Full text of The Southwest Economy : May 1989
The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
1111 II III I{ \1 Itl "I I{\ I U \'k. 01 () \1 L\S Maquiladoras and the Southwest Economy T he Mexican maquiladora sedor is a large and growing assemblage of foreign-owned companies thaI produce chiefly for expon to the United States. Because more ~han 80 "percent of maquiladora manufacruring plants are within a few miles of the U.S.-Mexico border, this industry has imponam implications for the Southwesl economy. The maquiladora program was developed in response to the cancellalion of the U.s. bracero program. A \I \'i I')l'N shonage of domestic farm labor dUring World War" led the Uniled States to admit Mexican laborers to work in our country. This policy was fonnally sandioned in the early 1950s. Many workers left the interior of Mexico and established pennanent homes on that country's nonhern border, so they could take seasonal bracero jobs in the United States. These events caused Significant population growth in nonhem Mexico, but they also caused U.s. labor groups to organize political Maquiladora Centers AI ol Mexico This document was digitized and made available by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas' Historical Library (FedHistory@dal.frb.org). "Maquiladora expansion has been particularly strong during the middle and late 19805. ,. pressure against the program. [n 1%4, when 185,000 /'.texicans were working under Ihe bracero program, the United States lerminaK>d the program. To find jobs for the thousands of unemploy<.'(\ braceros, the Mexican government designed a program that used U.S. tariff laws to attract U.s. manufacturers to the oorder. One of these laws states thai if a firm brings inputs from the United St.1tes. assembles them abroad, and returns the product to our coumry, only the value added by manufacture is subject to tariffs. The IOlal value of the impon is not taxed. To benefit from this law, Mexico waivE.'<I a number of its traditional restrictions on foreign investment. It allowed l()()..percent foreign control of plant operatiOns. It also perrniUcd duty-free impons of materials and equipment, provided that all output would be exported from Mexico. These new rules made it easier for U.S. and other non-Mexican producers to use Mexico's low-cost labor to compete with Asian producers. Even Ihough the maquiladora program originally was designed to find new employment for fann workers, most of whom were male, the maquiladoras have usually hired females. During the 1970s, only about one-fifth of all workers were males. Since then, the share has risen to a little less than one-third, The maquiladorJ program has also often been called the "twin-plant program: The idea was Ihat a plant on the Mexican side would coordinate its operations with a twin just across the border in the United States. TIlese twins do exist. but they are the exception and not the nile. l.ess than 10 percent of the plants in Mexico have a twin along the u.s. border. At first, Mexicm law required maquiladoras to locate on the border. l":lter, Mexico allowL>d these plants into much of the interior (see 11)(! map), Despite Mexico's relaxation of locational restrictions. more than 80 percent of maquiladora employment is still on the border, Mexico also relaxed ils restriction that all products of maquiladords had to be exported. Now. 80 percent of total output has to be exported. but not all of it. Chart 1 Maquiladora Employment Thousands at Ernp1<>ye8s .., '00 o '81 '82 '83 '84 '85 '88 '87 What Made Maquiladoras Grow? Mexico's maquiladora employment growth h:ls been r::apid for some time, but expansion has been particularly strong dUring the middle and late 1980s. As Chart 1 shows, employment rose from a little more than 200,000 in mid-l984 to over 360,000 in mid-I988. This growth is a reaction. in part. to the devaluation of the Mexican peso in 1982 and 10 subsequent devaluations. Before 1982, the peso was persistently overvalued against the dollar. While changes in the exchange value of the peso against the dollar are related to maquilador::a gro'Nth, a more direct link is that between dollardenominated labor costs in Mexico and those in (){her countries. Chart 2 compares U.S. dollar-per·hour manufacturing labor costs in Mexico versus three of the newly industrialized Pacific nations. lltese countries are among Mexico's major competitors for foreignowned assembly plants. Despite some extreme fluctuations, Mexican labor This document was digitized and made available by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas' Historical Library (FedHistory@dal.frb.org). '88 Electrollics account for 42 percent oftotall'aille added by maqlliladora plallts. Chart 2 Labor Costs lor Selected Countries and Hong Kong u.s ea.r. Ptor Hour '.00 wage. low-skilled labor to attract manufaauring indusuies. One of the reasons for this decline in relative costs has been the adjustmenl of the Mexican '00 p""'. ~~-----;~~. ~~ '.00 costs have fallen relalive 10 lhose of other counuies (hal have relied on low- ....:._.. _.. -"'--::"'71""'~.: .... ...... ~:_. ~_ KorN 0.00 77 78 7i 110 'Ill '82 '83 '801 "$$ "llIS '11 What Do Maquiladoras Make? The mix of maqulladorn products is narrowly focused. Electronics account for 42 percent of (Olal \l:llue added by maquiladora plants. Shipping costs for electronics are low in relalion to product value, so long distance transport expenses are less significant in determining plant location than Ihey are for many Other producis. l1tc electronics-producing maquiladoras are generally assembly plants. They take components that are manufactured elsewhere and they put them logether. The tariff-saving char.lcteristics of such operations were whal originally helped to motivate finns to go to Mexico. More recently, other lypes of operations have expanded. Currently, about 24 percent of tOl:al value added in maquiladora plants is in lransponation equipment manufacture. Some of these plants, which manufacture parts that are used by U.S. and japanese auto companies, do nOi qualify for the special U.S. value-adck>d-only tariff ueaunem thai originally helped to motivate maquiladora activity. These plants do more than simply assemble components. Nevertheless, the labor savings are signiflC,mt enough SO that companies will start maquiladoras anyway. Who Owns Maquiladoras? Other factors also motivated the recem expansion of maquiladora activity in Mexico. A fairly recent phenomenon has been the gro"W of maquiladora plants that are not owned by U.S. finns. These plants represent only a small minority of toul maquiladoras. Of the 1,125 maquiladora plants operating in Mexico in 1987, 53 were owned by finns that were nOi of U.S. origin, including 5 French plants, 5 British plants, 4 Dutch plants, and, most significantly, 31 japanese plants. In 1988, the Japanese added eight more plants. Labor costs and access to U.S. markets are irn(Xlrtant mOlivations for lhese maquiladora.~, but protectionists in the United States argue that the Japanese also use the maquiladora progr.U11 to avoid quotas imposed on products that originate in Japan. Whether or not this is true, anticipation of funher anti-Japanese protectionist legislation in the United States may be motivating the establishment of japanese plants in Mexico. Nevertheless. a number of the japanese maquiladoras coordinate their operations with japanese manufacturing activity that already lakes place in the interior of the United States. RegardJess of the relative importance of each of these motivations, foreign maquiladoras have a more positive impact on U.S. economic activity than if they were located in their home COUntries. Maquiladoras' Impact 00 Tuas In mid-I987, wben employment in the great majority of Texas cities was This document was digitized and made available by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas' Historical Library (FedHistory@dal.frb.org). Rapid~}' rising maquiladora lI'ages, in dollar terms, u'Ould slou' maquiladora grou'tb, below :I year e;1rlier. all (our m3jor Texas dlies on the Mexic3n border were growing. And over lhe previous 24 months, maquiladora employmem in every one of the Mexican citIes across from Ihese Texas communities had grown by 25 percent or more. Though much is unknown about (he impact of maquilador.ls on the United $r:ales. :m estimate of some of the effects of nuquiladoras on Texas is possible. First, workers in the Mexican maquilador:1s spend some of their income jusl across the border in Ihe United Stales. [estim:lte that Mexican maquilador:l workers spend about 565 million annually on purchases in Texas. These expenditures mean about 4.000 additional jobs in the stale. A second impact involves the Texas workers in Texas-based twin plams. I estimate that about 16,000 Texas workers hold jobs in TCll;3S twins of the Mexic-.U1 m:lquiladoras. The impact of purchases in Texas by these plants and their workers result in an additional 25.000 jobs in the s~te, so that the tOtal impact of the U.S, twin plants is about 41,000 jobs. Third Is the direct impact that Mexican maquiladora operations ha\'e on Texas. We know these Mexican operations rt..'quire Texas-oo.sed customs brokers and transpon services. but the plants also purchase inputs from ITUny Texas companies. A Sludy of maqUiladoras showed they annually use about 56 billion of inputs from the United $tates. Though Texas firms supply only pan of the inputs. purchases from Texas suppliers could mean as many as 10.000 addidonal jobs for the state. Fut\ll"e Growth Chart 3 \'l;'h.i1e it is dear that the maquiladora sector has been growing rapidly, the outlook for future growth is less clear. \l1ut clouds this outlook is that. e\'en though Mexican wages are Slill far belov.· U.S. wages. Mexican monef.3ry and exchange rate policy is C1using the dollar cost of a Mexican worker to rise faster than the cost of a U.S. worker. ....Iexico has taken strong stcps to reduce its rate of infb.tion from over 1(1() percent in 1987 to about 60 percent in 1988. But even though the f'Jte of price increase in Mexico slowed subst:mtially last year, prices there h:l\'e increased considerably faster than in the United Statcs. In a markct of freely fiuClu:lling exchange rates. we would expect devalu:uions of the peso to bring the relative buying power of the dollar back into adjustment. The peso-dollar exchange rate, however, has changed very little since late in 1987, because the Mexican government has lx.-cn defending the peso by purchasing it with foreign currency. nle result has been a substantial decline in the real peso dollar exchange rnte (see Chart 3). This means that a dollar now buys much less of ffiOS( Mexican products than it did a )'ear ago. So far, the Mexican government has acted to hold wage increases well below the rate of inflation, SO the dollar cost of workers in MexiCO has nQl. risen by as much as o\'erall prices have. E\'en so. the average dollar "",-age and benefit cost per Mexican maquiladora employee rose by more than 21 percent between mid-l987 and mid-I988. (~,..o.--l U.S. Real Exchange Rate with Mexico "*' ...... 1~100 "" '" '" '" . ,'" tlO ·tlO "1 '82 "S3 ... "85 '81 "17 '1lll A more serious concern is the potential for funher wage pressures in response to recent infi:uion and the possibility that these pressures will be expressed through increases in dollar cost per worker. A wage adjustment would not demoy the maquiladora industry; it has existed and even grown when the dollar cost of wages in Mexico W:lS alx)\'e that in Far Eastern countries. But rnpidly rising maquiladora wages. in dollar teons, will slow growth. Summary In recent years, relatively low dollar wages have stimulated growth in maquiladora employment-with a significant impact on the Texas economy. Last summer, overall a\·ctage monthly wages and salaries ,,'ere less than S300 per employee. BUI if Mexic:.m rates of wage growth outpace those elsewhere, the potential for maquiladora expansion will diminish. -William C. Gruben This document was digitized and made available by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas' Historical Library (FedHistory@dal.frb.org). ECONOMIC COMMENTARY by Robert H. Boykin, President Federal Reseroe Bank ofDallas Excerpted below are bighlightsfrom testimOlly give'll try Robert Boykin at a special bearing ofthe Committee on Ballkill& Finance and UrlXIIl Affairs, U.S. HOUSll ofRepresentatives, 011 March II, 1989 ill san AII/onio, Texas. III his testimony, Mr. &ykill discussed the thrift crisis OIld the legislaliol/ recenl/y proposed try Presidem Blish loaddress this critical issue. l The Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas suppons, in principle, the legislation proposed by Presidem Bush for the refonn and recovery of the thrift industJy. A salis/aclory soIutio't to the problems pUlgui1l8 the thrifts is essemial to ensure the ceo/willie weI/-being C!ltbe nation as a whole and particularly the DaNas Federal Reserve DisJrict (Texas, Louisiana, and New Mexico). It is imperative mal a solution to this crisis be reached as qUickly as possible; the threat this situation poses ClfU10l be allowed [0 continue. Removing this thre:1.I could contribute substantially to broadening the region's rwo-year old economic recovery. The Impact of the Thrift Crisis on Banks and Healthy Thrifts The thrift crisis has Significantly increased the cost of funds for financial institutions in the District. 2 In Texas, interest premiums on deposits averaged 28 basis !Wints for banks and more than 50 basis !Wints for thrifts in 1988. Even sound, healthy Texas banks have paid an additional 10 to 20 basis points for funds in 1988, compared to banks in similar financial condition elsewhere. 'llle so-called Texas premium on deposits can be anributed to IWO factors. The first is the large volume of nonperfonning re-.ll estate loans held by banks and thrifts. Banks have not yet managed to fully write down their real estate loan portfolios to current values. Consequently, questioru; persist regarding the value of these assets, making the financial condition of these institutions unclear. llte second factor driving up the cost of funds at District institutions has been the aggressive pursuit of funds by insolvent thrifts. Insolvent thrifts bid up deposit rates to auract funds, forcing the healthy members of the industry to raise their own deposit rates in order to compele. The Texas premium on deposit rntes has affected the bottom line for commercial banks. This is illustrnted by the negative return on assets at Texas banks for the past twO years. As losses have mounted, the equity capital position of the District's banks has also fallen--from an avernge of 6.9 percent of assets in 1985 {Q an estimated 4.9 percem in 1988. Moreover, over the same period, the banks' primary capital position has declined from 7.8 percent of assets to 6.6 percent in 1988. This compares to the current regulatory standard of 5.5 percent for primary capital and suggests that District banks are approaching regulatory minimums. In fact, many banks have fallen below the regulatory minimum. TIle upshot of this situation is thaI otherwise healthy banks and thrifts have been negatively affected by the continued operation of insolvent thrift institutions. It is likely that the District's financial sector wlll continue to deteriorate until the situation is resolved. 1be Need for Both Public and Private capital One aspect of the President's proposal is panicularly importam for the SOUth\....est-namely, the need for both public and privatc capital in any successful restructuring of the thrift industry. PriV'".llC capital provides a cushion for the deposit insurance funds and is cssential if risk to those funds is to be kept within reasonable bounds. In the current environment, however, private capital cannot be anracted to the thrift industry without sufficient public capital. [n shon, there is a symbiotic relationship between those two components of capital. If the infusion of public capital falls shon of what is necessary to anrnct private capital, the effectiveness of the public infusion will be nullified in tlle long run. We have seen that !Wim illustrnted in the Southwest Plan. The recapilalizations undcnaken thus far have resulted in a disappointingly small infusion of private capital into the tluifts. Consequently, the restructuring has been too dependent on federal assistance. Another point should be addressed. Under the proposed legislation, thrifts are to be brought up to commercial bank capital standard~ over time. A large number of thrifts are currently solvent but not in robust health. Presumably, the worst of the thrift problems will be addressed under the plan now in Congress. BUl additional thought should be given to how these moderntely healthy and barely solvent thrifts (and, 10 some extent, banks as well) can rnise the required capital and, at the same time, compete with publicly recapilalized institutions. Summary The prolonged operntion of insolvent thrifts constitutes an immediatc threat to the deposit insurance fund, 10 solvent banks and thrifts, and to the stabi1i[y of thc financial system itself. Strategies that have been employed by insolvent institutions could both compound the problems of currently solvent institutions and lead to a new generntion of bankrupt thrifts and commercial banks. Any delays in resolving the current crisis will only seIVe to increase the cost to taxpayers, to further urxlennine the public's confidence in the financial system. and to endanger the frngile economic recovery currently under way in the Southwest. We view the President'S plan as one which can resolve the crisis, and we urge its prompt enactment. A copy of Mr. Boykin's romplete testimony is aV'"diiabie by writing the PubliC Affairs Dcpanmem. Feder.ll Reser,'c Bank of Dallas, Station K, Dallas, Texas 75222, or by ClUing (214) 651-6289. , See Genic D. ShOll and JeffCT)' W. Gunther. tbe Texas Thrift Sihmti()Il: Implicalkmsfvr the Texas Fillancial brdustry. Federal Reserve Bank of I Dallas, Financial Industry Studies Deparunen.t (Dallas, St.'P'ember 1988), for a romplell: discussion. This publication was digitized and made available by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas' Historical Library (FedHistory@dal.frb.org) The 1989 Drought: An Update During February and March, rain and snow improved soil moisture conditions in parts of Texas. But soils remain Probabllity 01 Drooght Conditions Ending by Mid·September (P",C8Il\) abnormally dry throughout most of the Siale. Rainfall is unlikely to end drought conditions before the end of summer. In 1988. drought. or abnormally dry soil, devastated agricultural production across the country. By midsummer, much of the nation was roasting in extreme drought. At that time the Southwest was experiencing only modernle drought conditions, and mosl famlCrs in the region completed the year with good crop and livestock production. During the fall of 1988, soil moisture conditions worsened in Texas. By Derember, a large portion of the slate was in severe drought. Historical rainfall indicated a low probability that dry soil conditions would improve by spring or midsum· mer. 1 Insufficient soil moisture began to threaten 1989 agriculrural production. Since January, rain and snow prOVided sufficient moisture to encourage some spring planting. Much of Texas remains in drought, however, and plantings of com and sorghum are below average. [n the Rio Grande Valley, dry weather is discouraging some planting. Fanners will need additional rain soon to ensure good crop development. While soil moisture conditions have improved in north· central and west Texas, conditions remain very dry throughout most of the state (see the map). The drought is now extreme in central and coastal Texas. In the panhandle, soil conditions have deteriorated from wet to near a mild drought in the past two months. Soil moisture has also declined around Brownsville, pushing that area into moderate drought. Given historical rainfall, dry soil conditions are likely 10 persist through the summer. In the drought-amicted areas of 1•.6'18.0' ""'=O:J the state, the probability of the drought ending by midSeptember ranges from 1.6 to 30.6 percent. l Dry soil does not guarantee poor crop and livestock production, but dry soil puts Texas agricultural in(.'Ome at risk. Well-timed rainfall remains essential for good crop and livestock production. -Fiona Sigalla I Sec The Soutbwest £Col/omy, March 1989. , See Thomas R. Karl, Richard w. Knight, D. S. Ezell, and Frank T. Quinlan, Probabilities and Prec/pilallor, Reql/ired to End/Ameliorate Droughts. Historical dimalology s<'Ties 3-16, (Asheville, N.C.: N3tionaJ Oceanic: and Atrnospheri<: Administration, National Climatic Data Center. 1986). Technically. a drought ends when soil moisture improves to mild drought. Oil Price Gains likely 10 Be Sustained Market conditions suggest that recent gains in oil prices will likely be sustained in the near future. And by year's end, oil prices may rise further. Although renewed OPEC solidarity has accompanied recent gains in oil prices, growing oil demand is driving the increases. Recent data indicate that world oil consumption increased by more than 3 percent dUring 1988. PreviOUS estimates were closer to 2 percent. Solid economic growth and continued adjustment to lower oil price expectations appear to be the main factors boosting world oil demand. Besides boosting prices, increasing demand is helping OPEC achieve solidarity. Because changes in crude oil inventories are inferred from estimates of production and consumption, the data revision also means that current oil inventories are much lower than analysts previously thought. With low inventories and continued growth in demand, oil prices are unlikely to drop in the spring, when demand typically takes a seasonal decline. When demand begins its seasonal rise in the fall, strong demand and the current degree of OPEC cooperation could mean rising oil prices. Higher oil prices and changing perceptions of oil market conditions have increased oil field exploration and development. On a seasonally adjusted basis, lhe U.S. and Texas rig counts were aboul 10 percent higher in the first half of March than in February. Further gains in drilling are likely. -Stephen P. A. Brown The Sowhwest £Col/amy is published six times annually by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views expressed are those of lhe authors and should not be altributed to lhe Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System. Articles may be reprinted on lhe condition that the source is credited and a copy is proVided to the Research Deparlment of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The Sowhwest Economy is available without charge by writing the Public Affairs Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Station K, Dallas, Texas 75222, or by telephoning (214) 651-6289. This document was digitized and made available by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas' Historical Library (FedHistory@dal.frb.org).