View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For use at 8 p.m. EST
January 10, 1996

Remarks by
Alan S. Blinder
Vice Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Senior Executives Conference
of the
Mortgage Bankers Association
New York, N.Y.
January 10, 1996

On the Conceptual Basis of Monetary Policy

I want to talk tonight not about what monetary policy
should do in the next week or month, but about a much broader
issue: the conceptual basis for monetary policy in a world in
which the monetary aggregates are all but meaningless.

This is

not a hypothetical world; it is the world in which we all live—
now and for the foreseeable future.
than theoretical interest.

So my topic is of much more

It is about as practical as you can

get.
First an important disclaimer.

While I believe that

the Federal Reserve should talk with society much more, and much
more openly, about the conceptual basis for our monetary policy,
that is a tiny minority view within the Federal Open Market
Committee at present.

The dominant opinion is that silence is

golden; and I have to respect that.

So I want to make it

absolutely clear that I am speaking only for myself.

There is no

official Fed view on these matters, and so there are no "secrets
of the temple" to be revealed.

The Goals of Monetary Policy

To think seriously about how monetary policy should be
conducted, it seems to me axiomatic that you must start with the
objectives.

Precisely what is it that monetary policy is trying

to accomplish?

This question is a relatively easy one because

Congress has provided the answer in the Federal Reserve Act.

2
Although worded somewhat awkwardly, the Act gives us a dual
mandate: to pursue both "stable prices" and "maximum employment."
This dual mandate is, as you may know, under attack
these days.

As you probably also know, I have defended it as

entirely reasonable and appropriate.
the arguments against the status quo.

So let's consider some of
Why might Congress want to

replace our current dual mandate by new instructions that direct
the Fed to focus exclusively on price stability?
First comes a very bad reason, but the one that is most
often offered nonetheless.

It is alleged that the Fed cannot

pursue two goals simultaneously because we have only one
instrument.

Superficially, this sounds correct.

than two, isn't it?

One is less

But as soon as you think seriously about the

argument, it begins to crumble in your hands.

Each of us, in our

everyday lives, pursues multiple goals with a limited set of
instruments.

We understand intuitively that we must trade off

one goal against the other; and we act this way in virtually
everything we do.
For example, when I drive somewhere I have one
instrument—driving s p e e d — a n d two objectives: getting to my
destination quickly, because driving time is unproductive and I
wish to minimize it, and safety, which is, of course, maximized
by driving slowly.

Like all drivers, I select a driving speed

that strikes some sort of reasonable balance between these two
conflicting goals.

3

Or consider the response of an investment adviser to a
client who expresses interest in both current income and price
appreciation.

Do you know any investment adviser who would

reject the client on the grounds that she can pursue only one
goal at a time?

The claim that one instrument limits you to one

target is simply logically fallacious.

Real life is about

tradeoffs, not purity.
So we can reject this first argument out of hand.

But

there are coherent reasons to favor an inflation-only mandate for
the Fed.

What are some?
One might be a belief that price stability is of such

overriding importance for society, and recessions so
inconsequential, that the central bank should be directed to
ignore recessions and focus single-mindedly on bringing down
inflation.
sense.

There may be times and places where this view makes

But nothing can convince me that the contemporary United

States is one of them.
A second reason could be a belief that monetary policy
is powerless to influence real growth and e m p l o y m e n t — i n the
economist's jargon, that money is "neutral."

In that case, the

effects of monetary policy would pass directly through to prices
without stopping off at real output along the way.

As some of

you know, this argument is a favorite intellectual plaything of
academic economists.

But the empirical evidence against it is

overwhelming and, so far as I know, not a single person in the
practical world believes it to be true.

4
A third possible argument could be that the Fed, while
able to stabilize employment in principle, is so incompetent in
practice that it should be enjoined from even trying.
you must judge the validity of this claim for yourself.

Each of
But from

where I sit, and even from where I used to sit, it sure looks
like the Fed has done a much better job than that.
So I conclude that none of the arguments for a monogoal has much merit.

But to make the dual mandate operational,

we must come to terms with the tradeoff between the two goals.

The Nature of the Inflation-Unemployment Tradeoff
Regarding that tradeoff, there is a widespread myth
that the Phillips curve is dead.

But what I like to call the

"clean little secret of macroeconomics" is that exactly the
opposite is true: The Phillips curve is actually among the most
reliable of all the statistical relationships in empirical
m a c r o e c o n o m i c s — a t least for the United States.
What does this reliable empirical Phillips curve say?
First of all, it says that the inflation process in the United
States is highly inertial.

Like one of Newton's bodies in

motion, prices tend to keep rising at the same rate unless acted
upon by an outside force.

That is why the best single predictor

of next year's inflation rate is this year's inflation rate.
Now, what are these "outside forces"?

Leaving aside

supply shocks, which occasionally change the inflation rate quite
dramatically, the principal factor that moves inflation up or

5
down is the so-called GDP g a p — t h e gap between potential and
actual GDP.

(Alternatively, you can measure the gap by the

difference between the actual and natural rates of unemployment.)
If GDP exceeds potential, inflation tends to rise.
short of potential, inflation tends to fall.

If GDP falls

And, of course, if

GDP is approximately at potential, inflation will remain at its
current level, whether that is high or low.
Thus the Phillips curve says, roughly, that the change
in the inflation rate depends on the GDP gap.

Since the natural

rate of unemployment (sometimes called the NAIRU) is the
unemployment rate that corresponds to a GDP gap of zero, we can
rephrase this empirical finding as a statement that inflation
will rise or fall as unemployment is below or above the natural
rate.
So far, I have two ingredients of the story: the dual
mandate that congress has given the Fed, and an empirical finding
about how the U.S. economy works.

Putting them together leads to

a simple two-part conclusion about the tradeoff between inflation
and unemployment:
First, there is no tradeoff between inflation and
unemployment in the long run, since any inflation rate can be
maintained indefinitely if unemployment remains around its
natural rate.

Furthermore, monetary policy cannot keep

unemployment below the natural rate forever.

Hence, the pursuit

of price stability is the appropriate long-run goal for the Fed.

6
Second, however, there is a short-run tradeoff between
inflation and unemployment, and monetary policy affects both
variables.

Hence the Federal Reserve Act's concern with "maximum

employment" should be interpreted as assigning us a short-run
objective: the stabilization of output and employment growth;
that is, the mitigation of business cycles.

While inherently

short-run, this goal is, in my judgment, crucially important.

How Monetary Policy Affects the GDP Gap
What I have said so far about how the economy works
puts the GDP gap at center stage.

It is, first, an indirect

measure of employment and, second, the best indicator of whether
inflation is likely to rise or fall.

So when I think about

monetary policy, I ask three principal questions:
1. Where is the GDP gap today? This involves estimating
potential GDP or, alternatively, the natural rate of
unemployment.
2. Where is the GDP gap likely to be a year or two from
now under unchanged monetary policy?

(The 1-2 year

horizon reflects the lags in monetary policy.)

Answers

to this question, of course, require forecasts of
economic activity.
3. How would a change in monetary policy affect the
likely GDP gap a year or two from now?
Each of these questions is terribly important and
involves many technical issues and difficult judgment calls.

7
But, for tonight, I want to skip over the first two and deal only
with the last: How does monetary policy affect the gap between
potential and actual GDP?
The growth rate of potential GDP is, as a matter of
arithmetic, the sum of two things: the growth rate of labor input
and the growth rate of labor productivity (GDP per hour of work).
In recent years, conventional estimates have been roughly 1%
annual growth for labor input and 1.5% for productivity, leading
to the widely cited 2.5% growth rate for potential GDP measured
in 1987 prices.
estimates today.

I don't want to discuss the validity of those
I only want to point out that the Fed has

rather little influence on either number.

To a first

approximation, we can do nothing about labor force growth and
nothing about trend productivity.

So monetary policy has

practically no influence on potential GDP.
But, by moving interest rates, monetary policy exerts a
great deal of influence over actual GDP.

Some types of spending-

-especially housing, but also business fixed investment and
consumer d u r a b l e s — a r e directly sensitive to interest rates.
Other types of spending are indirectly sensitive.

For example,

interest rates affect the stock market and exchange rates which,
in turn, influence consumer spending and foreign trade.

Now, for

the most part, spending reacts to real interest rates while the
Fed controls only nominal interest r a t e s — a point to which I will
return in a moment.

But since inflationary expectations are

8
pretty stable in the short-run, most changes in nominal interest
rates are probably changes in real interest rates.

The Concept of "Neutral" Monetary Policy
This point leads naturally to a concept that is elusive
but, in my view, is nonetheless extremely useful: the concept of
"neutral" monetary policy.

You may recall that this issue was

discussed extensively in the financial press while the Fed was
tightening in 1994; but it has barely surfaced since.

However,

it is fundamental to the way I think about monetary policy.
Here is my suggested definition of what "neutral
monetary policy" means.

At any moment in time, both the current

level of potential GDP and its likely evolution through time are
essentially independent of monetary policy.

But the evolution of

actual GDP is heavily influenced by monetary policy.

A neutral

monetary policy would set real interest rates at the level that
matches actual GDP to potential GDP, once all the lags are worked
out and in the absence of random shocks.

Notice several critical

aspects of this definition.
First, it is entirely oriented toward inflation, as is
appropriate in view of the Fed's long-term goal of price
stability.

According to my definition, a neutral monetary policy

would be consistent with constant inflation in the medium run.
Continuing what seems to me natural nomenclature, any real
interest rate higher than neutral should be called "tight" money,
because it will lead eventually to a GDP gap and to lower

9
inflation.

Similarly, any interest rate lower than neutral

constitutes "easy" money, for it will, if maintained, eventually
produce a negative GDP gap and rising inflation.
Second, the neutral real interest rate is not a fixed
number.

Many factors other than interest rates influence

aggregate demand, so the real rate needed to match actual GDP to
potential necessarily changes whenever these other factors do.
Among these factors, of course, are fiscal policy and net
exports.

For example, smaller fiscal deficits will, other things

equal, lower the neutral real interest rate.

However, if it is

to serve as a guide to monetary policy, the operational
definition of neutrality rate ought to filter out most of the
quarter-to-quarter fluctuations and focus on longer-run factors.
Finally, and implicit in what I have just said, the neutral real
rate of interest is difficult to estimate and impossible to
estimate precisely.

It is most usefully thought of as a concept

rather than as a number, as a way of thinking about monetary
policy rather than as a mechanical rule.

Nominal versus Real Interest Rates
Let me now come back to two points that I finessed
rather glibly before: the distinction between nominal and real
interest rates, and the distinction between short rates and long
rates (starting with the first).
Unfortunately for the monetary authority, we control
only the nominal interest rate, while it is mostly the real rate

10
that matters for spending.

As I noted earlier, this distinction

is normally not critical in the very short run because
inflationary expectations are quite sluggish, so that changes in
nominal interest rates are most likely changes in real interest
rates.

But, in the longer run, the two rates can diverge quite

sharply.
What happens if the central bank chooses a nominal
interest rate that mistakenly sets the real interest rate too
high?

Since GDP falls below potential, a gap opens up and, with

a lag, inflation begins to fall.

If the central bank fails to

adjust the nominal interest rate down, the real rate goes even
higher.

This spells trouble.

The GDP gap grows larger,

inflation falls faster,and real rates rise even more.

The

economy is put into a disinflationary tailspin.
The opposite happens if the nominal interest rate is
accidentally pegged at a level that makes the real rate too low.
In that case, loose monetary policy leads to an overshoot of
potential GDP and, eventually, to a rise in inflation.

If the

central bank holds the nominal interest rate fixed, the real rate
falls even lower, meaning that monetary policy gets even looser.
We are off to the inflationary races.
The moral of this story is simple: Holding the nominal
interest rate fixed while the inflation rate is changing (in
either direction) is likely to be hazardous to your economy's
health.

Before too long, the central bank must adjust its

nominal rate so as to guide the real rate back toward its neutral

11

setting.
1995.

That's more or less what we have been doing since July

But since (a) no one knows the neutral rate for sure and

(b) that rate changes over time, this is no easy task!

Short Rates versus Long Rates
The second important distinction is between long rates
and short r a t e s — which is really shorthand for the distinction
between the Federal funds rate, which we control, and financial
market prices that really matter for spending decisions—such as
long bond rates, stock prices, and exchange rates.

The problem,

of course, is that the funds rate is of direct interest only to a
few banks.

It has macroeconomic effects only to the extent that

it influences other rates.
The standard theory of the term structure of interest
rates is supposed to rescue us from this dilemma.

It holds that

long rates are the appropriate weighted average of expected
future short rates, plus a risk premium.

So, for example, the

one-year rate should depend on the next 3 65 expected overnight
rates.
But there are two severe practical problems with this
theory.

First, it does not work very well statistically; for

example, tests assuming rational expectations routinely reject
the theory.

Second, and presumably related to the first,

expectations about future short rates are not very well anchored
in reality.

You will note, of course, that it is the market's

12
expectations of future Fed actions that govern long rates, not
the Fed's.
It is this second problem to which I want to call to
your attention.

Because expectations of future Federal Reserve

behavior are not anchored by any underlying reality at present,
the reaction of long rates to a change in Fed policy may deviate
quite far from what we at the Fed see as "the fundamentals."
me cite two recent examples.

Let

Although I was not at the Fed in

late 1993 and early 1994, I am fairly certain that the Fed's
expectation of future Fed funds rates was quite a bit higher than
the market's.

A year later, I was at the Fed, and I know that

the market's expectations of where the funds rate was headed were
well above my own.

In the first case, long rates were "too low;"

in the second case, they were "too h i g h " — b o t h relative to the
likely future path of short rates. In each case, the faulty
estimate was attributable to misapprehensions about where the Fed
was headed.

The Fed and the Markets
When the response of long rates (and stock prices and
exchange rates) to changes in the funds rate is unpredictable,
monetary policy has a severe practical problem to cope with, for
our ability to predict the effects of our own actions hinges on
our ability to predict how those actions will move market prices.
Curing this problem is one reason—though not the only r e a s o n —
why I favor greater openness at the Fed.

13
If the Fed would give markets a wider window on our
goals, our worldview, and our general strategy, the market's
medium- and long-term expectations would be better anchored in
reality.

Market participants would then be able to make better

guesses about future Federal Reserve decisions.

And that, in

turn, might make it easier for the Fed to predict how long rates
would react to changes in the funds rate.

If that were t r u e — a n d

I admit it is just a h y p o t h e s i s — w e at the Fed would be better
able to predict the effects of our own policy actions on
financial markets and therefore on the real economy.

In a word,

you would be better at predicting us and we would be better at
predicting you.
Don't get me wrong, I am no polyanna on this score.
Markets have minds of their own and often move dramatically for
reasons having nothing to do with Fed policy.

They exhibit herd

behavior and seem to overreact to almost everything.

Bond

traders trading 30-year bonds are thinking somewhat less than 30
years ahead; indeed, many of them have not even lived 30 years 1
And there were speculative bubbles before there was a Fed to
speculate about.

So I don't believe that keeping the markets

better informed about monetary policy would render them either
stable or predictable.

But I do believe that we could at least

reduce the speculative bubbles that are rooted in bad guesses
about the Fed's behavior.
So far as I can tell, however, this remains a minority
view both at the Federal Reserve and on Wall Street, where the

14
prevailing view is that mystery is an integral part of sound
monetary policy.

But I remain unconvinced and know of no good

reason to think that markets work better when they are less well
informed.

Illustration: The Taylor Rule
One way to illustrate how the concepts I have been
talking about can be applied in practice is to refer to a
monetary policy rule suggested by Professor John Taylor of
Stanford University.

I hasten to add that the Taylor rule is

certainly not the official policy of the FOMC.

However, the

reason it has garnered so much publicity of late is that it
tracks Fed behavior since 1987 extremely well.
The Taylor rule is an equation that predicts where the
FOMC will set the federal funds rate.

It starts with an estimate

of the real federal funds rate that corresponds to neutral
monetary policy; Taylor uses 2 percent.

Add the current

inflation rate, say 3 percent, and you have an estimate of the
neutral nominal funds r a t e — i n this case, 5 percent.
According to Taylor, the FOMC will deviate from this
neutral interest rate if the GDP gap differs from zero or if
inflation differs from our long-run target—which the FOMC has
never enunciated, but which Taylor pegs at 2 percent.
Specifically, when inflation is above the presumed 2 percent
target or GDP is above potential, the Committee will raise the
nominal federal funds rate to put the real funds rate above 2

15
percent.

On the other hand, inflation below 2 percent or GDP

below potential will lead the FOMC to set the real funds rate
below 2 percent.
Now I could quarrel with many of the details of
Taylor's rule.

Were it being used in practice as a monetary

policy rule, these details would be important and well worth
arguing about.But that is not my purpose here.

I bring up

Taylor's rule only to illustrate how the four concepts I have
discussed t o n i g h t — t h e Fed's dual mandate, the tradeoff between
inflation and unemployment, the effect of interest rates on the
GDP gap, and the concept of neutral monetary p o l i c y — c a n be
brought together to create a way to think about monetary policy.
Notice four crucial aspects of the Taylor rule:
1. It uses an estimate of the neutral real federal
funds rate as a central concept in the formulation
of monetary policy.
2. It assumes that the Fed has two objectives:
driving inflation down to 2 percent and driving
the GDP gap to zero.

I argued earlier that such a

dual objective is both required by law and
entirely appropriate.
3. Its coefficients embody a presumed attitude
toward the tradeoff between inflation and
unemployment, which I argued the Fed must have.
4. It assumes, as I did earlier, that the Fed
regulates aggregate demand by changing the nominal

16
interest rate, but that it is the real interest
rate that matters.

Conclusion
To wrap us, let me tie this discussion back to the
question I raised at the outset: How do you conduct monetary
policy when the monetary aggregates are essentially useless?
Let's first remember the good old days.
Monetarists used to think of the "neutral" money growth
rate—Friedman's k p e r c e n t — a s the one that set the growth
rate of nominal GDP equal to the sum of the target inflation
rate plus the trend growth rate of real GDP. Faster money
growth than that would be expansionary in the short run and
inflationary in the long run; slower money growth would be
contractionary and disinflationary.

But no one can

operationalize such a policy nowadays because the
relationship between money and nominal GDP has broken down.
Today, the real short-term interest rate is the
logical replacement for the money growth rate.

Its

"neutral" value can be estimated from history and/or from
econometric models, although it can never be known with
certainty.

"Tight" monetary policy can then be defined as

keeping the real interest rate higher than neutral.

Such a

policy can be expected to contract the economy, after a lag,
and reduce inflation, after an even longer lag.

Conversely,

"easy" money means holding the real short rate below the

9

17

neutral setting to stimulate the economy.

Just how tight or

loose monetary policy should be depends on the goals of the
Fed, its attitudes toward the tradeoff between inflation and
unemployment, and the sensitivity of the economy to interest
rate changes.
There has been much talk in recent years of the
problem posed by the loss of the so-called nominal anchor
for monetary policy when monetary aggregates are abandoned
in favor of interest rates. The new "anchor" I am tacitly
proposing has three pieces:
1. the central bank's long-run inflation target;
2. its commitment to keep real interest rates
higher than neutral when inflation is above
target, other things equal;
3. understanding that nominal interest rates must
not be held fixed, but must be adjusted for
inflation because it is real interest rates that
matter.
Yes, I know this all requires a certain amount of
trust in your central bank. But can you think of an
institution you trust more?