View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
Monday, June 24, 1968
12:00 N o o n , E . D . T .

DOMESTIC STABILIZATION A N D THE U . S.
BALANCE OF PAYMENTS

Remarks by

A n d r e w F . Brimmer
Member
Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System

Before the

Economic Society of South Florida

DuPont Plaza Hotel
M i a m i , Florida

June 24, 1968

DOMESTIC STABILIZATION AND THE U . S .
BALANCE OF PAYMENTS
By
Andrew F . Brimmer*

The fiscal restraint p r o p o s a l s , finally adopted by Congress
after nearly a year of d e b a t e , should make a major contribution toward
the restoration of economic stability at home and the improvement of our
balance of p a y m e n t s .

H o w e v e r , while higher income taxes and reduced

Federal expenditures will begin immediately to dampen the pace of domestic
economic a c t i v i t y , the benefits to the balance of payments will come more
slowly.
The principal effect of the new fiscal measures on the balance
of payments should be an expansion in our trade surplus:

while exports

should be stimulated somewhat, there should be a noticeable moderation in
imports.

For the year 1968, the trade surplus m a y be $200 million better -

with the added fiscal restraint in place -- than without it, and by the
fourth quarter of 1968, the trade surplus may be running at an annual rate
of $400 m i l l i o n better than it otherwise would have b e e n .

Furthermore,

the trend of trade -- and also of domestic prices and costs -- should be
substantially better as we go into 1969.

All of these developments will

have beneficial implications for confidence in the dollar and for capital
flows as well as for the current a c c o u n t .

^ M e m b e r , Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. I am grateful
to M r . John Reynolds of the Board's Staff for assistance in the preparation
of these remarks.

In any effort to improve our balance of p a y m e n t s , the expansion
of our trade surplus must play a vital role.

In his N e w Year's Day

Message on the Balance of P a y m e n t s , the President stated that:
" . . .we are determined to achieve a substantial improvement in our trade surplus over the coming y e a r s . In the
year immediately a h e a d , we expect to realize an improvement
of $500 million."
The President made clear that, among other a c t i o n s , it would be
necessary
. .to enact the anti-inflation tax which I have sought
for almost a y e a r . Coupled with our expenditure controls
and appropriate monetary p o l i c y , this w i l l help to stem
the inflationary pressures which now threaten our economic
prosperity and our trade surplus."
In these r e m a r k s , I shall examine the consequences for foreign
trade and the balance of payments of the domestic inflation which has
emerged during the last few y e a r s .

I will also appraise the beneficial

effects which we might expect if domestic stability is restored.
F i r s t , I w i l l review the long-run importance of trade
to the balance of payments.
S e c o n d l y , I w i l l examine the adverse impact of the
Vietnam war on our balance of payments.
T h i r d l y , I w i l l appraise the implications of domestic
stabilization policies for foreign trade and the
balance of payments.
F i n a l l y , I w i l l assess the consequences of these balance
of payments developments for confidence in the dollar
abroad.

1

-3-

Foreign Trade and the Balance of Payments:

A Long View

Throughout the last decade of over-all deficits in U . S .
international t r a n s a c t i o n s , it has been evident that the international
competitiveness of U . S . goods in world markets was the crucial factor.
M e r c h a n d i s e exports and imports are by far the largest items in the U . S .
balance of international p a y m e n t s , amounting in 1967 to about $31 billion
and $27 b i l l i o n , respectively.

H e n c e , small changes in the relative rates

of advance of imports and exports can have large effects in dollar terms
on the size of the trade balance and the over-all d e f i c i t .

For example,

if exports were to rise from present levels by only 1 per cent a year
faster than imports, the trade surplus would increase by about $300 million
a y e a r , whereas a 1 per cent faster rise in imports than in exports would
have the opposite e f f e c t .
T h u s , even a rather gradual worsening in the trade position
could, over time, outweigh relatively large improvements in nontrade
sectors of the balance of payments — for example, on capital account and
travel.

C o n v e r s e l y , a slow but steady increase in the trade surplus could

suffice, over time, to reduce g r e a t l y , and ultimately eliminate, our
payments d e f i c i t .
F u r t h e r m o r e , in a growing world economy, trade adjustments that
are large in dollar terms but small in percentage terms can be accomplished

I

with a minimum of economic disturbance, and without governmental control or
interference.

From 1960 to 1967, U . S . merchandise exports increased by

$11 b i l l i o n , or 56 per c e n t , while merchandise imports increased by $12-1/2 billionj

-4-

or 84 per c e n t .

If exports and imports had each increased over this

period by 60 per cent — growth rates only marginally different from
those actually experienced — the trade surplus would by 1967 have been
$7-1/2 billion instead of the $3-1/2 billion actually recorded, and the
over-all payments deficit would probably not have remained an intractable
problem.

Impact of the Vietnam W a r
The acceleration of military activity in Vietnam in mid-1965
brought in train considerably adverse consequences for our trade surplus
and the balance of payments.

Experience shows that exports

and imports

respond fairly promptly to changes in levels of demand at home and abroad.
They also r e s p o n d , although more slowly and to a degree less easily m e a s u r e d ,
to changes in relative prices and costs, which in turn are influenced
partly by demand pressures and supply constraints.
From 1959-60 to 1963-64, exports increased much more

rapidly

than imports, and the trade surplus nearly d o u b l e d , from about $3 billion
a year to about $6 billion a y e a r .

This was a period during which foreign

economic activity and demand for goods of all sorts was expanding
B u t U . S . activity was also expanding

strongly.

strongly.

A key element in the improvement of the trade balance over this
period was the stability of U . S . price and cost levels in contrast to
generally rising price-cost levels in leading foreign countries.

For example,

during the years 1960-65, consumer prices in the United States rose by an

-5-

average of 1.3 per cent per y e a r .

In those leading industrial countries

who are our principal competitors, the annual percentage increases during
the same years were considerably larger:

J a p a n , 6.0; I t a l y , 4.9; F r a n c e ,

3.8; United K i n g d o m , 3.5; G e r m a n y , 2.8; C a n a d a , 1.6.
Also during this p e r i o d , U . S . manufacturers had sufficient
capacity beyond that required to meet domestic demands so that they could
fill foreign orders reasonably p r o m p t l y .
Beginning in 1965, h o w e v e r , demand conditions and the competitive
situation c h a n g e d .

The addition of Vietnam war demands to an economy

already fully employed produced inflation at h o m e , a huge surge in imports,
and a reduction in excess capacity which hampered exports.

Meanwhile,

Britain and Germany slid into a mild recession and excess capacity abroad
increased.

Price increases accelerated here and slowed a b r o a d .
During the two years ending in 1967, the annual rise in consumer

prices in this country averaged 2.9 per cent -- or more than double the
rate of increase registered in the first half of the d e c a d e .

A g a i n , except

for C a n a d a , percentage changes in prices in those countries which give us
the strongest competition in international markets moderated
during the two years 1966-67:

appreciably

J a p a n , 4.6;. I t a l y , 2.8; F r a n c e , 2.7; United

K i n g d o m , 3.2; G e r m a n y , 2.5; C a n a d a , 3.7.
Partly as a result of these developments in p r i c e s , in imports and
in domestic demand and supply conditions, the U . S . trade surplus shrank
from nearly $6 billion a year in 1963-64 to about $3-1/2 billion a year in
1966-67.

-6-

F u r t h e r m o r e , excess demand and inflationary pressures have
increased -- not diminished -- during the first half of this year.
the circumstances, the trade surplus has deteriorated further.

Under

During the

first quarter, exports rose by 6 per cent, but were only 3-1/2 per cent
higher than a year earlier.

Simultaneously, imports rose by nearly 10 per

cent in the first quarter, to a level 17 per cent higher than a year earlier.
C o n s e q u e n t l y , the annual rate of trade surplus shrank further by roughly $1
billion dropping from $1.3 billion in the final quarter of last year to only
$300 million in the first quarter of 1968.

Since exports and the trade

surplus were depressed by the New York port strike in M a r c h , the first four
months of this year provide a better indication of the trend.

Even so, the

annual rate of trade surplus in the January-April months was still only $1
billion -- far below the $4 billion rate of early 1967.

Stabilization Policy and the Foreign Trade Outlook
Success in increasing the trade surplus sharply, as we need to do,
from these very low recent levels, will require the attainment of two related
domestic policy objectives.

First, expansion of aggregate domestic demand

must be held down to the amount by which output can be expanded, given the
available resources of labor and capital.

Second, the rapid

increases

recently experienced in the level of u . S. prices and costs must be greatly
slowed d o w n .

The first will contribute to the second, but may not suffice,

since price-cost increases, once u n d e r w a y , acquire a momentum of their own.
Hence the President's stress in his New Year's Day Message on the urgent need
for business and labor

-7-

. . to exercise the utmost responsibility in their
wage-price d e c i s i o n s , which affect so directly our
competitive position at home and in world markets."
On the other h a n d , business and labor will find it much more difficult to
exercise the self-restraint that the national interest requires if aggregate
demand is excessive than if vigorous fiscal and monetary restraints are
applied in a timely m a n n e r .
Given the uncertainties of forecasting economic events, it is not
possible to state with any assurance precisely how large imports and exports
will be in 1968.

However, it is possible to sketch briefly the general

effects on our trade surplus of the enactment of greater fiscal restraint,
as compared with what might otherwise have happened.
For this purpose, it should be kept in mind that, with the long
delay in the adoption of the tax proposal, the Federal Reserve made considerable use of monetary restraint as an imperfect substitute.

And if the

fiscal package had not finally been enacted, still greater monetary restraint
would have been unavoidable.

As we know, tighter credit conditions bear

unevenly upon different sectors of the economy, affecting construction outlays
in particular, and also state and local government spending, while having less
effect on consumer spending.

A l s o , monetary restraint undoubtedly works more

slowly than a tax surcharge to slow down the advance of prices and costs.
I|
The end result of using monetary policy during the first half of the
year as an imperfect substitute for fiscal restraint may be that the total volume
of goods and services produced and purchased during 1968 (i.e., real GNP) may be
only moderately higher than what would have been produced and purchased with

a tax surcharge in effect during the entire year.

But its composition will be

different — with less construction, which has a relatively low import content,
and more of other things with a higher import content.

A l s o , prices will be

a little h i g h e r , and m a y still be rising faster by year-end than would have
been the case if fiscal action had been taken earlier.
imports will probably be h i g h e r .

For this reason also,

M e a n w h i l e , exports might be a little lower

by year-end than if the tax surcharge had been enacted earlier in the year -resulting in less erosion in the competitiveness of U. S. prices.

All these

tendencies would have gone further if fiscal restraint had been further d e l a y e d .
On the basis of these assumptions, we can derive come indication
of the quantitative importance of the income surtax for the trade surplus.

For

the full year 1968, imports may now be $150 million lower with the tax surcharge than they would have been without it, and by year-end they may be running
$300 million a year (one per cent) lower.

Exports for the full year may be only

$50 million higher for the full y e a r , but by year-end they may be running $100
million (or 1/3 of one per cent) higher.

The trade surplus may be larger

by about $200 million for the full year, and may be running $400 million a
year larger in the fourth quarter.

M o r e o v e r , prospects for the trade surplus

next year — during 1969 -- will be better by considerably more than $400
m i l l i o n , as compared with what they would have been in the absence of tax
action, and the prospective trend of the trade surplus will probably be
favorable instead of adverse.

Concluding Remarks
In the m e a n t i m e , our trade surplus remains much too small, and
the deficit in our balance of payments remains too large.

Last year, the

-9-

deficit amounted to $3.6 billion (on the liquidity b a s i s ) , having risen
sharply from $1.4 billion in 1966 and $1.3 billion in 1965.

It is still

far too early to have a firm estimate of the probable outcome for the U . S.
balance of payments this y e a r .
compared with a year ago.

There most likely will be some improvement

In the first three months of this y e a r ,

despite the adverse effect of the New York port strike on the trade
surplus, the liquidity deficit was at an annual rate of $2.4 billion,
compared with last year's $3.6 b i l l i o n .
On the other h a n d , it also seems clear that the improvement of
at least $3 billion visualized in the President's New Year's Day Message
w i l l not be achieved.

While substantial gains m a y be recorded with respect

to private capital flows, there appears to be no prospect of attaining the
projected expansion of $500 million in our trade surplus from 1967 to
1968.

As noted above, the deterioration in the trade position during

the January-April months was particularly disturbing.

Even with a

considerable improvement in the remaining months of the year, the trade
surplus in 1968 will be lower than the $3.5 billion reached in 1967.
T h i s , of course, makes all the more urgent those actions that can
be taken to remove excess pressures on resources and to slow the pace of
inflation.

Unless we can bring about greater domestic stability, we cannot

hope to achieve and maintain a trade surplus of the size necessary to help
us to erase the deficit in our balance of payments.

This failure in turn

-10-

m i g h t generate disturbingly adverse effects on capital m o v e m e n t s .

Hope-

fully, the adoption of higher income taxes and reduced Federal expenditures
(although the action came much later than needed) will help us restore
domestic stability and bring about some improvement in our international
payments position as w e l l .