View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

SOME COMPARATIVE EVIDENCE ON THE EFFECTIVENESS OF
INFLATION TARGETING

Thomas Laubach and Adam Posen

Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Research Paper No. 9714

April1997

This paper is being circulated for purposes of discussion and comment only.
The contents should be regarded as preliminary and not for citation or quotation without
permission of the author. The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily
reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank ofNew York of the Federal Reserve System.
Single copies are available on request to:

Public Information Department
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
New York. NY 10045

Some Comparative Evidence on the Effectiveness of Inflation Targeting

Thomas Laubach
Princeton University
and
Adam S. Posen•
Federal Reserve Bank of New York

May 1997

• Corresponding author. The views expressed here are solely those of the authors and do
not reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, the Federal Reserve System, or any
other member of their staff. Work on this project was undertaken while Laubach was a graduate
intern at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. We are grateful to Ben Bernanke, Ben
Friedman, Andrew Haldane, Ken Kuttner, Rick Mishkin, Mark Watson, and participants in
seminars at the Bank for International Settlements, the Bank of England, the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York, Harvard University, and the Swiss National Bank for comments and
suggestions.

1

Does the adoption of an inflation target by a country have an effect on that country's rate
of inflation and on inflation's interaction with real economic variables? Does inflation targeting
alter private-sector inflation expectations? Theoretical appeals to nominal anchors may justify
countries' various moves via targeting towards greater monetary policy transparency, but the
actually realized economic effectiveness of their targeting experiences should be assessed as
well. The question of effectiveness must be posed as a counterfactual - did target adopting
countries find economic benefits they would not have found had they not targeted?
Since only a few countries for only a short span of time have been targeting, there is no
simple conclusive econometric test for the effectiveness of inflation targets. Instead, we offer
three sets of measurements of the effect of inflation targeting: the first concerning whether the
disinflation has been achieved at lower cost, or whether inflation has come down in targeters to a
greater extent than we would attribute to normal cyclical factors, domestic and international; the
second concerning whether the interactions between inflation, monetary policy, and real
variables have changed; and the third concerning whether private-sector inflation expectations
have come down after targeting beyond that drop usually associated with a drop in inflation.

This multifaceted and (perhaps unfashionably) straightforward approach differs from that of the
few prior comparative empirical assessments of inflation targeting, which tend to focus on solely
one measure, usually having to do with extracting financial market expectations. 1
The sample of countries which adopted inflation targeting as a framework for monetary
strategy we consider consists of New Zealand, Canada, the United Kingdom, and Sweden (in

1

(1993).

See Ammer and Freeman (1995), Freeman and Willis (1995), Huh (1996), and Svensson

2
order of adoption). These are the OECD countries which have pursued inflation targeting
for at
least three years. Establishing a baseline for measurement of the effectiveness of inflation
targeting in these countries on the three aspects listed, however, is not trivial. Clearly, the
first
line of measurement must be performance versus a country's past prior to target adoption
;
equally clearly, since these countries have neither been through a complete business cycle
since
adoption nor adopted inflation targets under similar circumstances (two replacing a lost
exchange rate commitment, two installing a nominal anchor where there was none), this
measure
is not without limitations.

In response, we also ask whether a inflation targeting has been effective along these lines
in comparison to a similar country which did not adopt inflation targeting - for Canada and

New

Zealand, our point of compar ison is Australia2, another small open resource-exporting U.S.cycle tied economy, while for Sweden and the United Kingdom, our point of comparison
is
Italy, another ERM-exiting European industrial economy'. Finally, to make sure we are
not
expecting too much, we compar e the effects of monetary policy under inflation targeting
to that
seen in the two credible nominal targeters of longstanding, Germany and Switzerland. With
these three sets of structured comparisons on three criteria, we hope to get a reasonably robust
set of evidence on the effectiveness of inflation targeting.
It is worth emphas izing that at first look, inflation targeting has been a success - inflation
was in or below the target range for all sample targeting countries, as shown in Figure 1,
and
2

3

Which only adopted inflation targeting at the very end of our sample period.

Huh (1996), to our minds, compares apples to oranges by making the focus of his
analysis a comparison of the United Kingdom experience to those of France (an ERM adherent
with an at-the-time overvalued exchange rate and rising credibility) and of the United States
(a
country without a declared nominal anchor, a different business cycle, and lesser openness).

3

noticeably below these countries' average inflation levels of the 1970s and 1980s. Recapping
the macroeconomic baslines of Figures 2-5, the low inflation in .comparison to these countries'
earlier experience was sustained without unusual macroeconomic conditions. In New Zealand,
the disinflation during the four years prior to target adoption went with a period of sluggish GDP
growth and, since 1988, rising unemployment. The continuation of the disinflation during
1990/91, amidst recession in many other OECD economies, led to recession and sharply rising
unemployment in New Zealand. In Canada, the disinflation was achieved along with continued
progress in lowering unemployment (Figure 3), only a brief spike in nominal interest rates, and
continued positive, though slowing, growth. In the United Kingdom, similar to Canada, the
disinflation begun two years prior to target adoption continued on the background of improving
growth, falling unemployment, and much lower nominal interest rates in the wake of the UK's
exit from the ERM. Yet, while these countries' drops in inflation represent no small feat, it only
states that the adoption of inflation targeting was consistent with a preference shift to lower
inflation. The question of effectiveness lies in whether targeting made this result less costly in
terms of output or easier to maintain in terms of expectations, either of which would make prices
more stable over the long-run.

I. Sacrifice Ratios and Phillips Curves
Our first set of evidence concerns the response of inflation to the business cycle. We
look at two related measures of the responsiveness of inflation to the real economy, sacrifice
ratios and forecasts of moves in inflation from Phillips curves. Sacrifice ratios are the standard
measure of how many point-years of unemployment or output growth must be sacrificed to pay

4
for a point of disinflation. It is usually presumed that where a disinflationary policy is believed to
be credible, and is clearly announced, disinflation will be less costly because finns and households

will reset their expectations and recontract; at lower initial rates of inflation (and under less
coordinated or less frequent fonns of wage contracting) we expect that sacrifice ratios will be
higher, because the relative cost of recontracting versus getting inflation right, is higher.
Controlling for the pre-disinflation environment, a potential effect of inflation targeting would be
to lower the sacrifice ratio by making monetary policy announcements more immediately credible.
To compute sacrifice ratios for our countries, we follow the methodology of Ball (1994),
using quarterly data throughout. Ball defines trend inflation as a centered 9-quarter moving
average of annual inflation rates, and then identifies peaks (troughs) in trend inflation as quarters
in which trend inflation is higher (lower) than in the previous and the following 4 quarters. A
disinflation is an episode that starts at an inflation peak and ends at a trough with an annual
inflation rate at least two points lower than at the peak. He assumes that trend output is
piecewise log linear, and that output is at its trend level at an inflation peak (since at the peak the
change in inflation is zero) and four quarters after a trough (arguing that the effects of disinflation
are persistent, and that therefore output returns to trend only with a lag). The numerator of his
sacrifice ratios, i.e. the output loss during the disinflation, is computed as the area under the
straight line connecting log GDP at the peak with log GDP four quarters after the trough.

In their comments on Ball's paper, Friedman and Cecchetti level a number of criticisms at
Ball's methodology. Friedman raises the question of whether the sacrifice should be measured as
output foregone, or as the increase in unemployment, and offers some skeptical remarks regarding
Ball's assumptions when output is at trend. Justified as these concerns may be, since our goal is

5
to compare sacrifice ratios both across time and across countries, we are primarily interested in
the relative magnitude of the ratios. In this sense, consistent mismeasurement would appear not
to affect our results. More troublesome is Friedman's suggestion concerning the endogeneity of
central bank behavior, in that central banks might "pursue their presumed goal of disinflation more
rigorously when they have reason to believe that the short-run trade-offs associated with doing so
are more favourable" (p 186). Cecchetti emphasires this point by showing that Ball's
interpretation of the output loss as being due to demand contractions only, thus treating effects of
supply shocks as noise, affects the results critically. We will return to this question later when we
present results from estimating Phillips curves.
The data we use are real GDP series from the OECD MEI, and all-item CPI series from
the BIS. Quarterly inflation is computed as the percent change of the CPI in the last month of the
quarter over the corresponding month of the previous year4• For each of the eight countries we
identify two completed disinflations, following the two oil shocks respectively, and for all but
Germany and Switzerland we identify a third completed disinflation during the early 1990s, which
gives us 22 disinflationary episodes from which we compute sacrifice ratios. As a check for the
reasonability of our figures, we compare results with Ball for the first two disinflations for six
countries in our sample for which Ball also reports sacrifice ratios based on quarterly data. The
mean of Ball's sacrifice ratios is 1.50, while that of the comparable episodes in our sample is 1.33,
and the correlation coefficient between the two sets of ratios is 0. 75, indicative of good

4

Using alternatively the percent change of the middle month of the quarter, or the average of
the inflation rates of the three months within the quarter, did not affect the results strongly.

6
consistency5.
Given this standard, we consider whether the countries that adopted inflation targets did in
fact lower their costs of disinflation, both relative to their own past and relative to comparable
countries that did not adopt inflation targets. The regression reported in Table 1 attempts to
explain variation in the sacrifice ratio by the initial level of inflation (as above, assuming that at
lower inflation levels disinflation is more costly), the total amount of inflation disinflated in the
episode (assuming that a larger disinflation should lead to a smaller cost per unit disinflated once
recontracting begins), and the length of time of the disinflation (assuming that quicker disinflations
should be more credible and therefore less costly). Our results confirm the importance of initial
inflation to determining the sacrifice ratio, and we use this fact to forecast the expected cost of
disinflation for each of the countries in its most recent disinflation. For all four inflation targeters
except Sweden, the actual sacrifice ratio experienced was not only higher than the average
sacrifice ratio of previous disinflations, but higher than forecast, even controlling for the low
initial levels of inflation in the UK and Canada. For Australia and Italy, our non-targeting
comparison countries, the actual sacrifice ratio during the latest disinflation was by contrast lower
than forecast, although higher than the past average sacrifice ratio. Finally, the sacrifice ratios for

5

Discrepancies between our results and those in his Table 5.1 can be either due to differences
in the timing of disinflations, or differences in the measured output gap for a given episode. When
performing the exercise of using Ball's episodes and changes in inflation, our results are almost
identical to his, which means that the measured output gaps are not the cause for the
discrepancies. When instead using Ball's episodes, but our own measure of change in inflation,
there are discrepancies between Ball's and our ratios of the order of magnitude of 0.2 to 0.5.
Finally, when we date the disinflationary episodes ourselves using Ball's criteria, we arrive at
differences in the beginning and end dates of the order of 1 to 3 quarters. These differences in
episodes have strong effects on the resulting sacrifice ratios. This suggests that Ball computed
inflation in a different way, and therefore identifies slightly different episodes, from us.

7

Germany and Switzerland (from an earlier period) are both lower than the predicted values and
lower than their own past sacrifice ratios. Disinflation under inflation targeting - or at least the
first disinflation under targeting - is not less costly than without targets•.

We also examine the question of whether inflation targeting countries saw inflation come
down more than the business cycle predicted from a second related vantage point. We forecast
inflation for each country from a Phillips curve, in the manner of Gordon ( 1985) and Fuhrer
(1995). We regress quarterly inflation on lags of itself, a measure of output, and on two
measures of supply pressures, the lagged change in the nominal effective exchange rate, and the
lagged change in a U.S. dollar denominated commodity price index. 7 This exercise is intended
to see whether inflation dropped beyond the extent we would attribute to normal cyclical factors,

domestically and internationally, as well as whether introducing inflation targeting induced some
changes in the countries' wage- and price-setting structures. It also addresses Friedman's and
Cecchetti' s criticism, which we discussed earlier, that Ball's measure of the sacrifice ratio
attributes all of the output movement during disinflations to demand reductions, and none to

6

The absence of a direct credibility bonus for sacrifice ratios from monetary institutions is
consistent with the evidence on the effects of central bank independence (see Debelle and Fischer
[1995], Posen [1995]).
7

Inflation for New Zealand and Australia was computed using the two Reserve Banks'
underlying CPI series, for Canada using CPI excluding food and energy, for the UK using RPIX,
and for Sweden using CPI excluding indirect taxes and subsidies. Except for New Zealand and
Australia, CPI series for all countries are from the BIS. The measure of output was either the
unemployment rate, or residuals from Hodrick-Prescott filtered GDP (meant to capture the
output gap). Except for New Zealand, unemployment and real GDP are from the OECDMEI.
Below we will report on the robustness of our results with respect to the choice of output
measure. The nominal effective exchange rate and the US dollar denominated commodity price
index, excluding oil, are from the BIS (replacing this with an oil price index made no difference in
the results). The measures of supply pressures were only included if they improved the fit, as
measured by the adjusted R 2 •

8
supply-side factors.
The regression is estimated over the period 1971:2 to time of target adoption for each of
the four inflation targeters. For Australia, the sample for the estimation is the same as for New
Z'.ealand, while for Italy it is the same as for the UK, i.e. until the lira's exit from the ERM in
1992:3. For Germany and Switz.erland, the regression is estimated up to German economic
reunification in 1990:2, allowing comparison with credible nominal targeters of long-standing.
In Table 2 we report results from the regressions and the inflation forecasts. As a check
of the robustness of the results with respect to the number of lags included, for each country we
report results from two different lag specifications. The first specification is a fairly unrestricted
one, including four lags of each variable so as to produce the best possible fit. The second is a
more parsimonious specification, in which we reduced for each variable the number of lags until
the t statistic of the last lag included was significant at the 5% level. The adjusted R2's indicate a
good fit of both regressions for all countries except Sweden. Also, for Sweden the lags of the
output gap are jointly insignificant, which is why we do not report a parsimonious specification
(see also Footnote 5 below). For each regression and each of the variables included in the
regression we report the sum of the coefficients on all lags of that variable, as well as their joint
significance (i.e., the F-statistic from testing the exclusion of all lags of that variable; 5% critical
values are between 2.50 and 2.53). The sum of the coefficients captures the cumulative response
of inflation to a unit change in the variable considered.
Toe fact that the nominal exchange rate and commodity price inflation apparently do not
have a significant impact on inflation in a number of countries is rather surprising, in particular
in open economies with sizeable raw materials production such as Canada and Australia. The

9

exchange rate appears significant in half of the regressions, commodity price inflation only in
two out of eight.
An interesting result from the German regression is the insignificant impact of past on

present inflation. This result can be construed as supporting the view that over time the
Bundesbank has been successful in its attempt to keep inflation permanently around 2%, with
past deviations being corrected in due course. However, this interpretation begs the question
why the same does not seem to hold for Switzerland, despite the similar past inflation record of
the two countries. 8
Our interest in these Phillips curve regressions, however, is to obtain evidence which
would help us to identify changes in the co-movements of inflation and unemployment or output
following inflation target adoption. We therefore tum now to structural break tests and out-ofsample forecasts generated from the Phillips curves.

In Table 2 results from reestimating the regressions from 1971:2 through 1995:49 and

8

The major changes to the results reported in the last paragraphs from choosing the
alternative output measure are as follows. For New Zealand, the output gap does not enter
significantly, the significance of past inflation increases, and commodity price changes are again
significant; the implied sacrifice ratio is 9.35. For Canada, the exchange rate is again included
but insignificant, and the implied sacrifice ratio increases to l.56. For Australia, neither the
exchange rate nor commodity prices are included, and the lags of the output gap are jointly
insignificant; the implied sacrifice ratio is 2.23. For the UK, the exchange rate is now included
in the regression, but the four lags are jointly insignificant. The implied sacrifice ratio falls to
0.3. For Italy, the exchange rate is included and significant, while commodity prices are
excluded. The implied sacrifice ratio rises to 3.71. Finally, for Germany, lagged inflation enters
now highly significantly, the output gap does not enter significantly, and the implied sacrifice
ratio is 3.66, as reported earlier. Since Swiss unemployment data start only in 1983, and the
Swedish unemployment rate exhibits a break in the early 1990s, we do not report results for
these two countries using unemployment.
9

Through 1995:3 for Italy, through 1995:2 for Australia, and through 1995:1 for New
Zealand due to data availability.

IO
testing for a structural break are reported. For three of the four inflation targeters the hypothesis
of a structural break in the Phillips curve at the time of target adoption is clearly rejected at the
5% level. Only for Canada do we find evidence of a structural break. For neither the targeters
of long-standing nor the two comparison countries in our sample is there evidence of a structural
break around this time. The results for all eight countries are robust with respect to the choice of
output measure and the choice of lag length.
Although, with the exception of Canada, there is no evidence for a structural break
following target adoption, it is nevertheless interesting to ask whether inflation was below the
values predicted by the Phillips curve during this period. Furthermore, we are interested in the
distribution of the forecast errors, in order to make some sense out of the question whether the
actual value of inflation is enough different, given other variables, to indicate that targeting
affected inflation dynamics. In other words, we want to be able to ask whether a variable comes
in significantly under forecast at a specific time. Since the forecasts are out-of-sample, the
distribution of the forecast errors is a nonlinear function of the estimated parameters' 0 ; since the
forecasts are conditional, by definition, their distributions also depend on the actual values of the
remaining variables in the regression.
We address the measurement of the distribution as follows. Since we want to forecast
inflation from time target adoption+ I quarter over a horizon of 8 periods, we need to construct
an estimate of the standard deviation of the forecast error at each quarterly horizon from I to 8.
To do so, we compute 15 forecasts of each length (1-8 quarters) for each country, beginning at

More precisely, the forecast error of a k-horizon out-of-sample forecast is a function of the
k-th power of the estimated parameters.

11
dates sufficiently long before time of adoption such that the forecast horizon does not extend
beyond time of adoption. We use these pre-adoption forecasts only for estimating the standard
deviation of the forecast. This means that we first estimate the Phillips curve regression for each
country until twenty-three quarters prior to adoption, and then perform a forecast from adoption
minus 22 quarters to adoption minus 15 quarters. In the next step we estimate the Phillips curve
until adoption minus 22 quarters, and perform a forecast from adoption minus 21 quarters to
adoption minus 14 quarters. In this fashion we construct 15 different forecasts, and we estimate
the standard deviation of the forecast error at each quarterly horizon, 1-8, as the empirical
standard deviation of the 15 different forecast errors at each horizon we obtainedu.
The results of these forecasts are shown graphically in Figure 6, where the vertical line
represents the onset of forecasting, the dashed line is the forecast of inflation, the two heavy
lines are one standard error bands generated as described, and the simple line is the actual course
of inflation 12 • In Table 2 we report the average forecast error from forecasting inflation over 8
quarters following target adoption, expressed in points of annual inflation (likewise in Figure 6
quarterly inflation has been annualized on the axes to facilitate interpretation). A positive
forecast error implies that actual inflation was on average below what we would predict from the
regression results.

• The fact that the r forecasts are overlapping introduces serial correlation between the
forecast error at horizon j from forecast I and the forecast error at horizon j-1 from forecast 1+1
(see e.g. Hansen and Hodrick 1980). The empirical standard deviation of the forecast errors at a
specific horizon is nevertheless an unbiased estimate of the true standard deviation at this
horizon.
12

We discuss (and Figure 6 shows) only the results from the forecasts using the basic
specification with four lags of all variables included, since the parsimoniously specified models are
less good forecasting equations.

12
For three of the four inflation targeters, actual inflation during the eight
quarters
following target adoption shows no sign of persistent deviations from
the forecast, and stays well
within the one-standard-deviation band. The average overprediction
for New Zealand is 0.77,
that for Canad a 0.61, while for Sweden actual inflation exceeds the foreca

st on average by 0.11

percent. For the UK, however, there is stronger evidence that inflation
is lower than would be
expected, being below forecast in 7 out of 8 quarters, and outsid e the
error band in 3 out of 8
quarters. On average, inflation is below forecast by 1.9 percen t (Robu
stness of these results is
discussed in Footnote IO below).
Consistent with the results from the structural break tests, for none of
the other four
countries is there much evidence of a change in the behavior of inflati
on. In Australia, inflation
is almost consistently below forecast (0.86% on average), but mostly
inside the error band. In
Italy, inflation is more often above than below the forecast (0.95% on
average), but again mostly
within the error band. After the demand shock of economic reunification
in Germany, inflatio

n

exceeded the predicted values in all but one quarter, twice (in the third
quarters of 1990 and
1991) by far more than one standard deviation, resulting in an underp
rediction on average of
1.78%. Yet, by the end of the forecast horizon, German inflation has
returned to its predicted
value, which we interpret as being consistent with a successful price-s
tability commitment based
on targeting of a nominal anchor. Likewise, the upsurge of inflation
in Switzerland during
1989/90 is reversed during the next two years, almost exactly in line with
the predictions. On
average, inflation exceeds the forecast by only 0.11 %. 13

13

For most countries, the results reported in the preceding paragraph are
fairly robust with
respect to the choice of output measure. If the output gap is chosen,
the average forecast error
increases to 3.65 for New Zealand, to 5.98 for Australia, and to -1.26
for Germany, while that

13

In view of the potential shortcomings of Ball's methodology that have been discussed
earlier, we consider it interesting to compute sacrifice ratios from these regressions and compare
them to our earlier results. Dividing the sum of the coefficients on unemployment (the output
gap) by 1 minus the sum of the coefficients on lagged inflation yields a measure of the effect of
a I-point increase in unemployment (the output gap) sustained over four quarters on long-run or
"steady state" inflation. Hence the inverse of this ratio measures the increase in unemployment
(the output gap) over four quarters necessary to achieve a I percent reduction of inflation in the
long run, i.e. the sacrifice ratio. However, these estimates of the sacrifice ratio are not exactly
the same as the ones we presented earlier. First, in the regressions we control for external and
commodity price shocks (insofar as they appear significant). Second, in five out of eight
regressions we use unemployment, not a measure of output lost as in Ball's methodology, and
this may affect the estimated ratio.
Since the four lags of inflation included may not be sufficient to capture all
autoregressive dynamics of inflation, we report ratios computed from regressions including 8
lags of inflation, and four lags of all other variables. For five out of eight countries the sacrifice
ratios are broadly similar to those obtained by using Ball's method. For New Zealand, Australia,
and most notably for Germany the ratios reported in Table 2 are much higher. However, when
using the output gap instead of unemployment as the output measure, for Australia and Germany
the ratios fall to 2.23 and 3.66 respectively, while that for New Zealand rises to 9.35. In

for Italy decreases to -1.34. As a result, the overprediction of inflation for New Zealand and
Australia becomes more significant, while the underprediction for Germany becomes less, and
that for Italy more significant. By contrast, choosing the unemployment rate as the output
measure for Canada leads to an (insignificant) average underprediction of -0.75, while choosing
the output gap for the UK leads to an (again insignificant) underprediction of -1.06.

14
particular for Germany this discrepancy between the results may be due to hysteresis effects.
For seven out of eight countries, therefore, the earlier results are confirmed. Only for New
Zealand does it appear as if Ball's method would lead to underestimate the sacrifice ratio (which
means that it would be even more clearly above forecast or previous average).
In summary, our Phillips curve and sacrifice ratio results together present a robust result
that the adoption of inflation targeting did not alter the costs of disinflation, and therefore we
presume not the underlying wage- and price-setting structures either, of our four inflation
targeting countries. Given their desires to move inflation down, the inflation targeters got only
small, if any, extra disinflationary effect beyond the business cycle they experienced (or
induced), or beyond the disinflation experienced by countries without inflation targets for that
matter. Compared to the baseline of the German and Swiss experience, however, it is clear that
even a credible targeter of longstanding does not see these benefits, that they may be too much to
expect of even a successful price stability commitment. It is worth noting that, in comparison to
the explicit hopes of New Zealand and Canada (who similarly to Germany and Switzerland
adopted targeting without prompting of a crisis) detailed in the case studies, neither country
expressed an expectation that the cost of disinflation would decline with maintained credibility.

II. Dynamic Simulation from Target Adoption
Even if inflation targeting does not move the terms of the output-inflation tradeoff in
times of disinflation, inflation targeting could alter the process by which inflationary shocks are
responded to in the economy. Once a commitment to price stability would be made transparent
and credible through inflation targeting, some inflationary shocks could be discounted by the

15
private-sector rather than passed through, or at least discounted more quickly and completely
upon a given monetary policy response. Our second set of exercises focusses on the dynamic
interaction of inflation, output, and monetary policy.
We estimate a 3-variable unrestricted VAR model of core inflation, GDP growth, and the
central bank's overnight instrument interest rate 14 from 1971:2 to target adoption 15; we then
allow the system to run forward five years from time of target adoption, plugging in the model's
forecast values as lagged values. This exercise is meant to give a qualitative impression of
whether the interaction between inflation and short-term interest rates exhibits a markedly
different pattern of behavior after the adoption of the inflation target from that before 16 • The
unconditional forecast of each variable represents the way we would expect the system to behave
in the absence of shocks from the situation at time of target adoption. Given the absence of
major supply and demand shocks, and even political shocks, in our case economies over the
periods since their adoption of targets, this is appears an appropriate comparison.
In the adopting countries, disinflation through tighter monetary policy had largely been
completed by the time of target adoption, allowing real rates to come down (the year or less of

14

For New Zealand, we use the discount rate as the only continuously available series
which can be seen as reflecting the stance of monetary policy. Since the late 1980s, the Reserve
Bank is keeping the discount rate 0.9% above the interbank overnight rate.
15

Ammer and Freeman (1995) perform a similar exercise for three countries for a much
shorter period.
16

A formal test for structural breaks in monetary policy reaction functions has three
limitations preventing its use in this assessment of inflation targeting's effectiveness: first, the tests
would be of extremely low power given the limited time since adoption even in New Zealand;
second, the tests would require us to impose a structural model of monetary policymaking for
each country which appears excessive; third, it would provide a yes/no answer where more
qualitative results are of interest.

16
disinflation remaining attributable to prior instrument interest rate moves, given policy lags).
This is consisten t with the pattern remarked upon in the case studies of targets being adopted
when there was a desire to lock-in inflation expectations at a low level when loosening first
occurs after a disinflation. Our sacrifice ratio data from the previous part of this section, it
should be remembered, only runs to that point, so to look for the effect of inflation targeting on
the response to monetary policy we must look out a year or more after adoption. The question is
whether upward blips in inflation do or do not lead to persistent rises - holding output and
inflation constant - as they would have in a system estimated under the prior regime.
Figures 7-9 plot the results of these simulations (dashed line) versus the actual path of the
inflation and output over the period for each of our sample countries, as well as the implied
short-term real interest rate (the difference between the overnight rate and inflation). As might
be expected, the simulations over time flatten out towards their sample means or a slight trend
(given the absence of shocks imposed by the unconditionality of the simulation). For all four
inflation targeters, the actual inflation rate comes in consistently below what would have been
expected after one year from adoption, and exhibits something of a downward trend as opposed
to the simulations' slight upwards leaning. A year after target adoption output gap was visibly
below forecast at the same time inflation was below for all four target adopters (a negative
output gap in the figure indicates an expanding economy), but then went above expectations
after another year of low inflation (consistent with the Phillips curve results).

In short, while

there is some indication from the simulations that target adoption gave rise to an initial boom,
the basic co-move ment of inflation and output remains unaltered in pattern.
The key point is that in all the target adopters except Sweden (and there at least initially)

17
this movement downwards of inflation, and then output, was induced with real interest rates
below the forecast levels for such a movement. This is consistent with the idea that under targets
there is a greater response of the economy to movements in instrument interest rates than there
was in the pre-targeting regime. This interpretation, in turn, supports the concept raised in the
case studies that the majority of economic benefits accrued through inflation targeting come
through greater transparency and lesser confusion about the stance of monetary policy, rather
than broader credibility effects on price- and wage-setting.

In the comparison non-targeting countries, the results are more mixed. Australian
inflation is below forecast, but follows the general downwards trend of the forecast, versus New
Zealand's coming in well below a forecast rise; in Italy, a drop in inflation was predicted as
opposed to the UK and Sweden, and it popped up well above it in contrast to those targeters.
These inflation movements were accompanied by large booms in output and extremely low real
interest rates.
By contrast, the simulations for Germany reflect clearly the effects of reunification, with
both inflation and the monetary policy instrument above their projections, and returning to them
only in early 1994. GDP growth initially exceeds the projection as a result of the expansion in
aggregate demand, until in 1992 and 1993 the effects of the increasingly restrictive monetary
policy - as seen in the implied real interest rate well above forecast into the second half of 1994 force output growth below its projected trend. As in the earlier forecast exercise (compare
Figure 6) we interpret the return over time of inflation and the monetary policy instrument to its
projection after a surprise demand shock of great magnitude as a characteristic of a successful
targeting regime. It should be noted that while Switzerland did manage to bring inflation below

18
forecast even after the transmitted foreign inflation shock, it had more than forecast drop
in
output as well overall, and persistently high rates to accompany it. In other words, the targeters
of long standing largely behaved as expected estimated on their prior behavior - respond
ing to
large inflationary shocks with tight monetary policy and dropping output. Moneta ry policy
following a credible path still requires tightness to respond to even one time shocks, and
that
tightness still has real effects.

m, Evidence on Inflation Expectations
The third kind of evidence to assess the effect of inflation targeting concern s expectations
of inflation. We look at consensus forecasts of inflation, and at changes in interest differen
tials
vis-a-vis the United States or Germany at a long and short maturity, and at movements in
the
government nominal rate bonds yield curve 17 as a variety of measures for directly unobser
vable
inflation expectations. The question is whether the inflation target confers greater credibil
ity
either in the form of either less uncertainty about policy or lower risk premia on governm
ent
debt. Even if the structures in the economy which determine the response of inflation to
the
cycle remained fixed at the start of inflation targeting in our case countries, as indicated
by our
first set of investigations, expectations for future inflation might have moved. This could
reflect
a greater flexibility of financial market expectations than of wage- and product-market

17

The United Kingdom, and more recently Canada, have sold "real bonds" guaranteeing a
fixed return. While these can be used to back out inflation expectations, there are some
uncertainties given illiquidities in these markets and the nature of holders of these bonds
(especially for Canada, given the limited size and age - on the order of C$5 billion for three
years
- of the market). We discuss these in the text but do not feature analysis of these imputed
expectations.

19
contracting; it also would be consistent with the dynamic simulations' result that over time
inflation did not bounce back up as forecast, despite good forecasts of output.
The panels of Figure 10 show for each country actual CPI inflation rates as well as
consensus private-sector forecasts for inflation by the end of each year since 1990. A square
denotes the consensus forecast of inflation done 18 months prior (an asterisk 12 months prior, a
triangle 6 months prior) to the date at which the symbol appears, forecasting inflation at that
specific point in time. In New Zealand, the forecasts at all three horizons show a continuous
downward trend (with the exception of the 6-month forecast in 1995). Yet for the first four
years for which targets were announced, inflation expectations were either at the upper end of, or
exceeding the target range, although inflation was within or below target at the end of 1991,
1992, and 1993. It was only in mid-1993 that the 18-month forecast was within the target range.
Once inflation expectations had adjusted, the New Zealand targeting regime seems to have
acquired credibility: in mid-1995, while headline inflation was 3% above the target range, the
18-month forecast for inflation at the end of 1996 was still at 1. 1%.

In Canada, while not unexpectedly the forecasts of 1991 inflation made prior to target
adoption predicted a rise in inflation, interestingly so did the prediction made in June 1991.
Again, as in New Zealand, it would appear reasonable to model private-sector inflation forecasts
as (at least partially) a function of lagged inflation; the regime change does not appear to have
induced a revolution in expectations formation. Both 12-month and 18-month ahead forecasts
exhibited consistent downward trends over the remainder of the target period, with all of these
forecasts made after target adoption lying within the target range (even when the six-month
ahead forecast dropped below in accord with the first-round tax effect of 1994). On this

20
measure, the Canad ian inflation targets appear to have gained great credib
ility.

In the UK inflation expectations at the longer horizon stayed stubbornly at the

upper end

of the 1-4% target range, even during periods when headline inflation
was well within, or at the
bottom of the lower half of the target range. For all four years follow
ing target adoption (1993
to 1996) inflation expectations were initially higher than the outcome,
and were revised
downwards continuously.
The Swedi sh disinflation during 1992 was partially anticipated, as shown
by the 18month forecast for inflation by the end of 1992, but not completely, as
the successive downward
revisions of inflation expec tation s reveal. Vice-versa, the impact of the
devaluation of the krona
in fall 1992 on inflation in 1993 was initially underestimated. Since
the end of 1993, inflation
expectations at all horizons have remained just below, or slightly above
the upper end of the
target range, although inflation has been kept consistently inside of it.
Inflation expectations in Australia, a country converging upon inflatio
n targeting, had
until 1994 followed a similar course to those in New Zealand. Inflati
on expectations at all
horizons exhibited a consis tent downward trend, and for each year inflatio
n expectations were
successively revised downwards.

In contrast to New Zealand, however, since 1995 inflation

expectations in Australia at the 18-month horizon have trended upwar
ds, although the actual
inflation performance in Austra lia was not much different from the one
in New Zealand.
Expectations for inflation by the end of 1996 are now 1% above Austra
lia's informal target
range of 2-3%. The divergence _in medium-term expectations between
the comparable
Antipodes would suggest some direct role for the difference between
explicit and
medium-term targets as an anchor.

implicit

21
Italy, used for comparison to the other ERM-exiters Sweden and the United Kingdom,
has been remarkably successful in containing the inflationary consequences of its massive
devaluation following the lira's exit from the ERM. That this came largely as a surprise to
private sector forecasters is shown by the 12-month forecast for inflation during 1993, which
was revised upwards (on average) from the 18-month forecast of 4.8% by 0.9%, only to be
revised downwards six months later by 1%. As the downward trend of inflation continued
during 1993 and 1994, inflation expectations at the long horizon fell to 3.7%. This latest gain in
lowering inflation expectations has been lost, however, during the 1995 upsurge in inflation.
Still, inflation expectations at the long horizon are below their levels during the last years of
Italy's ERM membership, despite lack of target or explicit nominal anchor.
The extent to which inflation in Germany rose during 1991 and 1992 appears
unsurprisingly to have been unexpected; interestingly, the speed of the subsequent disinflation
seem to have been unexpected as well. While at the time of economic reunification inflation
expectations for the end of 1991 were barely above 3%, once inflation expectations had risen
close to 4% it took almost two years of disinflation until, in mid-1994, long-run inflation was
expected to be back around 2%. A very similar picture emerges from the Swiss data. In mid1990, while inflation was running above 5%, inflation during 1991 was still expected to be
around 3.1 %. Neither did long-term inflation expectations increase by much during 1991, when
inflation peaked. Inflation expectations at the 18-month horizon then fell gradually from a peak
of 3. 7% to 2.4%, staying consistently above realized inflation rates during the past two years.
The experiences of Germany and Switzerland suggest that in a reliably proven targeting
regime inflation expectations exhibit a high degree of inertia, limiting both the upwards motion

22
in inflation after shocks and the speed of reaction to disinflation. Moreover, as seen in the
experiences of the recent adopters of targets, and especially in the New Zealand-Australia
comparison, the inertia comes with a nailing down of the medium-term expectations for
inflation. The formation of expectations in the short-term quite rationally appears to allow
for
upwards movements in inflation and gradual disinflation, under the medium-term guidepo
st,
consistent with the targeters' demonstrated operational behavior.
Another perspective on inflation expectations is given by interest rates. The charts in the
left column of Figure 11 show the differentials between the yields on United States and New
Zealand, Canadian, and Australian 10-year government bonds and on 3-month treasury bills
respectively, while the right column presents the same differentials of UK, Swedish, and
Italian
government securities vis-a-vis German ones. The assumption is that cross-national interest
rate
differentials are driven by expected changes in exchange rates, which are in tum largely
determined by expected differences in inflation rates. In New Zealand, the long-term interest
rate differential in particular mirrors very closely the course of the disinflation for the three
years
following target adoption. At its lowest point in early 1994, long-term investments in NZ$
yielded lower than compar able investments in US$, while the 3-month differential had fallen
below 2%. Interestingly, while headline inflation was well above target during 1995, both
interest rate differentials rose only modestly, apparently reflecting continued confidence
in New
Zealand's commitment to low inflation.
In Canada, while short-term interest rates spiked enormously in late 1992 and 1993, even
after targeting, this has to been seen as a reflection of the general turmoil in world exchang
e
markets following the ERM shakeout and moves in the US bond market, followed by the

23
Canadian constitutional crisis and election; except for this spike, the differential on 3-month
interest rates has been on a consistent downward trend, and even briefly was in favor of Canada
at the end of 1994. The long-term interest rate differential has moved down slightly on average
in the second half of the targeting period, but remains on the order of 200 basis points, which is
on the high end of the historical range for the Canada/US differential. The ongoing fiscal and
Quebec doubts about the long-term future of Canadian policy apparently cannot be fully
compensated for by monetary policy.
The successive cuts in UK official interest rates following sterling's exit from the ERM,
combined with only cautious decreases in the German repo rate, is reflected in a negative shortterm interest rate differential between the UK and Germany from late 1992 until mid-1994.
Through this whole period the long-term interest rate differential hovered around 1%, only
briefly (in early 1994 before the onset of US monetary tightening) dipping to 0.5%. Thereafter
the long-term differential rose above 1%, and has been staying between 1 and 2% since. If one
is willing to interpret this differential as the difference in long-term inflation expectations
between the UK and Germany, and assuming those expectations for Germany are around 2%,
the resulting expectations for the UK are close to 4%, confirming the evidence from the
consensus forecasts. It should be emphasized that these UK-Germany differentials are relatively
low for the post-Bretton Woods period, and suggest that inflation targeting was a largely
successful substitute nominal anchor for ERM membership (given the continuing low levels
after devaluation).
The Riksbank' s efforts in September 1992 to defend the Swedish krona caused a sharp
spike in the T-bill yield differential vis-a-vis Germany, while the differential between

24
government bond yields also rose considerably. The subsequent cuts in the Marginal Rate
following the Riksbank's decision on November 19, 1992 to float the krona narrowed the shortterm differential during the following months, to 1.1 o/o in August 1993. From then until the end
of 1995 it widened to almost 6%, and has narrowed since then to below 3%. The fall in the
long-term differential continued until February 1994, when it reached 0.8%. On the background
of the 1994 bond market downturn, over the following six months the long-term differential rose
to 4%, and remained in the 3-4% range for another year. Of late, however, the long-term
differential has steadily fallen to below 2%. A potential gain in credibility for Sweden's
inflation targets may explain the recent narrowing of both interest rate differentials, as may the
prospect of European Monetary Union and the fiscal consolidation required in connection.
Interest rate differentials between Australian and US government bonds and treasury bills
respectively rose above their New 2.ealand counterparts from mid-1988 to mid-1990, when New
2.ealand headline inflation fell below the Australian one. Since 1991, the Australian short-term
differential vis-a-vis the US has been lower than the New 2.ealand one. By contrast, since 1992
the differential between yields on New 2.ealand and US government bonds has been below the
one between Australian and US government bonds, despite the two countries' almost identical
inflation performance during those years, and arguably lower liquidity in the New 2.ealand bond
market as compared to the Australian one. Only lately have the two long-term differentials
converged.
Interest rate differentials between Italian and German government securities have
followed very similar patterns to their Swedish counterparts. A sharp rise in both short and
long-term differentials during fall 1992 was reversed, with both differentials falling to historical

25
lows. As in Sweden, the narrowing of the short-term differential came to an end in August
1993, by which time it had reached 1.5%, while the long-term differential bottomed out in
February 1994 at 1.1 %. The short-term differential then rose steadily to reach 6.5% by the end of
1995, and has since fallen to 4.2%. The long-term differential peaked in April 1995 at 4.1 %, and
has since fallen to 1%. To what extent the recent narrowing of both differentials reflects
expectations concerning European Monetary Union, and Italian membership in it, is again an open
question.
Fmally, Figure 12 depicts movements in the nominal government bond yield curves for
Canada, the United Kingdom, Australia, and Sweden18• In Canada, yield curves start rising in
early 1987, with the onset of monetary tightening and, possibly, inflationary fears on the
background of strong growth. During 1987 and 1988, both ends of the yield curve move roughly
in proportion, with 3-month yields rising from 7 to 10.4%, and 10-year yields from 7.8 to 10.2%.
Only in 1989 does the hitherto relatively flat yield curve tum inverted, with monetary policy being
tight on this measure until mid-1991. During 1991 yield curves fall over the entire length: while
short rates fall from above 13 to below 7%, long-term yields are reduced by 2.5% during 1991.
The evidence from consensus forecasts presented earlier suggests that this fall in long-term yields
is mostly attributable to a strong downward revision in inflation expectations. During 1992 and
1993 yield curves are positively sloped, with short rates falling to 4.6% and 10-year yields to
7.4% by September 1993. The worldwide downturn in bond markets during 1994 following the
onset of monetary tightening in the US, and the subsequent recovery during the first months of
18

There is no market in New Zealand government bonds of sufficient depth to generate
such an analysis. Detailed yield curve data for Switzerland were not available, while only in 1990
Italy started issuing non-indexed Government Bonds with maturities longer than three years.

26
1995 are clearly visible, with yield curves only briefly becoming inverted in early 1995. Longterm bond yields in mid-1995 had approximately returned to their level of early 1993, again
confirming the evidence from the consensus forecasts.
Yield curves in the UK soared during late 1989 and 1990, and became sharply inverted as
the extent of the inflationary pressures, and of the required monetary tightening to bring them
under control, became apparent. The easing following sterling's entry into the ERM in October
1990 was accompanied by improvements in long-term inflation expectations, as long-term yields
fell 0.8% within the next quarter, and by 1.6% during the 12 months following sterling's entry.
Yield curves remained mostly flat until the ERM crisis in September 1992. Following sterling's
exit, the slope of the yield curve turned sharply positive, driven by a 4% fall in overnight rates at
the short end, and presumably a considerable increase in inflation expectations at the long end.
Only during the second quarter of 1993 long-term bond yields began to fall below their levels
during sterling's ERM membership of around 9.5%. As in Canada, yield curves in the UK rose
during early 1994 along the whole horizon, although more so at the short end than at the long
end, leading to a slightly inverted yield curve. Since then, long-term bond yields have remained
around 8.5%, almost 1% below their levels during ERM membership.
As shown in the lower right panel of Figure 12, during the late 1980s yield curves in
Sweden, as in the UK, were rising sharply along the entire horizon. Short-term rates peaked at
around 15% in August 1990, at which point long-term rates had been falling from their peak of
13.8% in April 1990 to around 13.4%, giving rise to an inverted yield curve. Yield curves then
fell rapidly along the entire length until August 199 l. Yields at longer maturities continued to fall
until summer 1992, with the IO-year bond yield falling below 10%. Short-term rates, however,

27
spiked during the fall of 1991, as the Riksbank was forced to defend the krona's peg to the ecu.
In the runup to the speculative attacks of September 1992 the yield curve rose during the summer
of 1992 at the entire horizon, with short-term rates standing at 13.25%, and long-term yields at
11% by August 1992. After the Riksbank's decision to float the krona, yield curves fell along the
entire horizon, and had turned flat by the end of 1993, with both short- and long-term yields
around 7% at historically low levels. While monetary policy tightened moderately during 1994,
with the Marginal Rate rising from 7 to 8%, bond yields soared by over 4% from February to
August, leading to a steeply sloped yield curve. Since the end of 1994, yield curves have been
falling.
During 1988 and 1989 the Reserve Bank of Australia tightened monetary policy
considerably, with real short-term rates rising from below 4% in early 1988 to above 12% in mid1989. By the end of 1989 nominal short-term rates peaked at around 18%, and, as the lower left
panel in Figure 12 shows, the yield curve had by then turned inverted. The rapid decline of the
Cash Rate that began in January 1990 was until May accompanied by rising long-term rates, with
10-year bond yields climbing to 13.8%. During the summer of 1990 long-term rates began to fall
as well, although initially slower than short-term rates, and by August the yield curve had turned
flat. Until the end of 1991 both long- and short-term rates fell in tandem, and since then the yield
curve has been positively sloped. Interest rates bottomed out at the beginning of 1994, with
short-term rates falling to 4.5% and long-term yields to 6.7%. During 1994 the yield curve rose
at all horizons, and turned somewhat flatter. By the end of 1994 short-term rates had increased to
8.25%, and long-term rates to 10%. During the first half of 1995 yields at all maturities have
been falling, by 1.5% at intermediate maturities, and by 0.5% at both ends of the curve.

28
On balance, private-sector inflation expectations appear to have declined for all the
inflation targeters, but most clearly for the medium-term and beyond for the targeters oflonger
standing, Canada and New Zealand. It would be consistent with the eventual decline of
expectations in Canada and New Zealand to state that the United Kingdom and Sweden could be
merely too short a time away from adoption to have reaped the full benefits. The comparisons
with Australia and Italy, respectively, however, work against this interpretation, with Canada and
New Zealand clearly registering counterinflationary credibility gains vis-a-vis Australia, while the
United Kingdom and Sweden are not so clearly outperforming Italy on this score. The
experiences of Germany and Switzerland during the strains of reunification seem to indicate that
the true test of target credibility is the resistance of medium- to long-term inflation expectations to
influence from short-term inflationary pressures. As discussed in the case studies, Canada has
already shown strong evidence of such a "lock-in" effect, preventing pass-through to prices of tax
rises or constitutionally prompted exchange fluctuations, while Sweden has fared considerably less
well in the face of one-time shocks since leaving ERM.

IV. A Preliminary Assmment of JnQatjon Ta,:getjng's Effectiveness
Taken all together, the adoption of inflation targets as the framework for monetary policy
in the four countries examined here appears to have been a success. While we cannot perfectly
answer the counterfactual of what would have happened had they not adopted inflation targeting,
these countries seem to have seen inflation levels and expectations drop far more for the point in
the business cycle than we would have expected on the basis of their past performance. And for
three of the four of them, this was achieved with smaller rises in short-term real interest rates than

29
past experience would have predicted. The hopes of some adopting countries, particularly of
Canada and New Zealand, to see the costs of disinflation drop versus past levels, however, were
not fulfilled through the first post-adoption disinflations. Whether this should be seen as a failure

' targeting credibility, or a confirmation of the limited effect of variation in monetary
of inflation
policy structures on the output-inflation tradeoff seen before, is left to the reader. The
comparison of the adopting countries' inflation record to that of the respective "control"
countries, Australia and Italy, underscores the apparent effect of inflation targeting on
expectations and the economic response to monetary policy.
It is the comparison of the effect of inflation target adoption in the sample countries to the
baseline of what longstanding targeters Germany and Switzerland experience which brings home
two crucial points. First, it may be too much to expect monetary regimes to alter the outputinflation tradeoff, even when credibly believed, and therefore the lack of effect of inflation
targeting upon them may be an uninformative result. Second, it is reasonable to expect that a
credible transparent targeting regime locks-in medium- to long-term inflation expectations in the
face of temporary shocks, and therefore demands less of monetary policy in order to limit the pass
through effect of those shocks. In other words, the primary effect of any nominal targeting
regime may be through increased transparency of monetary policy, rather than through increased
commitment to price stability19• This transparency to the public may give the targeting monetary
authority the flexibility with support necessary to repeatedly cope with inflation even when
disinflation remains expensive in terms of output, producing sustained price stability.

19

For an interpretation of the operational effects of the German and Swiss monetary
targeting frameworks consistent with this view, see Laubach and Posen (1997).

30
REFERENCES

Ammer, John and Richard Freeman. 1995. "Inflation Targeting in the 1990's: The Experiences
of New Zealand, Canada, and the United Kingdom." JOURNALOFECONOMICSAND
BUSINESS 47 (May): 165-92.
Ball, Laurence. 1994. "What Determines the Sacrifice Ratio?" In N. Gregory Mankiw, ed.,
MONETARY POI.ICY. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Debelle, Guy and Stanley Fischer. 1994. "How Independent Should a Central Bank Be?" In
Jeffrey Fuhrer, ed., GOALS, GUIDELINES, AND CONS'IRAINTS FACING MONETARY
POUCYMAKERS. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.
Freeman, Richard and John Willis. 1995. ''Targeting Inflation in the 1990s: Recent Challenges."
FEDERAL REsERVE BOARD INTERNATIONAL FINANCE DISCUSSION PAPER. No. 525
Fuhrer, Jeffrey C. 1995. ''The Phillips Curve Is Alive and Well." NEW ENGLAND ECONOMIC
REvIEW (March-April): 41-56.
Gordon, Robert R. 1985. ''Understanding Inflation in the 1980's." BROOKINGS PAPERS ON
EcONOMIC ACilVITY. 1:263-302.
Hansen, Lars Peter and Robert J. Hodrick. 1980. "Forward Exchange Rates as Optimal
Predictors of Future Spot Rates: An Econometric Analysis." JOURNALOFPOUTICAL
ECONOMY 88: 829-53.
Huh,Chan. 199. "Some evidence on the efficacy of the UK inflation targeting regime: an out-of
-sample forecast approach." FEDERAL REsERVE BOARD INTERNATIONAL FINANCE
DISCUSSION PAPER. No. 565
Laubach, Thomas and Adam S. Posen. 1997. "Disciplined Discretion: The German and Swiss
Monetary Targeting Frameworks in Operation." FEDERAL REsERVE BANK OF NEW YORK
REsEARCHPAPER No. 9707.
Posen, Adam S. 1995. "Central Bank Independence and Disinflationary Credibility: A Missing
Link?" FEDERALREsERVEBANKOFNEWYORKSTAFFREPORTS, May 1995, no. 1.
Svensson, Lars E. 0. 1993. ''The Simplest Test of Target Credibility." NBER WORKING PAPER
No. 4604.

TABLE 1: SACRIFICE RATIOS AND THEIR DETERMINANTS

Results from regressing a sample of 22 sacrifice ratios (3 for each country except for Germany and Switzer1and) on a constant, inflation at the
beginning of lhe disinflation, change in Inflation during the disinflalion, and the length (in quarters) of the disinflation. T stalistic:s in parantheses.

Constant

1.99 (2.37)

Initial Inflation

-0.17 {2.73)

Change in Inflation

0.07 (0.66)

Length of Disinflation

0.06 (1.13)

Adjusted A-Square

0.39

Sacrifice Ratios for the Lalest Completed Disinflation
New Zealand
Disinflation

8603-9204

Canada

9003.9304

Australia

8902· 9301

UK

Sweden

llaly

Germany

Switzertand

9001 • 9304

9004 • 9301

9002.9304

8004-8701

8201 · 8701

Initial Inflation

15.38%

5.25%

7.62%

8.84%

9.55%

6.42%

5.87%

5.93%

Change in Inflation

14.25%

4.16%

6.22%

6.48%

6.43%

2.17%

5.75%

4.82%

Sacrifice Ratio

2.05

3.04

1.89

2.14

0.36

0.62

2.47

2.15

Predicted Sacr Ratio

1.78

2.13

1.98

1.83

1.33

1.85

2.81

2.45

Past Avg Sac, Aalio

0.98

1.06

0.28

0.55

0.59

0.41

4.46

2.34

TABLE 2: RESUl TS FROM MODELLING ANO FORECASTING INFLATION
Results from regressing inflation on 111 own laga and lhON of eome output meaeure. changea in lhe nomlnel
effecttQ exchange ,ate, and changet in commodtty prioN prior to the adoption or inflation
target• (prior to German reunification for Gennany and Swilznnd. prior to 199001 for Au1tr11ia, and prior
to 199204 fo, llaly). and from lorecasting inflation conditional on actual values ror the remaining
variable• over 8 quartef'I followlng target adoption.

-·

Counl<y

New Zealand

Output Measure

Unemployment

Output Gap

Unernpk)yment

Unemployment

OutputGep

Unemployment

Unemployment

Output Gap

Sample

7102-890(

7102-9004

7102-690(

7102-9203

7102 · 9204

7102-9203

7102 • 9002

7102-9002

Forecast Horizon

9001 -9104

9101 • 9204

9001 • 910,

9204-9'03

9301 ·9'04

9204-9'03

9003-9202

9003-9202

Canada

Auat,aHa

UK

Italy

Germany

Switzerfand

A. BASIC SPECIFICATION, FOUR LAGS OF EACH VARIABLE INCLUDED
Adj R Square

0.61

0.64

0.63

0.56

0.23

0.73

0.57

0.,2

Sum of ooetficienta on all lags (joint significance or all lage) of variable:
Inflation
Output Measu,.

NEER

0.54 (7.87)"
-0.09 (4.03)
-0.10 (4.86)"
0

CommodUy PriOH

Implied Sacrilk:e Ralio
(8 Lags ol lnllatlon)

0.87 (28.00)"
0.09 (3.62)"

0.63 (25.54)"
-0.06 (1.88)

0.63

-o. 14

(7.44)
(3.83)"

0

0.02 (1.44)
3.95

Structural Break
(5% Critical Value)

0.64 (1.73)

Avg Forecast Error

0.77

0.67 (5.66)"
0.13 (1.55)
0.08

(2.70)"

0.80 (21.86)"
-0.13 (6.25)"
-0.6' (4.28)"
0.01 (1.30)

-0.01
-0.14
-0.15

0.0(

(0.24)
(6.26)"
(3.08)"
(3.28)"

0.50
0.13
0.01

(3.63)"
(5.59)"
(2.51)"

1.29

3.47

2.33

0.56

0.95

6.56

2.95

2.16° (1.72)

0.'1 (1.70)

0.39 (1.85)

1.11 (1.88)

0.92 (1.89)

0.93 (1.78)

0.40 (1.76)

0.61

0.86

1.90

-0.11

-0.95

-1.78

-0.11

0.73

o.59

0.40

B. PARSIMONIOUS SPECIFICATION
Adj R Square

0.61

0.63

0.64

0.53

NIA

Sum of coefficients on all lags (number of 1&g1, Joint a,gnllicenoe of all laga) of variable:

lnflalion
Outpul Measure
NEER
Commod,ly Prices

0.,1 , •• 7.21)"
-0. 11 (,. U9)"
-o... (3, 5.66)"

0.64 (3, ...70)"
0. 10 (1, 12.3')0

o. 75 (1, 109.95)"
-0.06 (1, U9) 0

o.'8 (1. 21.os1·
-0.17 (1, 13.70).

0.71 (1, 64.23)"
-0.15 (2, 15.82)"
-0.02 ,•• 5.80)"

Structural Break

0.57 (1.73)

1.98° (1.71)

0.42 (1.70)

0.42 (1.85)

0.89 (1.88)

0.95 (1.78)

0.38 (1.78)

0.38

0.93

2.79

2.40

1.64

-1.78

-0.14

(5% Crilical Value)

Avg ForeeaSI Error

-0. U (3, 31.28)"
-0.15 (4, 3.75)"
0.04 (4, 3.37)"

0.40 (3, 3.54)"
0.15 (4, 5 ...)"
0.0, (3, 3.92)"

..,

:3

....,

!

~

z

g

..

i

<
►

~

<

.::.

:!

~

.•

0

z

<

>
<

!

z

:,

z
z

~

<

N

"'e

z

g
<

.
0

~

'-

(.)
,.,,.

!

;:;

i

.,.,

~

!

<
z

<

....

C

.. o,

z

<

z

0

<
~

z

Lu

a::

::,

(.)

....

0

.:V

-z

i

::;
IX

<

0

..
,,,'> .,.

"'
c.,

Cl

!

-:
',1

_..-J

o,

•

0

!

i-

...,
...

I
I
I

i I'

!

--

..

!

.

<

~

,.:
z
<

...,

~

.

~

<

.::.
!

i-

c

!

~

i

...

,-

.:V

--

~

!

!

"'c.,

!

..

0

z
z

<
0

~

0

......

;:-

<

":I

►-

0

z

;::.

.

.....

<

~

!

!

X

<

...
........-

8

..
0

!

i

<

<

..
.,..
.,

'z

.:IX

~

·,i

:,

,;;

-

.

0

!

.
e
..,

e

!I:

'd

2

!

•

9

~

~

.
"

l_

',1

.•

!

(

0

x

r-:

;

5

0

....

,0

"'

(

z

t/l

.

'

!

o.

i

,

!
0

I·

o,

!

'

9

"

I·

.,

, - - - - - - - - - ~ - - - - - - - ~ g:

.."'

~

~
:.,

:'?
0

z

0

I

...

!

w

.....

:,
0

)(

-u<

.,,u

..•

u

<
a:

!

•

:.I)

z

)

..•

~

z:$

z

f

.."'

!

<
z

z

.

~

!

"'0

..

;;:

!

,..
g"'

..

-

5

.

'i

0

!

!

.,

.,.,

C

u

!

....,
""
..,,,

!

.,"'

;.)
<(

9t;

:'?

llL

....,

!

&o,

tOI

,...,

00,

96

l&

ii

ti

l£

il

tl

.

!

oz

91

ll

8

.,

z

<
<

•

..,,

!

!

."'

'3:

.•

!

z

!

.•

""w ...:r
n::

!

3:

::,
"
'-'

~

0

"'...

...~z

..
N

w

a:

0

....

ti.
0
:.,

!

!

2

►

..,
..,2
0

Q.

....

z:,

"'

..,

-

.,i

g"'

...

..

.,

.,.,

!

!

.,"'

9

,

.,,,

!

l-

·-

!L

"

o,

6

8

L

9

<;

•

!

r

FIGURE :l: CANADIAN ECONOMIC TIME LINE
FIG 1. I: ANNUAL ANO AVERAGE INf'LATION, ANO TARGETS

FIG 1.2: OVERNIGHT ANO LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES

.. .-~-.-~--. -..-.....--- ....----,-"T ""...,.-T"" ~-.-~--.-. .---,

~

,-....----,. -~--.-..--, ----,----.- -...,.-.-.... ----,.-~--. -..--,

0
N

2

'

''
''
'I

"'

'

"'

,,,

'

:::!

I

.,

vv.J

N

.

7L,-.-.~o-,-•L•-,--,-.~.-.--,-.~.-6--,-.~.-.--,-.~.-o-'-,-.~.-,--,~.~••---,.~.~6---,.~••
FIG 1.3: NOMINAL EFFECTIVE EXCHANGE RATE

:g .---.---,,- ---:.,..--- ..-~-.-~-- .-...-......---,---- .-----,

0

.____ _..__

_,,.,__ _.,__ _.,__ _.,__.__.,__ _.,__ _..__

1980 1982

.

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

-1V94

1996

__,

1998

FIG 1.4: GOP GROWTH ANO UNEMPLOYMENT

,-....----,. -~--.-..--, --.--,---.- ..--,--.--~ -.--.--..... ----,

N

0

2

I
I

,I
I
U) .... .. ...

~

:;:

........ - --- '

-,

'

... - ... - .. - ''

1,

I

I

'

,_

I

...

N

.,"'
N

I

:;j
~L_ _...__ _..__ _.,__ _.,__ _.._......_..__ _.,__ _..__ __,
1980 1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

199<1.

1996

1998

r•,-.-.~Q-f9~.-,~-,-.L.-.--,.~.-6,....._f_9~8-8--f-9L9-Q~-,.~.-,~-,-.L.-.--,.~.-6~-,.......

FIGURE ,f: UK ECONOMIC TIME LINE

N~-----------------~~-~--~--,
FIG t. t: ANNUAL AND AVERAGE INFLATION. AND TARGETS

FIG t .2: OVERNIGHT AND LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES

:!'

rr---..---..---..---..---..---..-.,....-~--~---,

:'!

0

,,,

.,

• l"'\,111,
- r •

' '

::!

"'

.

"'~ ,,

.

"

.

N

0

,A

e

1 . . . - -......- ~ _ . __ __.__~_.__ _......_ ~ _........._

1980 1982

1984

1986

1986

1990

1992

......_ _ _~ - - - -

1994

1996

1998

~~~~-----~~-~-----~~------~
FIG t .3: NOMINAL EffECTIVE EXCHANGE RATE

. .__.__.____,____._....__.___

__

...._...,_.__._~-----......--'

.._

1980 1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

FIG t .4: CDP GROWTH AND UNEMPLOYMENT

. ,---..---..---..---~-----..-.,....-..---..----,
e , ,,
,, ,

.

,,

'

-----,
'''

-,

'

' - - ...

,,

,,

' ,_

0

N
0
0

N

I

g
0
00

1........_

......_._....,__....._._....__.__._

1980 1982

1984

1986

1988

_.__ _ __,__,__

1990

1992

_._~_...__,___,

1994

1996

1998

"f L1_9_8~0-19-'8-2--1-9•8-4--19_.8_6_._1_9.88_._1_9•9-0_._19-'9-2....i._

_,__ __._....___,
1996
1998

1994

FIGURE

5:

SWEDISH ECONOMIC TIME LINE

FIG 1. 1: ANNUAL ANO AVERAGE INFLATION. AND TARGETS

"'~--~----~-.---.---..---~-..--.---.---

., ,---..- --..--- ..---..- --..--- ..--,-- ..----, ----,

;!

.,,
'

N

''
'

0

;!
,I r••I
N

.,
'

'

.

'

'•

.,
.,,

"'
L . ~ - ' - ~ - ' - ~ -....~ - ' - ~ -..........., -.........1.-'-......- ' -......--'
-----1980 1982
1984
1992
1986
1988
1994
1990
1996
1998

.------.---......--......--..----~---,---.---~

.......~-_._~, __.__-~ _......._,__.__~--.......
1980 1982

FIG 1.3: NOMINAL EFFECTIVE EXCHANGE RATE

~

;\/,

e

.,,

0

flG 1.2: MARGINAL ANO LONG-TER M INl(ff[SJ HAT[S

1984

1986

·--1988

1990

--~-....._,

......

-'1992
1994

1996

1998

FIG 1.4: GDP GROWTH AND UNEMPLOYMENT

;! , - - - . . - - - . . - - - . . - - - . . - - - . . - - - . . - - . - . . - - - , - - ~

g

,,

0

"' ,.
0

.,,

e

'

'

0
0

N

g
N

I

:.l

~

1980 1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

'f L1-98_0..._1_9._8_2_.__1_9._8_4_.__1_9._8_6_.__1_9._88_,__.__,_....._._....._,_....._..._..J
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

FIGURE ,/: INFLATION FORECASTS

~-•=
~~------------------,------, •...-------~---,.-----, •.---------------.--------,
rte s. t: NEW l£At.ANO, rOR£CASf fAOlil 1HD 01

,ic

~

nc

UIC, fORfCASf nou 1992 04

•

..,.,'·..r\·•''' .

•

\l.?\ 11v·
,:

1-'

.

I•••

I

,

'I

1

nc

...

...

•~,,e,c,,---,,e_e.:---, ..;.~--~
·- ··-.-.•-----..,,...J.-.t..~
'"'

'~•n""•'°"•"•t,a,---,,u,':,,--,,~,,s,=---:,,,n,.,.-•,••~n=--,a.,.!::---,,.,,':,,--,,,'.••a

S.2: CANAOA. FORECAST f'ROM " " 01

ita•

IH4

,ic

tHe

1t110

IHJ

1111•

5 . .J: AUSTRALIA. FORECAST f'ROU tHO Ot

. , ... .... ....

,

,

'"'

....

. , ,...

,

•

,. ltH

IN8

1tto

lflJ

,...

IHI

F'IG 5.6: JrAl,.Y. ,oMCAST f'ROM 1992 04

,.---------------.,...---~---,

•

11t4

...

,

,,c S.l!I; Swtll[RLAHO, f'ORCCAST f'ROU 1910 0.J

•'

... ,..,

1N4

nc S.S: Swto£N. ,oR(CAST FAOlil Ill) Qt

•~---~--------------~

,

l

·.---------...,------.-------, •~--------------.---------,
•

7

'

,ROM tHO O.J

..•.

0

7

•

,oR£CASl

~

•
•

I

S.7: C[RYANY.

7

'"'

••t:t

I

ltH

....

·-

'"'

...

,

....

7 ,...

IHI

IHI

IMO

IH2

lt9•

.!

•:

;

:•

•:

•

:

w

!

z

~
•l
••

~

i

s

•0

~

s

!

, ,
/

'

i

w

i

0

!

z

0

<{

:::>

•
•
•

•

"

•
!

•

.

•·

I

(/)

::!;
<{

z
>0

...!•

.

" "

i

I

•
!

;

•:

I

::!;

u

•
!

•
!

I

I

;

•

I-

....J

~

•

••

•

(/)

•

=

\

!i

•

'

\

•

!

"

I

~

0

I
1

~

s

!

i

I

•

rtw
0::

:::>

C)

u..

w

i
~
•

~

•
i
I !

!

•
!

•
!!

•

,.

•· •·

I

"

I
:

•
!

'•s

!

0

~

\

N

N

•z

z

;

"

•

•

;
;

~

•

!

~

~

;

=
•

0

•i

!

5
N

•z

w

:

"

" "

• •!I

=

w

,-•

;

I

w

I
I

~
w

w

•

0

0
\

I

!

...=
•
!

•

I•

!

i

i
•

I

I••

I

0

g

• ,. ,. •·

I

•:

" "

• ,.

... ... ...

;

!

•
!

;

«-

" " " "

:
:

:
:

\

.;

I
I
I

''

/

----

~

i

•:

':..

✓

;

s
i

-

0

:

z

0

I

<
....J

I
I

:E

s

,i

~

w

!•

-

-✓

.,J

•

--✓-

,i

!:

--:::,,

!

.

c
.

;•

~·

~

•

!

_>
"

/

,

;

!

c_

I

ii!

,i

~

__;>

"

'

,-.------------.;

••

•

I

/
\

/

::

•

/

'

i
1

!
•
!

-

i

s

;

s
0

,i

!

"

I

w
~

\

•~

ii!
0

i

•,
i

.;

!
" •

/

:

✓

;
"

0

•·

•·

;
t(•

'

'

~

s
•s
0

!

I
I

w

_r

:::)
C)

" " " • •

i

~

~

w
a:::

,,

✓

_,

!

:E '!

u...

:

•· ,,.•

-

--

Cf)

<
z
>0

•
!

-

I

:::)

(.)

•

"

.

I
I

•f-

!

;

,.:

'

!

••►
g

I

;
"

'

i

':..

w

0

•
!

I

~
~

1

!

►
g

Cf)

I

I

I

"

V)

z

0

I-

<(
_J

!

•

;

;

.

•

::J
:i:

i

V) z
0

u ~

:i:

•

~

s
s

•
!

Q

z w•~
>0 i

I
!

'

0

Q

' !

i

w

I

!

!

::J

•

"

~

z

2

,.!
!

•

!

0

!

•·

w

!

!

••

•

•
!

!

s~
,

!

0

~

•
•>w

'

:!
w

i
;/
w
•

I

0

~
!

!

\

I
/

!

►

•

0

!

!
:!

!
•~

!
• ,. •·

!

j

!

.. . •· ...!

!
;

•w
•

,.

I

~

I

I

•
!

!
3

!

!

i

<.:)

I

I

Q

•
:!

0,..

a::

i

g
•0

/

~

I

!

~

<(

!

.

"

,. •·

i
~

•

!

!

•
!

:

;

...•

•:

.

0

•
!
0

;

!
0 ..

!

i
0

J

~

;

•
~

:

w

u

!

I

~

!

'!

z

0

I-

<:

'

...J

LL.

z

'

0

•

•

'

i

•

• LL.

:

,.

0

,.•

!

••

•

!

(/)

!

••

•
!

I(/)

:

<:
C)
w

:

0 •,

!

0::
·LL.

i

0

•
!
~

!

►

~

!

(/)

:::,

'

(/)

z

w

!

i

(/)

z

0

::

C)

"

2
w

•
!

!

•

•

:•

•

0::
:::,

.

•

'

'

i

I

• •

!

•

•

•

<.:)

• •

•

N

•z

I

w

u

•
;

:

•

~

!
I

!

•

!

:

I
0

;

:

•
!

I. ..

••

••
~

!

•I

s!!l

. ,, " . " "

i

.

!
•
!

i
w

'

!

I

G:

!

•
!

0

,.•

" ·•

•

i

•

,---------------;
;

-<

'

!

-'

(/)
_J

-,
, ·'

f-

z

w >
er:
w •I
LL. ~
LL. ,'
•

; -··

0

w

.;

;

<(

j
!

,'

~

#.:-:-

w

,•·

'
~

-- -- '

l

f<(

,_

f-

(/)

w
er:
w

--·--:

.
:·

f-

z

.:

I

"

0
:::!?
I

,
,_ '

!

..

-

•I

.,
·-'
<

:

•

'',

-. -"'

.

·,.
.
-.::,

-

'

,. •·!-

0

!

i'

<'

•

✓------

f-

z

..-

..

:

-'

!•
=
• ~

.-_:·__,'

•

,~

•:

'--,

I

er:

-

;

)

·-.
, '

~

,

~

,

:

" "

0

, -··

•

" " •

;

!

'

'

'

!
0

-

!

")

0

z<(

-' '

ii

!'

er:

I:

<(

w

>-

,

;'

.
:

0

,

,

,>

-

!

!

i

.

.

-.

!

!

.,

,

-!
fl

'

w

·-·,

-,,.

I

~

-

!

·,

;!

w

~

er: •"•
::,

.

,•

,

',
'~

!

,_

<.:)

'

LL.

''
'

-

..

---- ..
--... ---"

,,

,

~

.

'

I

...'

'

i

i

i

i

;

-----

---

!

-- ..
'

-'.

1 ......

-

;

~

'
,

,.•

..

!

C

"

i

;,

;

:

"

,

fl

•

'

.

-. .:·
...... -.---'

-

----:.··--

;
0

-

!

...

"

.

"

-

!
0

FIG UR E

NO MIN AL YIELD CU RV ES FOR
GO VER NM EN T BO ND S

Id-.

Nom inal Yreld Curv es for Con
odio n Gov ernm ent Bond s,
198 2-19 94

Nom inal Yield Curv es for UK
Gov ernm ent Bond s, 1966 ~
1995

~
~

Nom inal Yield Curv es for Aust
rolio n Govt Bond s, 198 2-19
95

•

~

,

Nom inal Yield Curv es for Swe
dish Govt Bond s. 198 7-19
94

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK
RESEARCH PAPERS
1997
The following papers were written by economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York either alone or in collaboration with outside economists. Single copies of up
to six papers are available upon request from the Public Information Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, NY 10045-0001
(212) 720-6134.

9701. Chakravarty, Sugato, and Asani Sarkar. "Traders' Broker Choice, Market Liquidity, and
Market Structure." January 1997.
9702. Park, Sangkyun. "Option Value of Credit Lines as an Explanation of High Credit Card
Rates." February 1997.
9703. Antzoulatos, Angelos. "On the Determinants and Resilience of Bond Flows to LDCs,
1990- 1995: Evidence from Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico." February 1997.
9704. Higgins, Matthew, and Carol Osler. "Asset Market Hangovers and Economic Growth."
February 1997.
9705. Chakravarty, Sugato, and Asani Sarkar. "Can Competition between Brokers Mitigate
Agency Conflicts with Their Customers?" February 1997.
9706. Fleming, Michael, and Eli Remolona. "What Moves the Bond Market?" February 1997.
9707. Laubach, Thomas, and Adam Posen. "Disciplined Discretion: The German and Swiss
Monetary Targeting Frameworks in Operation." March 1997.
9708. Bram, Jason, and Sydney Ludvigson. "Does Consumer Confidence Forecast Household
Expenditure: A Sentiment Index Horse Race." March 1997.
9709. Demsetz, Rebecca, Marc Saidenberg, and Philip Strahan. "Agency Problems and Risk
Taking at Banks." March 1997.

9710. Lopez, Jose. "Regulatory Evaluation of Value-at-Risk Models." March 1997.
9711. Cantor, Richard, Frank Packer, and Kevin Cole. "Split Ratings and the Pricing of Credit
Risk." March 1997.
9712. Ludvigson, Sydney, and Christina Paxson. "Approximation Bias in Linearized Euler
Equations." March 1997.
9713. Chakravarty, Sugato, Sarkar, Asani, and Lifan Wu. "Estimating the Adverse Selection
Cost in Markets with Multiple Informed Traders." April 1997.

To obtain more information about the Bank's Research Papers series and other
publications and papers, visit our site on the World Wide Web (http://www.ny.frb.org). From
the research publications page, you can view abstracts for Research Papers and Staff Reports and
order the full-length, hard copy versions of them electronically. Interested readers can also view,
download, and print any edition in the Current Issues in Economics and Finance series, as well
as articles from the Economic Policy Review.