Banks
tanks
All
reducing member reducing member rc-ductng member
rate
rate
banks
banks
rate
banks

Size of Bank
(total
deposits
in millions
of dollars)

Number
of
Banks

Total

132

2.2

345

1.4

11.7

19.2

4.3

3.4

6.0

7.5

500 and over

1

1.1

15

0.2

68.3

23.3

4.6

3.2

8.9

7.8

100 - 500

7

2.4

76

1.7

6.2

17.8

4.1

3.4

4.5

6.6

50 - 100

10

3.6

74

3.5

0.1

19.5

3.3

3.5

2.4

7.9

10 - 50

48

2.4

123

2.1

14.5

16.4

4.4

3.5

7.2

7.7

Under 10

66

2.0

57

1.9

13.8

13.9

5.3

3.5

8.5

Per Cent
of Total

Cons.-Type time
Outst. 1-31-67
Per Cent
Amount of Total

7.8
1

Source:




Federal Reserve Board, Quarterly Surveys of Time and Savings Deposits

-14of total consumer time and savings deposits.

Banks that lowered

rates in the second quarter, and those that lowered rates in both
quarters had below average growth in total consumer deposits.

These

banks were probably cutting rates in reaction to inflows higher than
they desired.
About 6 per cent of member banks--45 per cent of those
banks changing rates--raised their offering rate on consumer-type
deposits between January and July.

(See Tables 4 and 5.)

Almost

twice as many of these banks raised their rates in the January-April
period as in the April-July period.

Most of the banks raising rates

in these early months (95 per cent of them) were small banks, with
deposits of less than $50 million and holding less than 2 per cent
of all member bank consumer-type time deposits.
Generally, these small banks had been paying lower rates.
And despite the declining level of market yields over most of this
period, they chose to bid more aggressively for funds.

As a result,

their inflows of consumer-type time deposits expanded quite rapidly:
for those banks raising rates earlier in the year, growth in consumertype time deposits was over twice as large as for all member banks.
At the very few banks--about 1 0 — t h a t raised rates twice, inflows
doubled their holdings of consumer-type time deposits in the JanuaryJuly period.

Banks that raised rates only in the April-July period

had inflows of time deposits over the first half below the all-bank
pace.




This pattern suggests that their rates had been out of line

Table 4 .

Size of Bank
(total
deposits
in millions
of dollars)
Total
500 and over

Number
of
Banks
231
—

Per Cent
of Total
3.8
- -

-14aMember Banks That Only Raised Maximum Interest Rates,
January - April 1967 (No Change April - July 1967)
by Size of Bank and Percentage Change in Consumer-Type
Time and Savings Deposits (Amounts in millions of dollars)
Cons.-type time
Outst. 1-31-67
Per Cent
Amount of Total
218
—

0.9
- -

Per Cent Change in A m t . Outst., J a n . 31 - July 31
Cons.-type Time
Savings
Cons.-type & Savgs.
All
All
All
Banks
Banks
Banks
raising member raising member raising member
banks
rate
rate
banks
rate
banks
44.7

19.2

2.6

3.4

- -

23.3

—

3.2

9.6
- -

7.5
7.8

100 - 500

7

2.4

15

0.3

96.6

17.8

1.3

3.4

4.5

6.6

50 - 100

3

1.1

8

0.4

- 4.0

19.5

9.9

3.5

8.9

7.9

10 - 50

54

2.7

107

1.8

47.4

16.4

2.3

3.5

12.0

7.7

Under 10

167

5.0

89

3.0

37.0

13.9

2.5

3.5

13.4

7.8

Source:




Federal Reserve Board, Quarterly Surveys of Time and Savings Deposits.

-14bTable 5;

Member Banks That Only Raised Maximum Interest Rates, April - July 1967 (No Change
January - April, 1967) by Size of Bank and Percentage.
Change in Consumer-Type Time and Savings Deposits (Amounts in Millions of Dollars)

Size of Bank
(total
deposits
in millions
of dollars)
Total
500 and over

Number
of
Banks

Per Cent
of Total

i30
- -

2.2
- -

Cons.-Type time
Outst. 1-31-67
Per Cent
Amount of Total
295

1.2

- -

Per Cent Change in A m t . Outst., Jan. 31 - July 31
Cons.-type Time
Cons.-typ e & Svgs
Savings
Banks
All
Banks
All
Banks
All
raising member raising nember
raising 3 ember
1
rate
rate
banks
rate
banks
banks
12.9
- -

19.2

2.0

3.4

23.3

—

3.2

6.0
- -

7.5
7.8

100 - 500

1

0.3

1

1/

30.8

17.8

3.2

3.5

4.1

6.6

50 - 100

5

1.8

28

1.3

21.9

19.5

0.7

3.5

5.1

7.9

10 - 50

47

2.3

205

3.4

11.7

16.4

2.1

3.5

6.3

7.7

Under 10

77

2.3

60

2.0

12.6

13.9

2.6

3.5

6.4

7.8

1/

Less than 0.05 per cent

Source:




Federal Reserve Board, Quarterly Surveys of Time and Savings Deposits

-15and that their increases in rates were defensive--or that the rate
change came late in the period and had not had time to affect inflows
appreciably.
Significantly, those banks that raised rates on time deposits
in this period had passbook savings inflows below the average and were
evidently selecting time deposits as the vehicle for increasing total
inflows.

Some of these banks were already at the ceiling rate on

passbook accounts; others apparently chose to offer higher rates to
only interest-sensitive customers in order not to increase the cost
of their larger total passbook deposits.

Even with their passbook

inflows below normal, those small banks that raised rates on time
deposits earlier in the year, or raised them once in each quarter,
had rates of growth of total consumer interest-bearing deposits above
the average.

Those that raised rates defensively in the second quarter

had total inflows below the average pace.
The very few large banks that only raised rates on consumertype time deposits in the first half also increased their inflows of
such deposits relatively rapidly.

However, they had been paying lower

than average rates and had very small amounts of deposits to begin with.
Their total consumer deposit inflows were generally below average.
The foregoing analysis demonstrates that banks which either
raised rates only or lowered rates only in 1967 generally had the
expected reaction in their growth rates of deposits.

They also

generally had other deposit inflows that might be expected to lead
them to the actions taken.




All other characteristics of banks being

-16-

equal, however, the expected rate actions (in light of developments
in market rates and loan demands) would have been rate reductions in
the first months of the year and rate increases in the late spring
and early summer.
To what extent did this pattern hold true?

A little over

3 per cent of banks did in fact change rates that w a y - r a n g i n g from
17 per cent of member banks with deposits of $500 million and over
to about 2 per cent of those with deposits below $10 million.
Table 6*)

(See

Since many of the rate increases probably occurred around

mid-year, late in the period under review, the effect of rate increases
on deposit flows probably was not large in the time period covered.
Consequently, in the January-July period these banks had growth rates
of consumer-type time deposits below the all-bank average.

For

example, these banks had inflows less than one-half as rapid as those
recorded for banks that did not change rates.

Among the largest banks,

inflows were less than one-third as rapid as for the banks of that
size that did not change rates.
No information is yet available for rate movements on bank
time deposits since mid-summer.

However, my guess is that more banks

have raised rates and increased promotions as market rates have continued
to rise.
Rate Flexibility and the Behavior of Business-type Deposits
Up to this point, the discussion has centered on bank policies
toward consumer deposits.

Developments in the business-type deposit

market have shown an even higher degree of interest rate flexibility on




-16aTable 6. Member Banks that Reduced Maximum Interest Rates,
January- April 1967, and then Raised Maximum
Interest Rates, April-July, 1967, by size of Bank
and Percentage Change in Consumer-Type Time and Savings Deposits
(amounts in millions of dollars)

Size of bank
(total
deposits
in millions
of dollars)

Number
of
tanks

Per cent
of
total

Per cent change in amount outst., Jan..
Cons.-type time
Cons.-typ e time
Savi rigs
All
Banks
All
Outst., 1-31-67
Banks
member
Per cent changing member changing
banks
banks
rate
rate
Amount of total

31 - July 31
Cons.-type & Savs.
Banks
All
changing
member
rate
banks

193

3.2

2,531

10.1

8.8

19.2

3.8

3.4

5.1

7.5

500 and over

16

17.0

1,606

17.1

8.6

23.3

3.9

3.2

5.2

7.8

100-500

36

12.4

628

13.9

9.0

17.8

3.9

3.4

5.2

6.6

50-100

18

6.6

111

5.3

12.0

19.5

2.4

3.5

4.6

7.9

-§0-50

58

2.9

134

2.2

5.5

16.4

4.3

3.5

4.6

7.7

U n d e r 50

65

1.9

52

1.8

14.0

13.9

3.1

3.5

7.0

7.8

Total

Source:

Federal Reserve Board, Quarterly Surveys of Time and Savings Deposits.




-17large
the part of member banks*

This is especially true of the 265 or so/

banks that are active in the negotiable CD market.
While over 1,200 banks issue negotiable CD's in denominations
above $100,000--of which between 800 and 900 are member b a n k s — a b o u t
265 large banks account for about 90 per cent of the total.

This part

of the analysis is based on the behavior of these 265 banks.
In the first half of 1966, with market yields rising and
f

banks extremely aggressive in their efforts to obtain C D s , offering
rates on negotiable CD's rose a 100 basis points to the Regulation Q
ceiling of 5-1/2 per cent.

You will recall that negotiable CD's are

substitutes in the portfolio of investors for other money market
instruments, and the relationship between CD and other rates is
extremely important in determining the ability of large banks to sell
CD's.

For example, it appears that CD's require a 20 to 30 basis point

premium over the investment basis yield on the more liquid Treasury
bills; about a 5 to 10 basis point over finance company paper yield,
but can yield 10 to 20 basis points less than commercial paper.

In

the summer and fall of 1966, however, the Regulation Q restrained
offering yields on CD's while all money market instruments rose to
record levels above CD rates.

As a result, from August to December,

banks suffered a $3.2 billion CD attrition.
Most of the attrition--almost 90 per c e n t — w a s centered at
19 very large banks whose CD's apparently are issued almost completely
as money market instruments.

Almost all of the remainder was accounted

for by the 18 other banks with deposits over $1 billion.




This does

-18not mean that individual banks with deposits of less than $1 billion
were able to avoid CD losses.

One-half of them did suffer losses of

CD's, but the amount of CD's they had outstanding was small relative
to the total and to their own deposits.

Many of these smaller banks

were able to increase their outstanding CD's during this period when
CD rates could not be competitive.

This ability of some smaller banks

evidently reflects the greater importance of customer relationships
and regional markets in their CD issuance.
As money market yields began to recede in late 1966, general
CD issuance was again possible.

With rates on CD's remaining at the

ceiling until mid-January of 1967, and declining less rapidly than
market yields throughout most of the first quarter, outstanding CD's
increased about $200 million in late 1966 and $3.7 billion in the
first quarter of 1967.

Most all of this increase occurred at the

largest banks.
After about February, however, outstandings increased
little and essentially fluctuated in a narrow range until mid-year.
This development reflected two main factors.

First, the very large

corporate tax payments and still reduced liquidity of corporations
limited the ability of banks to sell CD's to their corporate customers.
T h u s , in the second quarter, CD's held by individuals, partnerships,
and corporations declined by about $500 million.

With this market

limited, banks increasingly turned to other buyers--mainly State and
local Governments and foreign accounts.




Indeed, CD's issued to the

-19-

non-IPC group accounted for slightly over one-half of the increase
in total outstandings in the first half of the year.
The second factor tending to moderate CD growth in the
second quarter was that banks did not aggressively bid for CD's.

In

April and M a y , offering rates on such instruments at the largest banks
dropped to 4 per cent on the short-end and to 4.25 per cent on the
longest maturities.

Relative to competing instruments, the spread

against CD's dropped to levels equal to or greater than the enforced
disadvantage of CD's in the fall of 1966.

This abvious lack of bank

interest in CD's reflected, in turn, several factors.

Other inflows

of time and savings deposits, as we have seen, were very large.

In

addition, by early spring, many banks had succeeded in rebuilding
their portfolio liquidity and were less anxious to obtain funds for
that purpose.

Finally, loan demands in this period-~and bank projec-

tions of such demands--did not suggest to banks that an aggressive
stance in the CD market was desirable.
After mid-year 1967, however, there was a complete turnaround
in developments in the CD market.

Along with the general rise in market

yields, CD offering rates rose sharply.

By the end of September, a

few banks were back at the 5-1/2 per cent ceiling on longer maturities,
and in the 90-180 day range rates of 5 to 5-1/4 per cent were offered.
During the third quarter, CD rates rose more rapidly than market yields,
providing record margins above competing instruments--e.g., 10 to 25
basis points above finance company paper and 50 to over 100 basis points




-20above Treasury bills.

Outstanding CD's increased sharply--by about

$1 billion in the quarter.

This increase reflected not only yields

but the increased ability of corporations to buy CD's after most of
their accelerated tax payments were past.
This increased aggressiveness of banks in the CD market,
was partly a reflection of their growing expectations of increased
loan demands and rising yields.

Banks in the third quarter were

particularly interested in obtaining longer maturity CD money in
order to lock away funds which many thought would subsequently appear
cheap.
While outstanding CD's in the aggregate have more than recovered the attrition of last year, not all issuing banks have regained
their previous peaks.

A careful look at groups of issuing banks is

instructive for interpreting bank flexibility in the negotiable CD
the
covered in this review
market. About 60 per cent of/265 issuing banks/lost CD's from August
to December of 1966.

These included almost three-fourths of banks

with deposits over $1 billion and over one-half of issuing banks with
deposits under $1 billion.

Of the banks losing CD's from August to

December, over one-third had not regained their year earlier level of
outstandings by August of 1967.

This group included 40 per cent of

the large banks that had attrition and over one-fifth of the smaller
banks that had lost CD's in the fall of 1966.

A very few other b a n k s —

about 3 per cent of the total issuing banks--did not suffer attrition
during the rate squeeze last y e a r , but did lose CD's subsequently.




-21What kind of bank has not regained its preViotU peak in
1967 in a market in which they had the rate freedom to do so?

What

kind of bank lost CD's last fall?
No easy generalization can be made in answeting either of
these questions.

More big banks lost CD's in last years rate squeeze,

which was to be expected--given the fact that their certificates tend
to be closer to pure money market instruments.

Relatively fewer small

banks lost CD's* and most of these had particularly small amounts of
CD^s relative to their deposits--that is, CD's were a relatively
insignificant source of funds at most of the small banks losing CD's
last year.

Given the fact that so many small banks were able to

avoid attrition in the fall of 1966, it is likely that those banks
that lost CD's either did not consider it important enough to urge
their customers to maintain their certificates or perhaps had been
issuing CD's in a broader market type environment.

Unhappily these

are suppositions only.
Most of the banks that did not regain their previous peaks
of CD's outstanding--that is, who chose not to push the i n s t r u m e n t —
were small banks; two-thirds of the banks not regaining their past
peak have deposits of less than $500 million.

My guess is that most

of these banks have developed doubts about the advantage of competing
in a market which can produce an outflow of funds at a difficult time
since most of them had suffered attrition in the 1966 rate squeeze.
Many of these banks might have decided to look for interest-bearing




-22-

funds in the more stable consumer market.

It must be recalled, how-

ever, that the majority of issuing banks in this size class have
surpassed their previous peak of outstanding CD's, showing a larger
growth rate in outstandings than the large banks.

Most all of these

small banks had very small CD losses in the fall of 1966 or even
increased outstandings during that period.

Having been discomforted

very little they have aggressively remained in the market.
What about the large banks to whom CD's are a more important
source of funds?
this past peak.

One-third of these banks now have outstandings below
A l l but one of these banks had suffered relatively

sizable CD run-offs in the past, and they too might have decided not
to place themselves in an exposed position again.
Bank Behavior in the Euro-dollar Market
During last year's CD attrition, the dozen or so banks with
foreign branches relied heavily on Euro-dollar borrowing to counter
their CD losses.

In a market not restricted by ceiling rates, bank

bidding for funds pushed the Euro-dollar rate as high as 130 basis
points above the Regulation Q ceiling on time deposits.

For the banks

using Euro-dollars, foreign branch borrowing did not offset all CD
losses, and as soon as CD's could again be issued in early 1967, Eurodollar borrowing declined.
Having moved heavily into the Euro-dollar market, these
banks have continued to be attracted to it.

Even though CD's have

been available all year, the CD share of the total of CD and Eurodollar funds used by these dozen banks has declined all year.




Even

if the few dominant Euro-dollar borrowers are removed from the group,
CD's still account for a smaller share of the funds from these two
sources than in early 1966.
dollar borrowing was

In the third quarter of this year, Euro-

particularly large as the spread between

such borrowing and CD's narrowed sharply - R e f l e c t i n g the rising trend
of interest rates in the United States.The increased use of Eurodollars has clearly been a factor tending to moderate CD issuance of
the largest banks, representing for them a viable substitute for
CD's.
Concluding Observations
This review of member bank behavior in the market for time
and savings deposits demonstrates clearly that the degree of interest
rate flexibility is considerably higher than many observers have
assumed to exist.

It has demonstrated further that the flow of

f u n d s — e v e n the time and savings deposits of consumers--to these
institutions also responds in a rational way to changes in interest
rates offered.

T h u s , I think this body of evidence lends additional

support to the view expressed last spring(and which I shared) that
banks themselves are capable of setting offering rates--rather than
relying on supervisory authorities to fix them.
I come away from this review with still another conviction.
The increased reliance by banks (especially by smaller institutions)
on interest sensitive time

/

deposits as a major source of

funds exposes them to developments with which many of them will find




-24it difficult to cope.

Clearly, a great deal of market reseatch and

a carefully thought-out long-run strategy is required for a bank to
operate successfully in this market.

Undoubtedly, the use of these

funds exposes banks to the risks of reduced inflows or deposit attrition to a greater degree than before.

Moreover, efforts to o b t a i n —

and keep--time and savings deposits are costly.

T h u s , there is more

need than ever to weigh these higher costs against the expected rate
of return on the funds attracted.
This review of banks' experience with time and savings
deposits leaves me with mixed feelings with respect to the scale of
interest rates which they can offer to depositors.

Within the current

structure of rate ceilings on all depositary claims, one's attention
is immediately attracted to the passbook ceiling rate at commercial
banks.

As it now stands, this ceiling rate is 100 basis points below

what banks can pay on smaller time deposits and what savings banks
can pay on their passbook accounts, and 75 basis points lower than
the regular savings and loan share account ceiling.

One cannot deny

that this gap places the commercial bank passbook account at a
competitive disadvantage.
On the other h a n d , the rate differential may have advantages
for both the bank and its customers.

Those depositors that require

or desire maximum liquidity can obtain it via passbook accounts.

Those

that are willing to take somewhat less liquidity have the option of the
higher yielding time deposits.




From the bank's point of v i e w , it has

-25-

a greater ability to hold oil to the deposits of its more interestsensitive customers via time d e p o s i t s — b u t without increasing the
cost of maintaining or expanding the deposits of those customers who
attach more weight to liquidity than to the rate of return.

The

differential rate also has a more favorable impact on bank profits.
Nevertheless, in order to protect themselves from withdrawals
from somewhat more sophisticated investors, banks make available time
deposits at higher rates.

On the w h o l e , price differentials of this

sort seem desirable, since they allow greater bank flexibility in
meeting the needs of different types of customers.

B u t , I think we

must also bear in mind the adverse effects which could flow from it.
In order to maintain and increase inflows, some banks in marketing
time deposits may expose other institutions to excessive risks.

For

this reason, I think the supervisory authorities are fully justified
in maintaining--under present circumstances--the existing structure
of rate ceilings on time and savings deposits.