View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A Quarterly Review
of Business and
Economic Conditions
Vol. 24, No. 3

President’s Message
The State of the Debate
on “Too Big to Fail”

Job Creation

Government Spending
Doesn’t Seem to Help

July 2016

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS
CENTRAL TO AMERICA’S ECONOMY®

Neo-Fisherism
A Radical Idea, or the Most Obvious
Solution to the Low-Inflation Problem?

C O N T E N T S

4
THE REGIONAL

ECONOMIST
JULY 2016 | VOL. 24, NO. 3

Neo-Fisherism: Radical Idea or Obvious Solution?
By Stephen Williamson

Central banks around the world are struggling with inflation rates
that are below their targets. According to conventional central banking
wisdom, interest rate cuts should increase inflation, but that’s not working. Maybe—by Irving Fisher’s logic—increasing nominal interest rates
increases inflation.

3

PRESIDENT’S MESSAGE

10

The Gender Pay Gap:
Role of Irregular Hours

The Regional Economist is published
quarterly by the Research and Public Affairs
divisions of the Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis. It addresses the national, international and regional economic issues of
the day, particularly as they apply to states
in the Eighth Federal Reserve District. Views
expressed are not necessarily those of the
St. Louis Fed or of the Federal Reserve System.

14

Economic Mobility
across Generations
By George-Levi Gayle
and Andrés Hincapié

19

Expansion May Be Weak,
but It Keeps on Going

By Maria Canon and Limor Golan

By Kevin L. Kliesen
The U.S. economic expansion
marked its seventh anniversary in
June. Among the challenges to its
continuation are low inflation and
a slowdown in the growth of labor
productivity.

Director of Research
Christopher J. Waller
Chief of Staff to the President
Cletus C. Coughlin
Deputy Director of Research
David C. Wheelock

The gender pay gap persists, even
within occupations and even
though women’s educational
attainments are surpassing men’s.
Is it because women tend to
choose jobs with hours that are
more irregular than those taken
by men?

Director of Public Affairs
Karen Branding
Editor
Subhayu Bandyopadhyay
Managing Editor
Al Stamborski
Art Director
A.P. Westcott and Joni Williams

Please direct your comments

Are you likely to be in the same
income situation as your parents?
How about being in the same
wealth category? Analyzing such
intergenerational mobility can
shed light on economic inequality
and lead to better policy to deal
with this issue.

16

to Subhayu Bandyopadhyay
at 314-444-7425 or by email at
subhayu.bandyopadhyay@stls.frb.org.
You can also write to him at the
address below. Submission of a
letter to the editor gives us the right
to post it to our website and/or

12

N AT I O N A L O V E R V I E W

20

METRO PROFILE
Health Care, Hospitality
Buoy Hot Springs, Ark.
By Charles S. Gascon
and Faisal Sohail

DISTRICT OVERVIEW
District Households
Buck the Trend on Debt

Government Spending
Might Not Create Jobs

By Helu Jiang
and Juan M. Sánchez

By Bill Dupor
and Rodrigo Guerrero

While at a national level households have decreased their debt
substantially since the financial
crisis, in the St. Louis Fed’s District household debt has remained
constant. The evolution of house
prices may be the key.

publish it in The Regional Economist
unless the writer states otherwise.
We reserve the right to edit letters
for clarity and length.
Single-copy subscriptions are free
but available only to those with
U.S. addresses. To subscribe, go to
www.stlouisfed.org/publications.
You can also write to The Regional

Although this small MSA has
strong health care and tourism
sectors, it also has its share of
challenges: income inequality, no
airport and Americans’ changing
vacation patterns.

Economist, Public Affairs Office,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis,
P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, MO 63166-0442.

The Eighth Federal Reserve District includes

all of Arkansas, eastern Missouri, southern
Illinois and Indiana, western Kentucky and
Tennessee, and northern Mississippi. The
Eighth District offices are in Little Rock,
Louisville, Memphis and St. Louis.

A review of government spending
over 120 years seems to show little, if any, impact on job creation.
The result is the same whether the
economy is in a recession or not.

18

E C O N O M Y AT A G L A N C E

23

RE ADER E XCHANGE

ONLINE EXTRA
Read more at www.stlouisfed.org/publications/regional-economist.
Community Banks’ Compliance Costs and Performance

By Drew Dahl, Andrew Meyer and Michelle Neely

COVER IMAGE: © LIBRARY OF CONGRESS

2 The Regional Economist | July 2016

Research shows that complying with government regulations is more
burdensome for smaller community banks than larger community
banks. Despite spending proportionately more resources on compliance, the smaller banks do not perform as well as the larger ones, at
least in one key metric.

P R E S I D E N T ’ S

M E S S A G E

The State of the Debate on “Too Big to Fail”

F

ollowing the financial crisis, many new
regulations have been implemented to
address systemic risk within the U.S. financial system, including measures that address
capital requirements, liquidity ratios and
leverage levels, among others. Even with the
enactment of the Dodd-Frank Act, which
has yet to be fully implemented, debate
continues as to whether “too big to fail”
(TBTF) remains an issue or whether the
legislation has mitigated this risk to the U.S.
economy. Among those who believe TBTF
remains a key problem for the U.S. economy,
proposals to address the issue range widely.
Recent symposiums held at the Minneapolis Fed, under the leadership of President
Neel Kashkari, explored several of these
proposals.1 In this column, I provide a brief
overview of them and share some of my
perspectives on the topic.
Some researchers, such as Simon Johnson
from MIT, have suggested limiting bank size.
Others, such as Anat Admati from Stanford,
have suggested much higher capital requirements for large banks. A third proposal, by
John Cochrane from Stanford, emphasizes
changing the treatment of leverage in the tax
code as a way to mitigate financial fragility. A fourth proposal seeks to improve the
bankruptcy laws in a way that will allow a
financial firm that is in trouble to more readily go through bankruptcy court. While this
last proposal has garnered attention, it is also
fraught with technical complications. Therefore, I will focus on the first three proposals.
Bank Size Limits: I have been an advocate of a system with smaller financial
institutions which can be allowed to fail, if
necessary. Generally speaking, however, size
restrictions seem arbitrary. Why should a
particular bank size be risky and another
size not be risky? In addition, recent evidence suggests that substantial economies
of scale exist, perhaps even for the largest
financial institutions.2 Furthermore, the
primary concern could be that complexity
or interconnectedness is the trigger toward
financial fragility rather than size itself. For
these reasons, some analysts have concluded

that a size restriction by itself may not be the
most natural solution to the TBTF problem.
Higher Capital Requirements: Raising capital requirements for large financial institutions is emphasized in the Dodd-Frank Act.
The idea is that higher capital requirements
provide a larger buffer to absorb significant
shocks to the institutions, reducing their
risk of failure. Admati and others argue that
capital requirements should be even larger,
which would make their equity capital levels
more comparable to those of nonbanks.
These researchers also point out that banks
had much higher levels of capital in earlier
eras when owners and shareholders were personally liable for paying the banks’ creditors,
if necessary.3 This suggests that the market
solution is to have banks hold more capital
than they do today.
Is there a connection between capital
requirements and size requirements? Recent
comments by Fed Gov. Jerome Powell and
other Fed officials suggest that higher capital
requirements may cause firms to rethink
their optimal size.4 Some of the largest
firms, such as GE Capital, have divested in
an effort not to be designated as systemically
important within the Dodd-Frank Act, a
designation that can lead to higher capital
requirements.
Leverage: Many have suggested that leverage—rather than capital—is the issue, in
which case Cochrane’s proposal to rethink
the tax treatment of leverage might be a
good idea. Keep in mind what happened
during the “tech” bubble in the late 1990s
and early 2000s, when firms had to raise
their financing through equity. Although
investors lost money when the market
crashed, the repercussions for the economy
were not as significant as the crash of the
housing bubble several years later. The U.S.
tax system favors bond financing: Interest
payments on debt instruments are taxdeductible, while dividend payments to
shareholders are not. Giving a less favorable
tax treatment to bond financing and a more
favorable tax treatment to equity financing
might lead to enhanced stability.

These are certainly interesting ideas, but
there is also a global aspect. In particular,
we have seen efforts on a global level to limit
systemic risk through coordinated regulatory
policies across countries. In my experience,
however, other countries often seem to be less
concerned about TBTF as an issue than we
are in the U.S. There is sometimes a tendency
to view large financial firms as national
champions, deserving of protection. In part
because of this, we are evolving globally
toward a regulated utility model—whereby
very large financial institutions are under
heavy regulation, which in my view makes
them unlikely to innovate effectively in the
future. This may leave them vulnerable to
coming waves of financial innovation. This
is an additional consideration in the ongoing
TBTF debate.

James Bullard, President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

ENDNOTES
1		 See

www.minneapolisfed.org/publications/specialstudies/endingtbtf/symposiums.
2		 For instance, see Wheelock, David C.; and Wilson,
Paul W. “Do Large Banks Have Lower Costs? New
Estimates of Returns to Scale for U.S. Banks.” Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking, February 2012, Vol.
44, No. 1, pp. 171-99.
3		 See Admati, Anat; and Hellwig, Martin. The Bankers’
New Clothes: What’s Wrong with Banking and What
to Do about It. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press, 2013. Also see their paper “The Parade of the
Bankers’ New Clothes Continues: 31 Flawed Claims
Debunked,” from December 2015.
4		 See Powell’s comments in the Wall Street Journal
article “Fed Governors Signal Bigger Bank Capital
Requirements Looming,” from June 2, 2016.

The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 3

4 The Regional Economist | July 2016

MONETARY POLICY

Neo-Fisherism
A Radical Idea, or the Most Obvious
Solution to the Low-Inflation Problem?
By Stephen Williamson

D

uring the 2007-2009 global financial crisis, many central
banks in the world, including the Federal Reserve, cut interest rates and resorted to various unconventional policies in order
to fight financial market disruption, high unemployment, and low
or negative economic growth. Now, in 2016, these central banks
are typically experiencing inflation below their targets, and they
seem powerless to correct the problem. Further unconventional
monetary policy actions do not seem to help.
Neo-Fisherites argue that the solution to too-low inflation is
obvious, and it may have been just as obvious to Irving Fisher, the
early 20th century American economist and original Fisherite.
The key Neo-Fisherian principle is that central banks can increase
inflation by increasing their nominal interest rate targets—an idea
that may seem radical at first blush, as central bankers typically
believe that cutting interest rates increases inflation.

Irving Fisher, American economist, circa 1927.

The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 5

FIGURE 1

Year-Over-Year Percent Change in PCE Price Index (Inflation)

Evidence of the Fisher Relation (1954:Q3 to 2015:Q4)
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
–2

0

3

6

9
12
Effective Federal Funds Rate, Percent

15

18

21

SOURCES: Federal Reserve Board and Bureau of Economic Analysis/Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED).
NOTE: PCE=Personal consumption expenditures.

To see where Neo-Fisherian ideas come
from, it helps to understand the roots of the
science of modern central banking. Two
key developments in central banking since
the 1960s were the recognition that: (1) the
responsibility for inflation lies with the
central bank; and (2) the main instrument
for monetary control for the central bank is
a short-term (typically overnight) nominal
interest rate. These developments were driven
largely by monetarist ideas and by the experience with the implementation of those ideas
by central banks in the 1970s and 1980s.
Monetarism is best-represented in the
work of the economist Milton Friedman,
who argued that “inflation is always and
everywhere a monetary phenomenon” and
that inflation can and should be managed through central bank control of the
stock of money in circulation.1 Friedman
reasoned that the best approach to inflation control is the adoption by the central
bank of a constant money growth rule: He
thought the central bank should choose
some monetary aggregate—a measure of the
total quantity of currency, accounts with
commercial banks and other retail payments instruments (for example, M1)—and
conduct monetary policy in such a way that
this monetary aggregate grows at a constant
rate forever. The higher the central bank’s
desired rate of inflation, the higher should
be this constant money growth rate.
During the 1970s and 1980s, many central
banks, including the Fed, adopted money
growth targets as a means for bringing down
6 The Regional Economist | July 2016

the relatively high rates of inflation at that
time. Monetarist ideas were a key element
of the policies adopted by Paul Volcker,
chairman of the Fed’s Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) from 1979 to 1987. He
brought the inflation rate down from about
10 percent at the beginning of his term to 3.5
percent at the end through a reduction in the
rate of growth in the money supply.2
Though monetarist ideas were useful in
bringing about a large reduction in the inflation rate, Friedman’s constant-money-growth
prescription did not work as an approach
to managing inflation on an ongoing basis.
Beginning about 1980, the relationship
between money growth and inflation became
much more unstable, due in part to changes
in financial regulation, technological changes
in the banking industry and perhaps to monetarist monetary policy itself. This meant that
using Friedman’s prescriptions to fine-tune
policy to target inflation over the long term
would not work.
As a result, most central banks, including
the Fed, abandoned money-growth targeting in the 1980s. As an alternative, some
central banks adopted explicit inflation targets, which have since become common. For
example, the European Central Bank, the
Bank of England, the Swedish Riksbank and
the Bank of Japan have targets of 2 percent
for the inflation rate. The U.S. is somewhat
unusual in that Congress has specified a
“dual mandate” for the Fed, which, since
2012, the Fed has interpreted as a 2 percent
inflation target combined with the pursuit
of “maximum employment.”3
Conventional Practice

If a central bank is to move inflation
toward its inflation target without reference
to the growth rate in a measure of money,
how is it supposed to proceed? Central
banks control inflation indirectly by relying
on an intermediate instrument—typically
an overnight nominal interest rate. In the
U.S., the FOMC sets a target for the overnight federal funds rate (fed funds rate) and
sends a directive to the New York Federal
Reserve Bank, which has the responsibility
of reaching the target through intervention
in financial markets.
Conventional central banking practice
is to increase the nominal interest rate
target when inflation is high relative to the

inflation target and to decrease the target
when inflation is low. The reasoning behind
this practice is that increasing interest rates
reduces spending, “cools” the economy and
reduces inflation, while reducing interest
rates increases spending, “heats up” the
economy and increases inflation.
Neo-Fisherism

But what if central banks have inflation
control wrong? A well-established empirical regularity, and a key component of
essentially all mainstream macroeconomic
theories, is the Fisher effect—a positive
relationship between the nominal interest
rate and inflation. The Fisher relationship,
named for Irving Fisher, is readily discernible in the data. Look at Figure 1, for example, which is a scatter plot of the inflation
rate (the four-quarter percentage change
in the personal consumption deflator—the
Fed’s chosen measure of inflation) vs. the
fed funds rate for the period 1954-2015. In
Figure 1, a positively sloped line would be
the best fit to the points in the scatter plot,
indicating that inflation tends to rise as the
fed funds rate rises.
Many macroeconomists have interpreted
the Fisher relation observed in Figure 1 as
involving causation running from inflation to the nominal interest rate (the usual
market quote for the interest rate, not
adjusted for inflation). Market interest rates
are determined by the behavior of borrowers and lenders in credit markets, and these
borrowers and lenders care about real rates
of interest. For example, if I take out a car
loan for one year at an interest rate of 10
percent, and I expect the inflation rate to be
2 percent over the next year, then I expect
the real rate of interest that I will face on
the car loan will be 10 percent – 2 percent =
8 percent. Since borrowers and lenders care
about real rates of interest, we should expect
that as inflation rises, nominal interest
rates will rise as well. So, for example, if the
typical market interest rate on car loans is
10 percent if the inflation rate is expected to
be 2 percent, then we might expect that the
market interest rate on car loans would be
12 percent if the inflation rate were expected
to be 4 percent. If we apply this idea to all
market interest rates, we should anticipate
that, generally, higher inflation will cause
nominal market interest rates to rise.

But, what if we turn this idea on its head,
and we think of the causation running
from the nominal interest rate targeted by
the central bank to inflation? This, basically, is what Neo-Fisherism is all about.
Neo-Fisherism says, consistent with what
we see in Figure 1, that if the central bank
wants inflation to go up, it should increase
its nominal interest rate target, rather than
decrease it, as conventional central banking
wisdom would dictate. If the central bank
wants inflation to go down, then it should
decrease the nominal interest rate target.
But how would this work? To simplify,
think of a world in which there is perfect
certainty and where everyone knows what
future inflation will be. Then, the nominal
interest rate R can be expressed as
R = r + π,
where r is the real (inflation-adjusted) rate
of interest and π is future inflation. Then,
suppose that the central bank increases the
nominal interest rate R by raising its nominal interest rate target by 1 percent and uses
its tools (intervention in financial markets)
to sustain this forever. What happens?
Typically, we think of central bank policy as
affecting real economic activity—employment, unemployment, gross domestic
product, for example—through its effects
on the real interest rate r. But, as is widely
accepted by macroeconomists, these effects
dissipate in the long run. So, after a long
period of time, the increase in the nominal
interest rate will have no effect on r and will
be reflected only in a one-for-one increase
in the inflation rate, π. In other words, in
the long run, the only effect of the nominal
interest rate on inflation comes through the
Fisher effect; so, if the nominal interest rate
went up by 1 percent, so should the inflation
rate—in the long run.
But, in the short run, it is widely accepted
by macroeconomists (though there is some
disagreement about the exact mechanism)
that an increase in R will also increase r,
which will have a negative effect on aggregate economic activity—unemployment will
go up and gross domestic product will go
down. This is what macroeconomists call a
non-neutrality of money. But note that, if
an increase in R results in an increase in r,
the short-run response of inflation to the
increase in R must be less than one-for-one.

Neo-Fisherism says, consistent with what we see in
Figure 1, that if the central
bank wants inflation to go up,
it should increase its nominal
interest rate target, rather
than decrease it, as conventional central banking wisdom
would dictate. If the central
bank wants inflation to go
down, then it should decrease
the nominal interest rate target.

The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 7

Interest Rate and Inflation Rate, in Percent

FIGURE 2
Response to a Permanent Increase in the Nominal Interest Rate at Time T

SOURCE: Stephen Williamson.

R

r

T

Time

NOTE: R is the nominal interest rate, r is the real interest rate and π is the inflation rate. When R is increased, r increases one-for-one initially. As r moves back to
its long-run level, π increases. In the long run, r returns to its equilibrium rate and π increases one-for-one with R.

However, if inflation is to go down when R
goes up, the real interest rate r must increase
more than one-for-one with an increase in
R, that is, the non-neutrality of money in the
short run must be very large.
To assess these issues thoroughly, we need
a well-specified macroeconomic model. But
essentially all mainstream macroeconomic
models predict a response of the economy
to an increase in the nominal interest rate
as depicted in Figure 2. In this figure, time
is on the horizontal axis, and the central
bank acts to increase the nominal interest
rate permanently, and in an unanticipated
fashion, at time T. This results in an increase
in the real interest rate r on impact. Inflation π increases gradually over time, and
the real interest rate falls, with the inflation rate increasing by the same amount
as the increase in R in the long run. This
type of response holds even in mainstream
New Keynesian models, which, it is widely
believed, predict that a central bank wanting to increase inflation should lower its
nominal interest rate target. However,
as economist John Cochrane shows, the
New Keynesian model implies that if the
central bank carries out the policy we have
described—a permanent increase of 1
percent in the central bank’s nominal interest rate target—then the inflation rate will
increase, even in the short run.4
The Low-Inflation Policy Trap

What could go wrong if central bankers do not recognize the importance of
the Fisher effect and instead conform to
8 The Regional Economist | July 2016

conventional central banking wisdom?
Conventional wisdom is embodied in the
Taylor rule, first proposed by John Taylor
in 1993.5 Taylor’s idea is that optimal
central bank behavior can be written
down in the form of a rule that includes
a positive response of the central bank’s
nominal interest rate target to an increase
in inflation.
But the Taylor rule does not seem to
make sense in terms of what we see in
Figure 2. Taylor appears to have thought,
in line with conventional central banking wisdom, that increasing the nominal
interest rate will make the inflation rate go
down, not up. Further, Taylor advocated a
specific aggressive response of the nominal
interest rate target to the inflation rate,
sometimes called the Taylor principle. This
principle is that the nominal interest rate
should increase more than one-for-one
with an increase in the inflation rate.
So, what happens in a world that is
Neo-Fisherian (the inflationary process
works as in Figure 2), but central bankers
behave as if they live in Taylor’s world?
Macroeconomic theory predicts that a
Taylor-principle central banker will
almost inevitably arrive at the “zero lower
bound.” 6 What does that mean?
Until recently, macroeconomists argued
that short-term nominal interest rates
could not go below zero because, if interest
rates were negative, people would prefer
to hold cash, which has a nominal interest rate equal to zero. According to this
logic, the lower bound on the nominal

interest rate is zero. It turns out that, if the
central bank follows the Taylor principle,
then this implies that the central bank
will see inflation falling and will respond
to this by reducing the nominal interest
rate. Then, because of the Fisher effect, this
actually leads to lower inflation, causing
further reductions in the nominal interest rate by the central bank and further
decreases in inflation, etc. Ultimately, the
central bank sets a nominal interest rate
of zero, and there are no forces that will
increase inflation. Effectively, the central
bank becomes stuck in a low-inflation policy
trap and cannot get out—unless it becomes
Neo-Fisherian.
But maybe this is only theory. Surely,
central banks would not get stuck in this
fashion in reality, misunderstanding what
is going on, right? Unfortunately, not. The
primary example is the Bank of Japan. Since
1995, this central bank has seen an average
inflation rate of about zero, having kept its
nominal interest rate target at levels close
to zero over those 21 years. The Bank of
Japan has an inflation target of 2 percent
and wants inflation to be higher, but seems
unable to achieve what it wants.
Over the past several years, membership in the low-inflation-policy-trap club of
central banks has been increasing. This club
includes the European Central Bank, whose
key nominal interest rate is –0.34 percent
and inflation rate is –0.22 percent; the Swedish Riksbank, with key nominal interest
rate of –0.50 percent and inflation rate of
0.79 percent; the Danish central bank, with
key nominal interest rate of –0.23 percent
and inflation rate of 0 percent; the Swiss
National Bank, with key nominal interest
rate of –0.73 percent and inflation rate of
–0.35 percent; and the Bank of England,
with key nominal interest rate of 0.47 percent and inflation rate of 0.30 percent. Each
of these central banks has been missing
its inflation target on the low side, in some
cases for a considerable period of time.7 The
Fed could be included in this group, too,
as the fed funds rate was targeted at 0-0.25
percent for about seven years, until Dec. 16,
2015, when the target range was increased
to 0.25-0.50 percent. The Fed has missed its
2 percent inflation target on the low side for
about four years now.

How a Trapped Central Bank Behaves

Abandoning the Taylor principle and
embracing Neo-Fisherism seems a difficult
step for central banks. What they typically
do on encountering low inflation and low
nominal interest rates is engage in unconventional monetary policy. Indeed, unconventional policy has become commonplace
enough to become respectably conventional.
Unconventional monetary policy takes
three forms in practice. First, central banks
can push market nominal interest rates
below zero (relaxing the zero lower bound)
by paying negative interest on reserves at
the central bank—charging a fee on such
accounts, as has been done by the Bank of
Japan, the Swiss National Bank, the Danish
central bank and the Swedish Riksbank.
Second, there can be so-called quantitative
easing, or QE—the large-scale purchase of
long-maturity assets (government debt and
private assets, such as mortgage-backed
securities) by a central bank. Such programs
have been an important element of monetary policy in the U.S., Switzerland and
Japan, for example, in the years after the
financial crisis (2007-2009). Third, central
banks can engage in forward guidance—
promises concerning what they will do in
the future. Typically, these are promises that
interest rates will stay low in the future, in
the hope that this will increase inflation. But
will any of these unconventional policies
actually work to increase the inflation rate?
Neo-Fisherism suggests not.
First, given the Fisher effect, a negative
nominal interest rate will only make the
inflation rate lower, as has happened in Switzerland, where nominal interest rates have
been negative for some time and there is
deflation—negative inflation. Second, some
theory indicates that QE either does not
work at all or acts to make inflation lower. 8
This is consistent with what we have seen in
Japan, where an extensive QE program in
place for two years has not yielded higher
inflation. Third, forward guidance, which
promises more of the same unconventional
policies and continued low interest rates if
the low-inflation problem persists, will only
prolong the problem.

that is pursuing a policy of increases in its
nominal interest rate target. This policy,
referred to as “normalization,” was initiated
in December 2015. Normalization, however,
is projected to take place slowly and is not
motivated explicitly by Neo-Fisherian ideas,
though James Bullard, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, has shown
interest.9
What is the risk associated with NeoFisherian denial—a failure to take account
of the Fisher relation in formulating
monetary policy? Neo-Fisherian denial will
tend to produce inflation lower than central
banks’ inflation targets and nominal interest rates that are at central banks’ effective
lower bounds—the low-inflation policy trap.
But what of it? There are no good reasons to
think that, for example, 0 percent inflation
is worse than 2 percent inflation, as long as
inflation remains predictable. But “permazero” damages the hard-won credibility
of central banks if they claim to be able to
produce 2 percent inflation consistently,
yet fail to do so. As well, a central bank
stuck in a low-inflation policy trap with a
zero nominal interest rate has no tools to
use, other than unconventional ones, if a
recession unfolds. In such circumstances, a
central bank that is concerned with stabilization—in the case of the Fed, concerned
with fulfilling its “maximum employment”
mandate—cannot cut interest rates. And we
know that a central bank stuck in a lowinflation trap and wedded to conventional
wisdom resorts to unconventional monetary
policies, which are potentially ineffective
and still poorly understood.
Stephen Williamson is an economist at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. For more
on his work, see https://research.stlouisfed.
org/econ/williamson. Research assistance was
provided by Jonas Crews, a research associate
at the Bank.

ENDNOTES
1
2

3
4
5
6

7

8
9

See Friedman.
The inflation rate is measured as the fourquarter percentage increase in the personal
consumption deflator.
See Federal Open Market Committee.
See Cochrane.
See Taylor.
See Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe; Andolfatto and Williamson; and Bullard’s
2010 work for examples.
Data are for April 2016. For the European
Union, Switzerland and the United Kingdom,
the key nominal interest rate refers to the
April average of the overnight interbank lending
rate, while for Denmark it is the average of the
tomorrow-next interbank rate. For Sweden,
the rate refers to the end-of-period value of
the central bank-pegged repo rate. Inflation
rate refers to the 12-month percent change in
consumer prices.
See Williamson.
See Bullard’s 2016 work.

REFERENCES
Andolfatto, David; and Williamson, Stephen.
“Scarcity of Safe Assets, Inflation, and the Policy
Trap.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 2015,
Vol. 73, C, pp. 70-92.
Benhabib, Jess; Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie; and
Uribe, Martín. “The Perils of Taylor Rules.”
Journal of Economic Theory, 2001, Vol. 96,
Nos. 1-2, pp. 40-69.
Bullard, James. “Seven Faces of ‘The Peril.’” Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 2010, Vol. 92,
No. 5, pp. 339-52. See https://research.stlouisfed.
org/publications/review/10/09/Bullard.pdf.
Bullard, James. “Permazero in Europe?”
Presentation at the Ninth International
Research Forum on Monetary Policy,
Frankfurt, Germany, March 18, 2016. See
https://www.stlouisfed.org/~/media/Files/
PDFs/Bullard/remarks/Bullard-9th-IRFMPFrankfurt-18-March-2016.pdf.
Cochrane, John. “Do Higher Interest Rates Raise
or Lower Inflation?” Working paper, Hoover
Institution, Feb. 10, 2016. See http://faculty.
chicagobooth.edu/john.cochrane/research/
papers/fisher.pdf.
Federal Open Market Committee. “Statement
on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary
Policy Strategy,” Jan. 26, 2016. See http://www.
federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/
FOMC_LongerRunGoals_20160126.pdf.
Friedman, Milton. The Counter-Revolution in
Monetary Theory. London, U.K.: Transatlantic
Arts, 1970.
Taylor, John. “Discretion versus Policy Rules in
Practice.” Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public
Policy, 1993, Vol. 39, pp. 195-214.
Williamson, Stephen. “Scarce Collateral, the Term
Premium, and Quantitative Easing.” Journal of
Economic Theory, 2016, Vol. 164, pp. 136-65.

Conclusion

Among the major central banks in the
world, the Fed stands out as the only one
The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 9

LABOR MARKETS

Gender Pay Gap May Be Linked
To Flexible and Irregular Hours
By Maria Canon and Limor Golan
©THINKSTOCK / DIEGO_CERVO

10 The Regional Economist | July 2016

FIGURE 1

FIGURE 2

Female Employment by Occupation Type

Nonroutine Cognitive Employment:
Female

50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0

’93 ’95 ’97 ’99 ’01 ’03 ’05 ’07 ’09 ’11 ’13 ’15
Nonroutine cognitive
Nonroutine manual

Routine cognitive
Routine manual

SOURCE: Census Bureau Current Population
Survey and author’s calculations.

percentage of these jobs than did women until
1996, when the positions were reversed.
We also explored the trend in job flexibility by gender. The table presents changes in
flexibility of hours and patterns of irregular
hours due to employer and personal reasons
in 1997, 2001 and 2004 by occupation category.2 While the notion of “job flexibility” is
vague, intuitively job flexibility can be interpreted as having control over the timing of
work.3 However, individuals were also asked
whether they worked irregular hours due
to personal reasons or the job requirements
(employer reasons).4 Thus, one may think
of the ability to work irregular hours due to
personal reasons as flexibility, while working
irregular hours due to employer reasons as a
form of inflexibility.
The top panel of the table describes the job
flexibility and irregular hours in nonroutine
cognitive occupations. Overall, the fraction
of women who responded “yes” to the question of flexibility of hours declined slightly
from 1997 to 2004, but it increased for males.

Percent of Nonroutine Cognitive Employment

lthough women’s educational attainments
are increasingly surpassing men’s in the
U.S. and although women’s representation in
professional occupations is on the rise, there is
still a gender pay gap, even within occupations.
Recent research suggests that the gap exists
because women tend to choose jobs that offer
more-flexible hours than those chosen by men
and that these jobs typically pay less than jobs
with longer and more rigid hours.1 In order to
further understand the gender differences in
different aspects of employment, this article
explores the changes in patterns of flexibility
in hours of men and women from 1993 to 2015.
To get an idea of changes in the patterns of
types of jobs women sort into, we started off
by analyzing data from the Current Population Survey (CPS) for the period 1993-2015.
Figure 1 presents the changes in female
employment by category of work. We grouped
types of work into four categories based on the
tasks performed in each one. The categories
are nonroutine cognitive, which includes
professional occupations, management, business and financial; routine cognitive, which
includes sales, office and administrative work;
nonroutine manual, which is a broad category
that includes service; and routine manual,
which includes construction and mining,
installation, maintenance and repair, production and transportation.
As the figure shows, employment of women
in nonroutine cognitive occupations increased
from 34 percent in 1993 to 43 percent in 2015.
Employment of women in nonroutine manual
occupations also increased slightly. Employment decreased in both routine manual and
routine cognitive occupations.
Meanwhile, Figure 2 shows the upward trend
in the percentage of women working in nonroutine cognitive occupations. Men held a greater

Percent of Total Female Employment

A

53
52
51
50
49
48
’93 ’95 ’97 ’99 ’01 ’03 ’05 ’07 ’09 ’11 ’13 ’15
SOURCE: Census Bureau Current Population
Survey and author’s calculations.

However, this picture might be incomplete
because, among those who work flexible
hours, there are workers who work irregular
hours due to employer reasons, and among
those who responded “no” to the flexibility
of hours question, there are people who work
irregular hours due to personal reasons.
The overall fraction of workers who
worked irregular hours for both personal and
employer reasons in nonroutine cognitive
occupations was similar in 1997 and 2004
(although the percentage of workers who
worked irregular hours due to personal reasons increased from 1997 to 2001 and then
decreased, while the percentage of workers
who worked irregular hours due to employer
reasons decreased and then increased).
Interestingly, however, only 35 percent of
females who worked in nonroutine cognitive
occupations in 1997 worked irregular hours
for personal reasons, while 54 percent did so
in 2001 and 47 percent did so in 2004. At the
same time, the fraction of women in these
occupations who worked irregular hours due

to employer reasons declined substantially,
from 65 percent in 1997 to 46 percent in 2001
and 53 percent in 2004.
Thus, women in occupations characterized by nonroutine cognitive tasks were
more likely to have irregular shift schedules
in 2001 and 2004 relative to 1997 due to personal reasons. One possibility is that this is a
general trend driven by technological change
or other employer-related changes in these
occupations. If this is the case, then these
patterns should also be observed for males.
However, the table reveals that this is not the
case. It shows that the trend is the opposite
for men. Looking at the irregular work hours
for men reveals that a higher proportion of
men always worked more irregular hours
due to employer reasons and less because
of personal reasons, relative to women. The
percentage of men who worked irregular
hours for personal reasons declined from
34 percent in 1997 to 32 percent in 2001 and
24 percent in 2004. The proportion of men
who worked irregular hours due to employer
reasons increased substantially. In 1997,
66 percent of males worked irregular hours
because of employer reasons, increasing to
68 percent in 2001 and 76 percent in 2004.
Since overall in the nonroutine cognitive
occupations the percentage of workers who
worked irregular hours for personal and
employer reasons is the same in 1997 as in
2004, and since the percentage of women in
these occupations went up from 45 percent
to 50 percent between 1997 and 2004, the
increase in irregular hours due to personal
reasons of women offsets the decline in these
hours worked by men. The same applies for
irregular hours worked due to employer
reasons: The increase for men offsets the
decrease for women.
Looking at the trend in the percentage of
workers having irregular hours in nonroutine
manual jobs shows an overall increase in the
portion of workers with irregular hours for
personal reasons in 2001 and 2004 relative to
1997 and a lower fraction of workers working
irregular hours for employer reasons in 2001
and 2004 relative to 1997. In routine manual
jobs, there is a decrease in the percentage of
workers with irregular hours due to personal
reasons from 1997 and 2001 to 2004, and an
increase in the fraction of workers working
irregular hours due to employer reasons. These
patterns hold both for males and females.

Overall, almost in all occupations in all
years, a higher fraction of women work
irregular hours due to personal reasons and
a lower fraction work irregular hours due to
employer reasons, relative to men. This might
be due to more work at home for women than
men and more child care responsibilities for
women than men. Overall, both males and
females in nonroutine cognitive occupations are less likely to work irregular hours
due to personal reasons than they are in any
other occupation, while the opposite is true
for working irregular hours due to employer
reasons. This fact holds in all years. However,
as employment of women and the fraction
of women in nonroutine cognitive occupations increase, there has been an increase for
women in the irregular hours due to personal
reasons and a decrease in irregular hours due
to employer reasons.
Thus, to the extent that pay is related to the
type of shifts that people work, it probably
is important to further study differences in
employment patterns of men and women in
order to understand the persistence of the
gender pay gap.

ENDNOTES
1 See Goldin.
2 We present the fraction that worked irregular hours

due to personal reasons; therefore, 1 minus that
number is the fraction that worked irregular hours
due to employer reasons.
3 In the CPS, people were asked: “Do you have flexible
hours that allow you to vary or make changes in the
time you begin and end work?”
4 The question on irregular hours was: “What is the
main reason why you work this type of shift?”
		 Personal reasons included: better arrangements
for child care or other family members; better pay;
allows time for school; easier commute, less traffic;
personal preference; other—voluntary reason; and
some other reason.
		 Employer reasons included: could not get any
other job; requirement/nature of job; other involuntary reason; and mandated by employer to meet
traffic or pollution requirements.

REFERENCES
Blau, Francine D.; and Kahn, Lawrence M. “The U.S.
Gender Pay Gap in the 1990s: Slowing Convergence.” Industrial & Labor Relations Review,
October 2006, Vol. 60, No. 1, pp. 45-66.
Canon Maria E.; and Marifian, Elise. “Job Polarization
Leaves Middle-Skilled Workers Out in the Cold.”
The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis’ The Regional
Economist, January 2013, Vol. 21, No. 1, pp. 9-11.
Gayle, George-Levi; and Golan, Limor. “Estimating
a Dynamic Adverse-Selection Model: Labor-Force
Experience and the Changing Gender Earnings Gap
1968–1997.” The Review of Economic Studies, 2012,
Vol. 79, No. 1, pp. 227-67.
Goldin, Claudia. “A Grand Gender Convergence: Its
Last Chapter.” The American Economic Review,
April 2014, Vol. 104, No. 4, pp. 1,091-119.

Maria Canon and Limor Golan are economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
For more on their work, see https://research.
stlouisfed.org/econ/canon and https://research.
stlouisfed.org/econ/golan. Usa Kerdnunvong
provided research assistance.
Flexible and Irregular Hours for Women and Men
(In each
year)
Subtype
of Jobs
Nonroutine
Cognitive

Routine
Cognitive

Nonroutine
Manual

Routine
Manual

Gender
Distribution

Irregular Hours for
Personal Reasons

Flexible Hours
Percent
of Female
Workers

(among those who work irregular hours)

Percent
of Male
Workers

Percent
of Total
Workers

Percent
of Female
Workers

Percent
of Male
Workers

Percent
of Total
Workers

Year

Percent
of All
Jobs

1997

11.75

44.57

55.43

42.31

35.35

38.45

34.90

33.71

34.30

2001

22.29

49.47

50.53

39.79

45.31

42.58

54.46

32.00

42.39

Female

Male

2004

19.07

50.38

49.62

40.67

47.12

43.87

46.76

23.94

34.60

1997

34.03

58.51

41.49

38.26

44.08

40.68

51.68

36.04

44.65

2001

23.75

55.51

44.49

35.70

36.21

35.93

58.30

45.01

52.34

2004

24.23

56.73

43.27

38.97

33.44

36.58

51.26

52.03

51.56

1997

27.39

45.95

54.05

32.43

23.42

27.56

48.64

45.32

47.12

2001

28.83

49.68

50.32

31.22

24.40

27.79

60.52

48.62

55.26

2004

32.98

49.71

50.29

31.39

25.79

28.57

51.58

46.62

49.33

1997

26.82

19.58

80.42

18.16

20.55

20.08

61.78

40.27

44.08

2001

25.14

21.17

78.83

18.67

18.46

18.50

57.17

42.34

45.51

2004

23.71

17.03

82.97

15.74

19.70

19.03

51.04

31.86

34.56

SOURCES: Census Bureau Work Schedules Supplement and authors’ calculations.
NOTE: The questions regarding flexible hours and irregular hours were asked in the CPS Work Schedules Supplement, which was intermittently
included in the May CPS. Therefore, we reported the results from the three latest supplements, which were in 1997, 2001 and 2004.
The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 11

FISCAL POLICY

Government Spending
Might Not Create Jobs,
Even during Recessions
By Bill Dupor and Rodrigo Guerrero
©THINKSTOCK / GLEGORLY

C

ountercyclical economic policy refers
to the actions taken by governments to
soften or neutralize the detrimental effects
of business cycles. Governments have two
main tools at their disposal to conduct such
actions: fiscal policy and monetary policy.
In a time when it has become infeasible for
the monetary policymakers at the Federal
Reserve to reduce interest rates much further,
if at all, the effectiveness of fiscal policy has
moved into the spotlight for macroeconomists. Fiscal policy consists of adjustments in
tax rates and government spending levels; in
this article, we focus on the latter, specifically
on the effects of government spending on
employment, particularly during recessions.

The Intricacies of Fiscal Policy

The effectiveness of fiscal policy is often
questioned because its positive impact on
employment and output may be dampened by
secondary effects that “crowd out” economic
activity in the private sector. For instance, if
the expenditure is financed by borrowing,
then this borrowing might exert upward pressure on interest rates, which, in turn, would
cause a reduction in private investment.
Similarly, a surge in fiscal spending may bid
up wages, thereby reducing the demand for
labor in the private sector.
Times of high unemployment usually
see an uptick in calls for increased government spending from politicians, pundits and
economists. These observers appeal to a logic
for government intervention that might not
be valid during normal economic times; they
argue that the detrimental secondary effects
of fiscal spending are not as prominent when
the economy is slack.
The simple thinking is that because the
government’s demand for goods and services
12 The Regional Economist | July 2016

can be met with otherwise idle workers, additional public spending need not bid up wages
significantly or crowd out private demand.
There’s also a natural and undeniable urge for
political leaders to “do something” during a
downturn. As economist Robert Lucas wrote
during the 2007-2009 recession, “I guess
everyone is a Keynesian in a foxhole.”
Instincts and gut reactions notwithstanding, whether government spending is
particularly effective at increasing economic
activity during times of high unemployment
is an empirical question. A large amount of
research has been conducted on the effects
of government purchases on output (or
gross domestic product) during recessions;
relatively less research has focused on these
purchases’ employment effects. Understanding the employment effects of government
intervention during recessions is crucial—
much of the brunt from downturns, such
as the 2007-2009 recession, is likely felt by
people losing their jobs.
Public Spending and Employment

A researcher ideally would like to see macroeconomic experiments with government
spending changing over time for reasons
unrelated to business cycle fluctuations and
also to have these experiments occur during
both high- and low-unemployment times.
These exogenous changes would generate
natural experiments akin to the controlled
experiments used to test, for example, the
efficacy of new drugs.
Although truly exogenous large changes in
government spending do not exist in the U.S.
(or probably anywhere else), we in the U.S.
have something close in the form of defense
spending. Defense spending can be used
because changes in it are mostly determined

by international geopolitical factors rather
than macroeconomic conditions. In our new
research, we employed a recently created data
set containing more than 120 years’ worth
of data on government purchases; the data
set was introduced in a series of papers by
economists Michael Owyang, Valerie Ramey
and Sarah Zubairy.1 These data appear in
the upper panel of the figure. They include
episodes of large variation in government
spending during both low-unemployment
times, such as World War I and the Korean
War, and high-unemployment times, such as
World War II.
The spending data also include a time
series of “defense news shocks.” Using
historical documents, such as Business Week
magazine, Ramey constructed a time series
of changes in the values of future military
spending. These data appear in the lower
panel of the figure. Note, for example, the
large upward spikes near the start of World
War II and the downward spikes as that war
neared its end. Since this series is based on
military purchases that were not motivated
by business cycle conditions, the data help
to identify the exogenous component of the
government spending shocks. Moreover,
it is important to use news about military
spending to tease out exogenous changes
rather than military spending itself because
households and businesses may change their
behavior in response to new information
even if the actual defense spending is months
to years away. For instance, a military
contractor might react to news about future
government purchases by increasing its
workforce in anticipation of higher demand.
The upper panel of the figure plots real
(inflation-adjusted) per capita government
spending between 1890 and 2010. The shaded

bars indicate years when, according to our
measure, the labor market was slack, i.e.,
the unemployment rate was greater than
6.5 percent. In addition to a general upward
trend, there are spikes in government spending. The most notable ones result from World
War I and World War II. The lower panel of
the figure plots the military news variable. At
each quarter, it gives the change in the present value of expected future defense spending as a fraction of gross domestic product
(GDP). For many periods, its values are zero,
which indicate periods where beliefs about
future defense spending are unchanged. Not
surprisingly, there are major positive spikes
around the times of World War I and World
War II.
Specifically, our research aims to answer
the following two questions: (1) By how much
does national civilian employment change
when government spending increases? (2) Is
this estimate dependent on the unemployment level at the time in which the spending
occurs?2 We used the news about military
spending to infer the quantitative response
of employment to exogenous changes in
government spending.

possibility that the effect of public spending
on employment is the same during times of
high and low unemployment. This is due to
the fact that we lose precision in the estimation at longer horizons.

Small Employment Effects

SOURCES: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Bureau of Labor Statistics and
Ramey (2011).

1

2

Conclusion

The question of the efficacy of countercyclical fiscal policy during downturns is far
from settled. It is important that macroeconomists continue to study the issue. As
horse racing fans say, there is a lot of money
riding on it. For example, the total budget
impact of the most recent U.S. stimulus
($840 billion for the American Recovery
and Reinvestment Act of 2009) was larger
than U.S. defense spending in Iraq since
9/11.4, 5

3
4

5

Our paper largely follows the approach of a 2013
study by Michael Owyang, Valerie Ramey and
Sarah Zubairy.
In answering these questions, we used two econometric adjustment procedures. First, we estimated
the dynamic effects using the local projections
method to allow the effect of spending to vary
depending upon whether the unemployment rate is
high or low. Second, we used instrumental variables
with defense news shocks to correct for the possibility that government spending is endogenous to local
business-cycle conditions.
These ranges are based on 90 percent confidence
intervals.
According to a 2014 study by Amy Belasco, between
the 9/11 attacks and the end of 2014, congressional
appropriations for military operations in Iraq
totaled $815 billion.
Our findings suggest that the drop in unemployment since 2009 was probably not a result of the
Recovery Act’s spending component. Understanding the reasons for the decline in unemployment is a
topic that warrants further exploration.

REFERENCES

Bill Dupor is an economist and Rodrigo
Guerrero is a research associate, both at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. For more on
Dupor’s work, see https://research.stlouisfed.
org/econ/dupor.

FIGURE BELOW

NOTE: The upper panel shows real per capita government spending for the
years in our sample. The lower panel presents the change in the present value
of expected future defense spending as a fraction of GDP, as constructed by
economist Valerie Ramey. Shading indicates quarters in which the unemployment rate was above our benchmark threshold of 6.5 percent.

Belasco, Amy. “The Cost of Iraq, Afghanistan, and
Other Global War on Terror Operations since 9/11.”
Congressional Research Service, Dec. 8, 2014.
Dupor, William; and Guerrero, Rodrigo. “Robust
Inference about Fiscal Multipliers.” Unfinished
manuscript.
Fox, Justin. “The Comeback Keynes.” Time, Vol. 172,
No. 18, Nov. 3, 2008, p. 60.
Owyang, Michael; Ramey, Valerie; and Zubairy, Sarah.
“Are Government Spending Multipliers Greater
During Periods of Slack? Evidence from 20th Century Historical Data.” American Economic Review,
Vol. 103, No. 3, 2013, pp. 129-34.
Ramey, Valerie. “Identifying Government Spending
Shocks: It’s All in the Timing.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 126, No. 1, 2011, pp. 1-50.

Real per Capita Government Spending
(2005 dollars)

Government Spending and Military News Shocks in Times of High, Low Unemployment

Future Military Spending (% of GDP)

We found that, in the short and intermediate run, there are only small employment
effects of government spending in both highand low-unemployment times. We quantified the effects of government spending over
a four-year horizon following exogenous
news about future U.S. defense spending.
Following a policy change that begins
when the unemployment rate is high, if
government spending increases by 1 percent
of GDP, then total employment increases
by between 0 percent and 0.15 percent. Following a policy change that begins when
the unemployment rate is low, the same
government spending increase causes total
employment to change by –0.4 percent and 0
percent.3 Although the effect is larger during
times of high unemployment, even then, the
employment effect of government spending
is low.
In the longer run (e.g., seven or eight
years), we also found almost no effect on
employment from government spending.
The estimated effects are not statistically
different from zero. The main difference is
that in the long run we cannot reject the

ENDNOTES

10,000
8,000
6,000
4,000
2,000
0

1890

1900

1910

1920

1930

1940

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

1890

1900

1910

1920

1930

1940

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

80
60
40
20
0
–20

The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 13

E C O N O M I C

M O B I L I T Y

Which Persists More
from Generation to Generation
—Income or Wealth?
By George-Levi Gayle and Andrés Hincapié
©THINKSTOCK

D

o you earn more money than your
parents? Do you have more wealth,
i.e., assets minus liabilities, than your
parents? Economists use the answers to
these questions to determine what is called
intergenerational mobility—the changes in
a family’s economic status between successive generations. Why should we care
about intergenerational mobility? Being
able to do better than one’s parents is part of
the American Dream. Also, a society with
intergenerational mobility might have less
economic inequality across generations.
It is well-documented that income and
wealth inequality, i.e., the size of the differences in income or wealth between the
haves and the have-nots, has increased
significantly over the past 40 years.1 If
there were no inequality, then economic
mobility would probably not be a topic of
discussion because parents would have no
economic advantage to bequeath. However,
inequality exists, and as it increases, the
need for economic mobility becomes more
important. Policies that promote economic
mobility can reduce inequality in the next
generation.
What is it that makes one society more
economically mobile than another? Are
there factors that can promote economic
mobility? In discussing such questions,
economists have come up with two possible
approaches to these challenges: (1) the economic opportunity structure and (2) economic growth. Economic growth promotes
mobility by raising earnings or wealth for
the entire population, all else being equal.
For example, the growth following the Great
Depression greatly benefited the children
of those people who endured this period of
economic distress. We will not explore the
14 The Regional Economist | July 2016

effect of economic growth here. Instead,
we will focus on the effect of the economic
opportunity structure. Economists use
this phrase to describe everything from
equal access to good schools to equal career
opportunities. The economic opportunity
structure can promote economic mobility
by helping the poor escape poverty (perhaps
with the help of free preschool, for example)
or by limiting the advantage of those who
grew up privileged (by imposing inheritance
taxes, for example, so that they have less to
pass down to the next generation).
Which is more effective—instituting
policies that help the poor escape poverty or
instituting policies that limit the advantages
of the privileged? Some light can be shed on
this question by looking at the differences
between intergenerational persistence of
labor market earnings versus intergenerational persistence of wealth, as well as at
their sources.
It is well-documented that labor market
earnings are very persistent across generations,2 and a few studies have shown that
there is also intergenerational persistence of
wealth.3 Wealth, as a more comprehensive
measure of economic well-being, includes
the average labor market earnings over a
person’s working life (called permanent
income by economists). Therefore, decoupling earnings persistence from wealth
persistence will probably make it easier
to answer the above question on policies.
Economic research has shown that earnings
persistence is mostly due to investment in
early childhood education and other human
capital development;4 persistence of residual
wealth (net of permanent income and
education) would be due to bequests, asset
accumulation and the capital market.5

Income and Wealth Data

We used data from the Panel Study of
Income Dynamics from 1968 to 2013 on
both wealth and labor market earnings to
construct age-adjusted correlations of outcomes across generations.6 The correlation
in earnings from one generation to another
is higher than the correlation in wealth from
one generation to another. The intergenerational elasticity of earnings is 0.4 and that
of wealth is 0.38, meaning that a 10 percent
difference in parents’ income would lead
to a 4 percent difference in their offspring’s
income. For wealth, a 10 percent difference
in parents’ wealth would lead only to a 3.8
percent difference in their offspring’s wealth.
For technical reasons, the calculation of the
intergenerational elasticity of wealth excludes
households with no wealth or net debt. This
is an important omission, given that one
in five individuals has zero or negative net
worth. Therefore, we also report the correlation between an individual’s rank in his/her
generation’s income or wealth distribution
and rank of his/her parents in their generation’s income or wealth distribution (called
the rank-rank correlation), which includes all
households. The rank-rank correlation is 0.3
for wealth and 0.4 for labor market earnings; once the wealth distribution with both
positive and negative net worth is accounted
for, labor market earnings appear to be 33
percent more persistent than wealth.
One Number Isn’t Enough

Using one number to summarize the
intergenerational persistence of earnings and
wealth cannot answer whether such persistence is due to the inability of the poor to
escape poverty or the persistence of wealth

and income at the top. To answer this, we
need to look at how children move to a different rung of the income ladder and wealth
ladder from where their parents were. The
figure presents these transitions.
The figure shows that permanent income
is much stickier than wealth for those on the
bottom of the economic ladder (first quintile).
Those who are born to parents in the lowest
quintile of the permanent income distribution
have a 39 percent chance of remaining in their
parents’ position. However, those born in the
bottom 20 percent of the wealth distribution
have a 27 percent chance of remaining there.
At the top of the economic ladder (fifth quintile), both permanent income and wealth are
sticky: Those born in the top 20 percent of the
permanent income and wealth distribution
have a 41 and 47 percent chance of remaining
there, respectively.
Decoupling Income and Education

A significant percentage of wealth is
explained by permanent income and education. Therefore, we calculate residual wealth,
which is wealth net of the effect of permanent
income and education.7 Residual wealth is
much less persistent across generations, with
an intergenerational elasticity of between
0.17 and 0.21. Hence, more than 50 percent
of the persistence in wealth seems to be due
to the persistence in permanent income. This
is evident by looking at the residual wealth
panel of the figure, which shows significantly
more mobility. For example, 28 percent of the
children of parents in the top quintile of the
residual wealth distribution will end up in the
bottom two quintiles, and 28 percent of the

children of parents in the bottom quintile of
the residual wealth distribution will end up in
the top two quintiles.

ENDNOTES
1

Policy Implication

Permanent or lifetime labor market income
is much more persistent across generations
than is wealth. Although people born in the
lowest quintile of the wealth distribution have
a 73 percent chance of escaping this position,
the same is true for only 61 percent of those
born in the lowest quintile of the income
distribution. Furthermore, permanent or
lifetime labor market income accounts for
more than 50 percent of the persistence of
wealth. This evidence suggests that policies
aimed at human capital enhancement, e.g.,
free preschool for everyone, may be as effective at combating inequality as those aimed at
limiting the advantage of the wealthy, e.g., a
policy of a high inheritance tax.

2
3
4
5

6

7

Heathcote, Perri and Violante document the rising
level of income inequality in the U.S., while Saez
and Zucman document the trend in inequality and
wealth inequality in the U.S. from 1913 to 2013.
Both papers show that inequality has increased
significantly in both income and wealth since the
late 1970s.
See Gayle, Golan and Soytas for details.
See Charles and Hurst, as well as Pfeffer and
Killewald, for details.
This is the main conclusion of Gayle, Golan and
Soytas.
This is one of the main tenets of Thomas Piketty’s
2014 best-selling book, Capital in the Twenty-First
Century.
These results are available upon request from the
authors. The Panel Study of Income Dynamics data
are collected at the University of Michigan.
Residual wealth is computed as the residual of a
regression of wealth on permanent income and
education.

REFERENCES
Charles, Kerwin Kofi; and Hurst, Erik. “The Correlation of Wealth across Generations.” Journal
of Political Economy, 2003, Vol. 111, No. 6,
pp. 1,155-82.
Gayle, George-Levi; Golan, Limor; and Soytas,
Mehmet A. “What Is the Source of the Intergenerational Correlation in Earnings?” Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis, Working Paper 2015-019A.
Heathcote, Jonathan; Perri, Fabrizio; and Violante,
Giovanni L. “Unequal We Stand: An Empirical
Analysis of Economic Inequality in the United
States, 1967–2006.” Review of Economic Dynamics,
January 2010, Vol. 13, No. 1, pp. 15-51.
Pfeffer, Fabian T.; and Killewald, Alexandra. “How
Rigid Is the Wealth Structure and Why? Inter- and
Multi-generational Associations in Family Wealth.”
September 2015, Report 15-845, Population Studies
Center at the University of Michigan.
Piketty, Thomas. Capital in the Twenty-First Century.
Cambridge, Mass., Belknap Press, 2014.
Saez, Emmanuel; and Zucman, Gabriel. “Wealth
Inequality in the United States since 1913: Evidence
from Capitalized Income Tax Data.” The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, May 2016, Vol. 131, No. 2,
pp. 519-78.

George-Levi Gayle is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Andrés Hincapié
was a technical research associate at the Bank.
For more on Gayle’s work, see https://research.
stlouisfed.org/econ/gayle.
FIGURE BELOW
SOURCE: The Panel Study of Income Dynamics 1968 to 2013.
NOTE: Each panel shows the population in the study broken
down into five quintiles, with each quintile having roughly
the same number of people. The 1st quintile represents
those at the bottom of the income/wealth ladder, and the
5th quintile represents those at the top. How should these
figures be interpreted? Follow this example: In the Permanent Income panel, those born into the 1st quintile have a
39 percent chance of ending up there themselves. In the
Residual Wealth panel, residual wealth is defined as wealth
net the effect of permanent income and education. (In the
middle panel, wealth is just assets minus liabilities.)

Earnings and Wealth from One Generation to the Next
OFFSPRING QUINTILE:

1st

2nd

3rd

4th

W E A LT H

PERMANENT INCOME

R E S I D U A L W E A LT H

1

1

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4
0.2

0.2
0

Probability

1

Probability

Probability

5th

0
1st

2nd
3rd
4th
Parental Quintile

5th

0.4
0.2

1st

2nd
3rd
4th
Parental Quintile

5th

0

1st

2nd
3rd
4th
Parental Quintile

5th

The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 15

D I S T R I C T

O V E R V I E W

District Households Buck
the Trend To Pay Down Debt

The Eighth Federal Reserve District
is composed of four zones, each of
which is centered around one of
the four main cities: Little Rock,
Louisville, Memphis and St. Louis.

By Helu Jiang and Juan M. Sánchez

A

t the national level, households have
decreased their debt substantially since
the financial crisis of 2008. In contrast, in
the Eighth District, the average household
has kept debt constant. This article breaks
down the total debt into five different types
to uncover the differences between what’s
happening at the national level vs. the District level. The main finding is that a large
share of the discrepancy can be accounted
for by the evolution of mortgage and home

equity debt; those differences, in turn, seem
related to the differences in the evolution of
house prices.
The data are from the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York Consumer Credit Panel/
Equifax. The first panel of Figure 1 shows
the average debt for the national sample and
the District sample. The average household
debt in the District has been lower than the
national level for the entire period shown,
2004-2015. During this time, the average

household debt was $79,797 in the nation
and $53,111 in the District.
More interesting are the differences in the
evolution of average household debt during
this period. The average household debt in
the nation was $64,055 in the first quarter of
2004; it rose by 41 percent to $90,215 in the
fourth quarter of 2008; it then declined by
14 percent to $77,698 in the fourth quarter of
2015. In contrast, in the District, the average
household debt increased by only 28 percent,

FIGURE 1
Average Household Debt by Type

7,000

4,000

6,000

AUTO LOANS

70,000

6,500

60,000

6,000

50,000

5,500

2015

2014

2013

2004

2015

2014

2013

2004

2015

2014

2013

2012

2011

2010

2009

2008

2007

2006

2005

STUDENT LOANS

7,000
6,000

Dollars

5,000

40,000

Dollars

2004

MORTGAGES

2012

2,000
2011

2,000
2010

32,000

2009

3,000

2008

2,500
2007

42,000

2006

4,000

2005

3,000

52,000

2012

5,000

2011

3,500

Eighth District

2010

62,000

4,500

2009

72,000

Dollars

Dollars

82,000

National

Eighth District

2008

National

2007

92,000

8,000

5,000

Eighth District

2006

National

Dollars

102,000

Dollars

HOME EQUITY DEBT

CREDIT CARD DEBT

2005

TOTAL DEBT

5,000

4,000
3,000
2,000

SOURCES: Federal Reserve Bank of New York Consumer Credit Panel/Equifax.
16 The Regional Economist | July 2016

2015

2014

2013

2011

2010

Eighth District
2009

2008

2006

2005

2004

2015

2014

2013

2012

2011

2010

National

0

2012

1,000

Eighth District
2009

2008

2007

4,000

2006

2015

2014

2013

2012

2011

2010

2009

2008

2007

2006

2005

2004

20,000

National
2005

Eighth District

2004

National

2007

4,500

30,000

ENDNOTES

FIGURE 2
Average Median Home Values by ZIP Codes

1 Auto debt is defined as the sum of auto finance

300,000
261,000

245,000

Dollars

250,000
200,000

202,000

150,000

125,000

127,000

100,000

115,000
National

Eighth District

50,000
2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

SOURCE: Zillow Group, Home Value Index (ZHVI) All Homes Time Series.

from $44,331 to $56,744, in the period 20042008; it then decreased only slightly, by 2.3
percent, in the period 2009-2015, reaching
$55,428 in the fourth quarter of 2015.
Another way of looking at the difference
is to focus on the gap in average household
debt between the nation and the District. In
the period 2004-2015, that gap was, on average, $26,685. That gap widened in the period
2004-2008, increasing by almost 70 percent,
from $19,724 to $33,471. In the period 20092012, the gap shrank, decreasing by 33 percent, reflecting a sharper deleveraging in the
nation than in the District. In the past couple
of years, the gap fluctuated around $22,500.
Though mortgages account for 73 percent
and 66 percent of total household debt in the
nation and the District, on average, we look at
other types of debt because we want to understand not only the different levels of average
debt but also the different evolution patterns
of debt between the nation and the District.
Total debt is broken down into credit card
debt, mortgages, auto loans,1 student loans
and home equity debt.2 The remaining five
panels in Figure 1 compare the average debt
for households in the nation and in the District for different types of debt:
• Credit cards: For the period 2004-2015, the
average for the national sample was $3,826
and for the District was $3,159.
• Mortgages: For the nation, it was $58,897
and for the District was $35,066.
• Auto loans: For the nation, it was $5,162
and for the District was $5,111.
• Student loans: For the nation, it was $3,731
and for the District was $3,343.
• Home equity debt: For the nation, it was
$5,851 and for the District was $3,393.

Thus, for all five types of debt, the average debt in the District was lower than the
national average for the 2004-2015 period.
Interestingly, the evolution of credit
card debt, auto loans and student loans
was very similar in the District and in the
nation. Notice that this is true, although the
evolution for each variable was very different: Credit card debt decreased after the
financial crisis and has not recovered; auto
loans declined very sharply after the crisis
but recovered very quickly and, at the end of
the period, were above previous levels; and,
finally, student loans increased continually
since 2004.
Thus, the difference in the evolution of
total debt must be a consequence of mortgages and home equity loans. In particular, in
the period 2004-2015, mortgages accounted
for almost 90 percent of the total difference
in the behavior of the nation and the District,
while the other four types were much less
significant: credit card, 2.52 percent; auto,
0.13 percent; student loan, 1.55 percent; and
home equity, 9.14 percent.3
Now, why is the behavior of mortgages
and home equity debt different in the District than in the nation? The gap could be
explained by the differences in the level and
evolution of house prices. Using the average
median home values by ZIP code,4 we constructed the house prices for the nation and
the District. (See Figure 2.) Prices on houses
in the District are about half of the national
average (exactly 55 percent on average during
2004-2015), and the District prices fluctuated
much less than the national prices did. The
national home values increased by 29 percent
in 2004-2006, decreased by 23 percent in

debt and auto bank debt, both of which are
reported in the original Equifax data set.
2 Home equity debt is defined as the sum of home
equity installment debt and home equity
revolving debt.
3 The shares of the five types of debt do not add up
to 100 because there is a remaining “other” type
of debt not discussed in this analysis, including
consumer finance, retail and other debt reported
in the Equifax data set, which accounts for –2.76
percent of the difference in total debt between
the nation and the District. Notice that it can be
negative because it is the share of a difference.
The difference between the nation and the
District for total debt is positive (more debt in
the nation), but for “other” type of debt is negative (more debt in our District); so, the ratio of
the two differences, which represents the share
accounted by “other” type of debt, is negative.
4 The Zillow Home Value Index (ZHVI) All Homes
Time Series data are available at www.zillow.
com/research/data.

The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 17

E C O N O M Y

A

G L A N C E

REAL GDP GROWTH

CONSUMER PRICE INDEX (CPI)

6
PERCENT CHANGE FROM A YEAR EARLIER

4

PERCENT

4

2

0

–2

’11

’12

’13

’14

’15

’16

I N F L AT I O N - I N D E X E D T R E A S U RY Y I E L D S P R E A D S

3.00

10-Year

2.50

PERCENT

2.00
1.75

May

’11

’12

’13

’14

’15

’16

01/27/16

4/27/16

03/16/16

6/15/16

7/7/16

0.5

0.4
July 1, ’16

1.00

’12

’13

’14

’15

0.3

’16

1st-Expiring
Contract

NOTE: Weekly data.

C I V I L I A N U N E M P L O Y M E N T R AT E

3-Month

10-Year Treasury

3

8
PERCENT

PERCENT

7
6
5

2
Fed Funds Target

1
1-Year Treasury

4
3

12-Month

4

9

differences in the level and

6-Month

CONTRACT SETTLEMENT MONTH

I N T E R E S T R AT E S

10

could be explained by the

18 The Regional Economist | July 2016

–2

1.25

debt different in the District

Juan M. Sánchez is an economist and Helu
Jiang is a technical research associate, both
at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. For
more on Sánchez’s work, see https://research.
stlouisfed.org/econ/sanchez.

0

0.6

20-Year

2.25

mortgages and home equity

June

’11

’12

’13

’14

’15

0

’16

’11

’12

’13

’14

’15

June

’16

NOTE: On Dec. 16, 2015, the FOMC set a target range for the
federal funds rate of 0.25 to 0.5 percent. The observations
plotted since then are the midpoint of the range (0.375 percent).

U.S. AGRICULTURAL TRADE
90

AVERAGE LAND VALUES ACROSS THE EIGHTH DISTRICT

6

Imports

60
45
30
15

Trade Balance

0
’11

’12

’13

’14

’15

NOTE: Data are aggregated over the past 12 months.

May

’16

YEAR-OVER-YEAR PERCENT CHANGE

Exports

75
BILLIONS OF DOLLARS

mortgages is smaller, and (2) home equity
(the difference between the value of the house
and the remaining mortgage obligations)
declines sharply, implying a reduction in the
availability of home equity to borrow against
with home equity loans and refinancing for
home equity extraction. Thus, as the decline
in house prices was larger in the nation than
in the District, the deleveraging was larger in
the nation than in the District.
Of course, this evidence is suggestive, and
more research is needed to understand, for
instance, why the timing of fluctuations in
house prices seems to lead the fluctuations in
mortgage debt and home equity loans.

2

0.7

1.50

evolution of house prices.

All Items, Less Food and Energy

RATES ON FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES ON SELECTED DATES

5-Year

2.75

Now, why is the behavior of

than in the nation? The gap

CPI–All Items

NOTE: Each bar is a one-quarter growth rate (annualized);
the red line is the 10-year growth rate.

PERCENT

2007-2011 and then recovered to almost their
precrisis level. In contrast, in the District,
home values increased by only 13 percent in
2004-2006, decreased by 9.4 percent in 20072011 and later rose by 9.7 percent.
Thus, the difference in the level of prices,
which were lower in the District than in the
nation, seems to account for the differences
in the level of household debt in the District
and the nation. This is due to the fact that
households usually borrow (using both mortgages and home equity loans) up to a share of
their houses’ value. The difference in the fluctuations in house prices, which were less volatile in the District than in the nation, could
account for the difference in the evolution
of household debt between the District and
the nation. This may be the case because as
prices decline (1) the value of home purchases
is smaller and, consequently, the size of those

A T

4
2
0
–2
–4
–6
–8

Quality Farmland
Ranchland or Pastureland

2015:Q1 2015:Q2 2015:Q3 2015:Q4 2016:Q1
SOURCE: Agricultural Finance Monitor.

On the web version of this issue, 11 more charts are available, with much of those charts’ data specific to the Eighth District.
Among the areas they cover are agriculture, commercial banking, housing permits, income and jobs. To see those charts, go to
www.stlouisfed.org/economyataglance.

O V E R V I E W

Despite Weakness,
Economic Expansion
Marks Seven Years
By Kevin L. Kliesen

T

he U.S. economic expansion is into
its eighth year, having registered its
seven-year anniversary in June 2016. From a
historical perspective, the current expansion
is long in the tooth. However, expansions do
not typically die of old age. Instead, they end
because of some unforeseen disturbance that
causes firms and individuals to alter their
planned expenditures and expectations of
future incomes.
Although the current expansion keeps
plugging along, the U.S. economy’s pace
of growth during the past seven years has
been extraordinarily weak. Since the second
quarter of 2009 (when the Great Recession
officially ended), real growth in gross domestic product (GDP) has averaged 2.1 percent
per year. By contrast, growth in the previous
three expansions (1982-90, 1991-2001 and
2001-2007) averaged 4.2 percent, 3.6 percent
and 2.7 percent, respectively.
Despite the current expansion’s low growth
rate, the unemployment rate declined from
10 percent to 4.9 percent—a level consistent
with full employment—and inflation has
stayed quite low. The all-items personal consumption expenditures price index (PCEPI)
has increased by an average annual rate of
1.5 percent, which is below the 2-percent
inflation target of the Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC).
There are two obvious questions that follow
from this narrative. First, what explains the
weak real GDP growth during the current
expansion? Second, why has inflation
remained so low in the face of an extraordinarily easy monetary policy?
Tackling the answer to the first question is reasonably straightforward. Real
GDP growth is basically the sum of labor
productivity growth and the growth rate of
employment. Since mid-2009, productivity
has increased at an average annual rate of 1.0
percent. Over the three previous expansions,
it increased by an average of 1.9 percent per
year, 2.1 percent and 1.6 percent, respectively.
Thus, the current expansion’s weak performance importantly reflects a significant

Real GDP Growth during Business Expansions
Percent Changes Compounded at Annual Rates

N A T I O N A L

5.0
4.0

Real GDP

4.2

Labor Productivity

2.7

3.0
2.2
2.0

2.1

2.1

1.9

1.6

1.5

1.0
0.0

Labor Input

3.6

1982–90

1991–2001

1.1

1.1

2001–07

2009–16

1.0

SOURCE: Author’s calculations based on data from the Bureau of Economic Analysis and the Bureau of Labor Statistics.
NOTE: The sum of labor input and labor productivity may not exactly equal real GDP due to rounding.

slowing in the pace of labor productivity
growth. But what explains weak productivity growth? There are many hypotheses,
including increased government regulations,
less economic dynamism and the replacement of retiring, experienced baby boomers with younger, inexperienced workers.
The consensus of most forecasters is that
productivity growth will eventually rebound
and begin rising by about 1.5 percent per
year. As yet, there is scant evidence of such
an acceleration.
Turning to the second question, low inflation over this period coincided with three
rounds of quantitative easing (large-scale
asset purchases by the Federal Reserve) and
repeated assurances by the FOMC that it
would keep the proverbial monetary policy
pedal to the metal. Despite the onslaught of
a massively easy monetary policy regime,
inflation rarely moved above 2 percent. Low
inflation, it appears, importantly reflects the
FOMC’s promise to defend its 2-percent inflation target, which has helped keep inflation
expectations low.
But since the second quarter of 2014,
inflation has declined sharply, averaging 0.4
percent at an average annual rate. Falling
inflation reflects two key developments. The
first was the plunge in crude oil prices. The
second was the sharp appreciation of the value
of the U.S. dollar, which triggered declines in
prices of imported goods. However, measures
of the underlying inflation rate that attempt to
remove these temporary factors, such as the
Dallas Fed’s trimmed-mean PCEPI inflation
rate, show inflation to be much closer to the
FOMC’s target. As the effects of falling oil

prices and a stronger dollar wear off, headline
inflation should return to 2 percent.
Monetary policymakers now confront a
bevy of mixed signals as they decide how to
proceed with their goal of slowly raising the
federal funds target rate to its “normal” level.
First, crude oil prices have rebounded, and
the dollar has retreated modestly from its
highs. Both of these developments should put
upward pressure on inflation. Second, real
GDP growth remained weak in the first quarter, and inflation expectations have edged a bit
lower despite the rise in oil prices. Third, real
GDP growth was expected to have accelerated
in the second quarter, but there are few signs
of a pending acceleration in labor productivity growth that could push GDP growth
appreciably higher than 2 to 2.5 percent.
Fourth, inflation is expected to remain close
to 2 percent this year and next, but there are
some risks it could move higher. Finally, the
unemployment rate is projected to drop a bit
further from its 4.9 percent rate in June 2016.
Formulating monetary policy in the current environment appears challenging, given
that the economy appears to have settled
down to its long-run growth path of roughly
2 percent, with 2-percent inflation the most
likely outcome. Of course, if the economy and
inflation begin to perk up or asset prices begin
rising at worrying rates, then policymakers
will need to adjust policy accordingly.
Kevin L. Kliesen is an economist at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Joseph T.
McGillicuddy, a senior research associate at the
Bank, provided research assistance. See http://
research.stlouisfed.org/econ/kliesen for more on
Kliesen’s work.
The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 19

M E T R O

P R O F I L E

Health Care,
Hospitality and
Retirees Keep
Hot Springs Afloat
By Charles Gascon and Faisal Sohail
The water from the hot springs is one of the reasons why 1.5 million people visit Hot Springs National Park every year.
© QUAPAW BATHS & SPA

Located in central Arkansas, the Hot Springs metropolitan statistical area (MSA) is named
after the numerous natural hot springs that can be found in the region, including those at
Hot Springs National Park. The springs and surrounding area attract millions of visitors to
the MSA every year. Indeed, tourists played an integral role in the area’s early development
and continue to shape the region’s economy and demographics today.

T

he MSA is comprised of a single
county—Garland—and in 2015 had a
population of 97,177. It is one of the smaller
MSAs in the nation and accounts for only 3
percent of the Arkansas population. Population growth in the previous five years was
1.2 percent, a little more than half of the
state’s growth of 2.1 percent.
The regional economy produces about
$3 billion in goods and services each year,
as measured by gross metropolitan product
(GMP). Economic growth has averaged 3.9
percent per year over the past five years.
This is faster than the state’s average growth
rate of 1.8 percent and the national rate of
2.1 percent for that period.
The median household income in Hot
Springs is about $40,000, which is $1,000
less than the state median income. These
figures mask the greater inequality in Hot
Springs compared with that of the state
overall. The share of households in Hot
Springs earning less than $15,000 a year is
18.4 percent, compared with 16.6 percent for
the state. On the opposite side of the coin,
3.5 percent of Hot Springs’ households earn
about $200,000, compared with the state’s
2.9 percent. This level of inequality in Hot
20 The Regional Economist | July 2016

Springs is likely due to its industrial and
demographic composition.
Health Care and Hospitality

Of the 40,000 workers employed in Hot
Springs in 2014, about 60 percent were
employed in one of three sectors: health
services (21 percent); trade, transportation
and utilities (20 percent); and leisure and
hospitality (18 percent). While the employment share of the trade, transportation and
utilities sector is reflective of the nation’s,
the employment share of health services and
of leisure and hospitality is, respectively,
1.4 and 1.7 times larger in Hot Springs than
in the nation overall. In 2014, the average
annual income in leisure and hospitality
was about $15,000. In health services, it was
$40,000. This difference in income, combined with the large employment share in
each sector, can partially explain the higher
level of income inequality in Hot Springs.
The disproportionate size of the leisure
and hospitality sector, relative to the rest
of the country, should not be surprising,
considering more than 2 million people
annually visit a region of fewer than 100,000
residents. These visitors spent close to a

quarter of the region’s GMP in 2014 and
accounted for the bulk of tax revenue for the
region. Almost 1.5 million of these tourists visit the national park. The other major
attraction in the region is Oaklawn, a horse
race track and casino and the second largest
employer in the region.
The abundance of leisure activities is not
only ideal for tourists, but it makes Hot
Springs an attractive location for retirees.
About 22 percent of the region’s population
is over 65, well above the national average of
about 15 percent. (See Figure 1.) While the
U.S. is experiencing a general demographic
shift toward an older population, Hot
Springs has consistently featured a higher
share of older residents.
This demographic makeup also explains
the importance of the health services sector
in the MSA, as older people generally need
more of these services.
Typically, an older population is accompanied by lower tax revenue and lower population growth. Given that most of the area’s
tax revenue comes from visitors, the former
likely is not a concern for Hot Springs. However, the lower rate of population growth
already seems to be occurring in the data.

FIGURE 1
Percent of Population Over 65
24
Hot Springs, Ark.

Arkansas

Florida

U.S.

22

Percent

20
18
16
14
© VISIT HOT SPRINGS

12
10
1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

Horse racing is one of the draws at Oaklawn, the
second-largest employer in the metro area. Oaklawn
also has a casino.
Schuyler Scotland

SOURCE: U.S. Census Bureau.
NOTE: State-level population data were not available for 2015. Florida was included because of its reputation as a state to which many people retire.

Clar
Rutledge

MSA Snapshot

Kirksville
Adair
Knox

Hot Springs, Ark.

Lew

35
Population................................................................................................
97,177
Atlanta

FIGURE 2

Macon
1.2%
Population Growth (2010-2015).............................................

Nonfarm Payroll Employment

Percentage with Bachelor’s Degree or Higher............... 21%

105.0
Arkansas

29

U.S.

Monroe

Randolph
Per Capita Personal Income..................................................$23,514

102.5

Ha

Monroe City

Percentage with a HS Degree or Higher......................... 86.9%
Hot Springs, Ark.

Mar

Shelby

Median Household Income.....................................................$39,558

Audrain

RIVER

Index 2007:Q3=100

URI
MISSO.............................................................4.1%
Unemployment
Hallsville
KansasRate
City(May)

Boone

Real GMP (2014)................................................................. $3.132 billion

100.0

Columbia Callaway
GMP Growth Rate (2014).............................................................. 1.55%
RI

97.5
Largest Employers

95.0

U
SO
MIS

ER

RIV

Jefferso

Moniteau

Osage

Cole

CHI St. Vincent—Hot Springs.......................................................1,700
Oaklawn.........................................................................................................1,368
Miller
Osage Beach
Camden
653
National Park Medical Center.........................................................

R

E

AD

N
CO
City of Hot Springs....................................................................................
S591
GA

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).
NOTE: Data for 2016 are the average of the available monthly data in that year. Gray bar indicates recession.

5%
Lawrence

Private Employment before, during and after the Great Recession
Sector
Construction
Manufacturing

Employment in 2007

% Change,
2007 to 2010

% Change,
2007 to 2014

2,414

–33.5

–37.6

2,715

–30.2

–11.7

–756
–299

Professional and
business services

3,371

–5.6

–8.4

–271

Trade, transportation,
and utilities

7,471

–3.1

–3.1

–227

Financial activities

1,533

–10.9

–7.1

–105

Natural resources
and mining

370

–13.3

–24.4

–80

Other services

969

–0.6

–2.3

–22

Information

419

–23.0

20.6

96

6,383

–1.7

2.3

146

Education and health
services

7,121

3.9

6.0

442

Total, all industries

32,765

SOURCE: Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages, Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

–3.3

–1,075

Douglas
Education
and health
services

Barry

Manufacturing

Branson
8% Cassville Stone
Taney
20%
Professional and
12%
Eureka Springs
business services
Bentonville
18%
Carroll
Boone
Benton

Government

Crawford Franklin

Howell

Bakersfiel

Trade,
transportation
Baxter
and utilities
Marion

Fulton

Horseshoe Bend

Conway

Logan
Booneville

Faulkner

Searcy

W

Perryville

Yell

R

VE
FAYE RI

CHE LA

FOUR

Izard

Mountain V
Stone
Inde

Clinton
Van Buren
Cleburne

Johnson
Clarksville
Pope

Fort Smith

Perry

Pulaski Lonoke

Little R

Saline

Montgomery Garland

Polk

Em
Mountain View

Ozark

Jasper
Newton
Searcy

ARKANSAS

Scott

Texas

Leisure and
hospitality

Fayetteville
Washington
Madison

Sebastian

Licking

Hot Springs
Wickes

Sevier

Foreman
Little River

Hot Spring

Pike

Grant

Jefferson

Murfreesboro

Clark

30

Hempstead Nevada
Camden

KA
N

Dallas Rison
Cleveland

Calhoun

The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 21 Bradley
Texarkana
Ouachita
Miller

Magnolia
Columbia

Pine Bl
AR

Arkadelphia
ER
A RIV
CHIT
OUA

Leisure and hospitality

–6.0

Christian

7%

Change in Employment
2007-2014

and mining 1%

21%

Ro

Pulaski

Lebanon

Construction

E
RIV

Phelps

Bolivar Dallas
Laclede
Polk
Industry Breakdown by Employment
Dade
Greene
Other services 3%
Information 1%
Webster
Springfield
Financial activities
Natural resources
Wright
4%

Lafayette

2006

Howard

90.0
2005

Maries

Wal-Mart Stores (3 stores).............................................................1,026

92.5

SA
S

Lincol

Mo

Drew

Fountain Hill

El Dorado
Union

Ashle

After the Great Recession

© VISIT HOT SPRINGS

Tourism is one of the main drivers of the economy in the Hot Springs metro area. The leisure and hospitality sector employs
almost one in five workers. There is some concern, however, that the vitality of this industry might suffer in the future as
Americans’ intentions to go on vacation are declining, as are the number of people who say they will drive to a vacation
destination. Hot Springs has no airport. For now, 2 million people visit the area annually, about a third driving from one of five
neighboring states. One of the attractions is the Magic Springs and Crystal Falls Water and Theme Park (above).
FIGURE 3
Vacation Intentions of Americans
65
60
55
Percent of Respondents

Although the Great Recession (2007-2009)
ended seven years ago, the Hot Springs MSA
has still not fully recovered from its impact
on local employment. Figure 2 shows the
evolution of the nonfarm payroll employment
for the U.S., Arkansas and the Hot Springs
MSA. The decline in Hot Springs’ employment during the recession was much more
protracted than the state or national decline,
and the MSA’s recovery started a year after the
Arkansas recovery began. What is perhaps
most striking is that employment has not
yet returned to its prerecession levels in Hot
Springs despite state and national recoveries.
It is instructive to consider which sectors
might be holding back a full recovery in Hot
Springs. The table shows the changes and
levels in employment before, during and after
the most recent recession and features two
salient findings. First, the scant recovery that
did take place in Hot Springs was led by the
leisure and hospitality sector and by health
services,1 reinforcing the importance of these
two sectors for the area. Second, the lack of
a full recovery is largely due to a sluggish
recovery in the construction sector.
While the recession disproportionally
impacted the construction sector throughout
the U.S., the housing market has generally
been on the rebound and the construction
sector is adding jobs. A recovery in construction is not yet apparent in Hot Springs, as the
sector has struggled to create jobs with new
projects in the region. Several business contacts noted that the area’s geography is not
particularly well-suited to large construction
projects, and this factor may play a role in the
lack of a rebound in that sector.

50
45
40
35
30
25
20
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

Vacation intended within six months

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

Vacation by automobile intended within six months

SOURCES: Conference Board, Haver Analytics.
NOTES: The solid lines show 12-month moving averages of underlying data (dotted lines). Gray bars indicate recessions. The intentions refer to plans to vacation
in the U.S.

Outlook

A consequence of a large leisure and
hospitality sector is that the short- and
long-term economic outlook of the MSA is
highly dependent on the number of visitors
to the area. The lack of a major airport in the
area means that many visitors drive to Hot
Springs for their vacations and most are from
neighboring states.2 Contacts in the area
report that the economic growth in Texas
is being felt in Hot Springs through a high
volume of visitors from the state. While Hot
Springs may regularly benefit from the shortterm booms of neighboring economies, it is
also exposed to their busts.
22 The Regional Economist | July 2016

Hospitality-driven areas should be wary of
households’ intentions to take a vacation and,
perhaps more importantly for Hot Springs,
their intention to drive for a vacation. Figure
3 shows these intentions, and it highlights
a long-term decline in the percentage of
households reporting that they intend to take
a vacation within the U.S. This decline is
mirrored in households’ intentions to drive
for a vacation. While Hot Springs has enjoyed
steady increases in the annual number of
visitors in the recent past, these changes in
household sentiment may pose a longer-term
risk for the MSA.

Charles S. Gascon is a regional economist and
Faisal Sohail is a technical research associate,
both at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
For more on Gascon’s work, see http://research.
stlouisfed.org/econ/gascon.

ENDNOTES
1

2

Only 1 percent of total employment in the education
and health services sector in the MSA is actually in
education.
The chamber of commerce reported that in 2013
just over 30 percent of all visitors were from
one of five states: Illinois, Louisiana, Missouri,
Oklahoma and Texas. Twenty percent of visitors
were from Arkansas.

AR SE KA D
A N
S TG E
E R E CE OX NC OHMA I N
ASK AN ECONOMIST

NEW PUBLICATION FOCUSES ON CONSUMER DEBT
Alexander Monge-Naranjo has been an
economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis since 2012. His research focuses
on cross-country income differences and
human capital. Outside of work, he enjoys
spending time with his family, traveling
and reading. For more on his research,
see https://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/
monge-naranjo.
Alexander Monge-Naranjo with his family
in Kamakura, Japan, earlier this year.

The Center for Household Financial Stability at the Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis has begun a new publication, The Quarterly Debt Monitor: Trends
in Consumer Debt in St. Louis, Little Rock, Louisville, Memphis—and Beyond.
Each issue will provide details on auto and student loans, credit card balances,
mortgages and home equity lines of credit. Data and analysis are provided for the
nation as a whole, as well as for the four largest metropolitan areas in the Eighth
Federal Reserve District, which is served by the St. Louis Fed.
The inaugural issue includes data through the first quarter of this year. That
quarter was the 10th in a row in which consumer debt has risen, the authors
found. The trend is a reversal from what had been occurring since the Great
Recession—an era when many consumers had either paid down their debts or
even paid them off.

Q. Recent college graduates have a higher chance
of unemployment than their more experienced
counterparts. How could student loans be
designed to mitigate this risk?
A: Unemployment is an important risk for recent college gradu-

The recent increases in debt, fueled in part by the rapid growth of auto and
student loans, “represent more economic activity as consumers take on new
liabilities to finance consumption,” the report says.
The full report can be found on the center’s website at www.stlouisfed.org/hfs.
FORUMS AIM TO STRENGTHEN DELTA COMMUNITIES

ates, who typically have little labor market experience, especially
related to their field of specialization. Although unemployment
insurance exists, workers need to be experienced to qualify.
Furthermore, student loan programs do not account for the fact
that finding a good-paying job may take a while; repayment is
expected to start soon after graduation, although some loans do
provide a grace period. Hence, these two programs do not offer
much help to fresh college graduates who don’t find a job right
away. My recent research looks at ways to mitigate the burden
for those who are in this situation.
In an article in the latest Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis’
Review, I showed how the design of student loans could mitigate
the unemployment risk for recent graduates.1 I found that unem-

Corey Wiggins, director of the Hope Policy Institute, speaks at the Delta Communities meeting
June 10 in Helena, Ark.

ployment compensation would be a key element of the optimal

The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis recently began the Delta Communities

student loan program, whereby the student would receive

initiative to build awareness of tools and strategies to help strengthen commu-

financing not only for the time in college but also for the time

nities across the Arkansas and Mississippi Delta region. This series of regional

until the student finds a job. An important feature of the optimal

forums features presentations by St. Louis Fed staff, as well as by other regional

program is that the unemployment benefits received and the debt
balance would depend on the length of the unemployment spell.
In particular, to keep the recent graduate motivated to seek a job,
the unemployment benefits should decline as the person remains
unemployed, and also the amount of debt the person should
pay must be increasing with the length of the unemployment. If
well-designed, such a scheme would provide the optimal balance
between insurance against the risk of unemployment and providing
the right incentives to look for a job. Such schemes can be made
revenue-neutral (on average), so taxpayers would not need to
finance any deficits from the programs.

and national representatives with experience in community and economic development efforts.
Forums began in June and are scheduled through the beginning of next year.
The next set of meetings is titled Understanding the Credit Environment for
Small-Business Development and Expansion and will take place Aug. 11 in
Greenwood, Miss., and Aug. 12 in Helena, Ark.
For more information on this and other St. Louis Fed Community Development
initiatives, go to www.stlouisfed.org/community-development.
ST. LOUIS FED IS NAMED A TOP WORKPLACE
The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis was recently ranked as the No. 1 workplace
among St. Louis’ large employers in a competition sponsored by the St. Louis
Post-Dispatch newspaper. The rankings were based on surveys of employees.

1

Monge-Naranjo, Alexander. “Student Loans Under the Risk of Youth Unemployment.”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis’ Review, Second Quarter 2016, Vol. 98, No. 2,
pp. 129-58. See https://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/2016/06/17/
student-loans-under-the-risk-of-youth-unemployment/.

St. Louis Fed employees listed meaningful work, good opportunities and inclusiveness among their reasons for liking where they work. The Bank was honored
in the category for employers with at least 500 employees. For details, see
www.stlouisfed.org/careers/about-us/top-workplaces-award.
The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 23

Change Service Requested

ECONOMIC RESEARCH

REGISTER

Search FRED

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

N E X T

I S S U E

FRED® Economic Data Information Services Publications Working Papers

EDIT LINE 1

ADD LINE

FORMAT

EDIT LINE 1
St. Louis

Economists About

Home > Categories > Prices > Consumer Price Indexes (CPI and PCE)

Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers: All Items (CPIAUCSL)

(a) Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers:
All Items, Index 1982-1984=100, Seasonally Adjusted
(CPIAUCSL)

DOW
Units:

Home Economics in the 21st Century

Observation:

Units:

Updated: May 17, 2016

Seasonally Adjusted

Apr 2016: 1.1 (+more)

Percent Change from Year Ago,

Frequency:

1Y | 5Y | 10Y | Max

Monthly

1948-01-01

to

EDIT

2016-04-01

Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers: All Items

Read about the economic impact
of these changes in family structure in the October issue of
The Regional Economist.

Modify frequency:

15.0

i

Monthly

12.5
Percent Change from Year Ago

As the level of education for
women rises, their role in providing economic support for
their families is changing. More
women are working outside the
home and are working full-time.
Simultaneously, more men are
working part-time or even not
working outside the home at all.

i

Percent Change from Year Ago

Customize ideas:

10.0

i

Write a custom formula to transform one or more series or combine two or
more series.

7.5

You can begin by adding a series to combine with your existing series.

5.0
Type keywords to search for data

Add

2.5
Now create a custom formula to combine or transform the series.

Need help? [+]

0.0

Formula:

-2.5
-5.0

a

Apply

Finally, you can change the units of your new series.

1950

1955
1950

1960

1965
1960

Shaded areas indicate US recessions

1970
1970

1975

1980

1985

1980

1990
1990

Source: US. Bureau of Labor Statistics

1995

2000
2000

2005

2010

2015

Units:

2010

fred.stlouisfed.org

NOTES
Source: US. Bureau of Labor Statistics | more from this source
Release: Consumer Price Index | more from this release
The Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers: All Items (CPIAUCSL) is a measure of the
average monthly change in the price for goods and services paid by urban consumers between any
two time periods. (1) It can also represent the buying habits of urban consumers. This particular index
includes roughly 88 percent of the total population, accounting for wage earners, clerical workers,
technical workers, self-employed, short-term workers, unemployed, retirees, and those not in the labor

The CPI can be used to recognize periods of inflation and deflation. Significant increases in
within a short time frame might indicate a period of inflation, and significant decreases in CF
short time frame might indicate a period of deflation. However, because the CPI includes vo
and oil prices, it might not be a reliable measure of inflationary and deflationary periods. For

FRED Has More Curb Appeal and a New Address
Renovations to FRED, our signature economic database, have made it easier to
keep your eye on your graph. The graph is bigger, for one thing, and the editing box
is next to it on the right, meaning you no longer have to scroll below the graph to
change units of measurement, data frequency and the like, or to customize the chart
with additional series.
Check out the upgrades and tutorials at the new address for FRED (Federal
Reserve Economic Data): fred.stlouisfed.org. Don’t worry about getting lost—all
traffic from the old address will be redirected.

ECONOMY

AT

A

THE REGIONAL

GLANCE

ECONOMIST

JULY 2016

REAL GDP GROWTH

CONSUMER PRICE INDEX
4
PERCENT CHANGE FROM A YEAR EARLIER

6

PERCENT

4

2

0

–2

VOL. 24, NO. 3

|

’11

’12

’13

’14

’15

CPI–All Items
All Items, Less Food and Energy

2

0

May

–2

’12

’11

’16

’13

’14

’15

’16

NOTE: Each bar is a one-quarter growth rate (annualized);
the red line is the 10-year growth rate.

I N F L AT I O N - I N D E X E D T R E A S U RY Y I E L D S P R E A D S
3.00

0.7

5-Year

2.75

10-Year

2.50

0.6

20-Year
PERCENT

2.25
PERCENT

RATES ON FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES ON SELECTED DATES

2.00
1.75
1.50

01/27/16

4/27/16

03/16/16

6/15/16

7/7/16

0.5

0.4

1.25
July 1, ’16

1.00

’12

’13

’14

’15

0.3

’16

1st-Expiring
Contract

NOTE: Weekly data.

C I V I L I A N U N E M P L O Y M E N T R AT E

3-Month

4

9

10-Year Treasury

3

8
7

PERCENT

PERCENT

12-Month

I N T E R E S T R AT E S

10

6
5

2
Fed Funds Target

1
1-Year Treasury

4
3

6-Month

CONTRACT SETTLEMENT MONTH

June

’11

’12

’13

’14

’15

0

’16

’11

’12

’13

’14

’15

June

’16

NOTE: On Dec. 16, 2015, the FOMC set a target range for the
federal funds rate of 0.25 to 0.5 percent. The observations
plotted since then are the midpoint of the range (0.375 percent).

U . S . A G R I C U LT U R A L T R A D E
90

AVERAGE LAND VALUES ACROSS THE EIGHTH DISTRICT
6

BILLIONS OF DOLLARS

75
Imports

60
45
30
15

Trade Balance

0
’11

’12

’13

’14

’15

NOTE: Data are aggregated over the past 12 months.

May

’16

YEAR-OVER-YEAR PERCENT CHANGE

Exports

4
2
0
–2
–4
–6
–8

Quality Farmland
Ranchland or Pastureland

2015:Q1 2015:Q2 2015:Q3 2015:Q4 2016:Q1
SOURCE: Agricultural Finance Monitor.

U.S. CROP AND LIVESTOCK PRICES
140

INDEX 1990-92=100

120

Crops
Livestock

100
80
60
40

May

’01

’02

’03

’04

’05

’06

’07

’08

’09

’10

’11

’12

’13

’14

’15

’16

COMMERCIAL BANK PERFORMANCE RATIOS
U.S. BANKS BY ASSET SIZE / FIRST QUARTER 2016
All

$100 million­$300 million

Less than
$300 million

$300 million$1 billion

Less than
$1 billion

$1 billion$15 billion

Less than
$15 billion

More than
$15 billion

Return on Average Assets*

0.94

1.02

1.00

1.05

1.03

1.07

1.05

0.92

Net Interest Margin*

3.02

3.79

3.79

3.79

3.79

3.78

3.79

2.86

Nonperforming Loan Ratio

1.57

1.15

1.18

1.06

1.11

1.09

1.10

1.71

Loan Loss Reserve Ratio

1.35

1.44

1.46

1.38

1.41

1.23

1.30

1.36

R E T U R N O N AV E R A G E A S S E T S *

NET INTEREST MARGIN*
1.08

0.88

1.30
1.18

1.20
1.17
0.91
0.97
1.03
0.98

.40

First Quarter 2016

.60

Indiana

3.63
3.88

Kentucky

3.80
3.75

Mississippi

3.82
3.70
3.50
3.53

Missouri

0.94

.20

3.51
3.57

Illinois

0.94
0.88

–.40 –.20 .00

4.10
4.10

Arkansas

1.02
1.08

–0.18

3.70
3.67

Eighth District

3.28
3.16

Tennessee

.80 1.00 1.20 1.40

PERCENT

0.0 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 3.00 3.50 4.00 4.50

First Quarter 2015

First Quarter 2016

N O N P E R F O R M I N G L O A N R AT I O
1.02

L O A N L O S S R E S E RV E R AT I O
1.23

1.11
1.03

1.33

1.63

0.98
0.99

.25

.50

First Quarter 2016

.75

1.00

Arkansas

1.22

1.25

1.50

1.26
1.35
1.10

First Quarter 2015

NOTE: Data include only that portion of the state within Eighth
District boundaries.
SOURCE: Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council Reports
of Condition and Income for all Insured U.S. Commercial Banks.
* Annualized data.

PERCENT

1.33
1.41

1.20

Tennessee
1.75

1.46

0.84
0.90

Indiana

Missouri

1.10

1.39

1.23
1.26

Mississippi

1.28
1.37

.00

1.23

Kentucky

1.15

0.87

Eighth District

Illinois

1.21
1.21

0.82

First Quarter 2015

.00

.25

.50

First Quarter 2016

.75

1.00

1.25

1.57

1.33

1.50

First Quarter 2015

For additional banking and regional data, visit our website at:
https://fred.stlouisfed.org.

1.75

REGIONAL ECONOMIC INDICATORS
N O N FA R M E M P L O Y M E N T G R O W T H / F I R S T Q U A RT E R 2 0 1 6
YEAR-OVER-YEAR PERCENT CHANGE
United
States

Total Nonagricultural

Eighth
District †

Arkansas

1.7%

2.3%

1.9%

Natural Resources/Mining

Illinois

Indiana

1.2%

Kentucky

1.5%

Mississippi

1.7%

Missouri

Tennessee

0.9%

3.2%

1.5%

–16.4

–13.5

–18.2

–6.3

–10.8

–18.4

–14.3

–4.1

–1.5

Construction

4.5

3.8

2.8

4.1

3.5

3.7

1.3

5.0

NA

Manufacturing

0.1

0.4

–1.2

–1.1

0.1

1.5

2.4

–0.5

3.3

Trade/Transportation/Utilities

1.8

2.1

3.7

1.0

2.5

3.3

2.7

0.5

3.9

Information

1.3

–1.8

5.1

–1.5

–5.1

–3.9

0.0

–3.1

0.5

Financial Activities

1.8

1.5

1.0

0.4

2.0

2.9

–0.5

2.1

3.2

Professional & Business Services

3.1

1.8

3.6

0.8

–1.0

3.0

–0.7

2.8

4.7

Educational & Health Services

3.1

3.0

3.4

2.4

3.5

3.8

2.6

2.5

3.5

Leisure & Hospitality

3.0

2.9

6.9

4.0

3.0

1.6

2.8

–0.3

2.9

Other Services

1.2

1.2

2.7

1.0

1.2

–0.7

0.3

1.5

1.9

Government

0.5

0.0

0.2

0.5

0.4

–1.4

0.8

–1.0

0.0

† Eighth District growth rates are calculated from the sums of the seven states. For the Construction category, data on Tennessee are no longer available.

U N E M P L O Y M E N T R AT E S

EXPORTS
YEAR-OVER-YEAR PERCENT CHANGE

I/2016

IV/2015

I/2015

–7.3

United States

United States

4.9%

5.0%

5.6%

Arkansas

4.2

4.8

5.6

Illinois

6.4

6.0

6.0

Indiana

4.8

4.5

5.2

Kentucky

5.7

5.6

5.3

Mississippi

6.5

6.6

6.6

Missouri

4.2

4.4

5.3

Tennessee

4.9

5.6

6.0

2.8

–14.3

Arkansas

–4.2
–7.0

Illinois

3.5

–5.1

Indiana

3.8
1.9

Kentucky
Mississippi

–3.7

Missouri

9.4

–1.6

Tennessee
PERCENT

8.9

–5.5
–7.7

–20

–15
–10
2015
2014

–5

1.7

0

5

10

HOUSING PERMITS / FIRST QUARTER

REAL PERSONAL INCOME / FIRST QUARTER

YEAR-OVER-YEAR PERCENT CHANGE IN YEAR-TO-DATE LEVELS

YEAR-OVER-YEAR PERCENT CHANGE

6.8
8.9
11.8

49.0
38.7

–13.5
–16.6
0.3

19.3

43.6

2016

20

30

40

2015

All data are seasonally adjusted unless otherwise noted.

50

2.9
2.7

3.3
4.6

Tennessee
PERCENT

4.3

2.6

Missouri

13.9

10

4.3
3.8

Mississippi

8.0

–0

3.7

Kentucky

25.4

–10

3.1
2.9

Illinois
Indiana

32.5

4.2

3.6
3.8

Arkansas

37.7

7.2

–20

3.4

United States

15

3.9

0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 3.00 3.50 4.00 4.50 5.00
2016

2015

NOTE: Real personal income is personal income divided by the PCE
chained price index.