View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The Regional Economist January 2007
n

www.stlouisfed.org

President’s Message

“ The council members also give us a better idea of
what lies ahead than can the formal data, which
primarily tell us about the recent past.”

William Poole
President and CEO,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Industry Councils Bring Firsthand Insights
to Our Regional Economic Outlook

I

suspect that when most people
think about a meeting of the
Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC), they picture a room full of
economists toiling over stacks of data
and picking out statistics with a finetooth comb. There is some truth in
that, but there is another side of monetary policymaking that is far more art
than science: collecting and analyzing
informal, or anecdotal, information.
Among the informal sources regularly used are the economic reports
from the directors of the 12 Federal
Reserve banks and their branches.
The banks also maintain a network
of industry contacts that are consulted on a regular basis in advance
of FOMC meetings; the acquired
information is used to produce the
Summary of Commentary on Current Economic Conditions, commonly
known as the Beige Book.
One new source for this anecdotal
information is the St. Louis Fed’s
Eighth District Industry Councils. We
began this program in June to help us
gather the economic insights important to gauging the overall health of
the regional economy. We set up four
councils, each focusing on an industrial sector that is important to our
area. Each council is anchored in a
St. Louis Fed office that is a natural
fit for that industry. The four councils,
along with their “home office,” are:
health care (Louisville), transportation (Memphis), agribusiness (Little
Rock) and real estate (St. Louis). We
recruited top-level executives, busi-

ness owners and academics for these
councils, 32 members in all.
Already, the councils have met
twice with me and Fed staff. Hearing reports on trends from the real
experts—the people who are making
day-to-day business decisions—is
extremely useful because such information helps us clearly see what is
happening in the economy and helps
us understand the fluctuations in
formal data. The council members
also give us a better idea of what
lies ahead than can the formal data,
which primarily tell us about the
recent past.
Because discussion in these meetings is confidential, we can focus
on issues that may not have been
reported in the mainstream news
or accounted for in the formal data.
This information from the trenches,
so to speak, helps me to identify
emerging trends before situations
occur and before trends appear in
official data. During the most recent
Industry Council meetings, for example, I heard some valuable information. I conveyed this information to
the FOMC when we met the following week. Although I can’t share the
exact nature of the information, I can
tell you that similar rumblings were
being heard on this matter from other
Fed districts. As a result, Fed economists across the country are polling
executives in the affected industry for
more information.
Although the main reason industry
experts serve on our councils is to
[3]

help us steer the economy, they get
something for themselves out of their
service. They meet other leaders in
the same industry and find out what
they are doing. As Bert Greenwalt, a
member of the Agribusiness Council, notes, “It is always interesting to
compare the similarities and differences among the group.” In addition, council members learn a good
deal about the Fed and what makes
the economy tick. “Presentations by
the Fed staff and president increase
council members’ understanding of
macroeconomic issues and help us
explain the Fed’s mission and tools to
our friends and industry colleagues,”
says the farmer and Arkansas State
University professor.
The efforts of our council members
reflect the importance of the Fed’s
public-private partnership, in which
a federal agency—the Fed’s Board of
Governors—and the 12 quasi-public
Reserve banks conduct monetary
policy together. In forming our
outlook for the economy, the Fed
gets direct input from public citizens
who serve on our boards of directors
and on groups such as our Industry
Councils. This structure and this
public involvement make the Federal
Reserve’s decentralized approach to
monetary policymaking so effective,
as well as unique among the world’s
central banks.

The Regional Economist January 2007
n

www.stlouisfed.org

The Taking of

Prosperity?
Kelo vs. New London
and the Economics of Eminent Domain
By Thomas A. Garrett and Paul Rothstein

The U.S. Supreme Court’s decision in Kelo vs. New
London was an unlikely source of public outrage.
After all, the court didn’t overturn anything in its
June 2005 ruling; it merely affirmed an earlier decision by the Supreme Court of Connecticut.
That decision allowed the city of New
London, which was officially designated
as “distressed,” to use the power of eminent domain to acquire 15 properties,
one of which belonged to homeowner
Susette Kelo. Although forcing the sale
of homes always raises delicate issues, it
is not an unusual event. Furthermore,
nothing in the court’s decision altered
the ability of state legislatures to limit
the practice of eminent domain. Viewed
in this way, the decision in Kelo should
have been one of the lower-profile decisions of the Supreme Court that year.
That’s not how things went, however.
The reaction against both the court and
its decision was swift and furious. The
U.S. House of Representatives passed a
resolution denouncing the court.1 The

House also passed a bill that would withhold federal development funds from
states and political subdivisions that use
eminent domain in certain ways.2 Since
the Kelo decision, 34 states have taken
action to limit eminent domain: 26 have
passed statutes, five have passed constitutional amendments and an additional three have passed both. (Five of
the seven states in the Eighth Federal
Reserve District have passed statutes.3)
President Bush issued an executive order
limiting the grounds on which the federal
government can take private property.4
Finally, the Supreme Court of Ohio
handed down a ruling in a case that, by
the court’s own assessment, raises social
and legal issues similar to those in Kelo.5
Drawing upon the reasoning of several

[5]

dissenting judges in the Kelo case, the
Supreme Court of Ohio gave property
owners the protection that was denied to
Susette Kelo in Connecticut.
This brief survey of the response to
Kelo suggests that its shock waves are
likely to reverberate for some time. Nevertheless, we are far enough beyond the
Kelo ruling that we can review the main
issues with the knowledge that the most
speculative and feared consequences of
Kelo—free-for-all takings for economic
development—have not yet occurred.
A History of Eminent Domain

The U.S. Supreme Court has long
recognized in the federal government
the power to acquire private property for
public use. This is true even though the
term “eminent domain”does not appear
in the Constitution or the amendments.6
The power is limited, however, by two
restrictions. First, as with any federal
action, the use of eminent domain must
be “necessary and proper” in accordance
with the congressional powers enumerated in Article 1, Section 8, of the Constitution. Second, the use of eminent
domain must obey the final clause of the
Fifth Amendment, which states, “Nor
shall private property be taken for public
use, without just compensation.”
The Fifth Amendment did not apply to
state governments prior to the 14th Amendment. By the late 19th century, however,
the due process clause of the 14th Amendment came to be regarded as requiring
the states’ use of eminent domain to be
consistent with federal interpretations of
public use and just compensation. A state
is free to establish a more-restrictive concept
of public use than the U.S. Supreme
Court finds in the Fifth Amendment, just
as a state could require “more than” just
compensation for a taking, but not a
less-restrictive concept. Although state
governments have the legal ability to
establish, to some degree, their own laws
regarding eminent domain, local governments like that of the city of New London
have only those powers granted to them
by state constitutions and statutes.
Although Susette Kelo’s house was in
a distressed city, neither her house nor
any of the other properties was in poor
condition. Rather, the city acted under
the authority of a Connecticut statute that
(more or less) explicitly declared that the
taking of land for purposes of economic
development was a taking for public use.
The city’s economic development plan
designated the parcels for office space,
parking and retail services. This scenario
highlights the central issues of the Kelo
case: What is a “public use,”and does the
answer to this question given by a state
legislature matter?
[6]

Public Use, Public Purpose
and Judicial Deference

In its majority opinion, the U.S. Supreme
Court stated in Kelo that the government
can never take property from one private
party for the sole purpose of giving it to
another, even if just compensation is paid.
On the other hand, the government can
always do so if the general public acquires
some actual use of the property. The court
has been defining the ground between
these extremes since the late 19th century.7
From the start, “it embraced the broader
and more natural interpretation of public
use as ‘public purpose,’ ” the court said in
Kelo.8 More precisely, the court began to
argue in the late 1800s that if property is
taken to create a widespread benefit, then
it is “put to”a public use and satisfies
this requirement.9
At the same time, the court developed
the language and rationales for deferring
to legislative declarations about public
use and purpose. The majority wrote in
Kelo, “For more than a century, our public
use jurisprudence has wisely eschewed
rigid formulas and intrusive scrutiny
in favor of affording legislatures broad
latitude in determining what public needs
justify the use of the takings power.”10
In particular, if a state declares that the
removal of blight serves a public purpose
or land redistribution does the same, then
the court would not subject those claims
to close scrutiny.11
Thus, following this line of thought,
the court essentially declared that it
would defer to legislative declarations
about public use unless, in a particular
application, they were transparently
covering up a purely private transfer of
property. The court decided this was not
the case in Kelo.
The Economics of Kelo

Economist Patricia Munch provides
an analysis of the economics of eminent
domain. In her model, a land developer
needs to assemble contiguous parcels of
property. All parcels have identical characteristics, and there is nothing special about
any particular location. The lowest price a
property owner will accept (his “reservation price”) for his property differs across
property owners. Munch assumes that
each developer offers all owners the same
price for their properties and that this price
is the (expected) maximum reservation
price of all property owners. Munch then
argues that the full additional cost of
adding a parcel to a development is likely
to be larger than just the cost of that parcel.
The reason is that, if the developer only
needs a few parcels, then he can easily find
a cluster in which the maximum reservation price is low. Since the developer (by

The Regional Economist January 2007
n

assumption) pays the maximum reservation price to each owner, it follows that
the cost of each parcel is relatively low.
The larger the number of parcels the
developer needs to assemble, however,
the more difficult it is to find a cluster
with a low maximum reservation price.
The general result is that, as long as the
developer can do a little searching, the
per-parcel cost will be strictly increasing
with the number of parcels.
It is not hard to see that the result is
likely to be inefficiently little land assembly. As in the standard single buyer story
(what economists term a monopsony),
assembling more parcels requires the
developer to offer each homeowner the
same (high) price. Assembly stops when
the cost to the developer of adding a
parcel equals the benefit to him from
adding it. In other words, assembly stops
when there is no additional profit from
adding parcels. The problem, however, is
that if the developer could offer different
sellers different amounts of money (i.e.,
he could price discriminate), he could
probably offer them prices at which they
willingly sell and at which he makes a
larger profit. One could argue that the
sellers and the buyer should figure this
out, but it is expensive for the developer
to deal individually with homeowners,
and homeowners are reluctant to sell at
prices below recent offers. As long as
all parcels must sell for the same price,
there are likely to be willing sellers whose
homes are not purchased.
Now suppose the developer has the
power of eminent domain. This makes
the reservation prices irrelevant: Every
homeowner is paid the market price for
his home. Now, land assembly stops
when the market price equals the benefit
to the developer from adding the parcel.
The problem in this case is that the market price is below the reservation price
for some of these sellers. In other words,
they are unwilling sellers. The result is
too much land assembly under eminent domain.
Munch notes that the assumption
that the developer is a single buyer is
central to the analysis. If there is competition among developers, then some will
develop better techniques for determining seller reservation prices. If communities choose these developers, then
more-efficient land assembly will result.
Munch also briefly discusses the “holdout”problem. She notes that there is no
inefficiency when the owner of a parcel
that has some unique value (perhaps as a
location) tries to benefit financially from
its uniqueness. The only genuine holdout
problem she considers occurs if some
sellers believe that other sellers did not
capture all the rents that were possible
to them in their transactions with the

www.stlouisfed.org

Select U.S. Eminent Domain
Laws and Court Rulings
1) Fifth Amendment to the U.S. Constitution (1791)
“Nor shall private property be taken for public use, without
just compensation.”
This statement is commonly referred to as the “takings
clause.” Most courts have equated just compensation with a
property’s fair market value. Narrowly defined, “public use”
requires that the taken property be used by the public at large—
what economists call a public good.
2) Fallbrook Irrigation Dist. vs. Bradley, 164 U.S. 112 (1896)
In a case concerning the requirement that a group of property
owners pay for the building of an irrigation ditch, the U.S. Supreme
Court ruled that the irrigation of arid land served a public purpose
and the water used was “put to” a public use. This is an important early case in the development of the public purpose doctrine.
3) Berman vs. Parker, 348 U.S. 26 (1954)
The U.S. Supreme Court ruled that taking private property (and
paying just compensation) to remove blight served a public purpose and met the requirements of the Fifth Amendment. This was
true even though the seized property was sold to private interests
and would not necessarily have a wide use by the public.
4) Hawaii Housing Authority vs. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229 (1984)
The U.S. Supreme Court ruled that a state could use eminent
domain to take land from private landowners and allocate it to
others. The case was based on the state of Hawaii’s complaint
that a vast majority of the privately held land in Hawaii was in
the hands of a few landowners, thus limiting competition in land
and property markets. Berman vs. Parker served as precedent
for the ruling.
5) Kelo vs. New London, 545 U.S. ____ (2005)
The U.S. Supreme Court ruled that eminent domain could
be used to take land from one private landowner and give it
to another for the sake of economic development. Berman
vs. Parker and Hawaii Housing Authority vs. Midkiff served as
precedent for the ruling. Critics of the Kelo ruling argue that the
court misinterpreted the Fifth Amendment by further broadening
“public use” to mean “public purpose.”
More information on these cases can be found at www.findlaw.com/
casecode/supreme.html. Other eminent domain cases can be
searched at http://caselaw.lp.findlaw.com/casesummary.
[7]

developer. Misinformation and speculation along these lines could, once again,
prevent willing buyers and willing sellers
from reaching a transaction.
The Public Good vs. Public Goods

Although the work by Munch suggests eminent domain can improve upon
market outcomes under certain conditions, her analysis fails to address several economic issues involving eminent
domain that have broader implications
for economic development and growth.
Specifically, any economic analysis of
eminent domain as it relates to the Kelo
decision must recognize the tradeoffs
inherent in giving local governments
this kind of power over local economic
development. Those who approve of
eminent domain as it was used in Kelo
fail to recognize the difference between
what economists call“private goods”and
“public goods.” They also fail to see the
inefficiencies often generated from government intervention in private markets.
An understanding of the differences
between a public good and a private good
and the ineffectiveness of governments in
providing a private good reveals the incorrect
premise behind the Kelo decision.12 Private
goods are both “rival in consumption”and
excludable. Rival in consumption means
that one person’s consumption of a private
good denies others the opportunity to enjoy
the good. The price of a private good is
essentially a result of the good’s scarcity—
as additional resources are employed to
produce more of the good, the opportunity cost and, thus, the marginal costs, of
producing the private good rises. This
increasing opportunity cost increases the
price and, as a result, some individuals will
be excluded from consuming the good
because they are not willing to pay the
higher price.
Unlike a private good, a public good is
both non-rival in consumption and nonexcludable. The textbook example of a
pure public good is national defense; other
examples of similar goods include parks
and highways.13 One person’s consumption
of a public good does not deny others from
consuming the good, and people can use
the public good without paying for it. As
a result, the marginal cost of an additional
user of a public good is zero, and this
suggests a market price of zero. Economists justify public (government) provision of public goods because too little of
the good would be available (given a
market price of zero) if production of the
good was left to the private market.
Government provision of public goods
and, thus, the taking of private property
to provide these goods, can be justified
under the narrow definition of public use,
i.e., used by the community as a whole.
[8]

However, the taking of private property
from one person and giving it to another
for economic development, even if one
considers the holdout problem and payment of just compensation, is unlikely to
create a net benefit to society. It is more
likely to create economic inefficiencies
and to reduce economic growth.14
Historical anecdotal information and
formal academic research show that, in
general, countries with less government
involvement in private markets experience greater levels of economic growth.15
The only possible exceptions in recent
times are the Asian Tigers (e.g., South
Korea, Taiwan and now China), but even
there, markets are used extensively, and
the strategies used by those governments
have been difficult to replicate elsewhere.
When governments interfere in the
private market, whether it be a market for
apples, cars or property, the likely result
is greater economic inefficiency and less
economic growth. The reason is that even
the most well-intentioned policymaker
cannot comprehend or replicate the complex interactions of buyers and sellers that
occur in free markets.
Of course, there will be certain groups
that do benefit from the taking of private
property, such as developers, property
managers and local politicians. Developers and property managers will gain
income from developing the property.
Many local politicians favor targeted
economic development because of what
they see as the immediate benefits from
development, such as increased employment and tax revenue. These economic
benefits also translate into political
benefits for those politicians who pledge
to improve local economic development.
Not realized, however, is that the supposed immediate and tangible benefits
from taking private property for economic
development are outweighed by the
greater economic costs of government
intervention in private markets.
Local Governments
and Economic Development

The use of eminent domain for
economic development as established
by Kelo complements already existing
economic development tools such as TIFs
(tax increment financing), tax breaks, local
development grants, etc. Local governments use all of these options to target
specific projects in their area because of
a perception, whether real or imaginary,
that the local area suffers from a lack of
growth. All of these economic development tools, however, are unlikely to lead
to an overall increase in societal welfare
because each tool simply involves a transfer of income from one group to another,
often resulting in a zero-sum gain.

The Regional Economist January 2007
n

A simple example can illustrate the
point. Suppose a local government takes
$10,000 from Peter and gives it to Paul,
who plans to open a business. Paul then
uses the $10,000 to open his business,
which creates tax revenue and jobs. From
a social welfare point of view, Peter loses
$10,000 and the savings or consumption benefits of his $10,000, Paul gains
$10,000 to open a business, and jobs are
created. By taking the $10,000 from Peter
and giving it to Paul, the local government is essentially saying that Paul can
create greater societal wealth with Peter’s
$10,000 than Peter can. The same would
be true if local governments paid Peter for
his house and then gave the property to
Paul for development purposes.
Of course, it is impossible for local
governments to know if greater wealth
would have been created by allowing
Peter to keep his $10,000 rather than
giving it to Paul. Economic theory tells us
that in the absence of incomplete information or externalities, free markets will
result in the most efficient allocation of
resources and greater economic growth.
By replicating the above scenario across
thousands or millions of individuals, the
likely result is that the costs and benefits
will average out to be the same, thus
creating a zero-sum gain. Thus, the same
level of economic development would
have likely occurred if Peter kept his
original $10,000.
There is reason to believe, however, that
a zero-sum gain is not the worst case outcome. In the face of a policy decision like
eminent domain, individuals and interest
groups on both sides of the issue will expend
resources (e.g., campaign contributions, the
cost of one’s time in campaigning for an
issue, etc.) to ensure that the policy decision
will favor their respective position. This
rent-seeking by opposing groups results
in a net economic loss because both groups
will expend resources to ensure a particular
outcome, but only one outcome will occur.
In the above example, even if the transfer
of $10,000 from Peter to Paul created a
zero-sum gain, the resources Peter and Paul
expended to influence the policy outcome
will result in a total economic loss for society
rather than a zero-sum gain. Most likely,
the policy outcome will be that desired by
the interest group that has expended the
greatest resources. As Justice Sandra Day
O’Connor states in her dissent to Kelo,
“The beneficiaries (of eminent domain)
are likely to be those citizens with disproportionate influence and power in the
political process, including large corporations and development firms.”16
What can governments do to promote economic development that yields
positive economic growth? Rather than
use eminent domain or other tools to
target individual economic development

projects, local governments should ask
the fundamental question as to why the
desired level of economic growth is not
occurring in the local area without
significant economic development
incentives. For example, are taxes too
high, thus creating a disincentive for
business to locate to the local area? Do
current regulations stifle business creation
and expansion? All of the targeted
economic development in the world will
not compensate for a poor business
environment. From a regional perspective, local governments should focus on
creating a business environment conducive to risk-taking, entry and expansion
rather than attempting targeted economic
development through eminent domain or
other means.17
Indeed, there is some risk for local
communities that use eminent domain
for economic development. One requirement for a well-functioning private market is secure property rights. Research
has shown that without property rights,
individuals will no longer face the incentive to make the best economic use of
their property, be it a business or home,
and economic growth will be limited.18
The Kelo decision essentially says that
individuals can lose their property if the
local government believes it needs the
property to generate greater economic
benefits. Potential residents and businesses may avoid communities that
have a record of taking private property
for economic development because of
a greater uncertainty about losing their
property to eminent domain.
Conclusion

The Kelo decision by the U.S. Supreme
Court was met by great opposition from
the public and many local government
officials. Numerous public opinion polls
taken immediately following the ruling
revealed that the vast majority of Americans disagreed with the court’s ruling.19
Supporters of Kelo argue that using
eminent domain for private development
will spur economic growth. Although a
lack of sufficient data currently prevents
empirically testing the economic effects of
eminent domain described in this article,
economic theory certainly suggests that
eminent domain used for private economic development will likely result in a
zero-sum gain and may actually hinder
economic development in the local areas,
as well as the region, rather than help.
Thomas A. Garrett is a research officer and economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Paul
Rothstein is an associate professor of economics and
associate director of the Weidenbaum Center on
the Economy, Government, and Public Policy at
Washington University in St. Louis.

[9]

www.stlouisfed.org

ENDNOTES
1

H.RES 340, 109th Congress.

2

HR 4128, 109th Congress.

3

Indiana, Illinois, Kentucky, Tennessee,
and Missouri have enacted statutes. The
National Council of State Legislatures
is keeping track of these activities. See
www.ncsl.org/programs/natres/
EMINDOMAIN.htm.

4

“Executive Order: Protecting the Property Rights of the American People,”
June 23, 2006.

5

Norwood vs. Horney, Ohio St. 3d, 2006Ohio-3799, paragraphs 7 and 76.

6

In Kohl vs. United States, 91 U.S. 367, 372373 (1876), the Supreme Court wrote,
“The Constitution itself contains an implied recognition of it [eminent domain]
beyond what may justly be implied from
the express grants. The Fifth Amendment
contains a provision that private property
shall not be taken for public use without
just compensation. What is that but an
implied assertion, that, on making just
compensation, it [private property for
public use] may be taken?”

7

More detailed citations are available
by request.

8

Kelo vs. New London, 545 U.S. ____, ____
(2005) (Court slip op., at 9).

9

Fallbrook Irrigation Dist. vs. Bradley, 164
U.S. 112, 164 (1896).

10

Kelo vs. New London, 545 U.S.____, ____
(2005) (Court slip op., 12-13).

11

Berman vs. Parker, 348 U.S. 26 (1954) and
Hawaii Housing Authority vs. Midkiff, 467
U.S. 229 (1984), respectively.

12

Cornes and Sandler (1996).

13

Highways and parks are called near
public goods because they are subject to
congestion, which limits consumption.

14

Davies (2006) and Rolnick and Davies
(2006) discuss the costs of Kelo.

15

See Gwartney et al. (2004).

16

Kelo vs. New London, 545 U.S.____,
____ (2005) (O’Connor slip op., 12-13).

17

Bauer (1972).

18

Knack and Keefer (1995).

19

See www.castlecoalition.org/resources/
kelo_polls.html.

REFERENCES
Bauer, Peter T. Dissent on Development: Studies and Debates in Economic Development.
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press, 1972.
Cornes, Richard; and Sandler, Todd. The Theory
of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods.
NewYork: Cambridge University Press, 1996.
Davies, Phil. “Condemned Prosperity.”
Fedgazette, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, March 2006, Vol. 18, No. 2,
pp. 14-17.
Gwartney, James; Holcombe, Randall; and
Lawson, Robert. “Economic Freedom,
Institutional Quality, and Cross-County
Differences in Income and Growth.”
Cato Journal, Fall 2004, Vol. 24, No. 3,
pp. 205-33.
Knack, Stephen; and Keefer, Philip.
“Institutions and Economic Performance:
Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative
Institutional Measures.” Economics and
Politics, November 1995, Vol. 7, No. 3,
pp. 207-27.
Munch, Patricia. “An Economic Analysis
of Eminent Domain.” Journal of Political
Economy, June 1976, Vol. 84, No. 3,
pp. 473-97.
Rolnick, Art; and Davies, Phil. “The Cost of
Kelo.” The Region, Federal Reserve Bank
of Minneapolis, June 2006, Vol. 20, No. 2,
pp. 12-17, 42-45.

A

mericans appear to be working less. Numerous economic
studies suggest that the number of hours that the average
American works in a year has
fallen by about 550 hours from 1900
to 2005.1 The cut in hours worked
presumably comes with the benefit
of increased time devoted to leisure.
Or does it? In two separate studies,
economists Mark Aguiar and Erik
Hurst and economists Valerie Ramey
and Neville Francis found conflicting evidence on the trends in leisure
time for Americans. What accounts
for these differences? Is it simply
alternative definitions of leisure, and,
if so, which definition more accurately reflects what Americans view
as leisure?
The New Leisure

The presumption that labor and
leisure are inversely related is the
foundation of many economic
models. Time not spent at work
must, by definition, be spent on
leisure. An innovation of the two
studies cited above is that they allow
for non-market labor, i.e., hours
spent outside the office performing
chores not considered leisure. These
activities include cleaning, cooking,
commuting, etc. Although non-market labor activities might seem straight­
forward to define, in practice some
activities, such as child-rearing, may
be difficult to classify.
In their 2006 study, Aguiar and
Hurst examined changes in the time
allocated to market work, non-market
work and leisure from 1965-2003 for
working-age adults—those aged
21-65. The accompanying table shows
the changes for the whole sample,
as well as the changes broken down
by gender. According to the authors,
total time devoted to the market sector
per week (paid hours plus commuting, breaks and meals) declined by
3.2 hours for all workers.2 However,
the trends for men and women were
vastly different; the decline in men’s
total weekly market work was over
three times larger than the increase
in women’s weekly hours. Similarly, total weekly non-market work
(housework plus time spent obtaining
goods and services and other home
production) fell by 4.6 hours for all
workers between 1965 and 2003. In
this case, the decline in women’s total
weekly non-market work was three
times larger than the increase in men’s
weekly hours. Thus, total weekly work
(market plus non-market) decreased

Working Hard or
Hardly Working?
The Evolution of Leisure in the United States
By Kristie M. Engemann and Michael T. Owyang

by 7.8 hours, with men and women
experiencing similar overall declines.
Rather than defining leisure simply
as the amount of time not spent on
market and non-market work, Aguiar
and Hurst defined four alternative
measures of leisure. The first accounts
for time spent on activities such as
socializing, relaxing, active recreation
and recreational child care (e.g., playing games with children). Overall,
working-age adults spent 5.1 more
hours on these activities in 2003 than
in 1965 on a weekly basis. The authors’
second measure, adding sleeping,
eating and personal care to their first
measure, increased by 5.6 hours during the sample period. Their third
measure, which includes all previous
activities plus primary and educational
child care, increased by 6.9 hours.

[10]

Finally, their last measure of leisure is
simply the residual from total work.
The authors claimed that adults spent
7.8 more hours a week on leisure in
2003 using this last definition. Based
on each of these measures then, adults
have more leisure time than they did
in 1965.
20th Century Trends
in Per Capita Leisure

The 2006 study by Ramey and Francis provides another perspective, yielding seemingly different results. Rather
than examining the allocation of time
for working-age adults, the authors
used the entire population to estimate
changes in market work, home production and leisure from 1900-2004.
In addition to the three components

The Regional Economist January 2007
n

used by Aguiar and Hurst, Ramey and
Francis estimated the time allocated to
school for their sample period.
The authors estimated that the average
employed person worked 55 hours per
week in 1900 but only 37 hours per week
in 2004. Because school and homework
are aimed at enhancing the productivity
of future market work, Ramey and Francis
included time spent on those activities as
non-leisure. They found that school hours
for those aged 5-22 rose from 330 to
nearly 900 hours annually.3 After including commuting, time spent on market
work and schooling per year declined by
only 40 hours between 1900 and 2004.
For home production, Ramey and
Francis included typical housework
(meals, cleaning, laundry, etc.) plus basic
child care and helping with school work.
They found that the typical non-employed
woman aged 18-64 spent 56 hours per
week on housework in the early 1900s but
only 45 hours per week since 1975. For
employed women aged 18-64, home production hours remained steady—about
25 hours per week—throughout the entire
period. Employed men aged 18-64, on
the other hand, saw an increase in housework from 2-3 hours per week in the
1920s to 16 hours per week in 2004. For
the entire population, annual hours on
home production increased by 67 hours
during the sample period.4
In their study, Ramey and Francis
defined leisure time as time spent on
activities that provide direct enjoyment.
Hence, leisure is time not spent on
market work, school work, commuting
or housework. The authors found that
the average person spent similar time on
leisure in 1900 (6,657 hours) and in 2004
(6,634 hours). These translate into 128
hours and 127.6 hours of leisure per week
in 1900 and 2004, respectively. During the
same period studied by Aguiar and Hurst,
Ramey and Francis’ estimate of leisure
time actually showed a slight decline in
2003 from the 1965 level.

www.stlouisfed.org

Discussion

Are Americans enjoying more free time
than they used to? Not if you ask them.
Social scientists John Robinson and Geoffrey Godbey found that in surveys conducted in various years between 1965 and
1995, Americans increasingly felt rushed.
In 1965, 24 percent of respondents aged
18-64 “always felt rushed”; this percentage climbed to 38 percent in 1992, but
then dropped to 33 percent in 1995.
Moreover, the percentage of respondents
who “almost never felt rushed” fell from
27 percent to 17 percent between 1971
and 1995.
Economists Daniel Hamermesh and
Jungmin Lee offered a different interpretation. The authors studied people’s perception of their time stress, finding that
people who make more money—but did
not work more hours—reported that they
felt more stressed for time.5 Hence, the
authors attributed at least part of the time
stress simply to having too much money
to spend, given the amount of time left
after working.
These conflicting studies leave open
this question of whether today’s Americans actually have more leisure time
than past generations had. The salient
difference in these studies’ conclusions
appears to stem from what one considers
leisure and who is being asked. Focusing only on working-age adults, as do
Aguiar and Hurst, suggests that Americans enjoy more leisure now than in the
mid-1960s. On the other hand, when
school and work by children and retirees
are included, Americans work about the
same amount of time now as they did in
both 1900 and 1965. However, no matter
which definition of leisure is preferred,
the broad conclusion is that Americans’
leisure time is, at worst, the same now as
it ever was—regardless of perception.
Kristie M. Engemann is a senior research associate,
and Michael T. Owyang is a research officer, both at
the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Changes in Weekly Hours

(1965-2003)

From study by Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst

All

Total market work (paid work, commute, breaks, meals)

Men Women

–3.2 –11.6

Total non-market work (housework, time obtaining goods and services, other) –4.6
Total  work (total market + total non-market)

3.4

3.7 –11.1

–7.8

–7.9

–7.7

Leisure 1 (socializing, relaxing, recreation)

5.1

6.3

3.8

Leisure 2 (Leisure 1 + sleeping, eating, personal care)

5.6

6.4

4.9

Leisure 3 (Leisure 2 + primary and educational child care)

6.9

7.9

6.0

Leisure 4 (total hours possible minus total work)

7.8

7.9

7.7

[11]

ENDNOTES
1

Total hours worked in business divided
by the civilian non-institutional population aged 16 and older (Ramey and
Francis 2006).

2

Aguiar and Hurst’s results control for
age, education, the day of the week
that the survey was taken and family
composition.

3

The results for school were due to
both higher enrollment and more
days attended.

4

The authors noted that the increase
is due to changes in the composition
of the population (e.g., retired people
now make up a larger percentage).

5

Hamermesh and Lee controlled for
health and various demographic characteristics (e.g., family composition,
age and location).

REFERENCES
Aguiar, Mark; and Hurst, Erik. “Measuring Trends in Leisure: The Allocation
of Time over Five Decades.” Working
Paper No. 06-2, Federal Reserve Bank
of Boston, January 2006.
Hamermesh, Daniel S.; and Lee,
Jungmin. “Stressed Out on Four Continents: Time Crunch or Yuppie Kvetch?”
Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming 2007.
Ramey, Valerie A.; and Francis, Neville.
“A Century of Work and Leisure.”
Manuscript, University of California,
San Diego, May 2006.
Robinson, John P.; and Godbey, Geoffrey.
Time for Life: The Surprising Ways Americans Use Their Time. Second Edition.
University Park, Penn.: The Pennsylvania State University Press, 1999.

Barnyard Boon or Bust?

The
National
Animal
Identification
System (NAIS)
By Michael R. Pakko

producers could choose their level of
participation in the program.6
Agriculture Department officials
envision the identification system as a
“public/private partnership.” However,
the lack of a clear division of costs
among various levels of government
and producers has created uncertainty.
Benefits and Costs

C

ity residents might not have heard
much about it, but a program
to identify and track U.S. farm
animals has many farmers and
ranchers angry and suspicious.
Now being implemented by
the U.S. Department of Agriculture
(USDA), the National Animal Identification System (NAIS) calls for registering all premises involved with animal
agriculture, tagging all farm animals
and tracking these animals through
a system of producer-reporting and
state-managed databases.
Opponents of NAIS worry about
data security and cite objections to the
program on constitutional and religious grounds.1 Small farmers, in particular, oppose the program, because
they say it will cost too much.2
About the NAIS

According to the USDA, the plan
will enable the federal government to
trace, within 48 hours, the origin of any
animal in the food chain found to be
infected by disease. Working groups
comprised of industry and government representatives are developing
implementation plans for cattle, swine,
sheep, goats, horses, poultry, bison,
deer, elk, llamas and alpacas. For
example, the cattle working group has
recommended radio frequency identification (RFID) ear tags to identify cattle.3
The plan has three phases:
• Premises identification: The first
phase, under way in most states,
calls for the registration of all premises housing farm animals. Each

location will get a unique seven-digit
premises identification number.
• Animal identification: The
second phase calls for assigning a
15-digit animal identification number to each farm animal. Methods
of identifying animals may differ
from one species to another, with
species working groups establishing
the standards. Animals that move
through the production chain as
a group (e.g., swine and poultry)
may get 13-digit group identification numbers.
• Animal tracking: When the program is fully operational, all animal
movements that involve possible
commingling will be reported and
stored in standardized databases
that will be run by state governments and industry groups.
The Agriculture Department’s draft
strategic plan originally called for the
system to become mandatory in 2008.4
Responding to criticism of this timetable, the USDA has backed away from
mandatory features of the program
and has begun emphasizing voluntary
participation. An implementation plan
published in October 2006 set milestones and benchmarks, envisioning
a fully functional system in operation
by January 2009. The plan noted that
“allowing market forces … to drive
producer participation in the NAIS
is preferable to mandatory federal
regulations.”5 A newly released User’s
Guide, published in November 2006,
emphasized voluntary participation
even further, describing how individual
[12]

When evaluating public policy
issues, a fundamental benchmark of
analysis is a cost/benefit study. The
principle is simple: It is worthwhile
to implement or expand a program
as long as the benefits exceed the
costs. In practice, these costs and
benefits can be difficult to quantify.
Nevertheless, policies should not be
implemented without a general consideration of this criterion.
With NAIS, no formal cost/benefit analysis has been undertaken,
although work is under way on such a
project. The User’s Guide sketches out
the general considerations.
The benefits of the program should
be calculated as the saving made possible by improved trace-back of disease
outbreaks. For example, if improved
tracking allows for only 2,000 animals
to be isolated and tested, rather than
20,000, the lower cost should be considered a net benefit. The nature of the
issue makes this exercise, in part, an
analysis of risk. The relevant calculations should include the probability of
specific disease scenarios, estimates
of the costs of these scenarios and
estimates of the savings that improved
tracking procedures could provide.7
The cost of identifying every U.S.
farm animal has been the focus of
much critical attention. Agriculture
Department officials foresee state
governments and producers paying for
much of the program. Federal funding
for the program was only $18.8 million
in 2004, with $33 million per year in
subsequent years. This funding level
has been sufficient to pay for initial
administration costs and to provide
support to states for setting up premises identification.
States and producers will pay
for the remaining costs, which are
likely to be substantial.8 Having
established criteria for uniform

The Regional Economist January 2007
n

record-keeping, the Agriculture Department is authorizing private database
managers to collect animal tracking
information and is authorizing particular
manufacturers to provide official identification tags. Individual states may allocate
some funding, but individual producers
probably will pay for a large share of tagging and tracking animals.
Researchers at Kansas State University
developed a spreadsheet that estimates
how much producers will have to pay to
implement RFID technology for cattle.
As the figure shows, the cost per head
of implementing the system varies in
proportion to herd size. The authors
point out that not all the costs included
in their analysis would necessarily be
associated with NAIS.9 In particular,
some smaller producers would probably
not have to buy chip-reading equipment
and computers for data management.
Nevertheless, the technology itself is
not scale-neutral: Fixed costs raise the
cost per animal for small farmers, while
economies of scale help keep the unit
cost down for larger operations.
Herd sizes in the U.S. beef and dairy
industry tend to be fairly small. According to the 2002 Census of Agriculture,
the median number of cattle and calves
per farm is fewer than 50.10 Opposition
to a national animal identification system
tends to come from these smaller producers. Ranches with more than 50 head
represent only one-third of all farms,
but account for 87 percent of all cattle
and calves.
Additional Considerations

One important feature of risk analysis
is the general principle of diminishing
returns. As in many economic analyses, the mitigation of some risk can be
relatively inexpensive, but the cost can
increase as more risk is addressed. It is
often cost-effective to follow policies that
mitigate some risk, but rarely can risk be
totally eliminated. In this particular exam-

ple, efforts to include the smaller producers face this escalating cost schedule.
Supporters of NAIS sometimes argue
that the benefits of an animal identification system include improved management tools for producers, as well as
enhanced opportunities in domestic and
international markets. This may be the
case, but these benefits would largely
accrue to the producers directly and
would not necessarily justify the NAIS
program itself. These considerations are
relevant to the cost-benefit analysis of
individual farmers, but not necessarily to
the ID system as a whole.
Nevertheless, these factors are relevant
for evaluating the voluntary nature of current plans. Large-scale producers are far
more likely to reap benefits from improving their inventory and marketing technologies and are likely to find it economical to
participate voluntarily in the NAIS.
With benefits of animal tracking technology increasing and costs decreasing for
larger herds, there is likely to be a threshold level where participation in NAIS
provides a net benefit. The distribution
of herd sizes suggests that even a fairly
low level of participation among producers could cover a large proportion of the
nation’s animals. Broader participation
in the program could be encouraged by
program design to keep down the costs.
As the most recent User’s Guide
indicates, this level of voluntary participation is likely to be far more economically efficient than the original plan of
mandatory 100 percent participation.
Indeed, much criticism about the NAIS
has focused on the high cost of the initial
mandatory proposals. Assuming that the
overall benefits of the program make its
costs worthwhile, a system based on voluntary participation is far more likely to
result in an efficient distribution of costs
than a mandatory program.
Michael Pakko is a research officer at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

ENDNOTES
1

See, for example, Zanoni (2006).

2

A recent article in USA Today describes
the intensity of opposition that has arisen
in some parts of the country, Hall (2006).

3

This article focuses on cattle as an
example, but many of the points likely
carry over to other species groups covered
under the plan.

4

USDA (2005).

5

USDA (2006a), p. 2. Although the
program is voluntary at the federal level,
some individual states are requiring
compliance with premises identification.

6

USDA (2006b).

7

An example of methodology is already
established: Disney et al. (2001)
showed how to evaluate both the costs
of animal tracking systems and the
benefits of trace-back after a disease
outbreak. Although details of the study
did not reflect some specific features
of the NAIS proposals, it did find that
a tracking program may or may not
be cost-effective, depending on the
assumed risks of disease outbreak and
the cost of technologies used.

8

Tagging 40 million new calves born
each year at a cost of $2.50 per tag, the
cost of identifying cattle alone could
exceed $100 million annually.

9

The costs include electronic tags, a
wand/stick reader, a laptop computer and software, and other costs
(including labor for implementing the
technology). The costs do not include
labor costs for the maintenance of
centralized NAIS databases.

10

The average (mean) herd size nationwide
is 94. For Missouri, the average is 69.

REFERENCES
Disney, W.T.; Green, J.W.; Forsythe, K.W.;
Wiemers, J.F.; and Weber, S. “Benefitcost analysis of animal identification
for disease prevention and control.”
Rev. sci. tech. Off. Int. Epiz., August 2001,
Vol. 20, No. 2, pp. 385-405.
Dhuyvetter, Kevin C.; and Blasi, Dale. “A
spreadsheet to estimate the economic
costs of a radio frequency identification (RFID) system.” Kansas State
University, 2006. See www.agmanager.
info/livestock/budgets/production/
beef/RFID%20costs.xls.
Hall, Mimi. “Animal ID plan angers some
farmers.” USA Today, Oct. 27, 2006.
See www.usatoday.com/news/nation/
2006-10-26-animal-id_x.htm.
“Tracking animals with RFID.” RFID
Gazette, Nov. 26, 2005. See www.
rfidgazette.org/healthcare/index.html.
U.S. Department of Agriculture. Animal
and Plant Health Inspection Service.
“National Animal Identification System (NAIS) Draft Strategic Plan 2005
to 2009.” April 25, 2005.

Total Annual Cost of Radio Frequency Identification System
25

$/head

www.stlouisfed.org

20

___. “National Animal Identification
System (NAIS): Strategies for
the Implementation of NAIS.”
October 2006a.

15

___. “National Animal Identification
System (NAIS): A User Guide.”
November 2006b.
Zanoni, Mary. “The ‘National Animal
Identification System’: A New Threat
to Rural Freedom.” Countryside & Small
Stock Journal, January/February 2006.
See www.countrysidemag.com/
issues/1_2006.htm#article4.

10

5

0
0

100

SOURCE: Dhuyvetter, Kevin C.; and Blasi, Dale.

200

300

400

500

Size of Herd

[13]

600

Community Profile

Tunica Lays Big Bet on the Casino Industry
Gamble pays off for Mississippi town after years of struggle
C

C

hi

C

mp

C

C

me

r

C
C
tunica arena
& expo center
Pr

C

ed
os
op

I-69

Tunica
C = casino
tunica
airport
downtown
ILLINOIS
INDIANA
MISSOURI
KENTUCKY

EIGHTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
ARKANSAS

By Glen Sparks

S

to

s
sis
mis

s

C
i ve
ir
ip p

TENNESSEE

MISSISSIPPI

Tunica, Miss.
BY THE NUMBERS

Population . .........................................City 1,089 (2005)
County 10,321 (2005)
County Labor Force...........................4,469 (June 2006)
County Unemployment Rate.......8.5 percent (June 2006)
County Per Capita Income...................$19,567 (2004)
Top Employers in Tunica County
Grand Casino............................................................2,556
Horseshoe Casino....................................................2,500
Sam’s Town Casino..................................................1,561
Gold Strike Casino...................................................1,547
Fitzgerald’s Casino...................................................1,130
The bright lights of the Grand
Casino (above) contrast sharply
with a pastoral scene several
miles west of downtown.

igns of prosperity pop up across the flat land of Tunica: nine flashy casinos, an
expo center, a new golf course, an outlet mall, a recreation center and other
attractions. Long-time residents like to brag about the “Tunica miracle.” The old
Tunica, the Tunica of the 1980s and early ’90s, seems like a long time ago. Or does it?
“There’s no way to forget,” says Clifton Johnson,
the Tunica County administrator and a life-long Tunica
resident. “I remember when there was nothing here.”
Flash back to the “old Tunica.” Residents had
depended for decades on the cotton industry for jobs;
the introduction of high-tech farming tools cut the
need for actual farmers, however. In 1991, the year
before the first casino opened, Tunica County had 15.7
percent unemployment, the highest in Mississippi and
6.8 percentage points higher than the state average.
Now, about 12 million people try their luck every
year at casinos here, making Tunica the largest casino
market in the Eighth District and the fifth largest in
the United States, according to the American Gaming
Association. Gamblers can choose from more than
14,000 slots and 400 table games and stay in one of
more than 6,300 hotel rooms.
The Tunica casino industry employs about 15,000
workers, most of them getting on-the-job training.
“The bottom line is that people have jobs,” Johnson
says. “Before, people weren’t working.”
The average annual salary of a Tunica County
resident has gone from $12,700 in the early 1990s to
$26,000 in 2004, according to the Mississippi Employment Security Commission. The county had just 2,000
jobs in 1992 and almost 17,000 jobs in 2005, according
to the security commission. Unemployment is about
one-half what it was in the pre-casino days.
Casino development also has had dramatic implications for local government finance. Through the first
[14]

10 months of 2006, the 26 casinos in Mississippi had
generated almost $245 million in tax revenue for state
and local governments, according to the Mississippi
Gaming Commission. In 2005, tax revenue totaled
about $254 million, despite Hurricane Katrina knocking
out the Gulf Coast casinos for nearly four months.
Tunica gaming revenue is subject to a 12 percent
tax: 8 percent from the state and 4 percent from
Tunica County. The Tunica County Board of Supervisors decides how to spend the local money. County
officials say that Tunica has benefited from millions of
dollars in capital projects since 1992, including:
• the 48,000-square-foot Tunica Arena and Expo
Center, which attracts more than 200,000 visitors
every year for trade shows and other events. Built in
2001, this $24 million venue already is undergoing a
$5 million expansion;
• Tunica RiverPark, which includes a museum,
aquarium, nature trails and a deck overlooking the
Mississippi River. The $26 million RiverPark has attracted
more than 100,000 visitors over the past two years;
• the Tunica Airport, which completed a $38
million expansion in 2000. Charter flights carry passengers to Tunica from at least 12 states;
• the Tunica County Library, which has doubled in
size at a cost of $1.5 million;
• the Tunica National Golf and Tennis Center, which
opened in March 2004; and
• the G.W. Henderson Sr. Recreation Complex,
which features a 38,700-square-foot county sports

The Regional Economist January 2007
n

www.stlouisfed.org

complex with an eight-lane swimming pool, basketball courts, a boxing ring and a
workout facility.
“We wouldn’t have been able to do any of this without gaming,” Johnson says.
In 1997, Tunica County cut property taxes by 25 percent. Since the first casino opened, the
county has allocated more than $100 million to road construction and improvement, $40.8
million to school improvements, $28.2 million to water and sewer upgrades, $13.2 million to
police and fire protection, and $5 million to housing rehabilitation and support services for
the elderly and disabled.
“There’s a feeling among some critics that if you make gambling legal, the entire town
will go to ruin,” says St. Louis Fed economist Tom Garrett, who has written about the gambling
industry. “That just isn’t the case.”
State lawmakers in 1990 made casino gambling legal for Mississippi counties that lie
along the Gulf Coast and on major waterways, such as the Mississippi River. The first Tunica
casino, Splash, opened in 1992. Lady Luck opened 11 months later, and other casinos followed:
Harrah’s in 1993; Treasure Bay, Hollywood, Circus Circus (now Gold Strike) and Fitzgerald’s in
1994; and so on.
Gold Strike added a 31-story hotel, the tallest building in Mississippi, in 1997. The Horseshoe Casino opened in 1995 and completed a $40 million expansion in 2000. Casino owners
built all this on their own, without a penny of tax increment financing or other subsidies.
“That’s the interesting thing, that in this age of subsidies and companies making all these
demands, the casino industry has traditionally received fewer economic development incentives than other industries,” Garrett says. “Of course, usually, there is a segment of the local
population that doesn’t support gambling, and the gambling industry is just glad to be there.”

“There has been a real vision”
Why don’t more towns—especially struggling ones, as Tunica was—open casinos, build
golf courses and outlet malls and then sit back and wait for prosperity? Well, for one thing, it
isn’t that easy.
What Tunica did is more complicated than just legalizing the lottery or putting a few
hundred slot machines on a riverboat. Tunica, about 30 miles south of Memphis, built a
destination resort. It did it in just a few years, and it did it from scratch.
Bob McQueen, the general manger of Fitzgerald’s Casino, credits forward-thinking public
officials for helping to pull off the “Tunica Miracle” that the county likes to advertise.
John Osborne, the general manager of Hollywood Casino, agrees: “There has been a real
vision if you look at the investment on infrastructure. Look at it all­—the school improvements,
the recreation centers, the museums, everything.”
The casinos continue to invest in Tunica. Fitzgerald’s plans to renovate its hotel lobby and
guest rooms, and add suites throughout the hotel; the Horseshoe hopes to put in a Starbucks
coffee shop; Resorts Casino is renovating its exterior; and the Sheraton will open a showroom to
attract variety acts.
The next phase in the Tunica transformation will be in the area of residential construction. Ask Matt McCraw, the president of Covenant Bank in downtown Tunica, whether Tunica
is just a southern suburb of Memphis and he smiles. “Tunicans don’t think so,” he says. “But
it’s coming this way.” Over the next five years, Johnson says 3,000 housing units will be
built in Tunica County. The additional housing may help bring more retail stores and chain
restaurants to Tunica, McCraw said.
Along with housing, and possibly more retail, Tunica hopes to attract more manufacturing jobs to the area. In late 2005, the county designated a 2,200-acre site for industrial
development, on a cotton field near Casino Row and the intersection of highways 61 and 304.
Johnson says the county wants to land an automobile assembly plant on the site.
In some ways, the old Tunica really does seem like a long time ago. Farming, once the
lifeblood of Tunica, is just a $70 million business—a fraction of what gambling generates.
“Some people don’t like gambling,” Johnson says, “but it has given people here some hope.
It is responsible for providing many people with a better life.”
Glen Sparks is an editor at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

[15]

Downtown Tries To Hit
the Jackpot, Too

D

owntown Tunica sits about 10 miles south of the nearest
casino. That doesn’t mean, however, that downtown doesn’t
reap the benefits of all the glitter and glamour that have made
Tunica famous over the past decade.
Since 1994, the city of Tunica has spent nearly $9 million in tax
revenue from casino gambling to build a new police station, post
office, market place, playground, Veterans’ Memorial Park and more.
“The downtown area has made tremendous progress over the
last several years,” says Matt McCraw, president of Covenant Bank
in downtown Tunica.
Tunica Mainstreet, a local improvement group, offers 50/50
façade improvement grants of up to $2,000 to local business owners. Twenty-two of the 70 downtown businesses have taken part in
the program. Now, downtown business owners hope more tourists
begin stopping by the other side of Tunica.
“You have 50,000 people coming to Tunica every day to
gamble and not enough come to downtown,” says Frank Scaggs,
a former steel fabricator in Memphis who opened Poore Frank’s
Antiques and Collectibles two years ago. “It’d be great just to get
10 percent of these folks.”
Downtown averages about 1,000 tourists every month.

TOP: Although casinos are king now in Tunica, there’s still plenty
of room for cotton, too. The harvest was in full swing last fall in
the northern part of the county. BOTTOM: The Schweikert family
of Olive Branch, Miss., visits RiverPark, a complex on the Mississippi River that includes a museum, aquarium and nature trails.

District Overviews

Louisville Zone

Louisville’s Job Growth Lags on Many Fronts
By Kristie M. Engemann and Howard J. Wall

T

he number of private nonfarm
jobs in the Louisville metro area
increased by 0.2 percent—or just
1,200—between October 2005 and
October 2006, according to estimates
from the Bureau of Labor Statistics.
This was a significant slowing of job
growth compared to the previous
12-month period, when nearly three
times as many jobs were added. The
metro area has underperformed the
country as a whole, too: Between
October 2005 and October 2006,
private nonfarm employment in the
United States rose by 1.6 percent.
On the other hand, in the 2006 calendar year through October, the number
of private-sector jobs in the Louisville
area rose by 0.7 percent at an annualized rate, indicating that job growth
has been accelerating somewhat.
As is usually the case, the employment numbers for the metro area as a
whole mask significant differences in
performance across sectors. For example, in contrast with trends in total
employment, the two largest sectors in
Louisville—trade, transportation and
utilities; and education and health—
have been generating more jobs than
previously. Also, the rate of job loss in
manufacturing has been accelerating,
while jobs have continued to be added
in all other sectors. The pattern across
industries is detailed by the figure.
Six of the eight private sectors
contributed positively to the employment growth since October 2005.
Trade, transportation and utilities—
the largest sector in Louisville—grew
by 1.6 percent since October 2005.
That percentage was larger than the
previous year’s growth rate and outpaced the 0.5 percent national-level
growth for the sector.
Louisville’s second-largest sector,
education and health services, continued to have slight positive employment growth since October 2004; the
most recent year-over-year growth
rate (0.4 percent) was unchanged from
the previous 12-month period. This
sector lagged significantly behind
the rest of the country, which saw
2.6 percent growth from October 2005
to October 2006.
Manufacturing employment fell
by 5.2 percent from October 2005 to

Private Nonfarm Employment in the Louisville Metro Area
percent
6

Y/Y% change October ’04 – October ’05
Y/Y% change October ’05 – October ’06

4
2
0
–2
–4
–6

Total

Trade,
Transportation
and Utilities

Education
and Health

Manufacturing

Professional
and Business
Services

Leisure and
Hospitality

Financial
Activities

Natural
Resources,
Mining and
Construction

Information

*

25.4%

14.4%

13.8%

13.5%

11.1%

7.6%

6.8%

1.9%

SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics and authors’ calculations; data are seasonally adjusted.
* The percentage beneath each sector represents its share of employment.

October 2006, or more than 4,000 jobs,
a sharp worsening over the previous
year’s 2.4 percent decrease. In contrast,
employment in the U.S. manufacturing
sector experienced a decrease of only
0.1 percent over the same period.
Professional and business services,
the area’s fourth-largest sector, has
been one of the strongest sectors since
October 2004. From October 2004
to October 2005, the number of jobs
rose by 3.8 percent. For the next 12
months, employment in this sector
grew by 1.6 percent. In comparison,
the U.S. sector grew by 2.7 percent
from October 2005 to October 2006;
this growth was the largest across all of
the U.S. sectors.
The fifth-largest sector in Louisville, leisure and hospitality, continued
to have gains in employment but at
a much slower pace. The year-overyear growth rate in October 2006
was 1 percent, which was half of the
previous year-over-year rate. The
U.S. sector grew by 2.6 percent since
October 2005.
The financial activities sector had
a similar experience. The most recent
year-over-year rate was 0.8 percent,
less than one-third of the previous
year-over-year rate. For the country,
the rate was 1.9 percent for the period
from October 2005 until October 2006.
Natural resources, mining and
construction had larger growth than
[16]

any other sector in Louisville since
October 2005. It is also the only sector
to have continuous upward growth
since October 2004. The year-overyear growth rate for October 2006 was
3.6 percent, and the pace for the first
10 months of 2006 was 6.3 percent.
The U.S. sector had 2.4 percent growth
since October 2005.
Louisville’s smallest sector, information, experienced no change in
employment since October 2005.
Employment in the U.S. information
sector rose 0.1 percent from October
2005 to October 2006.
Kristie M. Engemann is a senior research
associate, and Howard J. Wall is an assistant
vice president and economist, both at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

The Regional Economist January 2007
n

www.stlouisfed.org

memphis Zone

There Are Two Sides to Every (Employment Redistribution) Story!
By Joshua A. Byrge and Michael R. Pakko

T

he Memphis zone of the Eighth
Federal Reserve District includes
two metropolitan statistical areas
(MSAs) outside of Memphis itself:
Jonesboro, Ark., and Jackson, Tenn.
In many ways, these two MSAs are
very similar: They are roughly the
same size in population with similar
employment patterns and industry
compositions. They also have followed similar paths of employment
growth during the current economic expansion; both Jonesboro
and Jackson have exemplified the
national shift in employment from
goods production to service-providing sectors and have both outperformed their respective states’ rates
of employment growth.
Nationally, this employment
shift is often associated with movement from high-paying jobs to lowpaying jobs. However, this broadly
held sentiment belies a mixture of
local experiences. Jonesboro has
exceeded statewide growth of real
personal income per capita, while
Jackson has not.
During the expansion, both
Jonesboro and Jackson have redistributed employment more rapidly than
have their respective states. Between
November 2001 and October 2006,
Jonesboro’s concentration in serviceproviding employment grew by 0.4
percent annually relative to Arkansas’ statewide. Similarly, Jackson’s
concentration increased by 0.5 percent
when compared with Tennessee’s. In
addition, the concentration of goodsproviding employment in both MSAs
fell by nearly 1 percent annually relative to their respective states’.
This ability to move employment
into the expanding service sector has
allowed total employment growth in
both Jonesboro and Jackson to outpace their respective states’ since the
beginning of the expansion. Through
October 2006, private nonfarm payroll
employment in Jonesboro grew by 1.1
percent annually compared with 0.8
percent statewide. In Jackson, private
employment grew by 1.5 percent compared with 1 percent in Tennessee overall.
Although both Jonesboro and Jackson have added to their service-providing employment throughout this

Nonfarm Employment Growth by Sector
Seasonally Adjusted Monthly Data, November 2001 to October 2006
Annualized Growth Rate
3

Professional/Business
Leisure /Hospitality

2

Professional/Business

Education/Health

Leisure /Hospitality

1

Education/Health

Trade/Transport/Utilities

Trade/Transport/Utilities

0

Other

–1
–2
–3

JACKSON

JONESBORO
Total

Goods Producing

Government

Service Providing

SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics/Haver and authors’calculations.

expansion, the composition of these
additions has differed in important
ways. Through October 2006, new
service-sector growth in Jonesboro
was concentrated in the professional
and business services sector, which
grew by 7.9 percent annually compared with 4.2 percent from January
1990 through the business cycle peak
in March 2001. Professional and
business services include professional,
scientific and technical services, management of companies and enterprises, and administrative and waste
services industries. Nationally, real
earnings in these industries averaged
$9.55 per hour as of October 2006.
(The national average for goods-producing sectors was $8.93 per hour.)
In Jackson, new service-sector
employment growth occurred mainly
in leisure and hospitality services.
Employment in these services grew by
4.4 percent annually through October 2006 compared with 2.4 percent
from 1990 to March 2001. Leisure
and hospitality services include arts,
entertainment, recreation, accommodations and food services. In October
2006, real earnings in these industries
averaged $4.78 per hour—roughly half
the average hourly earnings in professional and business services.
Income growth, then, provides the
real distinction between the Jonesboro
[17]

and Jackson areas during the current
expansion. Because employment
growth in the Jackson metro area
has been concentrated in low-wage
industries, its income growth has only
matched Tennessee’s. From 2001
through 2005, real personal income
per capita increased by 1.3 percent
annually in Jackson and statewide.
The area’s leisure and hospitality
employment growth has not been
enough to bolster its overall income
growth beyond the statewide trend.
If Jackson exemplifies the national
sentiment regarding employment
reallocation, Jonesboro provides a
counterexample. Because of the area’s
exceptional employment growth in
high-wage industries, Jonesboro has
outperformed Arkansas in income
growth. From 2001 through 2005, real
personal income per capita grew by
1.7 percent in Jonesboro compared
with 1.5 percent statewide. Although
there is fear that the national shift
from a goods-producing economy to
a service-providing one will produce
lower wages, the Jonesboro experience demonstrates the potential for
higher standards of living in response
to employment reallocations.
Joshua Byrge is a research associate and Michael
Pakko is a research officer, both in the Research
Division of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

National Overview

Below-Trend Growth Is Predicted
for Most of 2007
By Kevin L. Kliesen

A

t first glance, last year’s economic performance was solid
but not spectacular. As this article
went to press in December 2006,
actual year-to-date growth of real
GDP and CPI were on track to finish
near their January 2006 consensus
forecasts of 3.3 and 2.2 percent,
respectively. By contrast, through
November, the unemployment rate
was one-half percentage point better
than expectations.
A closer inspection reveals that a
significant portion of the gains in real
GDP growth in 2006 was catalogued
in the first quarter, when output rose
at a robust 5.6 percent annual rate.
Over the following two quarters, real
GDP growth slowed to rates of 2.6
percent and 2.2 percent, respectively.
If real GDP increases by 1.7 percent
in the fourth quarter of 2006, modestly weaker than forecasters expect,
then real GDP will have increased
by at least 3 percent for the
fourth consecutive year.
The slowing in real GDP
growth over the latter
part of last year can be
attributed mainly to three
developments. First, real
short-term interest rates rose
by about two percentage points
as the Federal Open Market Committee pushed its target for the
federal funds rate from 4.25 percent
in December 2005 to 5.25 percent
in June 2006; this increase helped
to slow the demand for interestsensitive consumption goods. Second, oil prices rose unexpectedly
to more than $77 per barrel during
the summer, pushing retail gasoline
prices above $3 per gallon. Higher
energy prices not only reduced the
purchasing power of household
incomes, but also raised operating
costs for many firms and contributed
to increased financial market uncertainty. Rising gasoline prices also
decreased the demand for light trucks
and SUVs, causing manufacturers to
dramatically cut production.
The third and, perhaps, most
significant development last year was
the widely anticipated slowing in the

housing sector, which followed the
record-setting performance in 2005.
Although conventional 30-year mortgage rates rose by only about 50 basis
points over the first seven months of
the year and then dropped back to
their 2005 year-end levels, housing
starts, new home sales and median
prices of new homes fell sharply in
2006. With inventories of unsold new
homes rising to record levels, builders
significantly curtailed new construc-

tion. As a result, real residential fixed
investment subtracted a little more
than 1.75 percentage points from real
GDP growth in the second and third
quarters of 2006.
Strains in the housing sector
continue to dominate the economic
headlines, but the big picture looks
better. Solid labor market conditions
and growth of business capital outlays remain healthy, while the prospects for continued strong growth
of U.S. exports appear good. Longterm inflation expectations remain
relatively low and stable, and crude
oil and gasoline prices have fallen
significantly since August. Despite
these favorable developments, there
[18]

are some areas of concern. Two
stand out.
Continued elevated rates of
underlying price pressures are the
first area of concern. The FOMC
noted at its meeting of Oct. 24-25,
2006, that “current rates of core
inflation remained undesirably high,”
according to the minutes. Although
the FOMC expects core inflation to
“moderate gradually,” the timing and
extent of that moderation is “quite
uncertain.” Complicating matters is
the recent slowing in labor productivity growth in the face of an upswing
in the growth of labor compensation.
While worrisome, the consensus
forecast is that the CPI will increase
2.5 percent in 2007. Excluding food
and energy prices (core), the consensus expects CPI inflation to
average 2.4 percent in 2007.
The second area of concern is the potential threat
of much weaker growth in
real GDP. This threat is manifested by the inverted Treasury
yield curve, which has preceded every recession since
the end of World War II. One
well-known model based on the yield
curve posits a more-than-50-percent
probability of a recession sometime
during 2007. Other economists, such
as Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke, have
argued that global capital flows and
a reduced risk from holding longerterm securities have minimized the
yield curve’s importance as a business
cycle indicator.
Although business cycle peaks
and troughs remain difficult to
predict, most forecasters see a much
lower probability of a recession in
2007. Instead, they generally expect
below-trend real GDP growth
through much of 2007 and, then,
trend-like growth (3 to 3.5 percent)
over the latter part of 2007 and
into 2008.
Kevin L. Kliesen is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Joshua A. Byrge
provided research assistance.

The Regional Economist January 2007
n

www.stlouisfed.org

National and District Data

Selected indicators of the national economy
and banking, agricultural and business conditions in the Eighth Federal Reserve District

Commercial Bank Performance Ratios
third quarter 2006

U.S. Banks
by Asset Size

ALL

$100
million$300
million

Return on Average Assets*

1.35

1.25

1.16

1.38

1.27

1.40

1.34

1.36

Net Interest Margin*

3.46

4.34

4.34

4.30

4.32

4.03

4.17

3.19

Nonperforming Loan Ratio

0.74

0.75

0.79

0.64

0.72

0.58

0.65

0.78

Loan Loss Reserve Ratio

1.21

1.25

1.28

1.24

1.26

1.26

1.26

1.19

less than
$300
million

$300
million$1 billion

less
than
$1 billion

$1billion$15
billion

Return on Average Assets *

Net Interest Margin *

1.23
1.20
1.19
1.18
1.08
1.13
1.06
0.99
1.24
1.29
1.21
1.15
1.24
1.25
1.38
1.24

0

.25

.50

.75

1

1.25

1.50

3.91
3.87
4.14
4.20
3.65
3.74
3.65
3.49
4.08
3.78
4.14
4.13
4.11
3.96
3.42
3.57

Eighth District
Arkansas
Illinois
Indiana
Kentucky
Mississippi
Missouri
Tennessee

2

percent

1

Nonperforming Loan Ratio
0.77
0.80
0.85
0.92
0.89
0.90
0.92

2.5

3

Arkansas
Illinois
Indiana

1.17

Kentucky

0.69

Missouri
0.90
0.96

.75

1

4

4.5

0.94
0.91

Tennessee

1.25

3.5

1.24
1.31
1.38
1.47
1.21
1.24
1.36
1.47
1.17
1.49
1.26
1.36
1.36
1.38

Mississippi
0.58

.5

2

Eighth District

0.44
0.46

.25

1.5

Loan Loss Reserve Ratio

0.78
0.84

0

More
less
than
than
$15 billion $15 billion

1.5

Third Quarter 2006
NOTE: Data include only that portion of the state within Eighth District boundaries.
SOURCE: FFIEC Reports of Condition and Income for all insured U.S. commercial banks.
*Annualized data

0

.25

.50

.75

1

1.25

Third Quarter 2005
For additional banking and regional data, visit our web site at:
www.research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/

1.50

1.75

The Regional Economist January 2007
n

www.stlouisfed.org

Regional Economic Indicators
Nonfarm Employment Growth*

year-over-year percent change

third quarter 2006
Total Nonagricultural
Natural Resources/Mining
Construction
Manufacturing
Trade/Transportation/Utilities
Information
Financial Activities
Professional & Business Services
Education & Health Services
Leisure & Hospitality
Other Services
Government

united
states

eighth
district

arkansas

illinois

indiana

1.4%
8.8
2.7
0.2
0.3
–0.3
2.3
2.7
2.3
1.9
0.2
0.9

1.0%
3.9
2.4
–1.0
1.2
–0.9
1.3
2.2
1.6
1.6
0.4
0.6

1.2%
5.5
2.0
–1.9
1.1
1.8
1.9
3.9
2.2
2.1
1.7
1.1

1.1%
0.7
2.7
–1.4
1.0
–1.5
1.9
3.3
1.2
2.8
0.2
–0.3

0.5%
1.9
1.1
0.4
0.2
1.4
1.6
0.2
1.0
0.6
0.5
0.2

900

III/2006

II/2006

III/2005

4.7%
5.3
4.6
5.4
5.8
7.4
4.9
5.4

4.6%
5.2
4.7
5.0
5.8
7.4
4.6
5.5

5.0%
4.9
5.7
5.5
6.3
8.3
5.2
5.5

Illinois
Indiana
Kentucky
Mississippi
Missouri
Tennessee

missouri

tennessee

1.0%
6.8
1.3
–1.4
1.1
0.0
0.9
2.0
2.0
2.5
-0.4
0.6

1.2%
6.1
9.1
–0.7
2.0
–3.5
–0.6
4.2
2.2
–4.5
1.4
2.0

0.9%
–5.6
1.5
–1.6
1.7
–2.9
1.0
1.3
1.7
0.8
0.4
1.3

1.2%
4.0
2.6
–1.3
1.7
0.3
0.6
1.1
2.2
3.2
0.9
0.9

millions of dollars

percent

Arkansas

mississippi

Adjusted Gross Casino Revenue*

Unemployment Rates

United States

kentucky

Recession as determined by the
National Bureau of Economic Research

mississippi

800
700

indiana
600
500

illinois
400

missouri
300
SOURCE: State gaming commissions.

200
1999Q3

2000Q3

2001Q3

2002Q3

2003Q3

2004Q3

2005Q3

2006Q3

NOTE: Adjusted Gross Revenue = Total wagers minus player winnings. Native
American casino revenue (Mississippi only) is not included. In 2006 dollars.

*

third quarter

second quarter

Housing Permits

Real Personal Income ‡

year-over-year percent change
in year-to-date levels

year-over-year percent change

–10.8
–10.5

–0.5
–5.2

–21.3
–25.4

United States

7.1

10.1

Arkansas

2.0

Illinois

2.0

Indiana

–2.5

24.0

–2.1
–7.1

7.8
0.5
2.9

–35 –30 –25 –20 –15 –10 –5

2006

0

3.8
2.4

2.1

Mississippi

3.2
3.9

2.4

Missouri

3.7

2.3

Tennessee

5 10 15 20 25 30 percent

4.1

1.3

Kentucky

–7.8

3.8

2.8

2.9

0

2005

1

2

2006
‡

3.4

3

4

5

2005

NOTE: Real personal income is personal income divided by the PCE chained price index.

The Regional Economist January 2007
n

www.stlouisfed.org

Major Macroeconomic Indicators

Consumer Price Inflation

Real GDP Growth

percent

percent

8

5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5

6
4
2
0
–2

01

Additional charts can be found on the web version of The Regional Economist.
Go to www.stlouisfed.org/publications/re/2007/a/pdf/01_07_data.pdf.

02

03

04

05

06

NOTE: Each bar is a one-quarter growth rate (annualized); the green line is the
10-year growth rate.

all items

all items, less
food and energy

Nov.

01

02

03

04

05

06

NOTE: Percent change from a year earlier

Civilian Unemployment Rate

Interest Rates

percent

percent
7

6.5

6

6.0

5

5.5

4

5.0

3

4.5

fed funds
target

2

4.0

1

Nov.

3.5

01

02

03

04

05

0

06

NOTE: Beginning in January 2003, household data reflect revised population
controls used in the Current Population Survey.

Nov.

three-month t-bill
01

02

03

04

05

06

NOTE: Except for the fed funds target, which is end-of-period, data are
monthly averages of daily data.

Farm Sector Indicators
U.S. Agricultural Trade

Farming Cash Receipts

billions of dollars
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0

billions of dollars
130
125
120
115
crops
110
livestock
105
100
95
90
Aug.
85
06
01
02
03
04
05

exports

imports
trade balance
Oct.

01

02

04

03

05

06

NOTE: Data are aggregated over the past 12 months.

NOTE: Data are aggregated over the past 12 months.

U.S. Crop and Livestock Prices
index 1990-92=100
145
135

crops

125
115
105
95

livestock

85
75
1992

Nov.

93

94

95

96

97

98

99

[19]

00

01

02

03

04

05

06