View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

REGIONAL ECONOMIC
DEVELOPMENT
VO LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

Economics of Ethanol:
Costs, Benefits, and Future Prospects of Biofuels
Proceedings of a conference co-hosted by the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
and the Weidenbaum Center on the Economy, Government, and Public Policy
and the International Center for Advanced Renewable Energy & Sustainability,
Washington University in St. Louis, November 14, 2008

The U.S. Ethanol Industry
Mark D. Stowers
Roles for Evolving Markets, Policies, and Technology
Improvements in U.S. Corn Ethanol Industry Development
Paul W. Gallagher
Economic and Environmental Impacts of
U.S. Corn Ethanol Production and Use
Douglas G. Tiffany
The Impact of the Ethanol Boom on Rural America
Jason Henderson
Panel Discussion: The Future of Biofuel
Jerry Taylor, Rick Tolman, Nicholas Kalaitzandonakes,
James Kaufman, Wyatt Thompson, and Seth Meyer
Commentaries
Martha A. Schlicher, Max Schulz, Seth Meyer

REGIONAL ECONOMIC
DEVELOPMENT

Economics of Ethanol: Costs, Benefits,
and Future Prospects of Biofuels

1
Editor’s Introduction
Thomas A. Garrett

Director of Research

Robert H. Rasche
Deputy Director of Research

3

Cletus C. Coughlin

The U.S. Ethanol Industry

Editor-in Chief

Thomas A. Garrett

Mark D. Stowers

Center for Regional Economics—8th District (CRE8)
Director

Howard J. Wall
Subhayu Bandyopadhyay
Cletus C. Coughlin
Thomas A. Garrett
Rubén Hernández-Murillo
Natalia A. Kolesnikova
Michael R. Pakko

12
Roles for Evolving Markets, Policies,
and Technology Improvements in
U.S. Corn Ethanol Industry Development
Paul W. Gallagher

34
Commentary
Martha A. Schlicher

Managing Editor

Lydia H. Johnson

42

Editor

Graphic Designer

Economic and Environmental Impacts of
U.S. Corn Ethanol Production and Use

Donna M. Stiller

Douglas G. Tiffany

Judith A. Ahlers

The views expressed are those of the individual authors and
do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or
the Board of Governors.

59
Commentary
Max Schulz

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

i

65
The Impact of the Ethanol Boom on Rural America
Jason Henderson

74
Commentary
Seth Meyer

78
Panel Discussion: The Future of Biofuel
Jerry Taylor, Rick Tolman, Nicholas Kalaitzandonakes,
James Kaufman, Wyatt Thompson, and Seth Meyer

Regional Economic Development is published occasionally by the Research Division of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis and may be
accessed through our web site: research.stlouisfed.org/regecon/publications/. All nonproprietary and nonconfidential data and programs
for the articles written by Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis staff and published in Regional Economic Development also are available to
our readers on this web site.
General data can be obtained through FRED (Federal Reserve Economic Data), a database providing U.S. economic and financial data and
regional data for the Eighth Federal Reserve District. You may access FRED through our web site: research.stlouisfed.org/fred.
Articles may be reprinted, reproduced, published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author
name(s), and full citation are included. Please send a copy of any reprinted, published, or displayed materials to George Fortier, Research
Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, MO 63166-0442; george.e.fortier@stls.frb.org. Please note: Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Please
contact the Research Division at the above address to request permission.
© 2009, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
ISSN 1930-1979

ii

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Contributing Authors
Paul W. Gallagher
Iowa State University
paulg@iastate.edu

Max Schulz
Manhattan Institute for Policy Research
mschulz@manhattan-institute.org

Thomas A. Garrett
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
tom.a.garrett@stls.frb.org

Mark D. Stowers
POET
Mark.Stowers@POET.COM

Jason Henderson
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City–
Omaha Branch
Jason.henderson@kc.frb.org

Jerry Taylor
Cato Institute
jtaylor@cato.org

James Kaufman
University of Missouri–Columbia
kaufmanjd@missouri.edu
Nicholas Kalaitzandonakes
University of Missouri–Columbia
KalaitzandonakesN@missouri.edu
Seth Meyer
University of Missouri–Columbia
MeyerSe@missouri.edu

Wyatt Thompson
University of Missouri–Columbia
ThompsonW@missouri.edu
Douglas G. Tiffany
University of Minnesota
tiffa002@umn.edu
Rick Tolman
National Corn Growers Association
tolman@ncga.com

Martha A. Schlicher
GTL Resources
marthaschlicher@gtlresources.com

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

iii

Editor’s Introduction
Thomas A. Garrett

T

he Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis cohosted a one-day conference, “Economics
of Ethanol: Costs, Benefits, and Future
Prospects of Biofuels,” on November 14,
2008. Cohosts included the Weidenbaum Center
on the Economy, Government, and Public Policy
and the International Center for Advanced
Renewable Energy & Sustainability at Washington
University in St. Louis. The conference provided
a nontechnical description of the major issues
surrounding ethanol in the United States.1 Academics, industry leaders, and policy experts shared
opposing views on the role of government in the
ethanol industry, the long-run viability of the
industry, and the economic costs and benefits of
increased ethanol production. The conference
format consisted of presentations by academic
scholars and a panel discussion involving policy
experts and industry leaders. This issue of Regional
Economic Development contains the papers, discussions, and panelist remarks from the conference.

THE U.S. ETHANOL INDUSTRY
Mark Stowers, vice president of research and
development for POET, a company that produces
ethanol, provides the keynote address. Stowers
discusses the growth in the ethanol industry over
the past several decades and the current status of
the industry, the economic benefits of ethanol, the
1

Additional information about the conference can be found at
http://research.stlouisfed.org/conferences/ethanol/index.html.

effect of government policy on ethanol and competing energy markets, and the prospects for alternative ethanol sources in addition to corn ethanol.
He concludes with five factors critical to the widespread use of ethanol in the United States, including
research and development, government support,
and industry infrastructure.

THE PROFITABILITY OF CORN
ETHANOL PROCESSING
In the first paper of the conference, Paul
Gallagher examines issues critical to the profitability of corn ethanol processing, including the production and scale of corn ethanol processing and
efficient production processes. Gallagher discusses
how government policy and technological development can lead to a mature and profitable corn
ethanol industry. He also describes several ways
that reorganization of the ethanol industry could
lead to greater profitability over the next several
decades. Lastly, Gallagher outlines several strategies ethanol producers can use to reduce costs or
increase revenues to maintain profitability.
In her discussion, Martha Schlicher describes
the characteristics of a “perfect” fuel and suggests
that ethanol has these characteristics. Schlicher
discusses the evolution of the ethanol and alternative energy markets over the past several decades
and argues that various government policies have
contributed to the slow adoption of alternative fuels
such as ethanol. Schlicher concludes by outlining
several ways that changes in government support

Thomas A. Garrett is an assistant vice president and economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economic Development, 2009, 5(1), pp. 1-2.

© 2009, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced,
published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

1

Garrett

would lead to a more viable and sustainable ethanol
industry in the United States.

THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES
OF CORN ETHANOL AS A FUEL
SOURCE
Douglas Tiffany examines the environmental
effects of ethanol production, ethanol’s energy
balance with fossil fuels, the impact of ethanol
production on food prices, and the effect of ethanol
on farmers’ production decisions. Tiffany also compares the subsidy rate of corn ethanol with that of
other fuels and discusses changing land-use patterns as a result of ethanol production. He argues
that production of corn ethanol and an increased
demand for corn can pose environmental challenges
if care is not exercised when bringing additional
lands back into crop production.
In his discussion, Max Schulz acknowledges
the validity of many points raised by Tiffany, but
argues that the large government subsidies for
ethanol do not create enough benefits to justify
their cost. Specifically, Schulz questions the use of
ethanol mandates because it is doubtful that significant volumes of our national oil consumption
can be displaced with ethanol. He further cites a
global increase in food prices and greenhouse gas
emissions as reasons the benefits of our ethanol
policies are not worth their costs.

THE IMPACT OF THE ETHANOL
BOOM ON RURAL AMERICA
Jason Henderson explores the impact of the
ethanol boom on rural communities. Although the
large ethanol subsidies have increased economic
growth and development in rural agricultural communities, the question remains whether ethanol is
a viable strategy for continued economic development in rural areas. Henderson presents evidence
that although crop prices have risen, the ethanol
boom explains only some of the national increase in
crop prices, net returns, and land values. The geographic concentration of ethanol production has led
to some spatial changes in crop prices and livestock

2

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

production. Henderson argues that the ethanol
industry has helped nonfarm economic growth,
but the gains have been less than initially claimed.
In his discussion, Seth Meyer focuses on the
effects of ethanol production on commodity prices
and the role that federal policy plays in the market
for ethanol and other biofuels. He points out that
measuring the effect of ethanol production on
commodity prices is more difficult than some
acknowledge. It is clear that ethanol and other
biofuels have had an effect on commodity prices,
but estimates vary considerably from a negligible
impact to attributing most of the rise in prices to
increased ethanol and biofuel production. Thus,
the impact of ethanol on rural communities is
deserving of more research. Meyer also argues
that the success of ethanol as a viable industry is
dependent on appropriate federal policies.

PANEL DISCUSSION:
THE FUTURE OF BIOFUEL
The final session of the conference, a panel
discussion, focuses on the future of biofuels. The
panelists are Jerry Taylor from the Cato Institute,
Rick Tolman from the National Corn Growers
Association, and Nicholas Kalaitzandonakes from
the University of Missouri–Columbia. They discuss
the political economy of ethanol subsidies and
regulation, whether ethanol can be a viable industry
in the United States, and the prospects for other
biofuels, such as those made from switchgrass
and algae. The panelists represent different views
on the role of government in ethanol production
and the long-term viability of the industry. The
panelists’ remarks and opposing viewpoints
sparked lively audience discussion.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
I thank the authors, discussants, and panelists
for their participation. I also thank the Weidenbaum
Center and the International Center for Advanced
Renewable Energy & Sustainability at Washington
University in St. Louis for their professional partnership in organizing this event.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

The U.S. Ethanol Industry
Mark D. Stowers
Ethanol is vital to achieving greater American energy independence. It is today’s only viable and
available fuel that can be substituted for gasoline. Unlike oil, ethanol is renewable—it will never
run out. As science moves from making ethanol from corn to producing it from corn cobs and other
plant materials, ethanol will continue to be a sustainable and effective energy solution for the world.
America’s dependence on foreign oil causes enormous problems for Americans every day—raising
the prices on everything from gas to groceries and sending money and jobs overseas. This article
summarizes the state of the ethanol industry. (JEL Q20, Q21, Q28, Q40, Q42)
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economic Development, 2009, 5(1), pp. 3-11.

P

OET, headquartered in Sioux Falls,
South Dakota, is the largest ethanol
producer in the world. POET is an
established leader in the biorefining
industry through project development, design and
construction, research and development, plant
management, ownership, and product marketing.
The 20-year-old company has built 32 ethanol
production facilities and currently manages 26
plants in the United States while marketing more
than 1.5 billion gallons of ethanol and 4 million
tons of distillers’ grains annually.
Since 2000, POET has constructed 21 greenfield
ethanol plants in seven states and completed six
major expansions of existing facilities. The value
of POET’s design-build contracts since 2000 has
exceeded $1 billion. Each project has been successfully designed, built, and managed by POET. These
projects have resulted in the addition of more than
one billion gallons of new fuel ethanol capacity
per year.
The POET development model is unique. It
started on the Broin family farm in Minnesota and
has spurred the growth of investment by thousands
of farmers and individual Main Street investors.

POET’s business model is to invest in, develop,
design, construct, and manage ethanol production
facilities. However, the facilities are independent
limited liability companies (LLCs) owned by POET,
individuals, and local farmers that provide the corn
feedstock. POET employs the general manager and
on-site technical engineer at each facility. All other
employees are employed by the LLC. POET also has
representation on the board of directors at each
plant.
By leveraging business size and position, POET
has created the most successful ethanol facilities
in the industry. POET has achieved breakthrough
progress beyond ethanol processing, extracting
extraordinary new value from each kernel of corn.

ETHANOL INDUSTRY
BACKGROUND
The ethanol industry now produces more than
10 billion gallons of fuel ethanol, representing 7
percent of the gasoline supply, and 70 percent of
all gasoline sold contains some ethanol. Ethanol
contributes more than $45 billion to the U.S. gross

Mark D. Stowers is vice president of research and development at POET.

© 2009, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced,
published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

3

Stowers

domestic product annually, has created more than
238,000 jobs, and has contributed $12 billion to
consumers through lower transportation fuel prices.
During 2007, 6.5 billion gallons of domestically
produced ethanol displaced 228 million barrels of
imported oil (Renewable Fuels Association [RFA],
2008a). As of February 1, 2009, 180 ethanol plants
have been constructed with a production capacity
of 12.2 billion gallons with an additional 1.5 billion
gallons of capacity under construction. About 1.9
billion gallons of capacity is currently idled due
to poor market conditions (RFA, 2008b).

ETHANOL BENEFITS
Ethanol has the highest octane rating of any
fuel and keeps today’s high-compression engines
running smoothly. E10 (which is 90 percent gasoline and 10 percent ethanol) is a cleaner-burning
fuel than straight gasoline. Ethanol-blended fuels
do not leave gummy deposits on the fuel system
and prevent wintertime problems by acting as gasline antifreeze. Since the 1980s, all automaker warranties have allowed the use of E10. Ethanol has
been criticized for having fewer British thermal
units (BTUs) per gallon than gasoline. However,
ethanol’s combustion efficiency compensates for
some of its lower energy content. Ethanol’s 113 to
115 octane rating compared with unleaded gasoline’s 87 allows high-compression engines to perform just as well on fewer BTUs. The ethanol blends
used today (E10 and E30) have little impact on fuel
economy or vehicle performance.
Using ethanol as a vehicle fuel provides local
and global benefits: It reduces emissions of harmful
pollutants and greenhouse gases (GHGs). Ethanol
is the only currently available solution for reducing
GHG emissions from the current fleet of vehicles.
Ethanol results in fewer GHG emissions than gasoline and is fully biodegradable, unlike some fuel
additives. Production of ethanol requires one-third
less fossil-fuel energy than gasoline, reducing
GHG emissions. The higher the amount of ethanol
blended with gasoline, the lower the GHG emissions. In 2007, ethanol use in the United States
reduced carbon dioxide (CO2 )–equivalent GHG
emissions by approximately 10.1 million tons,
4

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

which is equal to removing more than 1.5 million
cars from America’s roadways (Wang, 2007).
Life-cycle analysis compares CO2 emissions
produced during the entire process of ethanol and
gasoline production (field to wheels and wells to
wheels, respectively). For ethanol these steps
include growing the feedstock crops, transporting
them to a production plant, producing the ethanol,
distributing it, and burning it in vehicles. For gasoline these include extracting crude oil from the
ground, transporting it to a refinery, refining the
crude oil into gasoline, distributing the gasoline,
and burning it in vehicles. Studies have shown
that, when these entire life cycles are considered,
using corn-based ethanol instead of gasoline reduces
GHG emissions by 49 to 58 percent, depending on
the source of energy for ethanol production (Liska
et al., 2009).

ETHANOL PRODUCTION
EFFICIENCY
Ethanol production efficiency has increased
dramatically since the late 1980s when corn starch
required cooking, enzymes inefficiently converted
starch to sugars, and fermentation ethanol titers
were 10 percent. Recently, the Argonne National
Laboratory compared ethanol plants built in 2006
and 2001. Results showed a 6.4 percent increase
in ethanol yields, 21.8 percent reduction in energy
use, and 26.6 percent decrease in water consumption with the newer plants (Wang, 2007). Today
POET ethanol plants produce ethanol at titers of
20 percent without cooking the starch and with
enzymes that efficiently process starch for pennies
per gallon of ethanol produced.

MID-LEVEL ETHANOL BLENDS
With the Energy Independence and Security
Act of 2007 the U.S. government mandated a gradual increase in the country’s use of renewable fuels
such as ethanol until 2022, when the mandate
reaches 36 billion gallons. However, because current
government regulation restricts the ethanol blend
to E10, ethanol producers will hit a regulatory cap—
although they can produce enough ethanol to dis-

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Stowers

place more than 10 percent of the fuel supply, no
more than 10 percent may be used. Ethanol producers expect to hit this regulatory cap in 2009.
Multiple comprehensive studies have evaluated the effects of ethanol-gasoline blends above
10 percent ethanol, including, specifically, E15
and blends as high as E85. These studies involved
over 100 vehicles, 85 vehicle and engine types, and
33 fuel-dispensing pumps and included a yearlong
drivability test and over 5,500 hours of materials
compatibility testing. One such study, West et al.
(2008), a peer-reviewed report by the Oak Ridge
National Laboratory for the Department of Energy
(DOE), studied the effects of E15 and E20 on motor
vehicles and small nonroad engines. This study
compared E15 and E20 with traditional gasoline
and concluded there were no significant changes
in vehicle tailpipe emissions, vehicle drivability,
or small nonroad engine emissions with either
ethanol blend.

ETHANOL AND GOVERNMENT
POLICY
Government support for ethanol levels the playing field in the heavily subsidized energy sector and
is designed to reduce U.S. dependence on foreign
oil, improve the environment, and foster rural
development.
The Volumetric Ethanol Excise Tax Credit
(VEETC) or “blenders’ credit” was created as part
of the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004. VEETC
provides oil companies with an economic incentive to blend ethanol with gasoline. The tax credit
totals 51 cents per gallon of pure ethanol; for example, 5.1 cents per gallon for ethanol in E10 (10 percent ethanol in gasoline). The VEETC provides
market access for ethanol and provides significant
benefits to U.S. taxpayers. In 2007 the blenders’
credits totaled approximately $3.3 million. In the
same year, the ethanol industry contributed $47.6
billion to the nation’s gross domestic product, created more than 200,000 jobs, and generated an estimated $4.6 billion in tax revenue for the federal
government. In addition, because of higher prices
for agricultural commodities, expected direct-

support payments to farmers (as provided through
the Farm Bill) was approximately $8 billion less
than expected (Urbanchuk, 2008). The VEETC is
currently authorized through December 31, 2010.
U.S. ethanol imports are subject to a 2.5 percent
ad valorem tariff, which is quite modest compared
with the tariffs that other countries impose. For
example, Brazil levies a 20 percent ad valorem
tariff on ethanol imports. All ethanol blended
with gasoline in the United States qualifies for the
blenders’ credit, regardless of the country of origin
of the ethanol. To offset this and ensure that taxpayer dollars do not support foreign ethanol production, U.S. ethanol imports from non-Caribbean
Basin countries are subject to a 54 cent per gallon
secondary tariff. This tariff is in effect through
December 31, 2010.
If the secondary tariff on ethanol imports were
to be eliminated, ethanol imports would jeopardize
the domestic ethanol industry that is already keeping gas prices lower. Many ethanol critics have
suggested that the tariff should be discontinued.
The removal of the secondary tariff would be harmful to the corn-based ethanol industry and also
have a devastating impact on the developing cellulosic ethanol industry in that investors would likely
not fund further infrastructure development. It is
critical for the cellulosic ethanol industry to have
a market opportunity while it is in its earliest
development stages. If the United States were to
subsidize foreign ethanol, it would significantly
diminish the promise of cellulosic ethanol.
The Renewable Fuel Standard (RFS) was part
of the Energy Independence and Security Act of
2007 and sets annual requirements for the amount
of renewable fuels produced and used in motor
vehicles. Under the bill, the RFS required 9 billion
gallons of renewable fuels in 2008 and progressively
increases to 36 billion gallons by 2022. Further, the
bill requires advanced biofuels, such as cellulosic
ethanol, to become an increasing portion of renewable fuels: from 3 billion gallons in 2016 to 21 billion gallons in 2022.
The RFS is important to the ethanol industry
because ethanol is the only available near-term
solution to two of our country’s most pressing
challenges: energy security and global warming.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

5

Stowers

Despite the obvious benefits, the RFS is needed to
ensure that ethanol has market access. Without
the RFS, it is highly unlikely that biofuels would
ever be much more than a blending agent because
oil companies would rather use their own product.
The RFS also helps to ensure a market for cellulosic ethanol. It calls for two-thirds of renewable
fuels to be from advanced biofuels like cellulosic
ethanol by 2010. Cellulosic ethanol already has a
steep hill to climb to be commercially viable.
Without an ensured market, it would be even
more difficult.

MEETING A SIGNIFICANT
AMOUNT OF DEMAND
THROUGH CORN ETHANOL
Corn has been the predominant feedstock for
the production of ethanol, and its main advantages
are that (i) its abundance and oversupply result
in lower costs for food, feed and, fuel products;
(ii) starch, which is the major component of the
corn kernel, is relatively easy to process; and (iii)
the infrastructure for corn distribution is well
established.
Seed companies’ ability to continually improve
corn yields represents the most important factor for
corn’s long-term viability as an ethanol feedstock.
Based on the current corn yield of 150 bushels an
acre (bu/acre) and historical trends for corn yield
growth, projected corn yields are 180 bu/acre in
2022 and 200 bu/acre in 2030. Monsanto, for example, projects corn yields of 210 to 250 bu/acre by
2022 and 265 to 300 bu/acre by 2030 (Begemann,
2008). Using 300 bu/acre and the current 86.5
million U.S. corn acres, the projected annual corn
production level for 2030 would exceed 26 billion
bushels—double the 2007 corn production. If corn
demand for food and feed in 2030 were to increase
by 40 percent from the 2007 level, there would be
enough corn to meet this demand and increase
corn ethanol production by over 425 percent from
the 2007 level—to 48.6 billion gallons (assuming
a 6.9 percent increase in ethanol-processing efficiency by then).
6

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

COMMITMENT TO CELLULOSIC
ETHANOL
According to a recent U.S. Department of
Commerce International Trade Administration
Study, “Energy in 2020: Assessing the Economic
Effects of Commercialization of Cellulosic Ethanol”
(Osborne, 2007), by 2020 there will be enough cellulosic feedstock available in the United States to produce nearly 50 billion gallons of cellulosic ethanol.
At this production rate, over 1.2 million barrels per
day of crude oil could be displaced while creating
over 54,000 jobs in U.S. agriculture. In more practical terms, at this level of ethanol production the
United States could eliminate all oil purchases
from the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting
Countries (OPEC) and the Middle East—eliminating the daily export of 1.4 billion U.S. dollars to
overseas oil producers (based on oil priced at $120
per barrel).
Along with economic benefits, cellulosic
ethanol offers significant environmental benefits.
Each gallon of gasoline produces 25 pounds of CO2 equivalent GHG emissions. By comparison, cellulosic ethanol reduces GHG emissions by a little
more than 21 pounds of CO2 per gallon—that’s an
85 percent reduction. To monetize that benefit we
can assign a value of $20 per ton of CO2 -equivalent
GHG emissions based on current European futures
prices for CO2 equivalents. Accordingly, the use of
a little more than 20 billion gallons of cellulosic
ethanol would reduce the cost of GHG emissions
by about 19 cents per gallon, or about $2.5 billion
per year. Cellulosic ethanol’s value to the U.S. economy, the environment, and national security is
substantial. At POET we believe that cellulosic
ethanol is real and achievable.
POET’s commitment to cellulosic ethanol
started eight years ago when our company developed proprietary fractionation and raw starch
hydrolysis technologies. Specifically, these technologies allow POET to process corn starch more
efficiently and economically. Our proprietary corn
fractionation technology, or BFrac as it is referred
to in the industry, allows the separation of the corn
starch from the corn germ and corn fiber, the cellulosic casing that protects the corn kernel.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Stowers

Another proprietary process called Broin
Project X (BPX) processes the starch without cooking, resulting in (i) an 8 to 12 percent reduction in
BTU consumption, (ii) greater conversion of corn
starch to ethanol, and (iii) a high-nutrient density
animal feed product, which we call Dakota Gold.
This technology uses less fossil fuel than previous
processes, yields more ethanol per acre of corn, and
provides an animal feed product that can replace
corn. The corn germ can be processed to produce
crude or refined corn oil, which has multiple end
uses ranging from cooking to biodiesel. The corn
fiber, due to its high sugar content, can be processed
to ethanol.
Important points to note about corn ethanol production plants are that they are (i) highly efficient,
(ii) actually produce more than just ethanol, and
(iii) serve as sources for cellulosic feedstocks.
POET began its efforts to develop cellulosic
ethanol technology in 2002 with one of the first
biorefinery grants from the DOE. The effort focused
on what was termed then a “second-generation dry
mill biorefinery,” which sought to incorporate corn
fractionation into a dry mill ethanol plant, processing the cellulosic corn fiber into ethanol and producing a higher-protein animal feed product. Quite
honestly, this effort produced mixed results. POET
was able to incorporate a corn fractionation system
into a dry mill ethanol plant and to produce a
higher-protein animal feed product, but the ability
to process corn fiber to ethanol proved more difficult because of limited ability to break down the
corn fiber into usable sugars and the lack of known
microorganisms to ferment sugar into ethanol.
In 2006 a new strategy for cellulosic ethanol
production was developed. The strategy uses existing corn ethanol plants to (i) capitalize on existing
infrastructure (utilities, roads, rail lines, materials
handling, and so forth); (ii) focus on corn cobs as
the primary cellulosic feedstock to use the existing
farmer (and often investor) network to collect cobs;
and (iii) eliminate the use of fossil fuels by processing waste streams (that is, by-products of the
cellulose-to-ethanol process) to generate energy
for the entire plant. This “bolt-on” approach is
designed to use the expansive ethanol base to enable
rapid adoption of the cellulosic ethanol process.
POET is implementing this strategy through Project

LIBERTY, which is the creation of an integrated
corn cellulose biorefinery.
Project LIBERTY will transform the POET
biorefinery in Emmetsburg, Iowa, from a conventional corn dry mill ethanol plant into an integrated
corn-to-ethanol and cellulose-to-ethanol biorefinery.
Once complete the facility will produce 125 million
gallons of ethanol per year, 25 of which will come
from a feedstock of corn fiber and corn cobs. Also,
the facility will produce 80,000 tons of Dakota
Gold Corn Germ Dehydrated and 100,000 tons of
Dakota Gold HP animal feeds annually. Project
LIBERTY will produce 11 percent more ethanol
from a bushel of corn through the corn fractionation
process and 27 percent more ethanol from an acre
of corn through the use of corn cobs. In addition,
Project LIBERTY will reduce the biorefinery’s need
for fossil fuels by nearly 100 percent. The total cost
of the project will exceed $200 million. It will create
at least 30 new jobs at the facility, but more importantly, Project LIBERTY will demonstrate the
profitability of cellulosic ethanol technology on a
replicable commercial scale. POET’s longer-term
plans are to roll out this technology suite to other
existing dry mills or new grassroots biorefineries.
As partners with POET in Project LIBERTY, the DOE
and the Iowa Power Fund will contribute up to 50
percent or $100 million in project costs. Project
LIBERTY is expected to be operational in late 2011.
Cellulosic feedstocks can be agricultural
residues such as corn cobs, rice straw, or corn
stover (leaves, stalks, and cobs left in the fields
after harvest). They can also be wood fibers such
as forestry wastes or wood wastes or energy crops
such as switchgrass or Miscanthus grass. Cellulosic
feedstocks could also be collected from municipal
waste. POET has selected corn cobs as the first
cellulosic feedstock for the production of cellulosic
ethanol because they offer significant technical,
environmental, and economic advantages. They
are typically left in the field as corn stover after
the harvest of the corn kernels and are easy to separate because they are heavier than the stalk. They
are rich in sugars yet can be removed from the field
with little environmental impact because they offer
little value as fertilizer. And they can be collected
relatively easily by the same farmers who provide
the corn grain to the ethanol plant.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

7

Stowers

Through work with collaborators and in particular the enzyme companies, POET continually
improves the cellulosic ethanol process. Recent
work at POET resulted in a process to break down
corn cobs into simple sugars, resulting in a 60 percent increase in the yield of ethanol from cobs compared with just a few months earlier. With this
process, corn-cob feedstocks are more easily
digested by enzymes without creating toxic byproducts, which results in significant amounts of
sugars for fermentation to ethanol.
Significant progress has been made in producing
ethanol from simple sugars through the discovery
of better microorganisms and a better fermentation
process. And, lastly, through POET’s cutting-edge
process engineering expertise, we have devised a
synergistic concept that enables a conventional
corn ethanol plant to transition into one that uses
only cellulosic feedstock. Although these are important breakthroughs, further process improvements
over the next few months are needed to make the
process profitable.

cobs collected as part of the cellulosic feedstock.
When coupled to an anaerobic digestion system
to process the liquid wastes from the cellulosic
operation, the boiler will supply nearly all of the
energy needs for the cellulosic- and starch-based
operations.

CRITICAL SUCCESS FACTORS FOR
WIDESPREAD USE OF ETHANOL
The continued development and commercialization of cellulosic ethanol underscores the
importance of the following1:
1. The Existing Corn-to-Ethanol Business and
Infrastructure. Without a viable corn-toethanol industry, cellulosic ethanol will be
delayed. The corn-to-ethanol industry can
provide an existing network of corn growers;
production knowledge; and product, market,
and logistics knowledge to emerging cellulosic ethanol producers.
2. The Renewable Fuel Standard. The RFS
provides an important target for cellulosic
ethanol—a real and attainable target. Continued support of the RFS will demonstrate
to the ethanol, transportation fuel, and financial industries that there will be a market for
ethanol.

ALTERNATIVE ENERGY AND
CELLULOSIC ETHANOL
Alternative energy plays an important role in
the cellulosic ethanol process. Because of the low
nutritional value of cellulosic ethanol waste streams
(the by-products of ethanol production), they
cannot be used as animal feed products. The most
favorable use of these streams is feedstock for
solid-fuel boilers or anaerobic digestion.
POET is currently installing a solid-fuel boiler
at its biorefinery in Chancellor, South Dakota,
which will process up to 500 tons of dried wood
chips from a waste pallet processor to produce
steam for the plant. This biorefinery has also
reached an agreement with the city of Sioux Falls
to purchase landfill gas for the boiler. By using wood
and landfill gas, 67 percent of the energy needs at
the Chancellor plant can be met, decreasing the
need for fossil fuels by the same amount.
POET’s Project LIBERTY will also incorporate
a solid-fuel boiler in its design. The feedstock for
the LIBERTY boiler will be solid wastes from the
cellulosic ethanol operation and additional corn
8

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

3. Increased Usage of Ethanol and Greater
Numbers of Flexible-Fuel Vehicles. Recent
important research (see Appendix B) supports
greater concentrations of ethanol to replace
gasoline—expanding the use of ethanol
beyond its historical role as a fuel oxygenate.
So called “mid-level blends” (those greater
than E15) of liquid transportation fuels have
shown no deleterious impact on vehicles in
the current U.S. automotive fleet. These midlevel blends will further reduce our dependence on foreign oil, reduce our fuel costs,
and help the environment.
4. Governmental Support. Governmental programs are necessary, especially during the
1

For further study of the ethanol industry, see the resources noted in
Appendix A.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Stowers

early stages of the cellulosic ethanol industry’s development, to enable financing at the
grower/farmer level and to offer cellulosic
ethanol producers incentives, loan guarantees, and market assurances. The maintenance of the VEETC and import tariffs on
ethanol remain important so long as ethanol
use in the liquid transportation fuels remains
low and the purchasing power of oil refiners
remains high.
5. Continued Investment in Research and
Development. Significant cost reductions in
the cellulosic ethanol process are required.
The cost of enzymes still remains one of the
most significant variable costs associated
with the process.

REFERENCES
Begemann, Brett. “Merrill Lynch Agricultural
Chemicals Conference.” Monsanto, June 5, 2008;
www.monsanto.com/pdf/investors/2008/06-05-08.pdf.
Liska, Adam J.; Yang, Haishun S.; Bremer, Virgil R.;
Klopfenstein, Terry J.; Walters, Daniel T.; Erickson,
Galen E. and Cassman, Kenneth G. “Improvements
in Life-Cycle Energy Efficiency and Greenhouse Gas
Emissions of Corn Ethanol.” Journal of Industrial
Ecology, 2009, pp. 58-74; www3.interscience.
wiley.com/cgi-bin/fulltext/121647166/PDFSTART.
Renewable Fuels Association. “One-Year Anniversary
of Energy Legislation Highlights Success of
Renewable Fuels Standard.” 2008a;
http://renewablefuelsassociation.cmail1.com/T/
ViewEmail/y/8ADFEF500F6774ED.

Renewable Fuels Association. “Biorefinery Locations.”
November 2008b update;
www.ethanolrfa.org/industry/locations/.
Osborne, Stefan. “Energy in 2020: Assessing the
Economic Effects of Commercialization of Cellulosic
Ethanol.” U.S. Department of Commerce International
Trade Administration Report, November 2007;
www.trade.gov/media/publications/pdf/
cellulosic2007.pdf.
Urbanchuk, John M. “Economic Contribution of the
Partial Exemption for Ethanol from the Federal Excise
Tax on Motor Fuel: Increased Revenues and Reduced
Dependence on Foreign Oil.” LECG, 2008;
www.lecg.com/files/Publication/e3c2b607-e4b14be3-96c7-99360d2b9993/Presentation/
PublicationAttachment/cf3c9c9e-9580-4e52-add99b878810e4d3/exisetax.pdf.
Wang, Michael. “Analysis of the Efficiency of the U.S.
Ethanol Industry 2007.” Presented to the Renewable
Fuels Association, March 27, 2008;
/www1.eere.energy.gov/biomass/pdfs/anl_ethanol_
analysis_2007.pdf.
West, Brian; Knoll, Keith; Clark, Wendy; Graves,
Ronald; Orban, John; Przesmitzki, Steve and Theiss,
Timothy. “Effects of Intermediate Ethanol Blends on
Legacy Vehicles and Small Non-Road Engines,
Report 1.” NREL/TP-540-43543; ORNL/TM-2008/117.
National Renewable Energy Laboratory, October 2008;
http://feerc.ornl.gov/publications/Int_blends_
Rpt_1.pdf.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

9

Stowers

APPENDIX A
Additional Reading
Argonne National Laboratory, Energy Systems Division. “Life-Cycle Assessment of Energy and Greenhouse Gas
Effects of Soybean-Derived Biodiesel and Renewable Fuels.” March 12, 2008;
www.transportation.anl.gov/pdfs/AF/467.pdf.
Dale, Bruce. “Thinking Clearly about Biofuels, Bioproducts and Biorefining.” SCITIZEN, August 15, 2007;
www.scitizen.com/stories/Future-Energies/2007/08/Thinking-Clearly-about-Biofuels-Ending-the-Irrelevant—
Net-Energy—Controversy/.
U.S. Department of Energy. “Ethanol Myths Under the Microscope.” 2007;
www1.eere.energy.gov/biomass/pdfs/ethanolmyths2007.pdf.
U.S. Department of Energy, Office of Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy. “Ethanol: The Complete Energy
Lifecycle Picture.” March 2007;
www1.eere.energy.gov/vehiclesandfuels/pdfs/program/ethanol_brochure_color.pdf.
U.S. Department of Energy. “Fact Sheet: Gas Prices and Oil Consumption Would Increase Without Biofuels.”
June 11, 2008; www.energy.gov/media/FactSheet__Biofuels_Lower_Gas_Prices.pdf.
U.S. Department of Energy. “Ethanol Greenhouse Gas Emissions.” February 4, 2009 update;
www.eere.energy.gov/afdc/ethanol/emissions.html.
Whitten, Gary. “Air Quality and Ethanol in Gasoline.” Presented at the 9th Annual National Ethanol Conference
Policy & Marketing, February 16-18, 2004;
www.oregon.gov/ENERGY/RENEW/Biomass/docs/FORUM/Whitten2004.pdf.

APPENDIX B
Summary of Research Findings on Higher Ethanol Blends
Bonnema, Grant; Guse, Gregory; Senecal, Neil; Gupta, Rahul; Jones, Bruce and Ready, Kirk L. “Use of Mid-Range
Ethanol/Gasoline Blends in Unmodified Passenger Cars and Light Duty Trucks.” Minnesota Center for Automotive
Research, July 1999; www.ethanol.org/pdf/contentmgmt/E30_Final_Report.pdf.
This one-year study evaluated the effects of E10 and E30 in 15 older vehicles in “real world” driving conditions
and found that regulated exhaust emissions from both fuels were well below federal standards.

Egebäck, Karl-Erik; Henke, Magnus; Rehnlund, Björn; Wallin, Mats and Westerholm, Roger. “Blending of Ethanol
in Gasoline for Spark Ignition Engines: Problem Inventory and Evaporative Measurements.” Report No. MTC 5407,
AVL MTC Tech Centre, Haninge, Sweden, 2005.
Researchers tested and compared evaporative emissions from E0, E5, E10, and E15 and found lower total hydrocarbon emissions and lower evaporative emissions from E15 than from E10 and E5. Specifically,

10

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Stowers

(i) no significant difference can be seen in regulated emissions when comparing the use of blended fuel
(with up to 10 to 15 percent ethanol) with the use of neat gasoline, and
(ii) due to the gasoline dilution effect of adding ethanol, the emissions of benzene, toluene, ethylbenzene, and
xylene blended with ethanol are lower than those from neat gasoline, which offers health and environmental
benefits.

Haskew, Harold M.; Liberty, Thomas F. and McClement, Dennis. “Fuel Permeation from Automotive Systems: E0,
E6, E10, E20 and E85.” CRC Report No. E-65-3, Coordinating Research Council, Inc., December 2006;
www.crcao.com/reports/recentstudies2006/E-65-3/CRC%20E-65-3%20Final%20Report.pdf.
Researchers evaluated the effects of E0, E6, E20, and E85 on the evaporative emissions rates from permeation in
five newer California vehicles and found there was no statistically significant increase in diurnal permeation
rates between E6 and E20.

Knoll, Keith; West, Brian; Clark, Wendy; Graves, Ronald; Orban, John; Przesmitzki, Steve and Theiss, Timothy.
“Effects of Intermediate Ethanol Blends on Legacy Vehicles and Small Non-Road Engines, Report 1.” NREL/TP540-43543; ORNL/TM-2008/117. National Renewable Energy Laboratory of the Oak Ridge National Laboratory
for the U.S. Department of Energy, October 2008; http://feerc.ornl.gov/publications/Int_blends_Rpt_1.pdf.
This peer-reviewed study regarding the effects of E15 and E20 on motor vehicles and small nonroad engines
concluded that compared with traditional gasoline neither E15 or E20 has significant changes in vehicle
tailpipe emissions. The findings include the following:
(i) Regulated tailpipe emissions remained largely unaffected by the ethanol content of the fuel.
(ii) As ethanol content increased, oxides of nitrogen and nonmethane organic gases showed no significant
change.
(iii) Nonmethane hydrocarbons and CO2 emissions dropped slightly on average, although CO2 did not change
appreciably from E10 to E20.

Shockey, Richard E. and Aulich, Ted R. “Optimal Ethanol Blend-Level Investigation, Final Report.” Energy and
Environmental Research Center and Minnesota Center for Automotive Research for the American Coalition for
Ethanol, October 2007;
www.ethanol.org/pdf/contentmgmt/ACE_Optimal_Ethanol_Blend_Level_Study_final_12507.pdf.
Researchers studied the effects of ethanol blends ranging from E10 to E85 on motor vehicles and found that
exhaust emissions levels for all vehicles at all ethanol blends tested were within the applicable Clean Air Act
standards.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

11

Roles for Evolving Markets, Policies,
and Technology Improvements in
U.S. Corn Ethanol Industry Development
Paul W. Gallagher
This article reviews changes in markets, technologies, and policies that affect corn ethanol profitability and industry expansion. Historically, the corn ethanol industry was stimulated by high petrofuel prices, successful corn and processing technology improvements, and government incentives,
such as a blenders’ tax credit and mandated markets defined by the leaded fuel ban and reformulated fuel. Presently, the corn ethanol industry has expanded slightly beyond the point of a normal
capital return, which is defined by limits on corn resource availability and ethanol marketing
infrastructure. A renewable fuel standard, included in a recent energy law, may eventually define
minimum consumption levels for ethanol and, implicitly, production levels for corn ethanol. Potentially impending marketing changes, such as voluntary E20 (20 percent ethanol) sales or expanded
sales of E85-equipped automobiles, may expand ethanol markets. Potential technology advances
include growth of corn yields, corn-processing improvements for lower costs or higher revenue,
and development of a corn-stover (leaves and stalks)–based biomass industry. Government policies
to induce biomass-fuel capacity investment are economically justified and probably necessary if
biofuel industry development remains a public priority. Still, more efficient policy approaches
could be developed. (JEL Q11, Q42, Q48)
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economic Development, 2009, 5(1), pp. 12-33.

P

rofit assessments in the ethanol industry
must account for market and policy
developments in the fuel and corn
industries because processors are positioned between both commodity markets. At the
beginning of the twentieth century, biofuel-based
industries such as ethanol were not feasible because
a pound of corn could be sold on the market and
exchanged for 5 to 7 pounds of petroleum at prevailing market prices. It made more sense to produce the corn for feed and food, sell it for cash, and
buy petroleum to process for energy. The circumstances have since changed and today’s scenario
is quite different: One pound of corn can be
exchanged for only about one pound of petroleum

(Gallagher, 2004). A century of declining corn
prices and increasing petroleum prices has radically changed society’s technology options.
Still, the oil price spike of the late 1970s
(Figure 1) is a major event responsible for the
birth of the ethanol industry. Ethanol has recently
emerged as an equal partner among corn-using
industries during the oil price escalation of the early
twenty-first century. Technologies that improve
input costs or firm and marketing efficiency are
equally important in explaining the ethanol industry’s birth and expansion because investment in a
new processing technology was required. In the
ethanol industry, firm strategies have emerged during episodes of narrow profit margins.

Paul W. Gallagher is employed at the department of economics, Iowa State University.

© 2009, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced,
published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

12

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Gallagher

Figure 1
Saudi Petroleum Prices (January 1970–December 2008)
2008 $/Barrel
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

This review of profitability in the ethanol industry considers the combination of developments in
corn, fuel markets, and policy that led to the recent
ethanol expansion. Also, an estimation of the contribution from past firm efficiency improvements
is presented as one important factor contributing to
the ethanol industry’s development. For the present
and intermediate future, overall profit and output
growth rates in the industry will likely be moderate
because of moderate supply growth for the corn
input and widening ethanol price discounts to compete with gasoline. Thus, impending innovations
in production and marketing practices are also
reviewed for an indication of their profit-improving
potential in the current economic environment.

THE MARKETING-GOVERNMENTTECHNOLOGY MATRIX LEADING
TO THE CURRENT U.S. ETHANOL
INDUSTRY
Phases of the Ethanol Industry
Three phases of the U.S. corn ethanol industry
are discussed: birth, development, and maturity.

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

Birth. The right combination of petroleum
market and corn market events contributed to
the initial profitability and birth of the ethanolprocessing industry. In the petroleum market, the
Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries
(OPEC) was still pursuing a high-price strategy as
a hangover from the 1970s. Meanwhile, corn prices
had declined considerably because the export
boom of the mid-1970s had collapsed (Figure 2).
A generous consumption subsidy in the form of
a blenders’ tax credit1 was still needed to achieve
profitability (Gill, 1987). Nonetheless, production
in the new ethanol industry had expanded to
nearly 0.75 billion gallons by 1989.
Development. OPEC changed its pricing strategy in the mid-1980s (Stauffer, 1994). Then petroleum and fuel prices declined, which resulted in
a much narrower profit margin that allowed the
ethanol industry to become more competitive.
1

A mixture (blend) of 10 percent ethanol and 90 percent gasoline is
suitable for most automobiles with gasoline engines. Initially, the
U.S. government granted a partial exemption to its gasoline excise
tax when an ethanol blend was sold because ethanol was typically
more expensive than gasoline. The partial exemption is equivalent
to an ethanol consumer subsidy (Gallagher, Shapouri, and Price,
2006b).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

13

Gallagher

Figure 2
North Central Iowa Corn Prices (January 1970–December 2008)
2008 $/Bushel
12

10

8

6

4

2

0
1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

Although this period was not profitable for ethanol
processing, the groundwork for future ethanol
profitability was laid. Three events stand out in
this developmental phase.
First, the ethanol industry initiated a series of
improvements that enhanced profitability with
the existing market prices for fuel and corn. For
instance, ethanol yields increased 10 percent
between 1984 and 2007. The processing yield
increase elevated profits by $0.31 per bushel.
Further, operating expenses decreased by about
50 percent since the late 1980s—energy efficiency
improved, labor needs declined, and the cost of
processing enzymes dropped (Gallagher, Shapouri,
and Brubaker, 2007); the reduction in operating
costs was $0.38/bu. Finally, dry mill processors
discovered that they could reduce their average
capital costs, or capital costs per unit of capacity,
by increasing the size of their plants (Gallagher,
Brubaker, and Shapouri, 2005; Gallagher, Shapouri,
and Brubaker, 2007). Elsewhere, I have estimated
that annual capital costs declined by $0.27/bu by
increasing the plant size from 4 million bu/yr to
19 million bu/yr. Together the yield improvements
14

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

and costs reductions increased the processing margin by $0.96/bu.
Second, since 1980 the corn market has slowly
but steadily changed so that ethanol processing is
now profitable. Specifically, corn production has
grown steadily with yield growth (~224 million
bu/yr) while demand growth has remained relatively stable (110 million bu/yr). Export demands
have fluctuated from year to year but have exhibited no growth since 1980. Moderate feed demand
growth reflected saturation of American diets,
limited success of trade negotiations in developed
country meat markets, and the shift in livestock
feed rations toward more protein (Gallagher, 2000).
Since 1980, new corn supplies have gradually
pushed corn prices down and pushed marginal
corn farmland into other crops. Otherwise stated,
the cumulated excess supply growth of corn could
supply about 8.0 billion gallons of new ethanol
capacity without increasing corn prices. In contrast,
ethanol capacity grew by about 1.5 billion gallons
by 2000.
Third, ethanol demand and prices got a major
boost when a legislated oxygen standard was introduced to reformulated fuel in 1994 as part of the

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Gallagher

Figure 3
Corn Ethanol Processing Margin and Costs for Dry Mills with Current Technology
(January 1990–December 2008)
$/Bushel of Corn
10
Cash Operating Costs*
Operating Plus Capital Costs
9
Margin**
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

NOTE: *Includes electricity, fuel, labor, and chemicals. **Ethanol revenues plus DDG revenues less corn costs.

1990 Clean Air Act (Gallagher et al., 2003). In effect,
the oxygen standard required that ethanol or methyl
tertiary-butyl ether (MTBE, an additive) be blended
in the gasoline “recipes” used for cleaner fuels in
major urban areas with smog problems. This
requirement increased the ethanol demand and
capacity by 0.90 billion gallons (Gallagher, Otto,
and Dikeman, 2000).
Maturity. Two events in fuel markets triggered
the large-scale expansions of the twenty-first century. First, a “de facto” national ban on the use of
MTBE, the petroleum industry’s chemical for the
oxygen standard of reformulated fuel, evolved
through a series of public events. The national ban
evolved partly because several major states banned
MTBE after it was found in groundwater supplies
(Gallagher et al., 2000). Then the petroleum industry was unable to obtain a waiver removing their
liability for leaking tanks, so the industry decided
to phase out MTBE. Ethanol, initially sharing the
reformulated fuel market, is still benefiting from

a demand boost because of the MTBE phase-out—
the increase will add a total of 3.5 billion gallons
of ethanol demand when the 1998 level of MTBE
production is completely phased out. By 2000,
ethanol-processing margins had increased
(Figure 3). Further, returns on an equity investment
increased to respectable levels (~20 percent). Consequently, ethanol output expanded to annual
production levels of about 1 billion gallons.
Second, petroleum prices crossed the threshold of competition where ethanol could compete
directly with other additives in the petrochemical
industry (Gallagher et al., 2006a). By 2006, processing margins widened, and the return on an equity
investment in an ethanol plant reached eye-catching
levels—60 percent—using current corn prices and
spot market ethanol prices.
A stunning expansion in ethanol output has
since occurred; output is about 8.5 billion gallons
for the recently completed 2007-08 corn marketing year (Figure 4). Also, the Renewable Fuels

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

15

Gallagher

Figure 4
U.S. Ethanol Production (and Changes)
Millions of Gallons
15,000

Output
Change
Renewable Fuel Standard

14,000
13,000
12,000
11,000
10,000
9,000
8,000
7,000
6,000
5,000
4,000
3,000
2,000
1,000
0
–1,000
–2,000
1980

1985

1990

1995

Association (RFA, 2008) reported in October 2008
that ethanol production capacity is 10.26 billion
gallons, and the capacity will be 13.66 billion gallons when the processing plants currently financed
or under construction are completed.

THE ETHANOL INDUSTRY’S
CONTRIBUTION TO RESOLVING
THE GAP BETWEEN CORN
DEMAND AND ETHANOL
PRODUCTION CAPACITY
Economic theory suggests that an expanding
industry pushes product prices down and input
prices up, at least to the extent that product demand
and input supply curves are not perfectly elastic.
Indeed, wholesale ethanol prices have declined
relative to gasoline prices—and even in absolute
terms recently (Figure 5). Also, corn prices at the
farm level have escalated from typical levels of
$2.50/bu a few years ago to $5.00/bu recently.
16

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

2000

2005

2010

2015

2020

Although several developments are responsible
for recent price increases, ethanol expansion was
an important cause.
Market equilibrium occurs because declining
output prices and increasing input prices squeeze
processors’ profit margin to the point that the
marginal processors’ return is exactly offset by
their costs. Indeed, the data do suggest an upwardsloping processing supply curve with respect to
the processing price (margin): Ethanol price
increases (or corn input price decreases) represent
upward movements along the processing supply
curve (Figure 6 and Appendix A). For instance,
the October 2008 average processing margin less
operating cost (Mt ; see Appendix A) was $0.72/bu
after corn prices fell to $3.73/bu, which is $0.02/bu
above the point of capital cost return. Accordingly,
processing near 80 percent utilization could be
expected, keeping ethanol prices at moderate levels.
During November and December 2008, the margin
was $0.136/bu to $0.293/bu less than the annual
capital cost on a new plant investment. Hence,
most plants continue to operate, but new capacity

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Gallagher

Figure 5
Wholesale Fuel Prices in Iowa (January 1995–December 2008)
A.
$/Gallon
4.00
3.50

E85 (implied, with subsidy)
Regular Gasoline

3.00
2.50
2.00
1.50
1.00
0.50
0.00
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

B.
$/Gallon
4.00
3.50

E20 (implied, with subsidy)
Premium Gasoline
E20 (implied, without subsidy)

3.00
2.50
2.00
1.50
1.00
0.50
0.00
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

17

Gallagher

Figure 6
Ethanol Processing Supply, Unit Capital Cost, and Processing Equilibrium
Margin Less Operating Costs ($/bushel)
5
Supply
K Cost
Actual

4

3

2

1

0

–1

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

1.2

Utilization Rate, 0/1

plans were discouraged, as profits were not adequate to repay the annual capital investment cost
of $0.70/bu.2
Another point to consider in estimating how
long it will take to restore a balance between ethanol
capacity and corn supply is the balance between
corn production growth and ethanol output growth.
Some exploratory calculations are given in Table 1.
These calculations exploit three assumptions: (i) an
80 percent utilization rate by ethanol processors continues, (ii) planned capacity is brought online at the
recent historical rate but no new production plans
are developed (see Appendix A and equation (A2)
for profitability calculations), and (iii) trend rates
of production and feed demand growth continue.
Starting with the recently completed 2007-08
crop year, corn production growth of 2,539 million
2

Editor’s note: The author has updated prices for this publication
since the presentation of the paper in November 2008.

18

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

bushels was very large, partly because an additional
10.0 million acres of corn were planted. However,
the actual demand growth for 2007-08 was only
1,636 million bushels, so there was a market surplus of 903 million bushels. For subsequent years,
80 percent of ethanol capacity utilization implies a
growth in processor demand of 598 million bushels
for 2008-09 and 568 million bushels for 2009-10.
The external corn production growth between
2008-09 and 2009-10 (325 million bushels) is calculated as the trend yield growth (2.77 bu/acre/yr)
on the existing corn land base plus a small allowance for increasing acreage devoted to corn.
The yearly market surplus for 2007-08 was 903
million bushels, but a deficit in production growth
is likely for 2008-09 and 2009-10. Thus, falling
inventories could be expected as surpluses and
inventories are used to fill the demand of additional
ethanol plants. However, the external production
growth driven by corn-yield growth will begin to

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Gallagher

Table 1
Anticipated, Actual, and External Changes in Corn Demand and Production
External changes
Variable

Anticipated changes Actual changes*

Crop year

Anticipated

Anticipated

Anticipated

07/2008

07/2008

08/2009

09/2010

10/2011

110†

455‡

Demand
Feed
Exports

0†

Ethanol

1,681§

110

110

110

300

0

0

0

881

598

568

36

Subtotal

1,791

1,636

652

678

340

Production

1,664¶

2,539

325#

Difference

127

Cumulation**

325

325

903

–327

–353

179

903

576

223

402

NOTE: Data assume 80 percent utilization of corn-processing capacity ($2.00/gal ethanol and $5.00/bu corn).
*Office of Chief Economist’s Staff, 2008.
†Trend

rate of increase 1980-2006.

‡An

increase of 176 million bushels can be attributed to meat export expansion.

§Per

e-mail from R. Wisner and W. Tierney, December 29, 2006.

¶A

trend yield increase of 2.77 bu/acre times an acreage base of 81.3 million acres (planted) in 2006, plus an anticipated planted acreage
increase of 10.0 million acres times a trend yield of 145 bu/planted acre.

#A

trend yield increase of 2.77 bu/acre times an acreage base of 93.5 million acres (planted) in 2007, plus an anticipated planted acreage
increase of 0.46 million acres times a trend yield of 145 bu/planted acre.

**Implied inventory increase and/or price decline when positive.

catch up with the ethanol-induced expansion in
corn demand by the 2010-11 crop year. The production growth exceeds demand growth slightly
(by 179 million bushels) when ethanol processors
are operating at 80 percent of capacity. At that point,
increased profit margins pushed by declining corn
prices could begin to lift capacity utilization rates
of ethanol processors above the 80 percent rate.
Overall, the calculations in Table 1 suggest that the
net growth of the corn supply will catch up with
the planned ethanol capacity in about 3 years.

Clearing Up Some Misconceptions
The 2007-08 corn market year was one of major
forecasting mistakes and other market surprises.
First, a mood of hysteria prevailed when planting
decisions for the 2007-08 crop year were made. To
illustrate, recall that some analysts were suggesting
a 32 billion gallon corn ethanol industry by 2014

(Elobeid et al., 2006). If such a decade-long expansion occurred at a linear rate, 3.1 billion gallons of
additional ethanol (or 1,150 million bushels of corn)
would have been required every year for a decade.
Another private forecast anticipated an ethanol
production increase of 4.5 billion gallons (1,681
million bushels) for the 2007-08 crop year (Tierney
and Gidel, 2006). Even the widely watched United
States Department of Agriculture (USDA) Supply
and Demand report estimated ethanol expansion
of 3.4 billion gallons (1,250 million bushels), which
was 41 percent above the actual expansion (Office
of Chief Economist’s Staff, 2007, 2008). It is likely
that errors occurred in the corn area (acres planted)
and inventory allocations for the 2007-08 crop year.
Further, corn prices were likely destabilized; the
demand overestimate ensured higher prices and
increased inventory carryout, but larger carryin
and lower prices for the subsequent market year
(Hyami and Peterson, 1972).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

19

Gallagher

Second, the actual feed expansion of 455 million bushels was much higher than long-term trend
growth (110 million bushels) or early USDA projections would have indicated. Of the actual expansion in feed demand, 175 million bushels can be
attributed to the feed needed for an expansion of
U.S. meat exports in pork, chicken, and beef. Both
the domestic livestock and foreign livestock components of corn feed demand expanded more
rapidly than anticipated.
Third, corn export growth had been nonexistent
for 20 years, but the 2007-08 crop year saw a 300
million bushel expansion and a record export level.
The shift in corn exports can be explained mostly
by events and policy decisions in the European
Union (EU) and China. The EU had a production
shortfall of 257 million bushels between the 2006-07
and 2007-08 crop years. Furthermore, the EU made
up almost all of the domestic production shortfall
by increasing imports by 234 million bushels. This
is a well-known feature of EU policies—entire
shortfalls are made up on the world market because
domestic prices are insulated from fluctuations in
world commodity markets. China had no production shortfall. However, given their rapidly growing
population, and perhaps the opportunity for a quick
profit by the state trading enterprise, exports from
China declined by 184 million bushels. Even though
the U.S. corn export increase may have been sold
to other countries, the shift in export position by
the EU and China can explain most of the increase
in U.S. export demand for corn.
The total demand shock that some analysts
feared did actually occur: The total demand shift,
initially forecast at 1,791 million bushels, was 1,636
million bushels. However, many accounts hold the
ethanol industry responsible. The main point is
that all three groups—meat exporters, large corntrading countries, and the ethanol industry—cannot all expand at the same time. The corn market
is not large enough, as price behavior in the past
year has shown.
Corn inventory increased (by 320 million
bushels) during 2007-08. At first glance, an inventory increase is not typical in a tight corn market.
But was the inventory higher than a well-functioning
competitive market would have delivered? Offsetting factors complicate the answer. For instance,
20

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

inventory holders with good foresight probably
could accumulate some inventories to cover the
anticipated bulge in ethanol demand over the next
three years or so, but several other factors point to
the possibility of excess inventory. Specifically, the
extent of the future demand expansion was overestimated, so futures prices were high. Also, corn
futures prices are systematically biased upward in
comparison with the actual cash prices in subsequent periods (Appendix B), so inventory holdings
based on the futures price were likely too high.
Finally, there was speculation related to macroeconomic concerns about commodity inflation,
which would encourage higher inventories unrelated to events in the commodity market. A quantitative analysis of the offsetting factors could be
definitive. In the meantime, circumstances seemed
to point toward overaccumulation of corn inventories in the 2007-08 crop year.
Fortunately, corn producers responded with
more acreage in corn than many thought possible.
And good fortune prevailed with an actual production increase that more than offset the demand
expansion. Prices were quite high for the 2007-08
marketing year, but they were still considerably
lower than they would have been had a production shortfall occurred on top of a simultaneous
expansion in three market segments and excessive
inventories.

REORGANIZING THE ETHANOL
INDUSTRY FOR THE TWENTYFIRST CENTURY
Production Changes
The ethanol industry has changed considerably
during its expansion. First, production has become
more concentrated in the Midwestern United States
(Figure 7). Second, the ownership structure has
become less concentrated, which encourages fuel
pricing with competitive profit margins. Third,
ethanol markets have become more national in
scope. Arguably, all of these changes have improved
economic performance of the Midwestern economy
and provided substitutes for imported fuel.
Location of Production. Most new plants in the
rapidly expanding ethanol industry were placed

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Gallagher

Figure 7
Ethanol Biorefinery Locations
A. Currently Operating Ethanol Biorefinery Locations

50 MGY or Less
>50 MGY

B. Pending Ethanol Biorefinery Projects: Construction, Expansions, and Announcements

SOURCE: Renewable Fuels Association and Department of Economics, Iowa State University.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

21

Gallagher

Table 2
Ownership of U.S. Ethanol Capacity in 2000 and 2008
December 2000
Operating
(million gallons)

Ownership

December 30, 2008

Share (0/1)

Operating
(million gallons)

After building
(million gallons)

Share (0/1)

Large firms
Abengoa

0

Archer Daniels Midland

797

0
0.397

Hawkeye Renewables

0

—

POET (Broin)

7

0.004

VeraSun

0

Subtotal (large firms)

168

344

0.026

1,070

1,620

0.122

440

440

—

1,467

1537

0.116

—

7,80

880

0.066

804

0.401

3,925

4,821

0.364

529

0.264

1,698

1,898

0.143

Small firms
Farmer/local

681

0.339

5,216

6,516

0.493

Subtotal (small firms)

External

1,210

0.603

6,914

8,414

0.636

Total—United States

2,007

1.000

10,839

13,235

1.000

in the Midwest, where corn input supplies are
ample and cheap. Specifically, 65 percent of
ethanol plants are now located in seven Midwestern states (Iowa, Illinois, Indiana, Minnesota,
Missouri, Nebraska, and South Dakota).
The production expansion has provided a
larger economic base for the rural Midwest. The
direct effects of ethanol expansion include wages
at the processing plant, farm income derived from
additional corn sales, and expanded local transportation. Secondary effects include multiplier
effects in retail and service sectors. Local economy
benefits of about $0.20/gallon and reduced fuel
consumption expenditures offset the cost of ethanol
subsidies (Gallagher, Otto, and Dikeman, 2000).
Some ethanol plants are now near product markets. Locations in Texas, Oregon, and Washington
are near ethanol markets and by-product distillers’
grains (DG) feed markets. Here, the higher corn
costs are offset by the DG drying costs avoided by
local feed markets. Also, ethanol transport costs
are avoided for refiners with blending requirements
from the renewable fuels standard (RFS). Five percent of the ethanol plants in the United States are
in Texas, Oregon, California, and Washington.
Ownership Structure. The ethanol industry
that has emerged from the rapid expansion has a
22

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

less concentrated ownership structure. Three
equally large firms combined now control about
40 percent of the market, and each has about 12
percent of the market. In contrast, one firm alone
controlled 40 percent of the market in 2000
(Table 2). The remaining smaller firms represented
about 60 percent of the market in both periods.
However, the share of locally owned firms (i.e.,
firms owned by residents or farmers in the local
community where the plant is located) today is 12
percent—down from 26 percent before the expansion in 2000. Externally owned firms now (as of
2008) supply about 47 percent of the capacity, a
heightened presence in the industry. Dispersed
firms and diverse ownership encourages competition in the ethanol market.
Ethanol Markets. Distinguishing between
additive and commodity fuel markets for ethanol
is useful in understanding episodes of ethanol premiums or discounts relative to gasoline. In the
additive market, blending restrictions on scarce
quality attributes (e.g., octane and/or oxygen) can
create market premiums for ethanol over commodity gasoline (Gallagher et al., 2003). In the commodity fuel market, because high ethanol concentration
reduces fuel economy, the market discounts
ethanol relative to gasoline (Gallagher, 2007).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Gallagher

Historically, ethanol sold at premiums over
gasoline during the replacement of MTBE. More
recently, ethanol premiums have turned to discounts relative to gasoline as marketed ethanol
volume surpassed the MTBE replacement threshold.
Initially, larger sales volumes had to deal with
transportation bottlenecks. More recently, ethanol
discounts relative to gasoline have stemmed from
lower-valued uses in E10 and E85 (see Figure 5).
In the coastal urban areas of the United States,
federal regulations were probably responsible for
oxygen-based ethanol premiums. For instance,
reformulated fuel has an oxygen content standard
that is satisfied by a 5.5 percent ethanol blend in
Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)–designated
markets. For instance, the major population centers
in New York, California, and Texas are required to
follow the restrictions of reformulated fuel. Even
though the oxygen standard was repealed in the
Energy Policy Act of 2005, ethanol demand
remained high (2.0 billion gallons) in these major
population centers during 2006.
Much of the ethanol is voluntarily blended in
the Midwest (with subsidy).3 It has been blended
at 10 percent concentration (E10) for 20 years
because EPA regulations assume that 10 percent is
the maximum level that is compatible with conventional gasoline engines and ignition systems (EPA,
1995). More recent blends of ethanol (up to 85
percent ethanol concentration [E85]) can be used
in gasoline engines with modified fuel and ignition
systems. Both products are available at retail gasoline outlets around the Midwest. Six million flexiblefuel vehicles (FFVs, which are E85-compatible) are
currently in use in the United States. These FFVs
could consume up to 6.0 billion gallons of ethanol
if fully fueled by E85 blends (based on 15,000 miles
driven per car/yr and an average of 15 mpg). Since
2005 and through 2010, blenders of E10 and E85
receive a blenders’ credit on the U.S. gasoline excise
tax equal to $0.51/gallon of ethanol used (RFA,
2009).
During the past two years, ethanol price discounts against gasoline have been common (see
Figure 5A). Further, the discounts have tended to

widen as the volume of ethanol marketed has
increased. In fact, my estimate of the ethanol price
elasticity (E ) of demand with a fixed gasoline price
is E = 1.04 (see Appendix A, Ethanol Price Discounts). The implication is that revenues tend to
remain about constant with increased marketed
volume. Reasons for this price discounting include
the fact that the requirements of the octane deficit
and the E10 market in some Midwestern states have
been surpassed. Also, the marketing and consumption infrastructure for using higher ethanol concentrations (gas stations and FFVs) is limited. Marketing
practices and government policy are likely to
evolve with the combination of price discounting
and expanding supplies.
The recent situation was useful because wide
price discounts encourage construction of E85 retail
outlets. In addition, a subsidy encourages construction of E85 retail fueling stations.4 But accelerated
adoption of FFV technology by consumers will
occur only with sustained consumer incentives,
such as E85 retailing margins that more closely
reflect gasoline retailing margins or a consumers’
income tax credit for using ethanol instead of a
blenders’ tax credit. Rapid adoption of FFV technology given the market conditions of December
2008 is unlikely—Iowa’s wholesale price for regular
gasoline of $1.06/gallon was slightly higher than
the implied wholesale E85 price, but only after
the $0.51/gallon is subtracted from the weighted
ethanol-gasoline price of $1.51/gallon.
Another alternative is voluntary or mandated
use of E20 (20 percent ethanol blend in gasoline)
in non-FFV vehicles. A drivability study suggests
that E20 could be used in conventional automobiles
without mechanical problems (Kittleson, Tan, and
Zarling, 2007). A preliminary emissions test of E20
in 13 late-model (2002 and 2007) vehicles found that
(i) there were no statistically significant increases
in EPA-regulated auto emissions and some of the
regulated emissions actually decreased and (ii) the
catalytic converter was consistently cooler for all
vehicles, except for a subset of lean-running vehicles during a wide-open-throttle hill-climbing

3

4

At moderate and high gasoline prices, ethanol is competitive without
the subsidy; but at low gasoline prices, an ethanol subsidy is required
to maintain competitiveness (Gallagher et al., 2006a).

A 30 percent income tax credit up to $30,000 is available until 2010
to businesses that install clean-fuel (including E85) vehicle-refueling
equipment (RFA, 2009).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

23

Gallagher

Figure 8
Spot Ethanol Price Difference: Texas Less Iowa
$/Gallon
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
–0.1
2005.5

2006

2006.5

2007

experiment (West et al., 2008). Incidental fuel economy calculations from these two studies are mixed;
however, a test of late-model vehicles suggests that
fuel economy holds up with E20 (Shockey et al.,
2007). The E20 blend remains a competitive substitute for premium gasoline with the market conditions of December 2008—Iowa’s wholesale price
for premium gasoline was $1.29/gallon and corresponding E20 prices were $1.14/gallon without the
subsidy and $1.06/gallon with the subsidy (see
Figure 5b).
Marketing policies that encourage E20 or E85
use may reduce ethanol price discounting against
gasoline by encouraging ethanol-for-gasoline substitution and expanding ethanol demand. However,
additional testing to determine vehicle classes and
locations that are suitable for E20 is still needed.
The Renewable Fuels Standard. Impending
consumption mandates are a second avenue that
could boost future ethanol price and demand.
Since 2004, an RFS potentially mandates minimum
consumption levels for renewable fuels. A minimum level for corn ethanol consumption is also
24

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

2007.5

2008

2008.5

2009

implied but has not yet bound the minimum
level of corn ethanol demand (EPA, 2008; Federal
Register, 2008; Christian, 2008). Similarly, minimum corn ethanol demand from an RFS is not
likely to bind supply for the next few years,
according to my calculations based on the 2008
policy rule (Table A1). The existing RFS minimum
consumption levels for renewable fuels will likely
not constrain the ethanol supply until after 2011
(see Figure 4). If the corn supply continues to grow,
however, margins would improve and increase
capacity utilization rates toward 100 percent.
The RFS seems to function as a government
“investment signal” that defines a potential minimum market size in the future. Indeed, as noted in
Table A1, by 2016 the corn ethanol required for the
RFS (13.5 billion gallons) almost exactly matches
the “after building” capacity shown at the bottom
of Table 2 (13.2 billion gallons). Hence, the RFS
has been a second-best investment policy that signals potential government support of ethanol prices
and offsets some of the risk associated with biofuels
investment. The risk justification for the RFS fits

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Gallagher

to the extent that there are no well-functioning
futures markets for forward pricing.
Presently, the RFS also influences the spatial
pattern of ethanol use and prices. Refiners now
have a renewable volume obligation (RVO) to (i)
prove their own ethanol blending at the refinery
(refiners can fulfill their RVO through the purchase
of ethanol with renewable inventory number [RIN]
certificates) or (ii) prove another blender’s use of
ethanol through the purchase of that blender’s RIN
number (RFA, 2008; EPA, 2007).
A look at recent spot market price spreads
between Texas and Iowa shows how prices may
have been influenced by policies and rapid expansion of ethanol consumption. Initially, margins
were wide, but recent margins are about equal to
ethanol transportation costs from Iowa to the Texas
Gulf Coast, about $0.05/gallon (Figure 8). Finally,
the recent market value of RIN certificates was
also about $0.05/gallon. Apparently, arbitrage has
forced equality between the cost of transporting
ethanol with an RIN number to a coastal refinery
and the market purchase price of an RIN certificate.

FIRM-LEVEL STRATEGIES TO
REDUCE PROCESSING COSTS
OR INCREASE REVENUES
Today’s narrow margins have induced the
development of new technologies and new firm
organizations. Seven approaches are listed in
Table 3. Together, these modifications have the
potential to reduce ethanol production costs by at
least $0.50/gallon. However, some of these cost
reductions merely offset recent cost increases that
have occurred elsewhere. Further, individual
firms may use only some and not all of the new
technologies.
Early adoption of high-starch corn varieties
for ethanol processing is likely because no capital
outlay is required. Typically, high-starch corn will
increase the ethanol yield and revenues but decrease
by-product (DG) yield and revenues. On balance,
the ethanol yield gain from a starch increase offsets
the DG loss.
Most new technologies require capital expenditure to retrofit the plant. For instance, biomass

Table 3
Ethanol-Processing Firms: Proposed
Strategies for Increased Profits
Cost reduction or
net revenue increase ($/gal)

Strategies
Cost-reducing technology
High-starch corn

0.130*

Biomass power

0.191†

Revenue-increasing technology
Dry fractionization

—

Quick germ process
Fiber extraction

0.039‡
—

Business reorganization
Improved diversification

0.072§

Local producer/processor

0.042¶

SOURCE: *Gallagher, Schamel, Shapouri, et al. (2006a, p. 125).
†Gallagher,
‡Taylor

Schamel, Shapouri, et al. (2006a, p. 127).

et al. (2001).

§Gallagher,

Shapouri, and Brubaker (2007, p. 76).

¶Gallagher,

Shapouri, and Brubaker (2007, p. 75).

power requires the installation of a boiler or gasifier
in the ethanol plant instead of gas turbines and
market purchases of electricity—a choice that could
increase ethanol-plant costs by 50 percent. However, the long-term benefit—replacing more expensive natural gas—could reduce processing costs
by as much as $0.19/gallon.
Another capital-using, but potentially profitable, set of technology options separates elements
from the DG by-product stream. The dry fractionation process for a dry mill, which separates bran,
grits, and germ in the initial grinding phase, requires
additional capital investment, but additional revenues are obtained by producing ethanol from the
fiber and a food-grade corn oil from the germ. There
are also other processes that extract oil from the DG
stream with a smaller capital investment (Taylor
et al., 2001). Reduced fiber and oil content in DG
is more palatable to livestock and can be fed at a
higher (feed per animal) rate.
Retrofitting an ethanol plant to produce butanol
is also a possibility. Weighed against the cost of
conversion, the benefits would be the increased

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

25

Gallagher

price for butanol. Butanol is an attractive blending
agent to some gasoline processors because its lower
vapor pressure allows more butane use in the fuel.
Modifying the business organization also has
profit-increasing potential. For instance, the interest rate charged to an ethanol enterprise in a welldiversified portfolio should be about 3 percentage
points lower than a stand-alone ethanol enterprise
because the risk premium is lower. In turn, the
reduced interest cost would translate to a $0.07/
gallon reduction in annual capital costs for the
premium.
Finally, a producer-owned enterprise with a
combination of firm and cooperative practices could
increase the overall farm/processor return in the
local production area by about $0.015/gallon. The
increase occurs because the input market area of
the processor can be extended beyond the boundary
of the traditional competitive firm for higher joint
profits.

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
In the broadest sense, the ethanol industry owes
its existence to increasing petroleum prices and a
highly successful corn technology industry that
sustained corn yield growth in a stagnant market
for two decades. The industry has been supported
along the way by a complete array of government
policies: Consumption subsidies, import duties,
and minimum consumption requirements have
all supported the demand for ethanol during the
industry development phase.
During the past few years, the ethanol-processing
industry overexpanded somewhat. First, ethanol
sales are large in relation to existing marketing
infrastructure and ethanol-using technology.
Second, the ethanol-processing expansion is somewhat larger than the corn input market that can be
sustained without large-scale displacement of competing uses of corn. Signs already indicate that new
capacity plans for ethanol will not be brought to the
market for a while. Instead, existing capacity plans
will likely be completed. Also, existing plants will
likely operate below capacity for a few more years
before the balance between ethanol capacity and
corn supply is restored.
26

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

For the near future, a shift from mandated
regional use defined by the RFS and toward voluntary marketing of E85 and E20 in the Midwest may
improve ethanol sector profits and economic efficiency generally. Consumer use of E20 is expected
to grow because currently the price of this premiumgrade fuel is lower than comparable gasoline, even
with recent low gasoline prices. However, EPA
regulations that limit ethanol blending to 10 percent
in conventional automotives must first be relaxed.
In preliminary testing, E20 drivability and emissions results are encouraging, but further evaluation is needed to precisely define the automobiles
and locations compatible with E20 use.
Improved production management that
squeezes more profits from the existing capacity
warrants closer scrutiny in the near future. Given
the success of past innovations, the early adopters
of new technologies are expected to thrive. Innovations by processors will reduce the margin between
corn ethanol and gasoline markets, which in turn,
will reduce fuel prices and improve consumer welfare and increase corn prices and improve farm
incomes.
The longer-run prospects for corn ethanol
expansion will be defined by technologies, market
events, and policy choices. For instance, more rapid
ethanol growth would be possible with accelerated corn yield growth. But eventually, profitability would still be restored if petro-fuel markets
remained above recent thresholds of ethanol competition and corn yields grew at historical rates.
On the other hand, corn ethanol expansion may
hinge on some complex policy choices in the corn
market. For instance, whether the United States
should continue to accommodate the destabilizing
behavior of our large trading partners is debatable.
Similarly, a prolonged meat export expansion, if
it should occur, could carry some adverse consequences. To wit, our land may be approaching its
manure-carrying capacity after decades of already
expanding meat exports. Also, the expansion of
meat exports would likely reduce the carbon dioxide balance and future policies may begin to limit
carbon emissions. In contrast, an expanding ethanol
industry could improve the carbon balance. A balance of payments gain from petroleum import
substitution is also likely.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Gallagher

The development of stover-to-ethanol technology would benefit society in several ways. Use of
the sustainable portion of the stover supplies would
increase ethanol production in the Corn Belt states
by 12 billion gallons and, in turn, increase the U.S.
fuel supply by 4 percent of petroleum production
and reduce U.S. petroleum prices by 6 percent,
yielding a net annual welfare gain to the U.S. economy of $3.2 billion (Gallagher and Johnson, 1999).
Importantly, feed/food and fuel production could
become complementary instead of potentially competitive because corn and stover are joint products
(National Research Council, 2000).
If left to market forces, the rate and scale of the
development of biomass ethanol processing (such
as stover-to-ethanol) could be impeded, which
underscores the need for government involvement.
First, industrial policy could prevent the duplication of investment and dilution of returns under
competition and therefore improve the public good
by encouraging development of new processing
technology at a lower cost (Krugman, 1983). But
later, new patents could define monopoly power
for technology owners and retard adoption. Second,
increased biofuel development/usage would have
positive externalities for the environment; for
instance, corn ethanol contributes to improvements
in greenhouse emissions (Gallagher and Shapouri,
2009). Also, ethanol has contributed to urban air
quality improvements (Gallagher et al., 2008). Third,
private sector evaluations of the fuel markets do not
fully account for the potential of biofuels to stem
the macroeconomic instability imposed by petroleum markets and OPEC market power (Gallagher
and Johnson, 1999). Fourth, government involvement may lessen the fear of the substantial risks
in biofuel processing in the volatile fuel and agricultural markets, thus encouraging innovations.
Fifth, new fuel-processing investments directed
solely by oil sector profits would deliver the highest
profits for petroleum resources—and perhaps for
the world economy—but U.S. interests would not
necessarily also be served.
The United States now pursues two policies that
promote the development of biomass-processing
capacity. First, the RFS defines minimum levels of
biomass-fuel production for the next 15 years (RFA,
2007). Second, government subsidies for the con-

struction of a few biomass-processing facilities have
been provided (U.S. Department of Energy, 2007).
Generally speaking, capital subsidies may make
more economic sense than market mandates
because (i) the full extent of the public commitment
is defined up front with a capital subsidy and (ii)
the annual revision of minimum production levels
in a political process under the RFS is discarded
in favor of a market-based determination of fuel
production. A shift toward the capital subsidy, and
away from the production mandate, would likely
improve economic efficiency.

REFERENCES
Christian, Scott. “The Renewable Fuel Standard and
Corn Ethanol.” Correspondence, September 19, 2008.
Elobeid, Amani; Tokgoz, Simla; Hayes, Dermot J.;
Babcock, Bruce A. and Hart, Chad E. “The Long-Run
Impact of Corn-Based Ethanol on the Grain, Oilseed,
and Livestock Sectors: A Preliminary Assessment.”
CARD Briefing Paper 06-BP 49, November 2006, Iowa
State University, Center for Agricultural and Rural
Development; www.card.iastate.edu/publications/
synopsis.aspx?id=1029.
“Energy Independence and Security Act of 2007;
Public Law 110-140.” December 18, 2007;
http://frwebgate.access.gpo.gov/cgi-bin/getdoc.cgi?
dbname=110_cong_bills&docid=f:h6enr.txt.pdf.
Environmental Protection Agency. “Revised Renewable
Fuel Standard for 2008, Issued Pursuant to Section
211(o) of the Clean Air Act as Amended by the Energy
Independence and Security Act of 2007.” Federal
Register, February 14, 2008, 73(31), pp. 8665-67.
Environmental Protection Agency. “Regulation of
Fuels and Fuel Additives: Renewable Fuel Standard
Program; Final Rule 40 CFR Part 80, Part II.” Federal
Register, May 1, 2007, 72(83), pp. 23900-24014.
Environmental Protection Agency. “Regulation of Fuels
and Fuel Additives: Standards for Reformulated and
Conventional Gasoline: Final Rule 40 CFR Part 80.”
Federal Register, February 16, 1995; www.epa.gov/
EPA-AIR/1995/February/Day-01/pr-365.html.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

27

Gallagher

Gallagher, Paul W. “A Market and Policy Interpretation
of Recent Developments in the World Ethanol
Industry.” Biofuels, Bioproducts and Biorefining,
October 2007, 1(2), pp. 103-18.
Gallagher, Paul. “Economics and Rural Development
of Bioenergy.” Issue Paper 27C in Bioenergy: Pointing
to the Future, November 2004, Iowa State University,
Council for Agricultural Science and Technology.
Gallagher, Paul. “Corn Trade and Policy,” in Dale Colyer;
P. Lynn Kennedy; William Amponsah; Stanley M.
Fletcher and Curtis M. Jolly, eds., Competition in
Agriculture: The United States in the World Market.
Binghamton, NY: Food Products Press, 2000.
Gallagher, Paul W.; Brubaker, Heather and Shapouri,
Hosein. “Plant Size: Capital Cost Relationships in
the Dry Mill Ethanol Industry.” Biomass & Bioenergy,
March 2005, 28(6), pp. 565-71.
Gallagher, Paul and Johnson, Donald L. “Some New
Ethanol Technology: Cost Competition and Adoption
Effects in the Petroleum Market.” Energy Journal,
April 1999, 29(2), pp. 89-120.
Gallagher, Paul; Lazarus, William; Shapouri, Hosein;
Conway, Roger and Duffield, Jim. “Some Health
Benefits of U.S. Clean Air Policy: A Statistical
Analysis.” International Association for Energy
Economics, 2008, Proceedings of the 31st IAEE
International Conference, Istanbul, Turkey, June 18-20,
2008; www.iaee.org/en/publications/
proceedingssearch.asp%.
Gallagher, Paul; Otto, Daniel and Dikeman, Mark.
“Effects of an Oxygen Requirement for Fuel in
Midwest Ethanol Markets and Local Economies.”
Review of Agricultural Economics, November 2000,
22(2), pp. 292-311.

Competitiveness of the U.S. Corn-Ethanol Industry:
A Comparison with Sugar-Ethanol Processing in
Brazil.” Agribusiness, Winter 2006a, 22(1), pp. 109-34.
Gallagher, Paul W. and Shapouri, Hosein. “Improving
Sustainability of the Corn-Ethanol Industry,” in Wim
Soetaert and Erick R. Vandamme, eds., Biofuels. West
Sussex, UK: John Wiley & Sons, 2009, pp. 223-33.
Gallagher, Paul; Shapouri, Hosein and Brubaker,
Heather. “Scale, Organization, and Profitability of
Ethanol Processing.” Canadian Journal of Agricultural
Economics, March 2007, 55(1), pp. 63-81.
Gallagher, Paul W.; Shapouri, Hosein and Price, Jeff.
“Welfare Maximization, Pricing and Allocation with
a Product Performance or Environmental Quality
Standard: Illustration for the Gasoline and Additives
Market.” International Journal of Production
Economics, January 2006b, 101(2), pp. 230-45.
Gallagher, Paul W.; Shapouri, Hosein; Price, Jeffrey;
Schamel, Guenter and Brubaker, Heather. “Some
Long-Run Effects of Growing Markets and Renewable
Fuel Standards on Additives Markets and the US
Ethanol Industry.” Journal of Policy Modeling,
September 2003, 25(7), pp. 585-608.
Gill, M. “Corn-Based Ethanol: Situation and Outlook.”
Feed Situation and Outlook Report, May 1987, U.S.
Department of Agriculture, Economic Research
Service, No. 302, pp. 30-37.
Holthausen, D. “Hedging and the Competitive Firm
under Price Uncertainty.” American Economic
Review, December 1979, 69(5), pp. 989-95.
Hyami, Yujiro and Peterson, Willis. “Social Returns to
Public Information Services: Statistical Reporting of
U.S. Farm Commodities.” American Economic Review,
March 1972, 62(1), pp. 119-30.

Gallagher, Paul; Otto, Daniel; Shapouri, Hosein; Price,
Jeff; Schamel, Guenter; Dikeman, Mark and Brubacker,
Heather. “The Effects of MTBE Bans on Ethanol
Production, Feed Markets, and Local Economies.”
Staff Paper No. 342, Iowa State University Economics
Department, June 30, 2001.

Kittleson, David; Tan, Andy and Zarling, Darrick.
“Demonstration and Drivability Project to Determine
the Feasibility of Using E20 as a Motor Fuel.”
Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Department of
Mechanical Engineering, October 19, 2007.

Gallagher, Paul; Schamel, Guenter; Shapouri, Hosein
and Heather Brubaker. “The International

Krugman, Paul R. “Targeted Industrial Policies: Theory
and Evidence.” Presented at the Industrial Change

28

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Gallagher

and Public Policy Symposium, Jackson Hole, WY,
August 24-26, 1983, sponsored by the Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City; www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/
sympos/1983/S83KRUGM.pdf.
National Research Council Committee on Biobased
Industrial Products. Biobased Industrial Products:
Research and Commercialization Priorities.
Washington, DC: National Academy Press, 2000.
Office of the Chief Economist’s Staff. World Agricultural
Supply and Demand Estimates (WASDE-446).
Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture
World Agricultural Outlook Board, May 11, 2007.
Office of the Chief Economist’s Staff. World Agricultural
Supply and Demand Estimates (WASDE-462).
Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture
World Agricultural Outlook Board, September 12,
2008.
Renewable Fuels Association. Renewable Fuels
Standard: Summary of the Biofuels Provisions—
Title II; www.ethanolrfa.org/resource/standard,
accessed August 28, 2008.
Renewable Fuels Association. “Position Paper: New
Ethanol and Biodiesel Tax Provisions in the American
Jobs Creation Act of 2004.” January 27, 2005;
www.ethanolrfa.org/view/?id=6.
Shockey, Richard E.; Aulich, Ted R.; Jones, Bruce;
Mead, Gary and Steevens, Paul. “Optimal Ethanol
Blend-Level Investigation: Final Report.” Prepared
for the American Coalition for Ethanol, November,
2007; http://ethanol.org.pdf/contentmgmmt/ACE_
Optimal_Ethanol_Blend_Level_Study_final_12507.pdf.

Stauffer, Thomas. “OPEC Prices and Non-OPEC Oil
Production: Survivors and Casualties of the ‘Market
Share’ Strategy.” OPEC Bulletin, April 1994, 25(4),
pp. 8-14.
Taylor, Frank; McAloon, Andrew J.; Craig, James C., Jr.;
Yang, Pingi; Wahjudi, Jenny and Eckhoff, Steven R.
“Fermentation and Costs of Fuel Ethanol from Corn
with Quick-Germ Process.” Applied Biochemistry
and Biotechnology, April 2001, 94(1), pp. 41-49.
Tierney, W. and Gidel, J. “2nd Week in a Row that RFA
Ethanol Plant List Boosts Capacity 600+ mlnglns.”
E-mail correspondence to R. Wisner, December 29,
2006.
Tomek, William G. and Gray, Roger W. “Temporal
Relationships among Price Relationships on
Commodity Futures Markets: Their Allocative and
Stabilizing Roles.” American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, August 1970, 52(3), pp. 372-80.
U.S. Department of Energy. “DOE Selects Six Cellulosic
Ethanol Plants for Up to $385 Million in Federal
Funding.” Washington, DC: U.S. Department of
Energy, February 28, 2007; www.energy.gov/news/
4827.htm.
West, Brian; Knoll, Keith; Clark, Wendy; Graves, Ronald;
Orban, John; Przesmitzki, Steve and Theiss, Timothy.
“Effects of Intermediate Ethanol Blends on Legacy
Vehicles and Small Non-Road Engines, Part 1.” Oak
Ridge, TN: Oak Ridge National Laboratory No. NREL/
TP-540-43543, ORNL/TM-2008/117, October 2008;
http://feerc.ornl.gov/publications/Int_blends_Rpt_1.pdf.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

29

Gallagher

APPENDIX A
Processing Supply Estimate
A statistical estimate of the processing supply function is denoted as follows:

U t = 0.6262 + 0.2505 M t – 0.3841 M t2 .
% % (12.6) (3.5)
(2.3)
R 2 = 0.50
root mean square error = 0.099
The numbers in parentheses below the coefficients are t-values.
Variable Definitions
Ut = utilization rate = Qet /St
Qet = ethanol production (billions of gallons)
St = ethanol production (billions of gallons)
Mt = margin less operating costs ($/bu of corn processed)

M t = Pet % Yet + Pdgt % Ydt − Pct − Copt
Pet = ethanol price in Iowa ($/gallon)
Yet = ethanol yield (2.7 gallons/bu corn)
Pdg = DG price ($/lb)
Ydt = Dg yield (1.75 lb/bu)
Pct = Corn price ($/bu)
Copt = operating (non-corn) costs ($/bu)

Capacity Adjustment
The estimate of ethanol capacity investment suggests that capacity responds to profits. ∆St , the rate
of capacity increase, will slow and eventually cease when zero profits are sustained.
The estimate is

∆st = 0.0433π t + 0.697∆st −1
% % % % % (2.9)
% % % % % % (5.1)

R 2 = 0.77% % Root % MSE = 0.070.

Historical Period (Annual Data): 1987-2008
Variable Definitions
∆st = st – st –1, and st = ln共St 兲
π t = Mt – kt
kt = unit capital cost ($/bu corn processed)
The constant, which suggests a steady rate of capacity increase when profits are zero, was not statistically significant in preliminary regressions, so it was discarded.
To see how capacity might adjust after 2008, notice that
St /St –1 = e0.043π 共St –1/St –2 兲0.697.
30

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Gallagher

Next, notice that S08 /S07 = 1.36, and suppose that π t = 0 is sustained for several years. Then (1 plus)
the percentage increase in capacity for the next 5 years would be
2009: 1.360.697 = 1.24,
2010: 1.240.697 = 1.16,
2011: 1.160.697 = 1.11,
2012: 1.110.697 = 1.07, and
2013: 1.070.697 = 1.05.
Thus, the rate of capacity increase would be only 5 percent after the 2012 crop year.
Suppose prices fall to variable costs (π t = –0.7). Then (1 plus) the percentage increase in capacity for
the next 5 years would be expressed as follows:
2009: 0.97 × 1.360.697 = 1.21,
2010: 0.97 × 1.210.697 = 1.11,
2011: 0.97 × 1.110.697 = 1.04,
2012: 0.97 × 1.000.697 = 1.00, and
2013: 0.97 × 1.070.697 = 0.97.
Thus, capacity decreases by 3 percent after the 2012 crop year.

Ethanol Price Discounts
In a market with well-informed consumers and uniform blending of ethanol into gasoline, the percentage price discount of ethanol compared with gasoline is positively related to the ethanol blending
rate (Gallagher, 2007). Statistically, the ethanol price discount can be explained by ethanol’s share of the
gasoline marketing volume:

dt = – 0.589 + 12.96X t
% % % (30.7) (16.57 )
R 2 = 0.95% % Root % MSE = 0.15.

Historical Period (Monthly Data): 2000-08
Variable Definitions
dt = 共Pgt – Pet 兲/Pgtr, where
Pgt = wholesale price for regular gasoline in Iowa ($/gallon)
Pgtr = retail price for regular gasoline in Iowa ($/gallon)
Xt = Det /Dgt
Det = ethanol demand in period t (billions of gallons)
Dgt = gasoline demand in period t (billions of gallons)
In general, the price elasticity of ethanol demand from the price-discount estimate is

E Qe .Pe = –

1 Pe 1
.
12.96 Pg r X

Using data from October 2008 yields the following:

E Qe .Pe = ( −0.0769 )( 0.75) (1 0.0646), % or % E Qe .Pe = 0.893.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

31

Gallagher

Table A1
RFS for Renewable Biofuel and Its Components
Soy oil for
biodiesel
(bil lb)

Actual
Biodiesel
anticipated
production Biodiesel
corn
(bil gal)‡
RFS credit§ production

Year

Renewable
biofuel*

Biodiesel
credit

Ethanol
imports†

Corn
ethanol
production

2006

4.00

0.73

0.19

3.09

3.10

0.43

0.73

4.86

2007

4.70

0.73

0.22

3.75

3.10

0.43

0.73

6.49

2008

9.00

0.73

0.47

7.80

3.10

0.43

0.73

8.49

2009

10.50

0.73

0.55

9.22

3.10

0.43

0.73

9.97

2010

12.00

0.73

0.64

10.63

3.10

0.43

0.73

10.93

2011

12.60

0.73

0.67

11.20

3.10

0.43

0.73

10.93

2012

13.20

0.73

0.71

11.76

3.10

0.43

0.73

2013

13.80

0.73

0.74

12.33

3.10

0.43

0.73

2014

14.40

0.73

0.77

12.90

3.10

0.43

0.73

2015

15.00

0.73

0.81

13.46

3.10

0.43

0.73

2016

15.00

0.73

0.81

13.46

3.10

0.43

0.73

NOTE: All production data listed in billions of gallons unless otherwise stated.
*Defined by Energy Independence and Security Act (2007).
†Six

percent of corn ethanol production.

‡0.43
§1.7

bu/gal biodiesel = 3.10 billion lb soy oil × 共0.985 lb biodiesel/1 lb soy oil兲 × 共1 gal biodiesel/7.114 lb biodiesel兲.

× biodiesel production.

APPENDIX B
In a widely used test of future market performance, Tomek and Gray (1970) proposed a regression
comparison of actual post-harvest cash prices and the futures price quotation in the planting period for
delivery in the post-harvest period. To update, we used the following regression:

Pct +1 = α + β Pftt +1 + εt ,
where Pct +1 is the actual corn cash price (December futures price) on December 11 (November 18 for 2008)
of the following crop year, Pftt +1 is the April 30 corn futures price for delivery in the following December,
and εt is a random disturbance term.
The idea is that the parameters take on particular values when the futures market is performing adequately. Specifically, α = 0 and β = 1 when futures prices are an unbiased forecast of the upcoming market
price.
The significance of this result is that economic agents who use the futures price as an expected price
can shed the risk associated with production or inventory holding under uncertainty (Holthausen, 1979).
Further, the producer who sees future output on future markets will, on average, produce the same output
or hold the same inventory as a risk-neutral agent.

32

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Gallagher

Figure B1
Corn Futures Prices, Cash Prices, and Cash Price Predictions
December Cash Price, $/Bushel
7.00

6.00

5.00

4.00

3.00

2.00
Actual
Regression
Unbiased

1.00

0.00
0.00

1.00

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

7.00

April Futures Price, $/Bushel

We estimated the following price relationship for the 1980-81 to 2007-08 period:

Pct +1 = 1.269 + 0.462Pftt +1
% % % % % % % % % % % % % % % (3.6)% % % % % % % % (3.8 )
R 2 = 0.32% % DW = 2.01% % s = 0.52.
t-Tests reject the unbiased futures price hypothesis. The statistic is tα = 3.0 under the null hypothesis
that α = 0. Similarly, the test statistic is tβ = 4.37 under the null hypothesis that β = 1.
The upshot is that the springtime futures price tends to be above the actual cash price, especially when
futures prices are above their mean for the historical period (Figure B1), so corn producers can increase their
average returns by forward pricing in the futures market. In contrast, corn users such as ethanol plants
will reduce their average returns by forward pricing in the futures market.
Oddly, the variability in the springtime futures price is higher (SD = $0.80/bu) than the variability of
the December cash price (SD = $0.63/bu). Hence, routine hedging by producers or consumers would tend
to be more risky than unhedged sales or purchases on the cash market.
For comparison, Tomek and Gray (1970) found that the corn futures market performed well over the
1952-68 period. That is, estimated values approximately verified the unbiased forecast result with α = 0
and β = 1. Furthermore, the SD of the cash price exceeded the SD of the futures price, so using the futures
reduced price variability.
Overall, results suggest that the corn futures market performed better in the 1952-68 period. For reasons
to explain the difference, notice that trading was limited to futures contracts in the early period and speculators focused mainly on upcoming corn market conditions. In contrast, options and derivatives trading
was prevalent over the past two decades. Further, speculation on the macroeconomic inflation rates in
commodity markets has become commonplace in recent years.
F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

33

Commentary
Martha A. Schlicher

I

f we could create the perfect fuel, what
would that be? It would be a fuel that
would burn clean, improving the quality of
our air. It would be a fuel that comes from
many diverse, renewable resources so that we
wouldn’t be dependent on any one source and
sources would never be depleted. It would be a
fuel derived from readily available resources that
have alternative uses, meaning that a raw supply
infrastructure is already in place—and ideally,
from which multiple products, in addition to
fuel, could be made. It would be a fuel that
would be miscible with current fuels, which
would allow for its ready and economical use in
existing vehicles and with the existing fuel-delivery infrastructure.
Time is not an ally and so our perfect fuel would
be able to be produced immediately, bypassing
Nobel Prize–winning science, unresolved technology issues, and uncertainty. Our fuel would be produced close to where it would be used, on a small
enough scale that barriers to entry would be minimized, fuel costs to transport the product would be
low, and the risk of centralized supplies or production to our national security would be lessened. It
would be a fuel that would run as efficiently, or even
more efficiently, than gasoline does today with little
or no vehicle modifications. And finally, it would
be a fuel that would readily break down in soil or
water, which would dramatically reduce the environmental consequence of an accidental spill.
Does such a unique combination of attributes
exist? Or is the list of desired criteria too lofty to

ever achieve and thus sentences us to a future of
gasoline and its negative consequences?
Astonishingly, a fuel that meets all of these
criteria exists today. Ethanol from corn will provide
U.S. vehicles more than 10 billion gallons of their
fuel consumption in 2009. In the next several years,
ethanol from a multitude of other feedstocks (such
as garbage, wood chips, and unused plant material)
could greatly increase our domestic renewable fuel
production.
Despite the already significant contribution to
our ongoing fuel needs and tremendous prospects
for future contributions in only a few short years,
ethanol’s brightest days may be in the rearview
mirror (of a car fueled by Mideast and Venezuelan
oil).
How could a source that today meets so many
of our objectives for a perfect fuel become so unpopular? How could the United States forgo a substantial and growing renewable fuel source for concepts
that “may deliver something better, someday”?
The concept of ethanol as a renewable fuel was
believed to be the ultimate vehicle fuel solution
as far back as the turn of the last century with great
agriculturalists like George Washington Carver,
great industrialists like Henry Ford, and great
inventors like Thomas Edison (Kovarik, 1998). The
idea was revitalized in the 1970s during the Arab oil
embargo when we feared for the security of our oil
supplies (Shapouri, Duffield, and Graboski, 1995).
The idea came back again in the mid-1980s when
corn growers realized their net return from burning a bushel of corn was greater than from selling
it to the feed market (Dorn, 2005).

Martha A. Schlicher is vice president of business and technology, GTL Resources.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economic Development, 2009, 5(1), pp. 34-41.

© 2009, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced,
published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

34

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Schlicher

The idea made sense and the time was right.
Energy costs were high, with corn worth more as a
fuel than as a feed. Agricultural corn productivity
continued to gain with no increased outlet and thus
corn prices continued to languish. And standard
production technologies for corn-based ethanol had
been optimized such that plants could be built in
an assembly-line fashion to run reproducibly and
reliably.
The U.S. ethanol industry started when farmers,
livestock producers, local businesses, and cooperatives pooled their own capital and invested in
new-generation corn-based ethanol plants. Their
objectives were clear: Increase demand for their
product and create new revenue opportunities.
What could not have been fully understood at the
time was the positive impact of these plants on
the environment and on revitalizing rural communities by creating jobs, new income, and new tax
sources.
Growth of the corn-based ethanol industry was
evolutionary, initially with plants averaging 20
million gallons per year (MGY) of production capacity (Hettinga et al., 2009). These early cooperatives
were firmly rooted in rural agriculture. They were
composed of local equity investment and agricultural debt providers who understood the cyclical
nature inherent in agriculture and the low margins
that could be expected from a commodity business.
The majority of this growth was in the western U.S.
Corn Belt where corn yields were high, local livestock production could use the animal feed coproducts, and local and regional markets could use the
ethanol. Rail lines built to ship grain to California
could also deliver ethanol and the animal feed
resulting from ethanol production.
Modest plant construction allowed corn productivity growth to keep pace with the increased
demand for corn (Korves, 2008). In other words,
while farmers consistently increased their productivity (yields) in small increments each year, the
small incremental growth of ethanol plants and
the corn supply they required was not disruptive
to corn supply and demand.
The ethanol produced in those early plants
helped to meet the reformulated gasoline requirements in clean-air attainment zones and began to
make its way into broader E10 (gasoline mixed

with 10 percent ethanol) and E85 (gasoline mixed
with 85 percent ethanol) applications. Investors
were satisfied with their modest returns because
of the ancillary benefits: a local alternative market
for their corn, jobs for their community, and incremental expenditures for other services the plant
required. The hardware store, the corn grower, the
grocery store, the bank, the restaurants, the municipal government, and the local environment all
benefited.
Demand for ethanol rose as states’ clean-air
requirements began to phase out gasoline oxygenate
additives suspected of causing cancer (methyl
tertiary-butyl ether [MTBE]), turning instead to
ethanol. This new demand was accelerated by federal legislation that prescribed renewable fuels as
a component of the gasoline blend. The 2005 Energy
Policy Act (EPACT; Energy Policy Act, 2005) provided a renewable fuel standard (RFS) requirement
for major petroleum blenders to blend 7.5 billion
gallons per year (BGY) of renewable fuel (largely
ethanol) with gasoline by 2015. More importantly,
the act provided no limited liability protection for
the use of MTBE. Because of the mandatory requirements to blend fuels to meet clean-air requirements,
the oil industry now needed to blend fuels above
the minimum level stipulated by the RFS. They
rapidly exited their MTBE contracts and moved
into ethanol, which briefly drove up the price of
ethanol from less than $2.00 gallon in November
of 2005 to $4.00 per gallon and higher prices by
June 2006 (Center for Agricultural and Rural
Development [CARD]).
Federal legislation created a clear marketing
opportunity, and new investors from outside traditional agriculture entered the market. These new
investors augmented local investors, which allowed
equity to be raised more quickly. Many of these new
investors also brought their knowledge and expertise from other industries and were astonished to
find that the modern ethanol production technologies lacked many of the advancements commonplace in other process manufacturing facilities.
While many investors were interested in dramatically improving the process and energy efficiencies of new ethanol plants with readily available
technology, they were quick to learn that established
financing structures prevented funding of anything

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

35

Schlicher

but a standard plant design template. Debt providers
for new plants wanted a “sure thing” to quickly
exploit the market opportunity. Improving plant
technology and efficiency was not their motive for
entering the market. Although higher debt loads
were allowed to accommodate higher construction
costs in a booming market, significant incremental
operational requirements that added cost were also
brought in. These requirements often included the
use of external providers for corn merchandising,
risk management, ethanol marketing, and coproduct
marketing. Senior debt covenants limited incremental capital investment, which further restricted
the adoption of significant technological improvements that experienced industrial manufacturers
viewed as fundamental to the industry’s future
operational and financial success.
Providers of ethanol-processing equipment
were also slow to push new and better technology
because the new owners were positioned to buy
quickly from the preestablished menu. The “old
stuff” was clearly in high demand, commanding a
premium, and selling in volume. Providers were
having difficulty meeting demand and resources
were not available to invest in the future. Reminiscent of Henry Ford’s first Model T assembly lines,
you could purchase and finance any process design
“as long as it was black.”
While it was expected that Wall Street’s deep
pockets would bring modern technology investments that would positively evolve the plants, this
was not the case. New owners faced a dilemma: a
choice of available project financing if they accepted
the current state of technology, or an inability to
finance their projects if they tried to improve them.
Most invested, believing they would first pay off
their debt and then add the diversification and
enhancement capabilities core to a successful
industrial production facility.
Logistical efficiencies remained despite growth
of the industry because ethanol plant coproducts
could now directly substitute for corn transported
to cattle feed markets. These coproducts, containing all the protein, fat, and fiber of corn in a more
concentrated form, cost less to transport per pound
of nutrient value. West Coast markets matured, and
southern and eastern ethanol and feed markets
began to develop. Thus, plants began to spring up
36

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

in the eastern Corn Belt with eastern-serving rail
service. U.S. ethanol production capacity increased
30 percent from the end of 2005 to the end of 2006
(Renewable Fuels Association [RFA]). The large
volume of corn-based ethanol now entering the
distribution channel was beginning to take market
share from petroleum refiners.
The nonagricultural state environmental groups
became concerned that the growth of corn-based
ethanol forced more land into cultivation and negatively affected our global carbon footprint. A
groundswell of interest had also developed from
earlier Department of Energy (DOE) work about the
promise of using “wasteland” (nonproductive land)
for the production of biomass crops that could
“eliminate all the problems associated with corn
based ethanol.” Environmental groups, academic
groups, DOE scientists with looming job cuts, and
states with vast acres of nonproductive land coalesced to create broad-spread bipartisan support for
a bill that would limit corn-based ethanol and pin
future promise on alternative feedstocks and fuels.
In December 2007, the Energy Independence
and Security Act (EISA) of 2007 was enacted, mandating 15 BGY of ethanol by 2015—up from the 7.5
BGY mandated in EPACT—and 36 BGY of renewable fuels by 2022 (EISA, 2007). Fifteen BGY was
allowed for corn-based ethanol, and the remainder
was allocated to cellulosic and other advanced biofuels (defined as any renewable feedstock except
corn-based starch to ethanol). A ceiling was placed
on corn-based ethanol because it was believed the
need for corn for both food and fuel was causing
additional land to go into agronomic production
with speculated negative environmental consequences. EISA mandated that renewable fuels must
demonstrate a carbon footprint 50 percent to 60
percent better than conventional gasoline and that
new corn-based ethanol production facilities must
demonstrate a footprint 20 percent better than
gasoline.
In his February 2007 State of the Union speech,
President George W. Bush proclaimed that 36 BGY
of renewable fuel production, outlined in the yet to
be passed Energy Bill, would allow us to eliminate
three-quarters of all the oil currently imported
from the Middle East…as if the 16 BGY associated
with cellulosic ethanol was right around the corner.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Schlicher

The bill misrepresented what was possible given
the current state of the science, providing the
American public with a false understanding of the
current potential of renewable fuels. The new law
additionally served as a lightning rod to those
already opposed to renewable fuels to organize and
actively oppose its vision and the tangible reality
of 15 BGY from corn-based ethanol.
Most astonishingly, the new bill provided the
framework for the demise of the existing corn-based
ethanol industry, which would effectively end the
cellulosic-based industry before it was ever allowed
to start. The bill neglected to offer a plan providing
for the transition from an existing technology (cornbased ethanol) to the experimental technology
(cellulosic ethanol) or for a certain channel for the
product. Such a plan would have ensured a steady
and increasing volume of renewable fuel to meet
the requirements established in the RFS and a distribution system for it.
First, the vast operational efficiencies available
to corn-based ethanol through available technology
were bypassed for an alternative fuel that is literally
still on the drawing boards. Second, the bill lacked
a viable implementation plan to provide a mechanism for blending the renewable fuels mandated
into the existing gasoline supply. Third, the bill
created an ill-defined requirement for biofuels to
achieve life-cycle greenhouse gas reductions relative to gasoline produced in 2005, including any
indirect impact of the use of the land for biofuel
production. Finally, the 15 billion gallons of corn
ethanol allowed by the RFS immediately created a
real and significant threat to the oil industry.
The EISA capped corn-based ethanol volume
via a false premise that inaccurately compared it
with other fuels while failing to recognize the wellknown fact that corn ethanol performance could
substantially improve with modest investment in
available technology. In determining RFS-required
volumes, the bill compared today’s nascent cornbased ethanol industry with the mature sugar cane–
based ethanol industry and the theoretical cellulosic
ethanol industry in its risk/reward assumptions.
This was one of the most frustrating aspects of the
bill—it included narrowly selected measurements
of the impact of renewable fuels, with limited

extrapolation of their future potential, and then
used these assumptions to dictate volume limits
15 years into the future.
For example, because sugar cane–based and
cellulosic-based ethanol combust their by-products
to fuel their plants, with the RFS measurements
they are credited with minimizing fossil fuel use.
In contrast, corn-based ethanol production is not
recognized as having the same ability to minimize
its fossil fuel use, even though this possibility
exists. With this comparison, the bill wrongly relies
on old corn ethanol technology performance and
willfully ignores not only the new corn ethanol
technology but also the current scientific and technological work that will result in commercial
application during the life of the bill. And while
legislators overlooked the potential of an industry
already providing more than 9 BGY with outdated
technology, future manufacturing concepts yet to
be proved were not so burdened. As noted, sugar
cane–based and cellulosic-based ethanol were
again assumed to use their by-products to fuel
their plants. Never were the technologies of a
corn-based ethanol plant, with the adoption of
technologies commercially viable today, used as
the basis of comparison with either sugar cane–
or cellulosic-based technologies. This yawning
recognition gap in the opportunity for continued
adoption of new technologies—allowing cornbased ethanol to deliver in the near term the same
environmental benefits as cellulosic-based ethanol
when it moves out of the laboratory and into commercial application—was completely missing from
the 2007 EISA.
In addition to capping the volumes of allowable
corn-based ethanol, the base number of gallons
allowed was assumed “mature” and incapable of
improving over time such that additional gallons
could be warranted. Second, DOE funding was
focused on an initiative to create a future technology. No funding was provided as a bridge from the
current technology to that future state. This gap
created the real and significant potential for the
demise of the existing ethanol industry. With no
future corn-based ethanol industry, no outlet above
10 BGY of production would be required, thereby
eliminating the need for infrastructure development to ensure a future outlet for cellulosic ethanol

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

37

Schlicher

technologies. This, by definition, capped our commitment to renewable fuel at a volume less than
10 percent of our gasoline usage and well below
our imported volume of oil.
Why is corn ethanol’s success essential to
cellulosics? Although cellulosic ethanol remains
a promising future fuel for reducing our dependence on gasoline as a vehicle fuel source, the time
required for cellulosic ethanol to overcome significant feedstock, logistical, and production issues is
not insignificant and well beyond the time allotted
for production volumes established in the RFS.
Additionally, the first significant volume of cellulosic ethanol is likely to come from the fiber already
brought into existing corn ethanol production facilities as a part of the corn kernel. This type of cellulosic ethanol is not a new concept and, in addition
to wood chips, is the nearest-term viable means
of producing cellulosic ethanol. It is important to
note that efforts have existed since the oil crisis
of the 1970s to demonstrate its commercial viability. In 1993, the DOE National Renewable Energy
Laboratory (NREL) declared its technology for converting corn cellulose ethanol ready for commercialization (NREL, 1993). Fifteen years and billions of
dollars later, corn cellulose is still not ready to be
produced on a commercial scale. And this technology, requiring only process-conversion technology
development, will be ready long before the incremental work required to develop energy crops still
in the developmental stages.
The current corn-based ethanol industry provides a means of developing the infrastructure
required for cellulosic ethanol distribution. With
lower costs of production and a real product to distribute, corn-based ethanol should be in a position
to bear, along with the petroleum industry, the costs
for infrastructure development.
The Energy Bill did not adequately address the
infrastructure challenges of a 36 BGY RFS. This
created a constraint for market growth and thus a
supply/demand-driven market demise via margin
erosion. The RFS of 36 BGY implied that 36 BGY
of renewable fuels would be blended into the existing petroleum base of 140 BGY of gasoline-based
transportation fuel. Gasoline infrastructure today
allows for the blending of ethanol up to 10 percent
in conventional vehicles, or roughly 11.6 BGY. This
38

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

number excludes states that do not allow blending
at 10 percent and small refiners not required to
blend.
Higher use of E85 would create a significant
incremental outlet for ethanol. However, while a
blenders’ credit of $0.51/gallon was created in
EPACT and retained in EISA (reduced to $0.45/
gallon in 2009) for the petroleum industry to add
the infrastructure required for full incorporation
of E10 and adoption of E85, there has been little to
no adoption of E85 by the major oil companies.
With ethanol distribution today limited to E10,
the size of the market for E10 is entirely dependent
on the RFS floor (10.5 BGY in 2009) when ethanol
prices (including the blenders’ credit) exceed gasoline prices and is capped when gasoline prices
exceed ethanol prices by the ability to blend E10:
today approximately 12 to 13 BGY. Additionally,
because petroleum blenders are allowed to “carry
over” a portion of their blending requirements,
even with an RFS floor, use of higher blend levels
when ethanol’s price is low allows blenders to
underblend when the ethanol price is high. With
2008 use well above the RFS, petroleum blenders’
2009 mandatory blending—at an ethanol price
greater than gasoline—could be 1 to 2 BG less than
the 10.5 BG mandated.
As the Energy Bill was passed, incremental
ethanol capacity was already under development
because its lead time from construction to operation is more than two years. Thus, despite significantly reduced margins and production already
above and beyond the new RFS schedule, the industry, with already committed capital, moved from
56 plants in 2000 producing 1.8 BGY to more than
180 plants in 2008 capable of producing more
than 10 BGY (RFA). Thus, installed ethanol plant
capacity was on line to meet the RFS mandate for
2009, 2010, and beyond. All capacity now became
vulnerable with production volumes above the RFS
and the lack of a “blending home.” Older plants
faced higher operating costs and inefficient logistics;
newer plants faced higher debt loads. No plants
were positioned to have the capital available or
accessible to add technological innovations to
improve their base assets.
Rapid industry capacity growth created speculation about the dramatic increase in the renewable

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Schlicher

fuel industry purchasing a portion of the annual
U.S. corn crop, which led to corn market speculation that resulted in skyrocketing corn prices.
Further, a poor European wheat harvest, increased
global demand for grain, and dramatic flooding
across key parts of the U.S. Corn Belt combined to
create uncertainty about 2008 corn production.
High and erratic corn pricing resulted, surpassed
only by new highs in the price for oil and gasoline
at the pump. Food companies raised prices to protect margins and were quick to cast the blame on
fuel-based ethanol’s demand for corn despite the
small cost of grain to their total product cost
(Rosenfeld, 2008).
Oil companies were further threatened by the
growing volume of ethanol reducing their refining
capacity needs. Food companies were threatened
by an alternative demand for their feedstock that
increased prices. A well-funded, well-organized
campaign convinced consumers and legislators
around the world that corn-based ethanol was causing starvation and food riots. An organized, factbased information campaign was never conceived
by the fragmented and poorly funded ethanol industry. Many of the anti-ethanol campaign messages
are now taken as fact by legislators, the media, and
other stakeholders.
Seizing another opportunity to increase the
vulnerability of the industry, those opposed to
corn-based ethanol began a similar campaign
related to the life-cycle assessment requirements
outlined in the Energy Bill. A campaign suggesting
that land used for fuel instead of food production
was not being appropriately penalized for its global
warming impact in determining the fuel’s environmental benefits. Because this criterion had never
been used to determine any alternative use—say,
the impact of a new subdivision, an acre grown for
nonhealthy versus healthy food, or a marginal acre
used for cellulosic instead of food production—
new theories about how to make this determination
were placed on the back of—and remain on the
back of—corn-based ethanol.
The number of U.S. farm acres has largely
remained flat and total tonnage of protein, fat, and
fiber available for food consumption is greater than
at any time in U.S. history (despite the increase
in corn-based ethanol production), yet it is now

believed important that an environmental penalty
be assigned to corn-based ethanol in the form of the
indirect land impacted—that is, the land forced
into production, from the U.S. use of a portion of
its corn crop for corn-based ethanol. The ongoing
debate about how to determine and assign indirect
land use environmental impacts in the form of its
global warming impact to corn-based ethanol production—first to corn and then to cellulosic
ethanol—successfully creates further uncertainty
about the future of renewables, effectively stalling
future investment to improve the base industry or
to create incremental capacity.
Despite all this, the mid-2008 U.S. Department
of Agriculture (USDA) production reports were
beginning to indicate that corn yields were on track
for another bumper crop. At the same time the
economy began to falter, high gasoline prices led
to a precipitous drop in fuel consumption and miles
driven, and corn prices plummeted from a high of
$7.99/bushel in late June to $5.40 in mid-August
(Platts, 2008). Ethanol companies, unable to lock
in margins owing to the lack of a forward market
from the oil companies for ethanol, were caught
with corn cost positions exceeding ethanol sales
prices. A number of these companies, with significant exposure, took large write-offs, required additional capital infusions from shareholders, or
declared bankruptcy. With the ethanol supply continuing to exceed mandated demand and at a price
above which discretionary blending of ethanol is
unattractive, ethanol margins remained razor-thin
and often negative.
Stalled construction, a lack of new construction,
and continued bankruptcies continued to reduce
available capacity, leading to production 20 percent
below available capacity (Caldwell, 2008). A lack
of confidence in the future of the industry limited
interest in acquisition of existing facilities or the
investment required to transform these facilities
into true biorefineries that could also produce food
and eliminate their fossil fuel use.
Cellulosic start-ups began to announce delays
in technology development, the ability to access
and develop feedstock, and the ability to secure
financing. The DOE publicly indicated that the
near-term RFS goals for cellulosic ethanol would not
be met (U.S. Energy Information Administration,
2008). In addition, overcoming the cellulosic tech-

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

39

Schlicher

nical hurdles to meet the RFS-mandated volume
and meeting the timeline objectives outlined in
the Energy Bill are proving difficult. Corn-based
ethanol could most certainly help to bridge this
gap, even if the industry is held to the same global
warming reduction impacts possible with cellulosics, yet we have turned our back on it. Thus,
while oil and gasoline imports continue, more than
2 BGY (>20%) of the existing available capacity for
corn-based ethanol is idled and estimates suggest
another 2 BGY reduction is possible.
All of this is happening when a simple solution
exists. Instead of the DOE and the USDA funding
only the speculative and basic research needs of a
future industry, they could, in addition, provide
grants and loan guarantees for the adoption of currently available and commercially demonstrated
technologies in existing corn-based production
facilities. These facilities would be those with a
demonstrated ability to produce fuel and an interest
in and ability to incorporate readily available technologies. These technologies would allow cornbased ethanol to deliver environmentally and
economically viable ethanol with a 50 percent
reduction in the carbon footprint impact—an
impact that today is already 40 percent better than
gasoline (Mueller and Copenhaver, 2008). This
approach would bridge the time gap and technological innovation required for the introduction
of cellulosic ethanol and other advanced biofuels
today. This would allow time for the development
of the blending infrastructure and regulations
required to blend above the 10 percent level, it
would ensure continued diversification of our fuel
supply, and it would allow time for the development of the innovations so critical to the future of
our energy independence.

REFERENCES
Bush, George W. “State of the Union Address.”
January 23, 2007; www.cbsnews.com/stories/2007/
01/23/politics/main2391957.shtml.
Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa
State University. “Historic Ethanol Margins.” Ames,
IA: Iowa State University; www.card.iastate.edu/
research/bio/tools/hist_eth_gm.aspx.

40

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

Caldwell, Logan. “Two Year Ethanol Supply and
Demand Forecast.” Houston, TX: Houston Biofuels
Consultants, October 2008.
Dorn, Tom. “Burning Shelled Corn as a Heating Fuel.”
University of Nebraska Acreage and Small Farm
Insight. Lincoln, NE: University of Nebraska;
December 2005; http://acreage.unl.edu/newsletter/
NLS/Dec2005.htm.
“Energy Policy Act of 2005.” Pub. L. 109-58, 119 Stat.
594, August 8, 2005.
“Energy Independence and Security Act of 2007.”
Pub. L. No. 110-140, 121, Stat. 1492, December 2007.
Hettinga, W.G.; Junginger, H.M.; Decker, S.C.; Hoogwijk,
M.; McAloon, A.J. and Hicks, K.B. “Understanding
the Reductions in U.S. Corn Ethanol Production Costs:
An Experience Curve Approach.” Energy Policy,
January 2009, 37, 190-203.
Korves, Ross. “The Potential Role for Corn Ethanol in
Meeting the Energy Needs of the United States in
2016-2030.” Chelsea, MI: ProExporter Network;
October 2008; www.ilcorn.org/uploads/documents/
uploader/77for%20press%20conference.pdf.
Kovarick, Bill. “Henry Ford, Charles F. Kettering and
the ‘Fuel of the Future.’” Automotive History Review,
Spring 1998, 32, pp. 7-27; www.radford.edu/
~wkovarik/papers/fuel.html.
Mueller, Steffen and Copenhaver, Ken. “The Global
Warming and Land Use Impact of Corn Ethanol
Produced at the Illinois River Energy Center.”
Chicago: University of Illinois at Chicago, Energy
Resources Center, July 2008; www.ilcorn.org/uploads/
documents/uploader/79IRE%20GWI%20Study%
20Final072908.pdf.
National Renewable Energy Laboratory. “NREL Getting
Extra ‘Corn Squeezins.’” NREL Technology Brief:
NREL Advances in Technology at the National
Renewable Energy Laboratory, NREL Report No. MK336-5639, November 1993;
www.nrel.gov/docs/gen/old/5639.pdf.
Platts. “USDA Drops Corn Price Forecast 60 Cents to
$5.40/Bushel.” Boston: Platts, August 15, 2008;

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Schlicher

www.platts.com/Petrochemicals/highlights/2008/
petp_ppr_081508.xml.
Renewable Fuels Association. “Statistics.”
www.ethanolrfa.org/industry/statistics.
Rosenfeld, Irene. “Food as Fuel; Unintended
Consequences.” GMA Centennial Special Issue,
2008 Forum. Washington, DC: Grocery Manufacturers
Association; www.egmaforum.com/gma/2008csi/
?pg=38.
Shapouri, Hosein; Duffield, James A. and Graboski,
Michael S. “Estimating the Net Energy Balance of
Corn Ethanol.” Agricultural Economic Report
Number 721, United States Department of Agriculture,
July 1995; www.ethanol-gec.org/corn_eth.htm.
U.S. Energy Information Administration. “The Annual
Energy Outlook 2009.” Report No. DOE/EIA-0383.
Washington, DC: USEIA, December 2008;
www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/aeo/overview.html.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

41

Economic and Environmental Impacts of
U.S. Corn Ethanol Production and Use
Douglas G. Tiffany
For many years, U.S. policy initiatives and incentives have favored the production of ethanol from
corn. The goals have been to increase corn prices and farmer income, enhance rural employment
through encouragement of value-added businesses, increase energy security, and produce additives
and/or fuels capable of reducing tailpipe pollutants and greenhouse gases. The Energy Policy Act
of 2005 established annual goals via a renewable fuels standard that would have increased production of ethanol and biodiesel to 7.5 billion gallons by 2012. That bill was superseded by the Energy
Independence and Security of Act of 2007, which increased usage targets and specified performance
standards for ethanol and other biofuels. The 2008 Farm Bill identified incentive payments for
ethanol produced in various ways. The effects of these three laws have been magnified by rising
crude oil prices, which helped maintain profits for corn dry-grind ethanol plants. This paper discusses environmental effects of corn ethanol production and use, energy balances of corn ethanol
versus gasoline, subsidies for corn ethanol and gasoline, impacts of ethanol production on farmer
decisionmaking, and effects of corn ethanol on food prices. (JEL Q4, Q42, R32)
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economic Development, 2009, 5(1), pp. 42-58.

T

he period from 2005 through 2008 has
probably seen some of the wildest swings
in magnitude in the economics of agriculture, as well as the entire U.S. economy in the past century. In 2008 alone, record high
prices for corn and other grains were followed by
a record sell-off of these commodities, which
accompanied the stock market sell-off of October
2008, a consequence of faulty regulation of currencies and financial instruments. These years saw
dramatic shifts in agricultural income not seen
since the early years of WWI or the years following
the “Russian Wheat Deal” of 1972. From 1914 to
1916, German U-boats sank ships laden with grain
and meat from the United States destined for wartorn Europe, reducing supplies of food crops and
agricultural products when the United States was
still neutral and trading with both sides. After the
Russian Wheat Deal, the world suddenly became

aware of the enhanced demand represented by
entry into world markets of new players, including
other Eastern European countries and China.
More recent history has been characterized by
U.S. government policies that encouraged the production of biofuels (for several reasons) and high
prices for commodities, including crude oil. This
article reviews the history of and motivations for
the policies encouraging corn ethanol production
and how the original intent of these policies became
magnified in a time of rapidly rising energy prices.
Throughout the following discussion, it is important to distinguish the effects of corn ethanol production from the amplified effects of corn ethanol
production resulting from crude oil price changes.
These changes were driven by a rapidly growing
demand for energy in emerging economies during
wars or potential conflicts that have involved key
petroleum-producing regions. Another factor of

Douglas G. Tiffany is an assistant professor in the University of Minnesota Extension Service.

© 2009, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced,
published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

42

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Tiffany

great importance is the financial community’s use
of futures markets for crude oil and other commodities as a hedge against further declines in the U.S.
dollar.
The economic consequences of corn ethanol
production in terms of environmental effects are
discussed. The entire process, from the production
of corn, to the fermentation and distillation of
ethanol, to the distribution and effects of ethanol
as a transportation fuel, also is addressed. A discussion and comparison of the energy balances for
ethanol and gasoline are included, as is discussion
of the net energy balance (NEB) of ethanol produced
from corn grain and by other methods. This examination of life-cycle energy inputs and outputs
reveals the net energy yields of biofuels and the
fossil fuels they typically replace.
The subsidy rates on corn ethanol are quantified
and compared relative to crude oil and the gasoline
that can be derived from it along with the effects of
corn ethanol on gasoline prices. The accumulated
effects of corn ethanol production on corn prices
and the ways in which these effects influence a
farmer’s decisions about crop choices for land under
tillage or land that could be brought back into tillage
are also discussed. Environmental issues certainly
must be considered when land-use decisions are
made. The levels of livestock feeding and the composition of livestock feed are also discussed.
Finally, corn ethanol’s effects on consumer food
prices are discussed. The price effects of ethanol’s
demand for corn have been dramatic; ethanol
plants quickly grasped their greater ability to pay
higher prices for corn than traditional markets for
livestock feed, both domestic and foreign. Once
again, a weak U.S. dollar exaggerated the effects of
ethanol production by making U.S. corn a great
bargain to foreign buyers, who maintained levels
of buying even as prices rose.

POLICY HISTORY
The U.S. government has sponsored and supported the production of fuel ethanol in various
ways over the years. During the Carter administration (when U.S. diplomats and embassy staffers
were held hostage by Iran), sponsorship of ethanol

found favor as the nation faced high crude oil prices
caused by supply curtailment by the Organization
of the Petroleum Exporting Countries. Later, crude
oil prices fell, and the goal of developing alternative domestic sources of transportation fuel was
put aside, taking with it the economic fortunes of
a number of relatively small ethanol producers.
Environmental goals replaced energy security
in the George H.W. Bush administration, when the
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) sought
to enforce provisions of the 1990 Clean Air Act
(EPA, 1990). Starting in 1995, the use of oxygenates,
including ethanol produced from corn, became
important as gasoline was modified to burn more
cleanly in urban settings to reduce the adverse
health effects of tailpipe emissions (i.e., criteria
pollutants). Ethanol drew political support from
farm groups who sought to create value-added
enterprises that could reduce crop surpluses and
raise corn prices.
Ethanol works very well as an oxygenate and
serves the valuable role of increasing the octane of
gasoline. However, the petroleum industry favored
an oxygenate that they could produce (i.e., methyl
tertiary-butyl ether [MTBE]) from relatively cheap
natural gas and from the by-products of petroleum
refining. Farm states generally favored, and some
farm states (such as Minnesota) mandated, that
ethanol be the oxygenate of choice over MTBE. The
modern boom in fuel ethanol expansion shifted
into high gear in 2005, when MTBE was banned
by numerous states and when the U.S. Congress,
in the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPA, 2005), failed
to grant the manufacturers of MTBE liability protection from environmental damage and health
claims.

ENVIRONMENTAL EFFECTS OF
ETHANOL USE AND PRODUCTION
Effects of Ethanol Use
Ethanol’s use as an oxygenate in gasoline was
mandated by the 1990 Clean Air Act. In 1995,
enforcement began as the U.S. EPA addressed air
quality and the use of oxygenates. These programs,
the Winter Oxygenate Fuel Program and the
Reformulated Gasoline (RFG) Program, were initi-

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

43

Tiffany

ated in response to evidence that poor air quality in
certain regions of the United States was damaging
human health. The Winter Oxygenate Fuel Program,
with a requirement for gasoline with 2.7 percent
oxygen content, was originally implemented in 36
areas of 23 states to reduce carbon monoxide levels
that became dangerous in certain cities in the
winter months. Many of these cities were at higher
elevations or in western states (EPA, 2008). Today,
improvements in engine performance and gasoline
composition have left just nine areas in the country
remaining in this program.
The RFG Program is more wide reaching; its
requirements affect approximately 30 percent of
the gasoline sold in the United States and the air
quality of approximately 75 million U.S. residents.
RFG must contain 2.0 percent oxygen. The primary
goal of using this fuel is the reduction of emissions
that contribute to ozone formation; an additional
goal is the reduction of toxic emissions such as
benzene (EPA, 2007).
The EPA staff has recently estimated that 7.5
billion gallons of ethanol will be needed to fulfill
the requirements of the Winter Oxygenate Fuel
Program, the RFG Program, and states’ mandates
for the period 2008-2022. This estimate assumes
greater vehicle-miles traveled with higher miles
per gallon in the latter years (Boledovich, 2008).
Further demand for ethanol may depend on
future EPA efforts to reduce aromatics, which are
used as octane enhancers in gasoline. At considerable expense, the EPA has already implemented
stricter standards for stationary sources of hazardous air pollutant emissions, such as hexane and
xylene, associated with tire production. In the
future, the EPA may choose to reduce hazardous
air pollutants further by implementing stricter
standards for mobile sources of aromatics in gasoline, a common source of particulate matter of 2.5
microns or less (PM2.5). It has been estimated that
replacement of aromatics in gasoline with another
octane enhancer will cost $250 billion per year
(Gray and Varcoe, 2005). Ethanol could be used as
a replacement; the added costs would be more
than offset by ethanol’s cost advantage over other
aromatic octane enhancers and by the net air toxic
reductions resulting from ethanol use. To reduce
80 percent of the aromatics currently in gasoline,
44

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

25 percent of the content of today’s conventional
gasoline would need to be replaced. This replacement would represent 37 billion gallons of ethanol
per year, approximately the goal for ethanol production in 2022 as articulated in the Energy Independence and Security Act of 2007 (EISA; Energy
Information Agency [EIA], 2007a; Gray and Varcoe,
2005). Implementation of this change would require
many more flexible-fuel vehicles (FFVs) in the U.S.
fleet, or car manufacturers would need to modify
warranty protection of vehicles using gasoline
blended with ethanol at levels approaching 25
percent.

Effects of Ethanol Production
Production of ethanol and other biofuels is
typically a more complicated process and leaves
a larger footprint in terms of land use than does
production of many fossil-fuel sources of energy.
Production involves the cultivation of land before
planting, spraying, harvest, and some level of primary tillage. Also, nitrogen fertilizer (which requires
natural gas as the feedstock and as the fuel source)
is typically applied. The other major nutrients that
are typically applied, phosphorus and potassium,
must be mined and refined and transported to farming areas. Energy used in the course of mining,
manufacturing, or transportation is embedded
energy. Overapplication of nitrogen, phosphorus,
or potassium can result in movement of these nutrients from the fields and into waterways, especially
in the cases of nitrogen and phosphorus. In the
field, nutrients are released or mineralized in the
natural process of decomposition of plant material
that grew in previous years. Embedded energy is
also used if irrigation is needed to grow the corn.
Diesel fuel and electricity are the typical energy
sources used to run the irrigation pumps.
At the ethanol processing plant or biorefinery,
greater amounts of energy are typically required
than were used in the growing and transporting of
the corn to the plant. Hill et al. (2006) identified a
32 percent expenditure of embedded energy at the
farmer’s field and a 68 percent expenditure at the
processing plant. The sources of energy at the processing plant are typically natural gas and electricity. In the United States, electricity is generated
from a number of sources, but the primary source

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Tiffany

is coal. In a typical ethanol plant, natural gas is
used for process heat to cook the corn mash formed
after the addition of water to powdered corn kernels
that had been ground by hammer mills powered
by electricity. Two types of enzymes are used to
sequentially enhance the flow of the mash and
convert the starches to sugars. Fermentation is
the process in which yeast converts the sugars to
ethanol in a period lasting from 55 to 70 hours. As
fermentation subsides, the ethanol is then stripped
by high-temperature steam from the liquid whole
stillage. The water is driven off from the wet stillage
in distillation columns, and molecular sieves are
used to remove the last of the water tightly held
by the ethanol molecules. The unfermented solids
of the corn kernels and yeast cells are removed by
centrifuge machines and are eventually used as
animal feed after being dried using natural gas as
a heat source. In about one-third of processing
plants, the carbon dioxide (CO2 ) released by the
respiring yeast is captured, chilled, and sold as a
liquid for use in making dry ice or carbonated
beverages. Approximately one-third of the energy
used at dry-grind ethanol plants is allocated to the
drying of the by-product, distillers’ dried grains
and solubles (DDGS).

CALCULATIONS OF NET ENERGY
BALANCE
The amounts of embedded energy used in the
life cycle of the entire process of ethanol production must be determined to calculate the NEB of
corn ethanol. The energy used at the field level, at
the biorefinery, and in transportation to the fuel
distribution center must be added and compared
with the energy found in the ethanol fuel and displaced by the by-product of processing that becomes
animal feed (i.e., DDGS). (Most life-cycle analyses
represent the energy of the feed by the amount of
direct and indirect energy that the feed displaces
by avoiding production of corn and soybean meal.)
Argonne National Laboratory has reported the NEB
of both gasoline and ethanol produced by the drygrind process. Gasoline produces 0.81 British thermal units (BTUs) for each BTU of fossil energy
applied in the process. Ethanol produces 1.36 BTUs

for every BTU of fossil fuel used when the entire
process of ethanol production by the dry-grind
process and the credits for the by-products are
considered (Hofstrand, 2007).
Figure 1 shows the analysis of a particular
study (Hill et al., 2006) in which the NEB of corn
ethanol was estimated at 1.25 to 1.0. This means
that for every unit of energy applied in the process,
1.25 units of energy are recovered in fuel or feed.
It is important to note that the results of calculations such as these are highly dependent on the
assumptions accepted. It is also important to recognize that in a year of poor corn yields, the NEB
would be reduced. This occurs because fewer
bushels of corn are produced despite the use of
liquid fuels to operate machinery and the embedded
energy associated with the application of fertilizer,
herbicides, and pesticides. The NEB of soy biodiesel
is presented alongside that of corn ethanol. The
various energy inputs and outputs from the processing of soybeans and soybean oil to make biodiesel
are shown. The energy applied at the field (F) or
plant (P) level is shown for both biofuels (Hill et al.,
2006).
Another set of calculations was performed on
a more elaborate ethanol plant that uses biomass
(e.g., corn stover1 or the concentrated wet stillage2
from the ethanol production process) as fuel for
process heat or even to generate electricity. Figure 2
shows the higher NEBs that result when process
heat, electricity for running the plant, or electricity
for sale to the grid are produced. Higher renewable
energy ratios can be realized by more efficiently
using biomass in more elegant and integrated systems. The conventional dry-grind ethanol plant
represented in Figure 2 has a renewable energy ratio
of 1.50 to 1.0, whereas a corn dry-grind ethanol
plant using corn stover as a fuel for process heat,
generation of electricity for plant operations, and
electricity for sale to the grid performs with a threefold higher ratio, exceeding 4.5 to 1.0 (De Kam,
Morey, and Tiffany, 2007).
1

Corn stover is the above-ground portion of the corn plant remaining
after harvest of the grain.

2

Concentrated wet stillage, or syrup, is a 30 percent solid material
derived from the liquid portion of the stillage after the ethanol has
been stripped away.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

45

Tiffany

Figure 1
Net Energy Balance of Corn Ethanol and Biodiesel Fuel
Process
(Biofuel + Co-Products)

1.8

Corn Grain Ethanol

Ouputs

1.6

Soybean Biodiesel

1.4

Soybean Meal

1.2

Glycerol

1.0
Facility Energy Use
Processing

0.8

P
F

0.6
0.4
0.2

Facility Laborer Energy Use
Facility Construction
Transportation

P
F

Inputs

Energy Input or Output (MJ) per Energy in Biofuel (MJ)

DDGS

Household Energy Use
Machinery Production

0.0
ts

ts

Soybean
Biodiesel

0.24
1.25

0.81
1.93

NEB
NEB Ratio

Farm

pu

In

pu

ut

O
ts

ts

pu

pu

In

ut

O

Corn Grain
Ethanol

Fertilizers and Pesticides
Fossil Fuel Use
Hybrid or Varietal Seed

NOTE: F, field level; P, plant level.

Related but more pertinent than determining
the net energy ratio is the concept of determining
the carbon footprint of biofuels and their relative
effects on greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Emerging policies suggest it may soon be possible to be
compensated for producing fuels with lower GHG
footprints than others. This concept underlies
efforts by California and other states to reduce the
carbon footprint of their fuels. This standard of GHG
reductions by biofuels was also delivered in the
2007 EISA, which established performance standards for advanced biofuels and cellulosic ethanol.3
Advanced biofuels are required to reduce GHG
46

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

emissions by 50 percent relative to gasoline, and
cellulosic ethanol is required to reduce GHG by
60 percent relative to gasoline.
Figure 3 displays the reductions in GHG that
can be achieved by production of ethanol in biorefineries using various technologies. Ethanol
produced at many conventional dry-grind plants
using natural gas and purchased electricity can be
expected to reduce GHG by 19 percent. Cellulosic
plants are predicted to reduce GHG by 86 percent,
3

Cellulosic ethanol is made from the non-starch, typically fibrous,
structural parts of plants, in contrast to most ethanol, which is made
from the starch contained in kernels of grain.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Tiffany

Figure 2
Renewable Energy Ratio (Lower Heating Value)
Ratio (Energy Returned/Fossil Energy Applied)
5.0
Corn Stover Combustion
Syrup and Corn Stover Combustion
4.5
DDGS Gasification
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0

Conventional

Process Heat

CHP

CHP + Grid

NOTE: CHP, combined heat and power.

Figure 3
Fuel Ethanol GHG Reductions Relative to Gasoline Well-to-Wheels GHG Emissions

10

Coal

Coal + Wet Current NG + NG and
DGS
Syrup
Elect.

DDGS

Biomass

Cellulosic
EtOH

3

0
–10
–20

–18

–19

–30
–40

–36

–39

–50
–60

–52

–70
–80
–90

–86

–100
Percent of Gasoline

NOTE: DGS, distillers’ grain with solubles; NG, natural gas; EtOH, ethanol.
SOURCE: Wang, Wu, and Huo (2007).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

47

Tiffany

which includes the production of a certain amount
of electricity that displaces amounts of emissions
from coal-fired power generation and other fossil
sources. Plants that display intermediate improvement in GHG emissions are labeled “biomass”;
they use woodchips, corn stover, or grasses to eliminate their requirements for process heat derived
from natural gas. The figure also shows that coalfired ethanol plants end up producing ethanol with
GHG emissions 3 percent greater than gasoline,
according to the Greenhouse Gases, Regulated
Emissions, and Energy Use in Transportation model
used by Argonne National Laboratory (Wang, Wu,
and Huo, 2007).

LAND-USE CONTROVERSIES
Changes in Land Use
The most controversial issues related to GHG
emissions associated with biofuel production are
the direct and indirect changes in land use that
occur when additional lands are devoted to production of biofuels. Controversy revolves around
the extent to which land-use changes, direct or
indirect, will be applied when determining the
GHG reductions that result from the production
and use of ethanol. The way in which the state of
California applies land-use changes when it implements its low-carbon fuel standard will be important
information for firms seeking to produce biofuels
for sale in that market because it will determine the
premium that may be available to particular biofuels. A similar decision on appropriate accounting for direct and indirect land-use changes is also
anticipated from the EPA.
In the February 29, 2008, issue of the journal
Science, two articles touched on the land-use issue
(Fargione et al., 2008; and Searchinger et al., 2008).
Fargione et al. (2008) at the University of Minnesota
examined direct land-use changes that would result
if lands parcels with various climax vegetative
covers were converted to cropland for production
of biofuels. This research team used published
literature to identify the amount of CO2 and other
GHG chemicals that would be emitted to the atmosphere if plants comprising the original vegetative
material were tilled under with the organic matter,
48

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

subsequently decomposed, and oxidized to release
GHG. Representative vegetative covers in various
climates of the world were assessed. In addition,
the research team calculated the number of years
required to recoup the CO2 emissions resulting
from conversion of the land to biofuel production
and compared this with the annual reductions in
CO2 emissions resulting from the production and
use of biofuels. For example, in Brazil, the conversion of cerrado grasslands to biofuel production
would require 37 years of biofuel production to
overcome the additional CO2 emissions. In the
United States, conversion of central grasslands to
grow corn for ethanol production would require
93 years to recoup the CO2 emissions from land
conversion. The area with the longest carbon debt
was determined to be the peatland rainforests of
Indonesia and Malaysia, where conversion of land
to palm oil plantations for biodiesel production
would require 423 years to recoup the CO2 emissions. In all, carbon debts were calculated for nine
land cover climatic regions.
Searchinger et al. (2008; Princeton and Iowa
State University) addressed indirect land-use
changes resulting from biofuel production in the
United States. These authors attempted to measure
the amount of land, largely outside the United
States, that would be converted to food crop production if ethanol production in the United States
were to increase from 15 billion gallons per year to
30 billion gallons per year. They sought to measure
the effect of increased U.S. domestic biofuel production on worldwide GHG emissions. A key
assumption underpinning this research is that
decreased production of food crops in the United
States (due to production of biofuels) will result in
higher commodity prices, signaling the possibility
of profitable production of food crops elsewhere
and prompting conversion of land to food crop production. By adding the GHG emissions of land-use
conversion in foreign lands induced by market
forces from using U.S. land for biofuels production,
this paper reported that the production and use
of ethanol from corn ethanol would result in net
greater emissions of GHG than gasoline.
These research reports have attracted criticism
for a variety of reasons. Some critics have expressed
concerns about the rationale for determining land-

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Tiffany

Table 1
Energy Information Agency and Koplow Estimates of Narrow Category of Subsidies
Direct
expenditures
($ millions)

Tax
expenditures
($ millions)

Research and
development
($ millions)

Federal
electricity support
($ millions)

Total
($ millions)

Natural gas and petroleum
liquids (EIA, 2007b)

—

2,090

39

20

2,149

Ethanol-low* (Koplow, 2007)

150

3,380

290

—

3,820

Energy beneficiary

NOTE: *Koplow differentiated between the amount of subsidy for the VEETC under “low” and “high” estimates as follows: “[The] primary
difference between high and low estimates is inclusion of outlay equivalent value for the volumetric excise tax credits. A gap in statutory
language allows the credit to be excluded from taxable income, greatly increasing their value to recipients” (footnote to Table 4.1, p. 29).

use changes related to U.S. biofuel production,
especially when the level of ethanol production
used in the Searchinger et al. (2008) model (30
billion gallons) exceeds by a factor of 2.0 the goal
set for corn-based ethanol production by the 2007
EISA (i.e., 15.0 billion gallons). Other critics assert
that economic and cultural forces, such as population growth and unrelated efforts for resource
development, were not taken into consideration.
Such forces have been behind efforts to clear land
since time immemorial, far in advance of the expansion of biofuel production. Still other critics have
stated that land conversion in other parts of the
world is not the result of orderly, calculated business decisions based on world grain prices but
instead reflects desires to harvest native timber
for quick cash by timber bandits.

SUBSIDY RATES FOR CORN
ETHANOL COMPARED WITH
OTHER FUELS
The topic of subsidies can be quite involved.
The Energy Information Agency (2007a) of the
Department of Energy reports subsidy levels with
identifiable budget impacts that conform to the
following categories for various types of energy:
• direct expenditures,
• tax expenditures,
• research and development, and
• electricity programs serving targeted
consumers and regions.

Others, such as Koplow (2007), separate the levels
into more encompassing categories of subsidies and
require additional assumptions about tax liabilities
of the recipients and market effects of any mandates,
tariffs, loan guarantees, and other tax treatment
items that may or may not be used. Some authors
categorize substantial national defense expenditures and other categories as subsidies for crude
oil and gasoline (International Center for Policy
Assessment, 1998).
EIA figures for ethanol are lumped in the category “renewables.” For gasoline, EIA figures are
lumped in the category “natural gas and petroleum
liquids.” Table 1 presents the federal government’s
(EIA, 2007a) subsidy figures for 2007 for natural
gas and petroleum liquids and Koplow’s (2007) low
subsidy estimates for similar categories for ethanol.
Koplow distinguishes between low and high estimates because of the ability of a firm that receives
a volumetric excise tax credit (VEETC) to use those
payments and their marginal tax rates. Use of the
low-estimate figure closely conforms to the assumption that most recipients of the VEETC will be able
to use $0.51 per gallon of ethanol blended.
Considering that the United States used 142
billion gallons of finished gasoline and produced
6.5 billion gallons of ethanol in 2007, one can estimate subsidy levels of $0.015 and $0.588 per gallon,
respectively, for gasoline and ethanol using these
narrowly defined definitions of subsidies that are
most easily documented (Renewable Fuels Association, 2008). However, the figure of $0.015 per gallon
for gasoline is certainly overstated because some

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

49

Tiffany

Table 2
Estimated 2007 U.S. Ethanol Subsidies per Gallon of Ethanol Produced
Estimate using low effect of VEETC
($ millions unless noted)

Subsidy category
Market price support

1,690

Output-linked support
Volumetric excise tax credit (low)

3,380*

Volumetric excise tax credit (high)

—

Reductions in state motor fuel taxes

410

Federal small producer tax credit

150*

Factors of production: Capital
Excess of accelerated over cost depreciation

220

Federal grants, demonstration projects, research and development

290*

Credit subsidies

110

Deferral of gain on sale of farm refineries to co-ops
Feedstock production (biofuel fraction)

20
640

Consumption
Credits for Clean Fuel Refueling Infrastructure
Total

30
6,940

Average subsidy per gallon of ethanol produced in 2007†

1.068

NOTE: *Categories recognized by the federal government.
†Based

on 6.5 billion gallons.

of the subsidy funds are applied to natural gas.
The largest subsidy for ethanol is the tax expenditure (or loss of tax revenue) resulting from the
VEETC, which was $3.38 billion in FY 2007. The
amount of this subsidy exceeded subsidies offered
to any conventional or renewable fuel in 2007 (EIA,
2008b). The VEETC was $0.51 per gallon through
the end of 2008, with a reduction to $0.45 per gallon starting in 2009. This credit is not received by
the farmers or the plants that produce ethanol; it
is a credit that the firms blending ethanol with
gasoline typically apply to their federal excise tax
liabilities. The availability of this credit rewards
sellers of gasoline as they buy, blend, and distribute
ethanol in gasoline. The existence of the VEETC
makes blenders of ethanol willing to pay a higher
price for ethanol than they would have in the
absence of this credit. Firms marketing gasoline
blended with ethanol typically realize a benefit of
$0.51 per gallon in addition to the marketable value
50

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

of the BTUs of energy that are released with the
burning of the ethanol. In this manner, the benefit
of the VEETC is transmitted back to the ethanol
producers in the form of a higher price for their
product. Funding of $727 million for research and
development was made available for all renewables
in FY 2007 (EIA, 2008a); Koplow (2007) has identified $290 million of this as associated with improving processes in ethanol production.
Koplow (2007) has compiled a more extensive
list of subsidies for corn ethanol using broader
definitions than those used by the EIA. While there
are, indeed, indirect transfers to firms and individuals associated with the production and use of corn
ethanol that go beyond those listed by the EIA,
Koplow includes several that are somewhat harder
to quantify and compare fairly. Table 2 lists all of
the categories that Koplow identified for ethanol
in 2007 with the categories recognized by the federal government marked by an asterisk. Note that

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Tiffany

Koplow recognizes the market price support category because the production levels mandated by
the RFS amount to the creation of a market that is
obligated to purchase a given amount of product
without regard to the price.
Koplow (2007) recognizes the influence of the
import tariff on foreign ethanol as a subsidy by
reasoning that this barrier prevents the import of
cheaper foreign ethanol to satisfy the mandated
demand. He also recognizes and quantifies the
reductions in state motor fuel taxes through waivers
of state fuel excise taxes and sales taxes on materials
for new construction of ethanol plants. In addition,
Koplow notes that Internal Revenue Service regulations offering accelerated depreciation on assets
and deferral of gains on sales of farm refineries are
subsidies that benefit ethanol production, although
they may not be used by many participants. Unequal
participation also exists for credit subsidies that
include loan guarantees by agencies of the federal
government for ethanol development projects. In
the category of subsidies that encourage the production of feedstock, he lists $640 million attributable
to the biofuel fraction of corn production. The
validity of this category is somewhat questionable
because many crop-support payments have been
cut as a consequence of high corn prices—partially
because of ethanol demand. Finally, Koplow lists
$30 million to help pay for the required installation
of blending facilities by gasoline marketing firms.
To the extent that the blending facilities help
achieve RFG Program and Winter Oxygenate
Program standards, human health benefits (which
are hard to quantify) may partially offset the costs
of the blending facilities. Based on Koplow’s broader
definitions, subsidies totaling $6,940,000,000 for
ethanol in 2007 average $1.068 per gallon, substantially more than the $0.588 per gallon calculated
using the EIA categories and the $0.015 per gallon
attributed to gasoline.

Corn Ethanol Benefits to U.S. Consumers
While, on one hand, funds are expended or
tax revenues are reduced as subsidies for ethanol
production, the growth in production of this fuel
offers certain monetary benefits to most consumers.
Du and Hayes (2008) examined the monthly retail
prices for regular gasoline over the period 1995-

2007 and discovered that ethanol production within
the five Petroleum Administration for Defense
Districts in the United States resulted in retail gasoline prices that averaged from $0.29 to as much as
$0.395 per gallon lower than they would have been
absent the ethanol production capacity. In addition,
their models indicated that added ethanol production capacity reduced the profitability of petroleum
refineries by preventing dramatic price increases,
which are often associated with an industry operating close to capacity. If the average $0.29 per gallon
price reduction is applied to the 146 billion gallons
of gasoline used in the United States in 2007, the
benefit to U.S. consumers could have been $42.34
billion.
Based on the monetary benefit to consumers
(measured by Du and Hayes, 2008) and the subsidies paid directly to the industry (using Koplow’s,
2007, more expansive list of categories; see Table 2),
one can calculate a net benefit to consumers of
corn ethanol of $35.4 billion for 2007. However, it
should be noted that the period Du and Hayes
(2008) analyzed (1995-2007) was characterized by
general prosperity, heavy consumption of gasoline,
and high rates of refinery utilization. As the United
States enters a period of lower demand for gasoline,
the sponsored production of ethanol will probably
not produce the same reduction in gasoline prices.

Farmer Decisionmaking
Before 2005, ethanol typically enjoyed a price
premium on a per-gallon basis over wholesale
gasoline (often $0.25 or more per gallon) because
of the mandated markets for RFG and winter oxygenated gasoline (Figure 4; Nebraska Energy Office,
December 2008 data). As individual states banned
the use of MTBE as an oxygenate, ethanol gained
that share of the market. The death knell for MTBE
was sounded when the Energy Policy Act of 2005
failed to provide liability protection for MTBE producers. At this point, numerous gasoline marketers
made the switch to ethanol and higher prices for
corn and ethanol followed. With increasing supplies
of corn ethanol on the market in 2006 and 2007,
ethanol lost its price premium over gasoline. This
was partly related to transportation constraints and
a lack of blending facilities in some regions of the
country.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

51

Tiffany

Figure 4
Ethanol and Unleaded Gasoline Rack Prices per Gallon (Free on Board Omaha)
$/Gallon
4.00
3.50
3.00
2.50
2.00
1.50
1.00
Ethanol
Unleaded

0.50
0.00
Jan-95

Jan-97

Jan-99

Jan-01

Jan-03

Jan-05

Jan-07

Jan-09

SOURCE: Nebraska Energy Office; www.neo.ne.gov/statshtml/66.html.

After ethanol lost its premium as a mandated
oxygenate, its price came to reflect its role as an
octane enhancer and as a BTU substitute for gasoline. As a substitute for gasoline, ethanol’s price
became directly related to the price of crude oil,
which rose dramatically over the period beginning
with the enactment of the Energy Policy Act in
2005 through the summer of 2008. Figure 5 shows
the corn price that an ethanol plant of 50 million
gallons per year capacity, built in 2007, with 50
percent debt can pay for corn and just break even
assuming a natural gas price of $8.00 per dekatherm,
full receipt of the $0.45 per gallon VEETC, and
DDGS selling at 91 percent of the corn price. The
figure also shows how price combinations of corn
and crude oil can move the plant into either the
profitable region (below the line) or the unprofitable
region (above the line). Of concern to livestock
producers, who purchase corn as animal feed, is
the effect of the $0.45 per gallon VEETC, which
when fully realized in the price of ethanol in the
market, translates into an approximately $1.24
higher bid price per bushel of corn by ethanol
plants. This figure can also be obtained by multiply52

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

ing the tax credit available to the ethanol blenders
by the typical yield of ethanol, which is 2.75 gallons per bushel of corn ($0.45 × 2.75 = $1.2375
per bushel). Figure 5 shows the effect that higher
crude oil prices can exert on corn prices and ultimately, the desire to grow additional corn acres.
Figure 5 was constructed by first determining
the price of wholesale gasoline for a range of crude
oil prices. Then the BTU-equivalent price of ethanol
(two-thirds of gasoline) was added to the VEETC
of $0.45 effective for 2009. The resulting prices of
ethanol as a subsidized BTU substitute for gasoline
can be forced into a model for an ethanol plant of
a certain size and debt percentage for assumed
prices of natural gas, DDGS, and other expense
items to learn the maximum price that the ethanol
plant can pay for corn and produce zero profits.
The line for each ethanol plant is unique due to
its capital cost, the amount of debt it carries, and
its opportunities to sell DDGS. As prices of natural
gas, DDGS, or other revenue and expense items
change, the line will shift up or down.
Figure 6 is from the United States Department
of Agriculture Agricultural Projections Report to

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Tiffany

Figure 5
Breakeven Corn Price for Dry-Grind Ethanol Plants at Various Crude Prices with Full Receipt of
$0.45 per Gallon VEETC
Corn Price ($/Bushel)
8.00
Region of Ethanol Plant Losses

7.00
6.00
5.00
4.00
3.00

Region of Ethanol Plant Profits
2.00
1.00
0.00
30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

Crude Oil Price ($/Barrel)
NOTE: Assuming 50 million gallon plant built in 2007 with 50 percent debt and costs of $8.00/dekatherm natural gas and DDGS 91 percent of
the corn price.

Figure 6
U.S. Corn Use
Billion Bushels
16
14
12

Ethanol
FSI Less Ethanol*
Exports
Feed and Residual

10
8
6
4
2
0
1990

1990

1990

1990

1990

1990

NOTE: *Food, seed, and industrial less ethanol.
SOURCE: USDA Agricultural Projections Report to 2017 (USDA, 2008).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

53

Tiffany

Table 3
Average Land Characteristics in Iowa
Characteristic

Corn suitability ratings*

Highly erodible land†

Slope range (%)‡

Conservation Reserve Program (acres)

45.05

1.53

10.89

All Iowa land

61.87

2.17

7.33

Corn and soybeans

70.99

2.46

5.45

NOTE: *Most productive land is rated at 100.00 corn suitability rating.
†The

highly erodible land categories are 1.0 for highly erodible, 2.0 for potentially highly erodible, and 3 for not highly erodible.

‡The

slope (%) is based on the percentage difference in the number of feet of rise or fall per 100 feet.

SOURCE: Secchi and Babcock (2007).

2017 (USDA, 2008), which recognized the powerful influence of ethanol producers’ increased corn
demand to fulfill the objectives of the 2007 EISA.
The strong demand for ethanol intensified the
demand for acres to produce corn. High corn prices
and the expectations for their continuation allowed
corn acres to outbid soybean, wheat, and hay acres.
The higher prices for corn, which were partly
responsible for lower or negative returns for livestock producers, may become the deciding factor
for a number of small-scale producers who decide
to exit hog, beef feeder cattle, and dairy operations.
Although this exodus was already under way
before corn prices increased because of higher
demand from biofuels, the growing biofuel demand
and the strong demand for exports may cause this
process to continue. The full effect of greater production of ethanol may take some time to be fully
realized because of the already advanced median
age of numerous livestock producers.
To a certain degree, the enhanced price of
corn induced by ethanol prompts the removal of
acres from the Conservation Reserve Program4
(CRP). Secchi and Babcock (2007) at Iowa State
University examined this phenomenon using crop
budgets and soil erosion models for a particular
watershed in Iowa. Table 3 compares the quality
of the land in the CRP program in Iowa with the
quality of the land throughout the state and the
quality of the land planted in corn and soybeans.
4

The Conservation Reserve Program pays a rental rate to farmers on
erosion-prone land, generally for 10-year periods when the land is
typically maintained in perennial grass production.

54

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

The Secchi and Babcock (2007) research team
found the following:
i.

At a corn price of $3.00 per bushel, landowners in the watershed region under study
would be economically rational to keep the
higher returns from their CRP contracts.

ii. At a corn price of $4.00 per bushel, some
CRP landowners in the watershed region
(for which levels of soil erosion were
known) would be motivated to remove
some of their land from the CRP program
and pursue crop production (corn and other
crops in rotation).
iii. At a corn price of $5.00 per bushel, much
of the CRP land in the watershed region
would return to crop production.
Secchi and Babcock (2007) used budgetary information for a particular area of Iowa to determine
the returns on particular lands and to determine
whether the landowners would be better off accepting prevailing CRP payments or taking their chances
at growing crops. They also used the ErosionProductivity Impact Calculator model to estimate
soil erosion, nutrient loss, and levels of carbon
sequestration on lands recruited back to crop production from the CRP. They concluded that higher
corn prices would bring environmentally fragile
lands from the CRP back into crop production and
estimated that sediment losses would increase from
baseline levels of less than 1 million tons per year
over 2 million acres. A corn price of $5.00 per
bushel would precipitate the conversion of

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Tiffany

1,350,000 acres from the CRP to crop production,
at a predicted loss of 5 million tons of sediment. If
all the CRP acres in Iowa were converted to crop
production, it is predicted that 9 million tons of
sediment losses would occur.

EFFECTS OF CORN ETHANOL ON
FOOD PRICES
In 2007, when U.S. retail food prices rose 4
percent above 2006 levels and twice as fast as overall core inflation (2.3 percent), consumers took
notice. Corn-based ethanol drew substantial attention as consumers sought a culprit for higher prices
at the grocery store. Higher corn prices were, in
part, driven by demand to make ethanol and these
higher prices effectively bid acres away from other
crops that provided lower returns, such as soybeans,
wheat, and hay. Foods experiencing the biggest
gains in price were meats and dairy. Dairy prices
rose 7.4 percent above 2006 levels. Prices of cropbased goods also increased; cereal and bakery products rose 4.3 percent, and fat and oil products rose
2.9 percent from 2006 to 2007.
However, it is important to note that in terms
of overall retail food costs, the farm values of crops
and livestock represent only 19.5 percent of total
retail costs, whereas labor accounts for 38.5 percent. Transportation represents 4.0 percent, and
the energy used to heat and cool stores, lockers,
and freezers represents 3.5 percent. The highest
farm share of retail food prices is commanded by
beef at 45 percent, followed by pork and dairy at
31 percent. The farm share for fresh fruits and
vegetables is 25 percent, while the farm share for
cereals and bakery products is just 5 percent
(Henderson, 2008).
Researchers at Texas A&M University
(Anderson et al., 2008) produced a detailed report
on ethanol’s effects on food and feed in Texas. They
reported increases in food prices and noted that
only small percentages of retail food prices can be
directly attributed to farm-level prices. They also
noted the importance of beef feeding in Texas, a
state that must import the majority of its corn. They
report that corn and grain sorghum growers benefit
from high corn prices when corn prices are squeezing profits from livestock-feeding operations.

Much to the chagrin of the governor of Texas,
who had sought relief from the RFS, the economic
modeling used for this report showed that relaxing
the RFS would not significantly lower corn prices
and provide meaningful relief to livestock producers. The report noted how the emergence and popularity of commodity index funds effectively drove
traditional users away from farm commodity futures
markets. This took away a risk management tool
when it was needed the most (Anderson et al.,
2008).
Ethanol expansion has cost U.S. consumers
relatively little overall, but effects on foreign consumers have been more pronounced, especially for
those countries sensitive to maintaining access to
agricultural commodities on the world market.
For example, South Korea’s Daewoo Logistics is
reportedly seeking a 99-year lease on 2.5 million
acres of land in Madagascar to produce corn and
other crops for Korean consumption. The production goal is 232 million bushels of corn within 15
years. This amount of corn is similar to South
Korea’s corn imports from the United States in
2005. China is seeking a similar land area for rice
production in the Philippines, as well as a land
area of unspecified size in the Zambezi Valley of
Mozambique. Because rice is not typically consumed in Mozambique, most of the rice produced
there would be destined for China. Efforts by developed countries to lease the productive capacity of
developing countries may become a source of international friction if the host country faces struggles
to provide adequate supplies of affordable food
for its own people (Ray, 2008).

CONCLUSION
It is difficult to describe a perfect fuel that produces no adverse impacts during its production or
use. This is the case with corn ethanol. However,
it is a fuel that burns cleanly (due to its function
as an oxygenate) and enhances octane. Anhydrous
ethanol5 can be readily blended with gasoline, the
dominant fuel used in the United States for personal
transportation in light-duty vehicles. As a blended
fuel, ethanol can be accommodated in our logistics

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

55

Tiffany

network, but not without additional cost. Ethanol’s
proclivities to attract moisture and its solvent qualities have prevented its transport in the U.S. fuel
pipeline network; this shortcoming necessitates
truck, rail, and barge transportation.
This article reviews the impacts (current and
potential) of fuel ethanol used as an oxygenate
and its role in reducing tailpipe emissions. At this
point, production levels have expanded to satisfy
demand for octane enhancement and as a mandated
BTU substitute for gasoline. Production of corn
ethanol and the ensuing increased demand for corn
can pose environmental challenges if care is not
exercised in bringing additional, and sometimes
fragile, lands back into crop production. Use of
corn by ethanol plants in times of rising crude oil
prices can exact price pressure on livestock producers partly as a consequence of the VEETC.
Corn ethanol has a positive NEB when produced with dry-grind technology. However, it is
well known that this technology can be improved
in terms of GHG emissions by the use of biomass
as a fuel source. GHG emissions and the process by
which ethanol is produced in the future are likely
to be keys to the financial success of this industry
as efforts are made to document and benchmark
production practices.
Ethanol is the recipient of direct and indirect
subsidies. Its direct subsidies exceed those of gasoline, but some authors have recognized that its
production has reduced gasoline prices by increasing fuel capacity overall and reducing gasoline
price increases related to limitations in petroleum
refinery capacity.
Up to this time, corn ethanol’s effect on domestic food prices has been minimal. Food prices in
certain foreign countries have been affected to a
greater extent in some cases. Over the longer term,
it appears developed countries will try to lease
agricultural lands from less-developed countries.
If relatively high corn prices persist, low margins
for livestock producers may accelerate the exodus
of many small-scale producers from livestock feeding and milking.
5

Anhydrous ethanol is the type produced in the United States; it
mixes very readily in various blends of gasoline. In the past, Brazil
used hydrous ethanol directly in its cars; this type of ethanol does
not mix well.

56

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

The U.S. Congress has taken measures to ensure
that production of ethanol from the starch in corn
grain does not advance beyond 15 billion gallons
per year, or approximately 10 percent of our
national gasoline usage. This measure is an effort
to preserve more corn for domestic livestock producers. In addition, the EISA’s performance standards and attractive subsidies and incentives for
advanced biofuels and cellulosic ethanol may some
day encourage production of ethanol without the
use of corn grain.

REFERENCES
Anderson, David P.; Outlaw, Joe L.; Bryant, Henry L.;
Richardson, James W.; Ernstes, David P.; Ralston, J.
Marc; Welch, J. Mark; Knapek, George M.; Herbst,
Brian K. and Allison, Marc S. “The Effects of Ethanol
on Texas Food and Feed.” Policy Research Report
08-1, Agricultural and Food Policy Center, Texas A&M
University, April 10, 2008;
www.afpc.tamu.edu/pubs/2/515/RR-08-01.pdf.
Boledovich, Julie. Chemical engineer, Fuels Center, U.S.
EPA Office of Transportation and Air Quality, Ann
Arbor, MI, October 15, 2008, e-mail correspondence
to author.
De Kam, Matthew J.; Morey, R. Vance and Tiffany,
Douglas G. “Integrating Biomass to Produce Heat
and Power at Ethanol Plants.” ASABE Proceedings
Paper No. 076232, American Society of Agricultural
and Biological Engineers, June 2007;
www.biomasschpethanol.umn.edu/papers/ASABE_
076232-8-8-07.pdf.
Du, Xiaodong and Hayes, Dermot J. “The Impact of
Ethanol Production on U.S. and Regional Gasoline
Prices and on the Profitability of the U.S. Oil Refinery
Industry.” Working Paper 08-WP 467, Center for
Agriculture and Rural Development, Iowa State
University, April 2008; www.card.iastate.edu/
publications/DBS/PDFFiles/08wp467.pdf.
Energy Information Agency. “Federal Financial
Interventions and Subsidies in Energy Markets 2007.”
Report No. SR/CNEAF/2008-01, April 9, 2008a;
www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/servicerpt/subsidy2/index.html.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Tiffany

Energy Information Agency. “How Much Does the
Federal Government Spend on Energy-Specific
Subsidies and Support?” September 8, 2008b;
http://tonto.eia.doe.gov/energy_in_brief/energy_
subsidies.cfm.
Energy Information Agency. “Energy Independence
and Security Act of 2007: Summary of Provisions.”
2007a; www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/aeo/otheranalysis/
aeo_2008analysispapers/eisa.html.
Energy Information Agency “Federal Financial
Interventions and Subsidies in Energy Markets 2007.”
2007b; www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/servicerpt/subsidy2/
pdf/execsum.pdf.
Environmental Protection Agency. “State Winter
Oxygenated Fuel Program: Requirements for
Attainment or Maintenance of CO NAAQS.”
EPA420-B-08-006, January 2008;
www.epa.gov/oms/regs/fuels/420b08006.pdf.
Environmental Protection Agency. “Reformulated Gas.”
August 2007; www.epa.gov/otaq/rfg/information.htm.
Environmental Protection Agency. “Energy Policy Act of
2005.” www.epa.gov/oust/fedlaws/publ_109-058.pdf.
Environmental Protection Agency. “Clean Air Act
Amendments of 1990.” www.epa.gov/air/caa/.
Fargione, Joseph; Hill, Jason; Tilman, David; Polasky,
Stephen and Hawthorne, Peter. “Land Clearing and
the Biofuel Carbon Debt.” Science, February 29, 2008,
319(5867), pp. 1235-38.
Gray, C. Boyden and Varcoe, Andrew R. “Octane, Clean
Air and Renewable Fuels: A Modest Step Toward
Energy Independence.” Texas Review of Law &
Politics, Fall 2005, 10(1), pp. 9-62.

Biodiesel and Ethanol Biofuels.” Proceedings of the
National Academy of Sciences, July 25, 2006, 103(30),
pp. 11206-10;
www.pnas.org/content/103/30/11206.full.pdf+html.
Hofstrand, Don. “Energy Agriculture—Ethanol Energy
Balance.” Ag Decision Maker, July 2007;
www.extension.iastate.edu/agdm/articles/hof/
HofJuly07.html.
International Center for Policy Assessment. “The Real
Cost of Gasoline.” Report No. 3, An Analysis of the
Hidden External Costs Consumers Pay to Fuel Their
Automobiles. November 1998; www.icta.org/doc/
Real%20Price%20of%20Gasoline.pdf.
Koplow, Doug. “Biofuels—At What Cost? Government
Support for Ethanol and Biodiesel in the United
States: 2007 Update.” Prepared for the Global
Subsidies Initiative (GSI) of the International Institute
for Sustainable Development (IISD), October 2007;
www.globalsubsidies.org/files/assets/Brochure_-_
US_Update.pdf.
Nebraska Energy Office. “Ethanol and Unleaded
Gasoline Average Rack Prices.”
www.neo.ne.gov/statshtml/66.html.
Ray, Daryll E. “Supply Response to Sky-High Prices:
Old Reliables and an Eye-Opening New Approach.”
Article No. 436, Agricultural Policy Analysis Center,
University of Tennessee, December 5, 2008;
www.agpolicy.org/weekcol/436.html.
Renewable Fuels Association. “Changing the Climate:
Ethanol Industry Outlook 2008.” February 2008;
www.ethanolrfa.org/objects/pdf/outlook/RFA_
Outlook_2008.pdf.

Henderson, Jason. “What Is Driving Food Price
Inflation?” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Main
Street Economist, 2008, III(1), pp.1-5;
www.kansascityfed.org/RegionalAffairs/MainStreet/
MSE_0108.pdf.

Secchi, Silvia and Babcock, Bruce A. “Impact of High
Crop Prices on Environmental Quality: A Case of
Iowa and the Conservation Reserve Program.” Working
Paper No. 07-WP 447, Center for Agriculture and Rural
Development, Iowa State University, May 2007;
http://agecon.lib.umn.edu/cgi-bin/pdf_view.pl?
paperid=26027.

Hill, Jason; Nelson, Erik; Tilman, David; Polasky,
Stephen and Tiffany, Douglas. “Environmental,
Economic and Energetic Costs and Benefits of

Searchinger, Timothy; Heimlich, Ralph; Houghton, R.A.;
Dong, Fengxia; Elobeid, Amani; Fabiosa, Jacinto;
Tokgoz, Simla; Hayes, Dermot and Yu, Tun-Hsiang.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

57

Tiffany

“Use of U.S. Croplands for Biofuels Increases
Greenhouse Gases Through Emissions from LandUse Change.” Science, February 29, 2008, 319(5867),
pp. 1238-40.
United States Department of Agriculture. “Agricultural
Projections Report to 2017.” Economic Research
Service Report No. OCE-2008-1, February 2008;
www.ers.usda.gov/Publications/OCE081/.
Wang, Michael; Wu, May and Huo, Hong. “Life-Cycle
Energy and Greenhouse Gas Emission Impacts of
Different Corn Ethanol Plant Types.” Environmental
Research Letters, 2, April-June 2007, p. 024001;
www.iop.org/ EJ/article/1748-9326/2/2/024001/
erl7_2_024001.html.

58

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Commentary
Max Schulz

U

niversity of Minnesota Professor
Douglas Tiffany’s article (2009) provides a valuable treatment about the
economics of ethanol production
and use. The debates on biofuels in Washington
in recent years have too often been focused on
slogans and sentiment rather than facts and figures. Professor Tiffany’s article brings very useful
detail and expertise to a topic that touches on
issues ranging from energy, the environment,
and agriculture to national security and foreign
relations.
While I take issue with some of his conclusions,
Professor Tiffany is to be commended for addressing several of the alleged negative implications of
federal ethanol mandates. At the same time, however, he doesn’t adequately address the core concern that has compelled those mandates: namely,
whether we can displace significant volumes of
our national oil consumption with ethanol.
Although this conference takes place shortly
after the election of a new president, it is a valuable
exercise to review the recent history of ethanol
policy under George W. Bush to provide insight for
charting ethanol’s future course. Conventions of
public disclosure demand I note that I served for
nearly five years in the George W. Bush administration at the U.S. Department of Energy (DOE).
However, the policies discussed here began to be
implemented largely at the end of my tenure at the
DOE. Furthermore, it will be clear that my views
represent no endorsement of the biofuels policy
embarked on (with the president’s support) in the

comprehensive energy legislation passed by
Congress in 2005 and 2007.
The push to boost the share of ethanol in our
fuel supply will go down as one of President Bush’s
legacies, albeit an unfortunate one. This development was a signature initiative of his second term.
Ironically, Bush’s first term, which placed a large
focus on energy policy issues, did very little to
encourage ethanol use and certainly didn’t hint at
the sort of mandated expansions that would occur
in 2005 and 2007.
When President Bush took office in 2001, the
country was dealing with the shocks of the
California energy crisis. There were also signs that
domestic natural gas production was plateauing;
more and more holes were being drilled to produce
the same amounts of gas. There were clear indications that global demand for oil would increase,
while our capacity to develop it at home was hindered by regulations and moratoria on exploration.
Among the first orders of business for President
Bush was to issue a comprehensive energy policy
that encompassed a host of various possibilities
(National Energy Policy Development Group, 2001).
It encouraged the development of domestic oil
and natural gas resources, as in Alaska’s Arctic
National Wildlife Refuge (ANWR). But the Bush
energy plan was much more than that. Emphasizing
that no one energy program or approach, including
ANWR, was a silver bullet, the plan highlighted
the necessity of a fully rounded energy policy.
The president’s National Energy Policy (NEP)
promoted a variety of energy technologies, fuels,

Max Schulz is a senior fellow at the Manhattan Institute for Policy Research.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economic Development, 2009, 5(1), pp. 59-64.

© 2009, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced,
published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

59

Schulz

and processes. It called for the expansion of nuclear
power; renewable energy research for wind, solar,
and biomass; energy efficiency and conservation;
clean coal and carbon capture; building a twentyfirst-century electricity grid; as well as investments
in infrastructure upgrades from wires to pipelines
to liquefied natural gas terminals and tankers.
In fact, despite political criticism that the president’s plan focused solely on ANWR, it devoted
as much (if not more) attention to efficiency and
conservation as it did to expanded oil drilling in
Alaska. But what was really curious was what the
NEP did not emphasize: biofuels. Ethanol was mentioned only in a cursory fashion, essentially noting
its role as an additive in gasoline. There was no
indication in the president’s comprehensive energy
plan of the importance that he would later assign
to it.
The overall theme of the president’s sweeping
plan was energy security. Far more than just considering energy as an economic or environmental
matter, the NEP considered energy as a component
of national security. Then came September 11, 2001,
which put the energy security/national security
nexus into sharper focus. It provided even more
impetus for the notion that we must take a national
security approach to our energy policy decisions.
In the back of everyone’s mind was the fact that the
terrorists who perpetrated the 9/11 attacks and subsequent acts of violence were funded (indirectly,
but funded nonetheless) through the revenues
reaped by national oil companies in the Middle
East. The Organization of the Petroleum Exporting
Countries (OPEC) dictatorships got rich selling us
the oil we use to power our transportation sector.
In return, for instance, the Kingdom of Saudi Arabia
used that money to establish the Wahhabi schools
and mosques that supported the 9/11 bombers and
other international terrorists.
Against this backdrop, consider the upward
creep in oil prices over the past eight years. The
wealth transfer to regimes in Saudi Arabia, Russia,
Venezuela, and Nigeria was worrisome enough
when oil was trading at $35 per barrel. But as oil
prices soared to well over $100 last summer, the
massive transfers of wealth lining the pockets of
some very bad actors seemed particularly egregious.
Even in the current economic environment, with
60

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

the price of oil having retreated considerably from
its mid-summer highs, the national oil companies
of OPEC (not to mention their like-minded allies
in Moscow) are reaping huge sums from the global
oil market that can be put to nefarious purposes.
It was in this context that the federal government took a significant policy leap with the 2005
and 2007 energy bills. We moved from a position
where the government encouraged ethanol use as
an additive to meet clean air goals to one where
ethanol would be used to displace gasoline use
and lower our consumption of foreign oil.
In 2005, the White House endorsed a renewable fuels standard that mandated the use of 7.5
billion gallons of ethanol and biodiesel in our fuel
mix by 2012 (Public Law 109-58, 2005 [also known
as the Energy Policy Act of 2005]). By the time of
the 2007 legislation, President Bush was pushing
even harder to expand that mandate nearly fivefold
by 2022.
The chief impetus for President Bush and for
allies in Congress was a stated desire to displace
foreign oil imports. The environmental goals or
the goals of helping the economies of Midwestern
states, to the extent these goals were discussed,
were far less important than the energy independence angle. Even so, the environmental argument
still has its champions. Green groups have advocated increased biofuel usage for years. But without
the Bush administration driving the issue from a
national security angle, we simply would not have
seen the extreme mandate for biofuels that was
passed in the 2007 legislation.
What is striking at a conference dedicated to
discussing the various economic and environmental consequences of ethanol is to consider that
Congress and the Bush administration originally
paid so little heed to what those consequences
might be. Goals certainly were discussed—from
energy independence and energy security to the
hope we might produce fuel at home instead of
buying from Middle Eastern sheiks. However, discussion of the practical consequences of such a
fairly dramatic policy shift was sorely lacking.
Washington’s ethanol debates were carried out
largely by reference to the legislation’s goals, not
its likely ramifications. Little thought was given
to consequences for consumers. Not considered

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Schulz

was how a law mandating ethanol usage might
affect farmers’ choices of crops to plant, or what
it might do to world food markets given that the
United States produces 40 percent of the global
corn supply and is responsible for more than twothirds of the world’s corn exports (U.S. Department
of Agriculture, 2009). What the legislation might
mean for the environment was barely discussed,
other than the occasional broad platitude that use
of renewable ethanol instead of gasoline would
cut emissions.
The rush to mandate ethanol’s usage in our fuel
mix in 2005, and then to supersize that policy in the
subsequent 2007 energy bill (Energy Information
Agency, 2007), was much like taking a running
jump off the diving board without checking to
see if there’s water in the pool. It turns out there
wasn’t much water in the pool. The near-term consequences so far have been, simply, unfortunate for
everyone but certain groups of farmers and agribusiness concerns.
The global increase in food prices tops the list
of unfortunate consequences. Professor Tiffany
addresses this issue somewhat in his article, noting
the record prices for corn brought on partly because
of Washington’s ethanol mandate. He correctly notes
that the values of crops represent only a portion of
the cost of food. “Up to this time,” Professor Tiffany
writes, “corn ethanol’s effect on food prices has
been minimal.” He cites consumer price index (CPI)
numbers, noting that 2007 U.S. retail food prices
rose 4 percent over 2006 levels.
Our ethanol policies seem to have had a more
harmful effect than Professor Tiffany allows. For
one thing, he could have noted the continued
increase in the CPI for retail food prices throughout
the course of 2008. With six weeks left in the year,
it looks as if the CPI will show a 5 percent to 6 percent increase over last year’s prices, meaning an
overall increase of nearly 10 percent over 2006
prices.1 That’s a significant rise.
The jump in crop prices has been dramatic, as
well, at least before the recent economic downturn.
In early 2008, corn prices were basically double
from the previous year. Not just corn has been
1

The year-end figure was 5.5 percent for 2008, so the overall increase
was 9.72 percent, or roughly 10 percent.

affected. One consequence of the federal government’s varied efforts to prop up the price of corn
(to increase the use of biofuels) has been farmers
choosing to plant corn in place of other crops. So
with land for other crops moved to corn production,
the prices of those displaced crops have increased.
Earlier this year, the price of wheat was triple what
it sold for the year before. Soybean prices doubled,
as did the price of rice.
One can argue about the effect of such dramatic
increases in crop prices on the retail cost of food.
But what cannot be argued is that food prices have
indeed increased over the past two years. Their
effect on the American economy may be said to
have been relatively minimal—but that has to do
with the fact we are a wealthy country. If the problems with our financial system and our monetary
policies are put aside, the economy is fundamentally sound.
That is to say, we are a productive nation. We
have created great stores of wealth for the vast
majority of Americans. As such, we have been able
to weather the effects of any number of troubling
developments in recent years: 9/11, corporate scandals at Enron and WorldCom, Hurricanes Katrina
and Rita, the 2005 blackout in the Northeast, flooding here in the Midwest, and rising energy prices,
not to mention the spike in food prices. These
events all have taken some toll, but generally our
economy has proven pretty resilient.
Citizens of poorer nations are not as capable of
taking an economic punch as are we. As a result,
riots over spiking prices for food have erupted in
Egypt, Haiti, Mexico, Indonesia, and elsewhere.
The effect of U.S. and European biofuels mandates
on other nations as prices for crops have skyrocketed is one that perhaps could have been explored
by Professor Tiffany in what is a fairly laudatory
article about ethanol.
Fortunately, the alarms over biofuels’ effect on
global food prices are being raised again and again.
This fall, the Food and Agricultural Organization
of the United Nations (2008) called for a review of
biofuels subsidies and mandates because of their
contribution to rising food prices.
The International Food Policy Research Institute
similarly voiced concerns (von Braun, 2008), as
did the Organisation for Economic Co-operation

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

61

Schulz

and Development (2008), which wonders if the
“cure” of biofuels is worse than the diseases it is
supposed to address.
In July, the World Bank suggested that biofuel
policies were responsible for nearly three-quarters
of the increase in global food prices, with higher
energy costs, the weak U.S. dollar, and increased
transportation and fertilizer costs making up the
difference (Chakrabortty, 2008). The World Bank
study seemed to confirm an earlier International
Monetary Fund report making similar claims
(Mercer-Blackman, Samiei, and Cheng, 2007).
And what of the environmental impact on the
developing world’s biofuel policies—specifically,
the demands for land? U.S. farmers planted a record
94 million acres in corn in 2007, yielding a record
13 billion bushels. And for all that, it displaced
just 3 percent of our total oil consumption (Tucker,
2008).
It isn’t that difficult to imagine what would be
required to make a truly significant dent in our oil
consumption. Two researchers at the Polytechnic
University of New York did just that in a 2006
Washington Post op-ed article. James Jordan and
James Power came to the conclusion that “Using
the entire 300 million acres of U.S. cropland for
corn-based ethanol production would meet about
15 percent of the demand” (Jordan and Powell,
2006, p. B07).
That’s a theoretical figure, to be sure. But to
date, I haven’t seen credible numbers suggesting
we can produce enough biofuels to make a worthwhile dent in our oil demand while also growing
the crops used for traditional uses.
If it’s theoretical to us in the United States,
however, in other parts of the world the clearing
of land for biofuels production is causing significant environmental damage. In Indonesia, forestland is being cleared at alarming rates to plant palm
oil crops to cash in on the artificial demand for biofuels. The result is a massacre for many endangered
animals, such as the orangutan.
Perhaps worse, depending on one’s view on
global warming, is that the land-clearing aspects
of biofuel production arguably increase greenhouse
gas emissions. That was the conclusion of two
reports in Science magazine. One article noted that
growing biofuels necessarily leads to deforestation,
which eliminates some of the planet’s most effective
62

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

carbon sinks (Searchinger et al., 2008). In the other
article, lead researcher Joseph Fargione claimed
that even though biofuels are a potential low-carbon
energy source, land clearing sped up carbon emissions and that “for the next 93 years you’re making
climate change worse” (Rosenthal, 2008).
It isn’t just the land that is being affected. The
National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration
(NOAA), in conjunction with Louisiana State
University, has sounded the alarm about a growing
dead zone in the Gulf of Mexico, an algae-filled
area with oxygen levels too low to maintain marine
life. Since 1990 this dead zone has averaged about
4,800 square miles. NOAA warns it could expand
to 8,800 square miles, largely because the recent
flooding in the Midwest and the increased use of
fertilizers to grow more corn have washed nitrogen
and phosphorus downstream into the Gulf (NOAA,
2008).
In his paper, Professor Tiffany notes that “it is
difficult to describe a perfect fuel that produces
no adverse impacts during its production or use.”
Quite right. Such a characterization applies to every
fuel and energy technology we use, each of which
has some drawbacks or dangers. Coal has to be dug
out of the ground in a laborious process and transported—often hundreds of miles—to be incinerated,
which is a dirty process. Our nuclear fuel cycle
leaves the problem of radioactive waste. Our oil
use enmeshes us in foreign entanglements, not to
mention that burning it emits pollutants as well as
greenhouse gases. Wind turbines require huge tracts
of land and pose serious aesthetic considerations.
The manufacture of solar panels requires the use of
highly toxic chemicals, and using the panels also
requires large amounts of land for solar farms and
other optimal conditions. Hydropower distorts
landscapes and natural environments.
The question we must ask with all of these
energy options is whether it is worth putting up
with the hassles involved for what we get out of
them. The risks and environmental impacts associated with nuclear power and coal are of a far greater
scale than those for windmills, but they also are
capable of generating vastly greater amounts of
reliable power than windmills. Over the course of
a century, we developed the production, delivery,
and refining system for petroleum because, in the

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Schulz

end, gasoline has proven to be the best, most durable, most available, most flexible fuel for powering
our transportation sector.
By and large these things occurred because of
decisions made by the market, not by government.
Certainly there have been government involvement
and distortions in energy markets since shortly after
the gusher at Spindletop, yet the energy system that
has matured to service the internal combustion
engine has done so organically.
For all the benefits of ethanol, many spelled
out by Professor Tiffany, those benefits cannot make
ethanol economically viable without explicit government sponsorship. Such sponsorship takes many
forms—from direct and indirect subsidies to tariff
protection to mandates ordering its use. One certainly can argue over the magnitude of our biofuel
policy’s effects: Did prices rise this much or only
that much? Was the environmental insult this large
or slightly smaller? Much harder to contest is the
notion that with just about any calculation, cornbased ethanol forever will be incapable of supplanting a significant amount of our oil consumption.
Cellulosic ethanol holds promise and will not
carry the baggage associated with corn-based
ethanol. But it’s far less evolved technologically
than corn-based ethanol at this point.
Following the road set by President Bush and
Congress, we should see continued adverse economic and environmental impacts. This will certainly be the case in the near term until a workable
process for cellulosic ethanol is invented. Even if
that happens (a questionable proposition), it is
worth considering that there likely will be other
similar, unforeseen adverse consequences if technology advances allow the United States to ramp
up cellulosic ethanol production.
Barring an unlikely change of heart by policymakers in Washington, we should expect our economy, not to mention consumers in other, poorer
regions of the world, to continue weathering these
assaults. And for what? To displace negligible
amounts of America’s oil consumption.
At some point, we should ask ourselves if the
benefits of our ethanol policies are worth the disruption and economic pain they cause. Given
ethanol’s inability to substitute in any meaningful
way for our current oil consumption, I would argue
they are not.

REFERENCES
Chakrabortty, Aditya. “Secret Report: Biofuel Caused
Food Crisis: Internal World Bank Study Delivers Blow
to Plant Energy Drive.” The Guardian, July 3, 2008;
www.guardian.co.uk/environment/2008/jul/03/
biofuels.renewableenergy.
Energy Information Agency. “Energy Independence
and Security Act of 2007: Summary of Provisions.”
December 19, 2007; www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/aeo/
otheranalysis/aeo_2008analysispapers/eisa.html.
Fargione, Joseph; Hill, Jason; Tilman, David; Polasky,
Stephen and Hawthorne, Peter. “Land Clearing and
the Biofuel Carbon Debt.” Science, February 29, 2008,
319(5867), pp. 1235-38.
Food and Agriculture Organization of the United
Nations. The State of Food and Agriculture 2008.
Rome, Italy: FAO, October 2008.
Jordan, James and Powell, James. “The False Hope of
Biofuels: For Energy and Environmental Reasons,
Ethanol Will Never Replace Gasoline.” Washington
Post, July 2, 2006, p. B07.
Mercer-Blackman, Valerie; Samiei, Hossein and Cheng,
Kevin. “Biofuel Demand Pushes Up Food Prices.”
IMF Survey, October 17, 2007.
National Energy Policy Development Group. National
Energy Policy: Report of the National Energy Policy
Development Group, May 2001;
www.gcrio.org/OnLnDoc/pdf/nep.pdf.
National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration,
U.S. Department of Commerce. “NOAA and Louisiana
Scientists Predict Largest Gulf of Mexico ‘Dead Zone’
on Record This Summer.” July 15, 2008;
www.noaanews.noaa.gov/stories2008/
20080715_deadzone.html.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development. Biofuel Support Policies: An Economic
Assessment. July 2008.
Public Law 109-58. “Energy Policy Act of 2005.”
August 8, 2005; http://frwebgate.access.gpo.gov/
cgi-bin/getdoc.cgi?dbname=109_cong_public_
laws&docid=f:publ058.109.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

63

Schulz

Rosenthal, Elisabeth. “Biofuels Deemed a Greenhouse
Threat.” New York Times, February 8, 2008;
www.nytimes.com/2008/02/08/science/earth/
08wbiofuels.html.
Searchinger, Timothy; Heimlich, Ralph; Houghton,
R.A.; Dong, Fengxia; Elobeid, Amani; Fabiosa, Jacinto;
Tokgoz, Simla; Hayes, Dermot and Yu, Tun-Hsiang.
“Use of U.S. Croplands for Biofuels Increases
Greenhouse Gases Through Emissions from Land-Use
Change.” Science, February 29, 2008, 319(5867),
pp. 1238-40.
Tiffany, Douglas G. “Economic Consequences of U.S.
Corn Ethanol Production and Use.” Federal Reserve
Board of St. Louis Regional Economic Development,
2009, 5(1), pp. 42-58.
Tucker, William. Terrestrial Energy: How Nuclear
Power Can Lead the Green Revolution and End
America’s Energy Odyssey. Laurel, MD: Bartleby
Press, 2008.
U.S. Department of Agriculture, Foreign Agricultural
Service, Office of Global Analysis. “World
Agricultural Production.” Circular Series WAP 02-09,
February 2009;
www.fas.usda.gov/psdonline/circulars/production.pdf.
von Braun, Joachim. International Food Policy Research
Institute. Testimony before the U.S. Senate Committee
on Energy and Natural Resources on “Biofuels,
International Food Prices, and the Poor.” Washington,
DC, June 12, 2008;
www.ifpri.org/pubs/testimony/vonbraun20080612.asp.

64

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

The Impact of the Ethanol Boom on Rural America
Jason Henderson
Since 2005, surging U.S. ethanol production has helped reshape the rural economy. Ethanol production has increased nonfarm activity in many rural communities. Moreover, increased ethanol
production contributed to rising crop prices, increased net returns, and a jump in cropland values
both nationally and regionally. However, rising crop prices cut livestock revenues by boosting feed
costs. As a result, while ethanol proponents tout the benefits emerging from the ethanol industry,
opponents rail against its adverse side effects. Although the expanding ethanol industry has made
a sizable impact on the rural economy, that impact has not been as large as initially estimated.
(JEL Q1, Q4, R4)
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economic Development, 2009, 5(1), pp. 65-73.

I

n 2006, the ethanol industry emerged as a
major influence both in and on the U.S. farm
economy. Changes in U.S. energy policy in
2005 bolstered the demand for ethanol. In
2006, the surge in crude oil and gasoline prices
boosted ethanol profits. The result was a perfect
storm for the farm community, where ethanol production and biofuels helped fuel sharp gains in
corn prices that spilled over into other agricultural
commodities. The promises of the ethanol industry
had been fulfilled.
However, the ethanol boom has since faded.
Current ethanol production capacity is higher than
the demand mandated in the Revised Renewable
Fuel Standard for 2008 (Environmental Protection
Agency, 2008). Ethanol prices have fallen, shrinking
profit margins and trimming forecasts of ethanol
production. As the ethanol industry matures, what
is the lasting impact on rural communities?
This article describes the economic effects of
the ethanol industry on rural communities.
Nationally, although crop prices have risen, the
ethanol boom explains only part of the national

increase in crop prices, net returns, and cropland
values. The geographic concentration of ethanol
production has led to some spatial changes in crop
prices and livestock production. The ethanol industry has helped spur nonfarm economic growth, but
the gains have been less than initially touted. As a
result, the economic effects of the ethanol industry
are probably not as large as most people expected.

FARM SECTOR IMPACTS
Ethanol’s primary economic impacts emerge
from the farm sector. Coupled with historically
high export activity, U.S. ethanol demand has
contributed to record high crop prices and strong
farm income gains. However, the less-desirable
side effects in the farm sector abound, including
increased feed costs (from higher crop prices),
lower livestock profits, and structural changes in
agricultural industries.
Since 2006, U.S. ethanol production has surged.
The phaseout of methyl tertiary-butyl ether (MTBE)

Jason Henderson is vice president and branch executive at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Omaha Branch.

© 2009, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced,
published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

65

Henderson

Table 1
Net Returns to U.S. Corn Production (dollars per acre)
2005

2006

2007

2008
forecast

2008 forecast (without
ethanol expansion)

386.88

409.74

443.97

567.36

567.36

Variable

186.37

205.98

228.99

335.15

335.15

Fixed

200.51

203.76

214.98

232.21

232.21

359.27

477.61

658.99

624.97

527.95

296.00

453.26

634.62

600.6

503.58

148.0

149.1

151.1

154.0

154.0

Variable
Total production costs

Total revenues
Market revenues
Average yield (bushel/acre)
Farm price (bushel)

2.00

Government receipts
Net returns
Net returns less variable costs

3.04

4.20

3.90

3.27

63.27

24.35

24.37

24.37

24.37

(27.61)

67.87

215.02

57.62

(39.4)

158.76

273.85

444.01

289.82

192.8

NOTE: All variables except average yield are expressed as dollars per acre.
SOURCE: Production costs were obtained from USDA data at www.ers.usda.gov/Data/CostsAndReturns/testpick.htm. Average yield and farm
price data were obtained from the “World Agriculture Supply and Demand Estimates–February 2009” at http://usda.mannlib.cornell.edu/
usda/current/wasde/wasde-02-10-2009.pdf. Government receipts data were obtained from FAPRI at www.fapri.missouri.edu/outreach/
publications/ag_outlook.asp?current_page=outreach.

in several key gasoline markets fueled a surge in
ethanol demand and a spike in ethanol profits.
The industry quickly responded and by 2008, U.S.
ethanol production capacity had reached 10.7 billion gallons, up from 3.6 billion gallons in 2005.
Expanding ethanol production translated into a
sharp rise in corn demand. Despite near–record high
corn production, the ethanol industry is expected
to consume 32.7 percent of the 2008 corn crop, up
from 14.4 percent in 2005.
In combination with rising export activity, elevated ethanol demand contributed to record high
corn prices. By 2008, robust demand was straining
U.S. corn production and prices soared to record
levels. According to the U.S. Department of
Agriculture (USDA), the annual farm price for
the 2008 corn crop is expected to reach $3.90 per
bushel, up from $2.00 per bushel in 2005.1 High
corn prices also contributed to strong gains in other
crop prices as the market competed for planted
acres. For example, average annual farm prices for
soybeans and wheat are expected to jump more
1

The average farm price is obtained from the “World Agriculture
Supply and Demand Estimates–February 2009” (USDA, 2009).

66

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

than 60 and 100 percent, respectively, from 2005
to 2008.
Research indicates that ethanol production
has a significant impact on corn prices. Based on
a quarterly corn price model, a 1 percent increase
in ethanol production led to a 0.16 percent increase
in corn prices (Fortenbery and Park, 2008). Since
2005, ethanol production has increased by 197.2
percent, which according to the model would lead
to a 31.6 percent increase in corn prices (197.2 *
0.16 = 31.6). Based on 2005 corn prices of $2.00
per bushel, corn prices should have risen to $2.63
per bushel, well below current corn price estimates.
As a result, ethanol production has contributed to
rising corn prices, but other factors such as export
demand have also contributed to price increases
(Fortenbery and Park, 2008). Moreover, as recent
studies indicate corn prices respond to energy
prices—the correlation between corn and crude
oil prices has strengthened in recent years (Tyner
and Taheripour, 2008).
With increased production and record high
prices, crop revenues have risen sharply in recent
years. On a net basis, corn revenues per acre are
expected to rise well above 2005 levels (Table 1).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Henderson

Table 2
Rail Summary: 2006-08 and 2016 Marketing Years
Variable
Ethanol production (billion gallons)

2006

2007

2008

2016

5.8

9.4

11.2

15.0

119,347

190,816

227,755

306,122

26,338

41,650

49,533

66,576

Number of projected rail carloads
Ethanol production
Distillers’ dried grains with solubles

SOURCE: USDA, “Expansion of U.S. Corn-based Ethanol from the Agricultural Transportation Perspective” in Ethanol Transportation
Backgrounder, September 2007; www.ams.usda.gov/AMSv1.0/getfile?dDocName=STELPRDC5063605&acct=atpub.

The surge in market-based revenues more than offsets the declines in government payments, primarily
from countercyclical payments2 and higher input
costs, emerging from energy-based inputs such as
fuel and fertilizer. However, ethanol did not contribute to all of the revenue gains from corn production. In fact, based on the model estimates discussed
previously, increased ethanol production from
2005 to 2008 contributed 63 cents to the price of a
bushel of corn. Assuming no increase in ethanol
production and the loss of 63 cents ceteris paribus,
corn prices would decline to $3.27 per bushel and
net returns would turn negative, roughly equivalent
to 2005 levels.
Ethanol production has been found to influence
both local and national corn prices. In analysis of
basis patterns that measure changes in the difference between local cash prices and national prices,
an ethanol plant raised corn prices by 12.5 cents
per bushel on average (McNew and Griffith, 2005).
Price increases tended to be greater at the plant site,
ranging from 4.6 to 19.3 cents per bushel. As a
result of transportation cost savings, other research
has estimated that corn prices fall 0.2361 cents
per bushel for every mile farther from an ethanol
plant (Gallagher, Wisner, and Brubaker, 2005).
2

Under the countercyclical payment program, government subsidy
payments are triggered when crop prices fall below specified levels.
In 2005 and 2006, crop prices in general were low, triggering larger
payments under the countercyclical payment program. The rise in
crop prices in 2007 and 2008 above the trigger prices led to lower
countercyclical payments. In 2005 and 2006, countercyclical program
payments topped $4.0 billion annually. In 2008, countercyclical
program payments are projected to fall to $720 million after dropping
to $1.1 billion in 2007.

Increased crop profits quickly translated into
higher land values. Nationally, U.S. cropland values
rose 12.5 percent in 2006 and an additional 10.4
percent in 2007, the strongest gains since the 1970s.3
The largest gains emerged in the Northern Plains
and the Corn Belt, where cropland values jumped
almost 20 percent in 2007. Even within major corn
production regions, cropland value gains rose faster
in locations in closer proximity to an ethanol
plant (Henderson and Gloy, forthcoming). In the
Federal Reserve District of Kansas City, farmland
value gains were almost double in locations within
50 miles of an ethanol plant. The larger land value
gains near ethanol plants reflected the capitalized
value of the stronger crop prices and net returns
to corn production closer to the ethanol plant
(Henderson and Gloy, forthcoming).
The rapid expansion of ethanol production has
also altered transportation and storage patterns in
some parts of the Corn Belt. After the surge in
ethanol production, anecdotal reports indicate
that ethanol producers experience more difficulty
shipping final products by rail. Ethanol production
has also altered the shipping flows of grain. In fact,
in 2006, the state of Iowa expected to import corn
to meet industry needs for rising ethanol production (Roe, Jolly, and Wisner, 2006). On a national
basis, reaching the 15 billion gallon mandate by
2016 is expected to increase ethanol rail shipments
and dried distilled grain shipments by more than
150 percent above 2006 levels (Table 2). Grain storage patterns have also changed as local producers
3

USDA farmland values are measured as of January 1. As a result,
reported increases from 2007 to 2008 reflect 2007 land value increases.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

67

Henderson

and grain storage facilities are needed to store more
grain for year-round processing at ethanol plants.
The livestock sector has probably been the most
strongly affected by rising crop prices. Higher crop
prices have led to major gains in feed costs. The
USDA indicates that in September 2008, cattle feed
costs increased 52 percent and broiler feed costs
rose 64 percent over the previous year (USDA,
2008). Feed costs rose less rapidly for cattle producers as they are better able to replace corn with
distilled grains, a by-product of ethanol production,
in cattle feed rations. Rising feed costs have boosted
the breakeven price from livestock feeding: Cattle
and hog feeders operated in the red for most of 2008.
Still, it is important to remember that rising crop
prices are driven by other factors, such as robust
export activity, in addition to the ethanol boom.
Ethanol production has contributed to shifts in
cattle feeding operations. Livestock numbers have
declined in response to higher feed costs and
declining profits. With higher feed costs, livestock feeders often slaughter more animals at lower
weights to reduce costs. In fact, the number of
heifers and gilts sent to slaughter increased in 2007
and slaughter weights for cattle and hogs declined.
The production of distilled grains may have
contributed to a modest shift in feeding locations.
Distilled grains are a by-product of the ethanol
industry and are a partial substitute for corn in
cattle feed. However, unlike corn, distilled grains
quickly spoil and are difficult to transport. As a
result, as was expected, the price of distilled grains
fell sharply near ethanol plants and reduced the
feed costs of local cattle feeders. With lower feed
costs, cattle feeders near ethanol plants would enjoy
larger profits and expand production, whereas
feeders farther away would cut production. In fact,
policymakers in the Corn Belt were touting ethanol
production as a way to spark an expansion in the
livestock industry. The large-scale shifts in cattle
feeding, however, have yet to emerge. From 2005
to 2008, cattle feeding costs in Nebraska and Texas
rose 9.3 and 9.5 percent, respectively.
In general, ethanol production has contributed
to higher corn prices at the national and local levels.
However, other factors, such as export activity,
have also contributed to higher prices. Still, higher
feed costs are straining profit margins for the live68

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

stock industry. Few shifts in the geographic location
of livestock production have emerged, although
local corn prices and farmland values have risen
more in locations closer to an ethanol plant.

NONFARM IMPACTS
While ethanol production has led to mixed
impacts on the farm sector, it has led to increased
nonfarm activity. Ethanol production stimulates
nonfarm activity initially from new plant construction and then through ongoing plant operation.
Although ethanol plants do help stimulate nonfarm activity in rural places, the benefits are probably not as large as some initial projections.
Over the past few years, several economic
impact studies have been conducted on the ethanol
industry. The economic impacts touted in these
studies are heavily dependent on the assumptions
embedded in the model. As a result, the economic
impacts vary with the local labor force, crop production impacts, the local business environment,
the economic multipliers used to calculated indirect impacts, changes to industries from ethanol
production, and induced impacts (i.e., changes in
household spending from additional income to
the region).4
Ethanol’s first nonfarm economic impact occurs
during plant construction. Construction activity
has the potential to stimulate economic growth in
the local community as new workers are hired and
various inputs are used for plant construction. However, these impacts are temporary and eliminated
after plant completion. A study of four Missouri
ethanol plants indicated that the construction
phase produced a total of 2,098 construction jobs
(Pierce, Horner, and Milhollin, 2007). However,
other studies do not model the economic impacts
of the construction phase because the jobs are temporary and often filled by out-of-state workers with
many of the other services and goods used during
construction imported from outside the region
(Swenson, 2008). Regardless, the increase in temporary workers does provide an economic boost at
4

Most economic impacts studies use input-output analysis to model
economic impacts. IMPLAN is the program commonly used to conduct the analysis (available at www.implan.com).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Henderson

Table 3
Economic Impact Estimates for a 100 MGY Capacity Ethanol Refinery
Hamilton, Illinois
Type of impact
Direct

Kankakee, Illinois

Iowa

Output
($ million)

Jobs

Output
($ million)

Jobs

Output
($ million)

Jobs

Value-added
($ million)

214.6

39

214.6

39

227.0

46

35.5

Indirect

14.6

97

27.2

152

25.3

95

11.0

Induced

1.6

17

5.7

59

2.0

29

1.2

230.8

153

247.5

250

254.2

170

47.7

Total

SOURCE: Low and Isserman (2009); Swenson (2008).

local restaurants and hotels as temporary workers
find places to eat and sleep.
The long-term direct economic impacts from
ethanol emerge from the continued operation of
the ethanol plant. First, ethanol plants employ
people to operate the facility. In general, ethanol
plants typically employ between 35 and 45 people.
Smaller plants (50 million gallons per year [MGY]
capacity) employ roughly 35 people; larger plants
(100 MGY capacity) employ more than 40 people
(Swenson, 2008; Low and Isserman, 2009). As the
size of new plants increases due to economies of
scale, the number of workers needed in the ethanol
industry could decline if larger plants replace older,
smaller plants.
Second, ethanol plants produce ethanol and
distilled grains, which boosts overall economic
activity in the community. Economic activity often
is measured on a gross basis in terms of output
(sales) and on a value-added, net basis, measuring
the wages and salaries paid to workers, returns to
proprietors, investors, and indirect tax payments
above and beyond the costs of inputs. Recent studies
indicate that a single 100 MGY ethanol plant would
boost direct output (gross sales) for the county in
which the plant is located by roughly $215 to $227
million dollars and value-added activity by $35.5
million dollars (Table 3).
The direct economic impacts from ethanol
plants are expected to ripple through the economy
and support increased industry activity and boost
household spending. The size of these industry and
household impacts depends heavily on the size of

the economic multipliers in the local economy.
Disagreements over the economic impacts of the
ethanol industry vary with the assumptions surrounding the economic multipliers. The biggest
economic assumption is the impact on crop production in the region. Studies assuming larger production impacts have larger economic multipliers.
Recent economic impact studies (Swenson, 2008;
Low and Isserman, 2009) have reduced economic
multipliers associated with the ethanol industry
(Table 4). Recent studies assume that the local
production response is muted because most of the
highly productive agricultural farmland is already
in production. As a result, most of the changes in
crop production will be the substitution of corn for
other crop production (Low and Isserman, 2009).5
In terms of output, industry (indirect) impacts
are much larger than household (induced) impacts.
For example, in Iowa, a 100 MGY ethanol plant
had an indirect multiplier of 0.11, meaning that
for every dollar of output, the ethanol plant stimulated an additional 11 cents in industry output
(see Table 4). In contrast, household spending is
expected to rise 1 to 3 cents for every dollar increase
in output from an ethanol plant.
Industry and household impacts, however,
varied with the local business environment and
size of the economy. For example, the industry multiplier for a 100 MGY plant was 0.13 in Kankakee,
5

Many initial studies assumed a fixed-proportions input-output
model that does not incorporate various types of potential substitutions in local economic activity (Low and Isserman, 2009).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

69

Henderson

Table 4
Output and Employment Multipliers from Ethanol Plants
Economic study

Output multiplier

Employment multiplier

Industry (indirect)

0.28

1.90

Household spending (induced)

0.09

0.95

Total

0.37

2.86

Industry (indirect)

0.11

2.14

Household spending (induced)

0.02

0.66

Total

0.13

2.80

Industry (indirect)

0.11

2.07

Household spending (induced)

0.01

0.63

Total

0.12

2.70

0.07

2.49

Household spending (induced)

0.01

0.44

Total

0.08

2.92

Industry (indirect)

0.13

3.90

Household spending (induced)

0.03

1.51

Total

0.15

5.41

Nebraska (Petersan, 2002)
40 MGY ethanol plant

Iowa (Swenson, 2008)
50 MGY ethanol plant

Iowa (Swenson, 2008)
100 MGY ethanol plant

Hamilton, Illinois (Low and Isserman, 2009)
100 MGY ethanol plant
Industry (indirect)

Kankakee, Illinois (Low and Isserman, 2009)
100 MGY ethanol plant

Illinois (year 2000 population 3,029), compared
with 0.07 in Hamilton, Illinois (year 2000 population 25,561). With a much larger and more complex
economy, Kankakee has a greater ability to provide
more inputs to the ethanol plant and thus a higher
indirect multiplier (Low and Isserman, 2009).
A similar pattern emerges from employment,
or job, multipliers. Indirect industry multipliers
are larger than induced (household spending)
multipliers (see Table 4). In addition, larger, morecomplex economies are expected to enjoy larger
multipliers than small rural economies. It is important to note that rising output and household spending would boost tax revenues at various levels.
70

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

LONG-TERM IMPACTS
The ethanol industry is expected to provide
valuable future contributions to rural communities.
Because expectations regarding the contribution of
ethanol plants to economic output have declined
recently, the biggest challenge might be shrinking
profit margins in ethanol production. Ethanol is a
policy-driven market and changes in policy will
shape its long-term survival.
The long-term impacts of ethanol production
clearly depend on the viability of the ethanol industry. Some analysts indicate that ethanol profitability will rise and fall with crude oil prices. In fact,
ethanol prices do move with crude oil prices. How-

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Henderson

Figure 1
Ethanol and Corn Price Spreads
$/Gallon of Ethanol
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
Apr-05

Oct-05

Apr-06

Oct-06

Apr-07

Oct-07

Apr-08

Oct-08

NOTE: Calculation based on Commodity Research Bureau data. The spread shows the net return from the sale of a gallon of ethanol after paying for the corn used to produce it. One bushel of corn is assumed to yield 2.8 gallons of ethanol. Spread = Ethanol Price – 共Corn Price/2.8兲.

ever, corn prices—the largest ethanol production
costs—also are moving with ethanol and crude oil
prices. Recent history shows that even with record
high crude oil prices, ethanol profits have narrowed
significantly. Since 2006, ethanol profits have
sharply declined as corn prices have risen faster
than ethanol prices. The ethanol-corn price spread,
which measures the net returns to ethanol after paying for corn, is just one indicator suggesting that
profit margins have fallen (Figure 1). The biggest
sign of struggles in the ethanol industry is the
recent idling of several ethanol plants under construction and the bankruptcy of VeraSun Energy
Corporation (McEowen, 2008).
Policy issues probably hold the key to ethanol
profitability. As the food-versus-fuel debate intensified, the appetite for ethanol subsidies diminished.
A decline in ethanol subsidies and the elimination
of the tariff on Brazilian ethanol is expected to lead
to lower ethanol production (Thompson, Meyer,
and Westoff, 2008). Yet the biggest impact could
emerge from the elimination of the ethanol mandate (Westoff, Thompson, and Meyer, 2008).

The reduction in ethanol production and the
closure of ethanol production plants could lead to
lower economic impacts on rural communities. In
general, idling plants would lead to lower crop
prices and reduced capitalized returns to cropland
at the local level as local demand shrinks. Lost output and employment at the ethanol plant could
ripple throughout the local economy, leading to
additional job losses and reduced business activity
and household spending.
As the ethanol industry works through its own
troubling times, which ethanol plants are most
susceptible to close? Are older, smaller plants or
newer, larger plants in the best position to weather
current strains in ethanol profits? Older, smaller
plants should have already paid a large proportion
of their fixed costs, whereas new, larger plants
should have lower fixed costs because of economies
of scale. In either case, closures of either type of
plant will produce economic losses. However,
smaller, older plants with local investors tend to
have higher induced impacts on the local economy
as local investors spend more money locally

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

71

Henderson

(Swenson and Eathington, 2006). As a result, the
closure of locally owned ethanol plants could have
larger economic impacts in rural communities than
investor-owned plants.
Alternatively, new technologies could emerge
to make ethanol more profitable. Since 2001, the
ethanol industry has significantly cut the amount
of water used in production from almost five gallons
of water per gallon of ethanol to less than four
(Keeney and Muller, 2006; Wu, 2008). What innovations will emerge from new technology that will
boost ethanol productivity? Over the past few years,
ethanol yields per bushel of corn have increased
6.4 percent for dry mills (Wu, 2008), rising to 2.8
gallons of ethanol per bushel of corn in 2008. Scientists are also exploring how enzymes could boost
ethanol yields (McGinnis, 2007). If the market stabilizes and mandates hold, ethanol production
could support economic activity into the future.

CONCLUSION
An ethanol boom has helped spur economic
activity in many rural communities. Ethanol production has added value to U.S. corn production
and contributed to higher cropland values, but it
has posed some challenges to the livestock sector.
New ethanol plants have added jobs in many rural
communities, which have supported additional
gains in related industry and household spending.
However, as more insight into the ethanol industry
is gained, expectations regarding the wave of pending activity have declined. Proponents have touted
ethanol as fueling the current farm boom and
spurring a wave of business activity on rural Main
Streets. Opponents have identified ethanol as the
root cause of lost profitability in the livestock industry. In both cases, the economic impacts of ethanol
are probably not as large as touted.

REFERENCES
Environmental Protection Agency. “Renewable Fuel
Standard Program: Technical Amendments.”
October 2, 2008; www.epa.gov/OMS/renewablefuels/.

72

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

Fortenbery, T. Randall and Park, Hwanil. “The Effect
of Ethanol Production on the U.S. National Corn
Price.” Staff Paper No. 523, University of Wisconsin,
Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics,
April 2008;
www.aae.wisc.edu/pubs/sps/pdf/stpap523.pdf.
Gallagher, Paul; Wisner, Robert and Brubacker, Heather.
“Price Relationships in Processors’ Input Market
Areas: Testing Theories for Corn Prices Near Ethanol
Plants.” Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics,
2005, 53(2-3), pp. 117-39.
Henderson, Jason and Gloy, Brent. “The Impact of
Ethanol Plants on Cropland Values in the Great
Plains.” Agricultural Finance Review (forthcoming).
Keeney, Dennis and Muller, Mark. “Water Use by
Ethanol Plants: Potential Challenges.” Institute for
Agriculture and Trade Policy, October 2006;
www.agobservatory.org/library.cfm?refid=89449.
Low, Sarah A. and Isserman, Andrew M. “Ethanol and
the Local Economy: Industry Trends, Location
Factors, Economic Impacts, and Risks.” Economic
Development Quarterly, February 2009, 23, pp. 71-88.
McEowen, Roger. “VeraSun Energy Bankruptcy Poses
Perils for Farmers and Elevators.” Center for
Agricultural Lay and Taxation, Iowa State University,
November 18, 2008;
www.calt.iastate.edu/verasun.html.
McGinnis, Laura. “Fueling America—Without
Petroleum.” Agricultural Research, U.S. Department
of Agriculture. Agricultural Research Service, April
2007, pp. 10-13;
www.ars.usda.gov/is/ar/archive/apr07/petro0407.pdf.
McNew, Kevin and Griffith, Duane. “Measuring the
Impact of Ethanol Plants on Local Grain Prices.”
Review of Agricultural Economics, June 2005, 27(2),
pp. 164-80.
Petersan, Donis. “Estimated Economic Effects for the
Prospective Fagen Ethanol Project at Central City,
Nebraska.” Economic Development Department,
Nebraska Public Power District, December 2002;
www.ne-ethanol.org/pdf/centralcityethanol.pdf.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Henderson

Pierce, Vern; Horner, Joe and Ryan Milhollin, Ryan.
“Employment and Economic Benefits of Ethanol
Production in Missouri.” Commercial Agriculture
Program, University of Missouri Extension, February
2007; http://agebb.missouri.edu/commag/
ethanolreport2007.pdf.
Roe, Josh D.; Jolly, Robert W. and Wisner, Robert N.
“Another Plant?!…The Rapid Expansion in the
Ethanol Industry and Its Effects All the Way Down
to the Farm Gate.” Presented at the American
Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting,
Long Beach, CA, July 23-26, 2006; http://ageconsearch.
umn.edu/bitstream/21066/1/sp06ro04.pdf.
Swenson, David A. “The Economic Impact of Ethanol
Production in Iowa.” Staff General Research Paper
No. 12865, Department of Economics, Iowa State
University, January 2008; www.econ.iastate.edu/
research/webpapers/paper_12865.pdf.
Swenson, David and Eathington, Liesl. “Determining
the Regional Economic Values of Ethanol Production
in Iowa Considering Different Levels of Local
Investment.” Department of Economics, Iowa State
University, July 2006; www.valuechains.org/bewg/
Documents/eth_full0706.pdf.
Thompson, Wyatt; Meyer, Seth and Westoff, Patrick.
“Model of the U.S. Ethanol Market.” FAPRI-MU
Report No. 07-08, Food and Agricultural Policy
Research Institute, University of Missouri, July 2008;
www.fapri.missouri.edu/outreach/publications/
2008/fapri_mu_report_07_08.pdf.

Tyner, Walle E. and Taheripour, Farzad. “Policy Options
for Integrated Energy and Agricultural Markets.”
Review of Agricultural Economics, 2008, 30(3), pp.
387-96; www.agecon.purdue.edu/news/financial/
RAE_paper_2008.pdf.
U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research
Service. “Livestock, Dairy, and Poultry Outlook–
December 2008.” December 2008;
www.ers.usda.gov/publications/ldp/.
U.S. Department of Agriculture, World Agricultural
Outlook Board. “World Agriculture Supply and
Demand Estimates–February 2009.” WASDE-467,
February 2009; http://usda.mannlib.cornell.edu/
usda/current/wasde/wasde-02-10-2009.pdf.
Westoff, Patrick; Thompson, Wyatt and Meyer, Seth.
“Biofuels: Impact of Selected Farm Bill Provisions
and Other Biofuel Policy Options.” FAPRI-MU
Report No. 06-08, Food and Agricultural Policy
Research Institute, University of Missouri, June 2008;
www.fapri.missouri.edu/outreach/publications/
2008/fapri_mu_report_06_08.pdf.
Wu, May. “Analysis of Efficiency of the U.S. Ethanol
Industry 2007.” Center for Transportation Research,
Argonne National Laboratory, March 27, 2008;
www1.eere.energy.gov/biomass/pdfs/anl_ethanol_
analysis_2007.pdf.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

73

Commentary
Seth Meyer

T

here has undeniably been a reversal of
fortunes in the ethanol industry since
2006. With petroleum prices well off
their peak of mid-2008, the current economic recession, and an uncertain policy environment, Jason Henderson’s examination of the role
that ethanol plays in rural economic development
is well timed and raises important questions concerning the industry’s contribution to stimulating
the rural economy.
He lays out the potential direct impacts on the
rural economy from biofuel-induced changes in
employment and commodity prices, as well as the
indirect and induced effects, noting the limited
direct employment effect found in several studies.
Further, he notes that secondary effects hinge on
the assumed multiplier effect, which depends on
production response, which itself depends on the
induced commodity price change. To this end, he
does an admirable job of attempting to determine
the contribution of biofuels to the runup in commodity prices in mid-2008—no small task. He
concludes that biofuels contributed a noticeable
amount to the increase in commodity prices but
that direct and indirect employment effects may
be limited, and given the role policy plays in the
industry, it could be dealt a blow with the stroke
of a pen. While this author makes no conclusions
about the broader benefits of biofuel production,
I hope to complement the discussion about effects
on commodity prices and the role that federal policy
plays in the market for biofuels.

COMMODITY PRICES IN 2007-08:
TRANSIENT OR PERSISTENT
FACTORS?
A number of factors came together during the
2007-08 crop year, creating the perfect storm. Shortand long-run issues of commodity supply and
demand, as well as policies around the world, combined for a significant spike in commodity prices
in a setting of strong and volatile petroleum prices.
In examining the factors that led to record commodity prices in the summer of 2008, Dr. Henderson
draws on research by Fortenbery and Park (2008)
to arrive at a $0.63 per bushel contribution to the
corn price from the growth in ethanol production
over the 2005-08 period. Although this is significant, the increase in prices during the same period
was well in excess of that amount.
It is clear that biofuels have had an effect on
commodity prices, but estimates have varied considerably from a negligible impact to attributing
most of the rise in prices to increased biofuel production. The varying estimates expose the difficulty
in arriving at a precise estimate. In addition, the
question remains: Are the other contributing factors
transient in nature or persistent and likely to resurface as world economies recover from the current
economic crisis?
Poor wheat yields in Canada, Eastern Europe,
and Australia helped fuel grain prices over the
summer of 2008, but these crop shortages could
clearly be considered a transient factor that would
disappear with a return to normal yields. However,

Seth Meyer is an analyst for the Food and Agricultural Policy Research Institute. He is also research assistant professor in the department of
agricultural economics at the University of Missouri–Columbia.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economic Development, 2009, 5(1), pp. 74-77.

© 2009, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced,
published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

74

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Meyer

Table 1
Change in World Grain Productivity (percent)
Growth measure

1960-70

1970-80

1980-90

1990-2007

Yield

2.8

1.9

2.4

1.3

Area

0.5

0.9

–0.5

–0.2

Production

3.3

2.8

1.6

1.0

SOURCE: USDA Production, Supply and Distribution database (accessed November 1, 2008).

an analysis of grain area and yield around the world
shows a potentially concerning slowdown in
growth over the past few decades (Table 1), thereby
limiting supply growth at the same time consumers
in the developing world became more affluent,
demanding more meat and therefore increased use
of feed. In addition, world grain stocks levels have
been low, by historical standards, for the past several
years. Policy changes in the United States in the
1980s reduced domestic grain stock holdings just
as Chinese grain stocks began to rise. In 2000-01
the Chinese began to liquidate those stocks, thus
limiting the ability to draw on them to moderate
short-run price increases (Figure 1). With supplies
constrained and demand showing little response,
prices continued to rise. Several countries, worried
about the effect of rising prices on their domestic
consumers, instituted trade restrictions on grains,
rice in particular. This drove prices yet higher.
Add to this the much discussed effect of demand
for grain and vegetable oils to produce biofuels
both at home and abroad, and it becomes obvious
that a precise estimate of the effects of biofuel production on commodity prices is both difficult to
quantify and highly context dependent (Westhoff,
Thompson, and Meyer, 2008). Had one or several
of these factors not been present, one may have
arrived at a different conclusion about the price
impact of biofuels.

THE IMPORTANCE OF POLICY
The role of current biofuel policy in commodity
and biofuel markets is equally context dependent
and, as Dr. Henderson clearly outlines, is subject
to change with policy priorities. Current policies

fall roughly into two categories: (i) tax credits and
(ii) quantity mandates established in the Energy
Independence and Security Act (EISA) of 2007
(Energy Information Agency, 2008). The credits go
to blenders who mix biofuels with traditional petroleum-based motor fuels and are payable at any
ethanol price. Mandates require the blenders to
blend a specific quantity of biofuel each year subject to a schedule in the EISA legislation. If petroleum prices are at levels similar to those seen in
mid-2008, the mandates may be irrelevant as
blenders choose to blend quantities in excess of
their required amounts, while the blenders’ credit
will induce further production. In this instance,
the blenders’ credits influence biofuel production
and therefore commodity prices, while mandates
have little to no effect. Alternatively, if petroleum
prices are at the lower levels seen at year-end 2008,
the mandates may be binding, determining demand,
and thus removal of blenders’ credits may have
little to no effect on the quantity of biofuel produced
and therefore the demand for grains.
Which policy is the most influential is dependent on the oil price, but the combination of policies
boosts biofuel production at all oil prices. A shift
in policy, that is, elimination of these policies,
would have sizable consequences for the industry
(Figure 2). With regard to the construction of new
facilities—approximately 13 billion gallons of cornbased ethanol capacity completed or under construction today—this is enough capacity to fulfill
corn ethanol’s targeted mandate for the next several
years. Additional plant construction and the associated jobs will be limited unless petroleum prices
return to mid-2008 levels and current policies
remain in place. The uncertainty surrounding the

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

75

Meyer

Figure 1
World Grain Stocks
Metric Tons (millions)
700

Rest of World
China
U.S.

600
500
400
300
200
100

8
-0

6
07
20

20

05

-0

-0

4

2
20

03

01
20

-0
99
19

-0

0

8
-9

6
-9

97
19

4
95
19

93

-9

-9

2
19

0

91

-9
89

19

-8
87

19

19

19

58

-8

6

8

0

SOURCE: USDA Production, Supply and Distribution database (accessed November 1, 2008).

Figure 2
Petroleum Price Impact on Ethanol Production (2011-17 Average) Under Various Policy Regimes

Without EISA, Credits, or Tariffs

Without EISA, with Credits and Tariffs

With EISA, without Credits and Tariffs

With EISA, Credits, and Tariffs
0

5

10

15

20

Gallons (billions)
Petroleum Averages $107/Barrel

Petroleum Averages $67/Barrel

SOURCE: Westhoff et al. (2008).

76

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Meyer

continuation of those policies makes for an uninviting investment atmosphere. Other classes of mandates such as cellulosic ethanol hold potential for
both increased crop production and profitability
and their associated economic activity. The path
of these second-generation technologies is unclear
and perhaps even more dependent on the continuation of favorable policies.
The current economic crisis and the corresponding decline in petroleum prices have brought
new scrutiny to the biofuel industry. High petroleum prices in the spring and summer of 2008 were
followed by increased grain production. Although
weakness in world income growth has cut demand
for feed grains and commodity prices, the decline
in petroleum prices has cut biofuel demand, leaving
production to be increasingly determined by policy
and idling excess capacity. Ethanol producers who
locked in grain inputs at higher prices, in fear of
yet higher grain prices, have experienced mounting
losses, and stock prices for public companies in the
industry have fallen precipitously over the past 24
months. When the world economy begins recovery
and world grain and petroleum demand strengthens, much in the biofuel sector will depend on how
petroleum prices respond. Should the recovery lead
to rapidly increasing petroleum prices, we could
return to strong commodity prices once again, likely
with a response by the biofuel industry that incorporates lessons learned during the past 24 months.
Whereas ethanol advocates cite numerous reasons for supporting domestic production of biofuels,
Dr. Henderson raises all the relevant concerns in
evaluating the industry as a rural development tool.
Biofuel production clearly has some impact on
commodity prices and his estimates appear plausible, but the size and persistence of such increases

remain uncertain, as do the net effect of those prices
given the offsetting livestock producer impacts,
increase in land prices, and concerns about consumers in developing countries. The direct effects
on employment appear limited with secondary
effects largely dependent on the assumed multiplier effect, and a portion of the industry production is also reliant on public policy for continued
viability. Dr. Henderson’s arguments concerning
biofuel production as a limited tool for rural development are convincing, but the broader discussion
about the objectives of supporting domestic biofuel
production is likely to continue for the foreseeable
future.

REFERENCES
Energy Information Agency. “Energy Independence
and Security Act of 2007: Summary of Provisions.”
December 19, 2007; www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/aeo/
otheranalysis/aeo_2008analysispapers/eisa.html.
Fortenbery, T. Randall and Park, Hwanil. “The Effect
of Ethanol Production on the U.S. National Corn
Price.” Staff Paper No. 523, University of Wisconsin,
Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics,
April 2008;
www.aae.wisc.edu/pubs/sps/pdf/stpap523.pdf.
Westhoff, Pat; Thompson, Wyatt and Meyer, Seth.
“Biofuels: Impact of Selected Farm Bill Provisions
and Other Biofuel Policy Options.” FAPRI-MU Report
No. 06-08, Food and Agricultural Policy Research
Institute, University of Missouri-Columbia, June 2008;
http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/37772/2/
FAPRI_MU_Report_06_08.pdf.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

77

Panel Discussion: The Future of Biofuel

An Economic Critique of
Corn-Ethanol Subsidies
Jerry Taylor

I

f corn ethanol is such a wonderful product,
why does it require government subsidy?1
If ethanol is truly economically competitive
with gasoline absent government preference—as many of its supporters seem to believe—
then private investors will produce ethanol for the
market regardless of whether government lends a
hand (Tyner and Taheripour, 2008).2 Subsidies in
this case will simply result in more ethanol pro1

2

This paper is exclusively concerned with ethanol made from corn.
Unless otherwise indicated, all references to ethanol are in relation
to ethanol made from corn. When economists discuss ethanol subsidies, they are almost always referring to four subsidies in particular:
a $0.51 per gallon blenders’ tax credit afforded to refineries that use
ethanol in motor fuel (known in the law as the Volumetric Ethanol
Excise Tax Credit, it is scheduled to be reduced to $0.45 per gallon
in 2009); a Renewable Fuels Standard that requires U.S. refiners to
consume a certain amount of ethanol per year (9 billion gallons, for
instance, in 2008, rising to 36 billion gallons by 2022); a 2.5 percent
ad valorem tariff on ethanol imports; and a $0.51 per gallon tariff on
the same. However, a number of other direct and indirect federal,
state, and local subsidies afforded to the ethanol industry in aggregate are quite large but are rarely considered in the peer-reviewed
literature (Hahn, 2008). That is largely because such subsidies are
difficult to quantify in a satisfactory manner and because they are
often afforded to other industries besides ethanol, leading to debate
about whether it is appropriate to consider them as ethanol subsidies
per se. The Energy Information Administration (EIA; 2008) pegs the
cost of ethanol subsidies to the taxpayer at $3 billion in 2007. The
best guess of the total federal subsidy afforded to the ethanol industry
that year, however, is conservatively estimated at $6.9 to $8.4 billion
and $9.2 to $11 billion in 2008, or $1.50 to $1.70 per gallon of gasolineequivalent ethanol (Koplow, 2007).
Tyner and Taheripour (2008) believe that ethanol production in the
United States was (barely) profitable without subsidy (defined as
operations clearing a 12 percent or better return on equity) for the

duction than is economically efficient. If ethanol
is not economically competitive with gasoline,
then subsidies distort the market by steering
investment away from economically attractive
gasoline and toward economically unattractive
ethanol. Consumer well-being and overall economic efficiency suffer as a consequence.
Support of ethanol subsidies and consumption
mandates offer a mix of arguments to justify government intervention. Those arguments can be neatly
sorted into two categories: those that forward wealth
distribution claims and those that forward efficiency
claims. The former arguments, although interesting,
are not addressed in this paper. Ethanol may or may
not transfer wealth to rural America, for instance,
but preferences with regard to wealth allocation
are subjective and not worth much analytic time.
The latter arguments, however, are grounded in
concrete claims that can be proven or disproven
and are, thus, the focus of this paper.
To have any intellectual force, the argument
that ethanol subsidies and consumption mandates
enhance economic efficiency must begin with a
discussion of market failure. Economists broadly
agree that, as a general rule, leaving production
and consumption decisions to market actors proves
more economically efficient than leaving the same
to governmental planners. Only if some unique and
fundamental failure occurs that prevents gains to
trade in a given market is there room for the argufirst time in 2001. From 2002 to 2003 production returned to unprofitability absent subsidies, but from 2004 to 2007 significant profits
were realized even without subsidy largely because of the de facto
ban on methyl tertiary-butyl ether as a fuel additive and a surge in
ethanol demand to provide those blending services. In 2008, however,
production again reached the break-even point.

Jerry Taylor is a senior fellow at the Cato Institute.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economic Development, 2009, 5(1), pp. 78-97.

© 2009, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced,
published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

78

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

ment that government intervention improves the
functioning of those markets (Cowen, 1988, and
Cowen and Crampton, 2003). Hence, the case for
ethanol subsidies hinges on whether concrete market failures exist in transportation fuel markets.
This paper examines the claims made about
alleged market failures in transportation fuel markets. Two claims in particular warrant examination:
that gasoline prices are too low because they do not
account for the national security costs associated
with gasoline consumption and that the environmental costs associated with gasoline consumption
are ignored in the pricing mechanism. Subsidy
proponents argue that if gasoline prices included
both the national security and environmental costs
associated with gasoline consumption, ethanol
would be much cheaper than gasoline and demand
for the latter would grow dramatically. Alas, those
costs (“externalities” in economic parlance) are
not embedded in final consumer prices and thus
market actors, left to their own devices, will overconsume gasoline and underconsume ethanol.
Other market failures have been alleged but they
are altogether less compelling than these two. A
cursory examination of a few of them follows.

“BIG OIL” MARKET POWER
We occasionally hear that “Big Oil” exercises
their market power to the detriment of motorists by
restricting ethanol’s entry into end-use fuel markets
(Cooper, 2005). The oil industry’s reluctance to use
high blends of ethanol in gasoline absent a government mandate, build ethanol delivery infrastructure to supply service stations, or provide E85
pumps3 are often marshaled as evidence that oil
companies are unfairly strangling an economic competitor in its bed. The existence of this self-serving
oil cartel is said to explain why this otherwise
commercially attractive transport fuel—ethanol—
requires government subsidies and consumption
mandates.
Yet, as of 2007, 38 percent of the retail fuels
market was composed of independent service
stations, not vertically integrated franchises, and
3

E85 is motor fuel that is 85 percent ethanol and 15 percent gasoline.

another 13 percent of grocers and other hypermarkets. Only 49 percent of retail fuel was sold
by stations associated with major oil companies.
Likewise, 56 percent of the refining market was
composed of independent, vertically deintegrated
refining companies (Lowe, 2008). Big Oil is simply incapable of keeping ethanol out of service
stations if profits are to be made by selling ethanol
to motorists.
Statistical analysis of market data finds no
evidence that market power in the oil sector has
any impact on national retail motor fuel prices,
although mergers and acquisitions have likely
increased fuel prices in some regions while decreasing them in others (Chouinard and Perloff, 2007,
and Taylor and Van Doren, 2006). Likewise, metrics
regarding market concentration in the refining
sector (such as the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index)
do not suggest much market power in four of the
five refining Petroleum Administration Defense
District regions of the United States (Du and Hayes,
2008).
The economic and regulatory hurdles to entering the refining or retail sales markets are modest.
Refineries change hands frequently—as do service
stations. This factor is important because many
economists now believe that, if a market is theoretically contestable, market power is functionally
modest to nonexistent (Baumol, 1982; and Baumol
and Panzer, 1982), although actual entry may still
be important in some industries (Borenstein, 1992).4
Finally, ethanol is delivered primarily by rail
but also by truck and barge. The oil industry is in
no position to block the expansion of that infrastructure or to prevent third parties from investing in
dedicated ethanol pipelines (ethanol cannot move
through pipelines used for oil or gasoline because
ethanol is water soluble).
A variation of the above narrative holds that
oil refining capacity is so tight that, absent govern4

Many states prohibit entry to some extent in retail fuel markets by
preventing major retailers like Cosco, Sam’s Club, and Wal-Mart
from selling motor fuel. Likewise, zoning laws and environmental
regulations have been identified as barriers to entry in some markets.
Those are government failures, however—not market failures—and
should be addressed by deregulation. Given the inclination of many
major retailers to project “green” images to consumers, it may well
be that deregulating entry would increase the availability of ethanol
to consumers.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

79

Panel Discussion

ment efforts to promote ethanol, American consumers would have suboptimal volumes of motor
fuel available to them and, accordingly, higher
pump prices. Thus, the argument is that ethanol
increases the amount of motor fuel available—effectively adding to capacity—and serves the role that,
for instance, Hamburger Helper serves in increasing
the volume of food on a plate of ground beef.
The argument is superficially true. Assume,
for instance, that all ethanol disappeared tomorrow.
In the short run, gasoline refining capacity is relatively fixed and consumers do not respond robustly
to price increases in the short term. Hence, the
highly inelastic short-term supply-and-demand
curves for gasoline suggest that gasoline prices
would increase dramatically—14.6 percent according to a 2004 analysis circulated by the Renewable
Fuels Association (Urbanchuk, 2004), a figure that
would be even higher today given ethanol’s larger
share of the motor fuels market in 2008. Supply
and demand are more elastic in the long run, so
ultimately, prices would rise only 3.7 percent in
the long term according to that same analysis.
What is the market failure, however, that leads
industry to underinvest in refining capacity? Sometimes we are told that industry conspires to restrain
refining capacity to maximize profit (Cooper, 2007).
This is a variation of the previous argument about
monopoly power in the oil sector. It is also an argument that, even if true, does not necessarily provide
evidence of market failure. The exercise of market
power may have an impact on wealth distribution
(refinery owners are wealthier and everyone else
is poorer), but it likely has little impact on overall
market efficiency (Posner, 1999).
Many analysts believe that the lack of excess
refining capacity is largely driven by the limited
profits historically made by those who invest in
refining. To the extent that ethanol programs significantly reduce refining profits (see Du and Hayes,
2008), the problems ostensibly addressed by ethanol
subsidies may actually contribute to the existence
of the underlying problem.
Other times we are told that government policies discourage the construction of new refineries
and the expansion of capacity at existing facilities.
Although it is unclear to what extent this is true,
if government policies inhibit optimal capacity
80

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

expansion it is a government failure, not a market
failure, and is best remedied by direct assault on
the policies in question.
The strongest study offered as evidence that
ethanol subsidies have reduced motor fuel prices
is by economists Xiaodong Du and Dermot Hayes at
the Center for Agriculture and Rural Development
at Iowa State University (Du and Hayes, 2008).
Their regression analysis concludes that ethanol
production has reduced retail gasoline prices by
$0.29 to $0.40 per gallon from 1995 to 2007
because it has “prevented some of the dramatic
price increases often associated with an industry
operating at close to capacity” (p. 13).
The Du and Hayes study (2008) does not,
however, support the contention that, in a hypothetical world in which ethanol production did
not exist, motor fuel prices would be higher. That
is because the study assumes that, without ethanol
production, gasoline refining capacity would not
have grown any more than it did with ethanol
production. Given that total refining capacity has
historically expanded to meet increased demand
(Shore and Hackworth, 2004), it is likely that, absent
ethanol production, capacity expansion would have
occurred and fuel prices in that counterfactual
world would have been no higher than they were
historically. The authors acknowledge as much:
“Because these results are based on capacity, it
would be wrong to extrapolate the results to today’s
markets. Had we not had ethanol, it seems likely
that the crude oil refining industry would be slightly
larger today than it actually is, and in the absence
of this additional crude oil refining capacity the
impact of eliminating ethanol would be extreme”
(pp. 13-14).
The Du and Hayes (2008) study also implicitly
assumes a fixed amount of oil production. Ample
anecdotal evidence, however, suggests that oil producers have responded to U.S. ethanol production
by reducing investments in upstream production
capacity. This seems reasonable given that ethanol
consumption displaces oil consumption and projections about the same heavily affect decisions
about investment in future oil production capacity.
Consequently, ethanol’s impact on oil prices is
ambiguous.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

Even if ethanol subsidies reduced motor fuel
prices, it does not follow that motorists are, on
balance, better off. For instance, the two Iowa State
economists who produced the aforementioned estimate regarding the reduction of motor fuel prices
that has followed from ethanol subsidies (Du and
Hayes, 2008) also contend (in Du, Hayes, and Baker,
2008) that the total social costs associated with
ethanol subsidies are greater than the aggregated
benefits. Cornell economists Harry de Gorter and
David Just (2007b) argue that the spread between
the two is even greater than alleged by Du, Hayes,
and Baker.
This should not be surprising. Subsidies for
wheat, corn, soybeans, and other crops produce
lower commodity prices, but very few economists
argue that gains to consumers outweigh the efficiency losses imposed by those subsidies on the
economy as a whole. What consumers gain is more
than offset by taxes and the loss as a market actor
in other sectors of the economy.

FARM SUBSIDIES
Some have argued that ethanol subsidies actually reduce the net burden of subsidies on the taxpayer because the higher corn prices yielded by
ethanol subsidies reduce other subsidy payments
that would have otherwise gone to corn farmers.
This appears to be correct, at least for 2007. Reductions in loan deficiency payments to corn farmers
exceeded the costs of the ethanol program by $3.45
billion in that year (Du, Hayes, and Baker, 2008).
Yet it does not follow that ethanol subsidies
therefore enhance efficiency. First, the taxpayer
savings identified by Du, Hayes, and Baker (2008)
do not account for all of the deadweight losses
associated with ethanol subsidies.5 Total deadweight losses are, in aggregate, greater than the
advertised savings to the taxpayer (de Gorter and
Just, 2007b). Second, although that same study
finds a net reduction in farm payments from the
5

Deadweight losses arise from the economic distortions associated
with tax avoidance and changes in social and economic behavior in
response to regulatory intervention. A textbook exposition of deadweight loss can be found in Rosen and Gayer (2008).

ethanol program, it also finds that the net total of
social cost associated with the refiners’ tax credit,
the ethanol consumption mandate, and the ethanol
tariff (absent any consideration of the alleged
national security or environmental benefits of
ethanol) was $780 million in 2007.
One further point should be made. The existence of farm subsidies is not a market failure—it
is a government failure. In a narrow sense, ethanol
subsidies may reduce the cost of farm subsidies to
the taxpayer, but a far more direct and less-costly
means of doing the same is simply to dismantle
the farm subsidies in question.

LEVELING THE PLAYING FIELD
Ethanol proponents frequently note that government provides substantial subsidies to the oil
sector. The belief is that those subsidies provide
commercial advantages to oil producers and oil
prices are lower as a consequence; that is, oil subsidies distort the market by encouraging excessive
oil consumption. Thus, ethanol proponents believe
that subsidies for ethanol, beyond simply leveling
the competitive playing field, make the economy
more efficient by reducing oil consumption from
the inefficiently high levels promoted by subsidies
to the oil sector.
The EIA pegged federal oil and natural gas
subsidies at $2.15 billion in 2007 (EIA, 2008). A
more ambitious tally suggests that oil subsidies,
broadly defined, were $5.2 to $11.9 billion in 1995,
or $1.20 to $2.80 per barrel (Koplow and Martin,
1998; the estimate does not include environmental
or national security externalities and, unfortunately,
has not been updated). Although laws and outlays
have changed substantially since Koplow and
Martin’s publication (although the EIA’s tally finds
no appreciable change in the sum of federal oil and
gas subsidies since 1999), their estimate illustrates
the importance of defining subsidy beneficiaries.
To wit, are subsidies programs that exclusively
benefit the targeted industry (the EIA definition),
or do they also include programs that benefit the
recipient and other parties outside that sector of
the economy (the Koplow and Martin definition)?

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

81

Panel Discussion

The EIA calculates that federal oil and gas subsidies outside the electricity sector total $30,000
per million British thermal units (BTUs). Biofuel
subsidies outside the electricity sector, however,
($3 billion of the $3.2 billion of which are directed
at ethanol via the blenders’ tax credit), work out to
$5.72 million per million BTU (EIA, 2008, Table 36).
Using EIA figures for oil and gas subsidies and estimates of the cost of the blender’s tax credit from
Koplow (2007), economist Douglas Tiffany (2008)
calculates that oil subsidies in 2007 were slightly
less than $0.15 per gallon of gasoline while ethanol
subsidies totaled $0.588 per gallon. Whether we
embrace a narrow or broad definition of subsidy,
the conclusion is the same; oil subsidies are relatively trivial while ethanol subsidies are relatively
substantial.
Although none of the identified oil subsidies is
defensible on economic grounds, they have very
little if any impact on oil prices because they do not
reduce marginal production costs (Metcalf, 2006).
Hence, oil subsidies do not distort the market and
do not disadvantage ethanol producers. There is no
efficiency problem for ethanol subsidies to correct.
Ethanol subsidies, however, are more pernicious. Unlike oil subsidies, ethanol subsidies reduce
marginal production costs and, as a consequence,
distort price signals and thus capital allocations
in the market. The ethanol subsidy “cure” in this
case is far worse than the oil subsidy “disease.”

NATIONAL SECURITY
EXTERNALITIES
Among the most fashionable preoccupations
in foreign policy circles is “energy security.”
Although the precise meaning of energy security
is unclear, foreign policy elites have long been
concerned about U.S. reliance on foreign energy
(an exception is Gholtz and Press, 2007). Fear of
embargoes and supply disruptions affects how
Western nations deal with oil- and gas-producing
states, what sort of policies are pursued in the
Middle East, and even fundamental questions of
war and peace.
Proponents of ethanol subsidies argue that if
the price of oil included the cost of our “oil mission”
82

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

in the Middle East, the wars that the U.S. military
engages there to protect oil supplies, the costs
associated with our need to “kiss the ring” of
Middle Eastern oil producers, the economic damage
by terrorists from the flow of petrodollars into their
coffers, and the harm done to U.S. interests by oilrich states like Iran, Venezuela, and Russia, then oil
consumption would be far less than it is now. Alas,
it is believed that those national security externalities are not embedded in gasoline prices and, as a
result, gasoline consumption is heavily subsidized.
Ethanol consumption is thus suboptimal and
ethanol subsidies are an appropriate remedy.
Economists, however, are far less worried about
the national security costs of America’s reliance on
oil (foreign or otherwise) (Bohi and Toman, 1996)
and with good reason: Economists understand oil
markets far better than do foreign policy elites.
The alleged national security externalities associated with gasoline consumption are for the most
part a figment of an imagination unmoored from a
good understanding of market reality.6

Blood for Oil
Many believe that reliance on foreign oil
requires the United States to militarily defend
friendly exporting states and to ensure the safety
of oil supply facilities and shipping lanes. Those
marching under banners declaring “No Blood for
Oil” seem to believe that is the case, as do most
mainstream foreign policy analysts. Delucchi and
Murphy (2008) offer a rigorous attempt to quantify
the public dollars associated with the “oil mission.”
They suggest that if motor vehicles in the United
States did not consume Persian Gulf oil, the U.S.
Congress would have likely reduced military expenditures by $13.4 to $47 billion in 2004 (one of the
6

Greene and Leiby (2006) argue that oil-price volatility imposes significant economic losses and that ethanol is less subject to disruption
and thus offers economic advantages. Although empirical claims
appear to be untrue, U.S. data from 1960 to 2005 demonstrate that
corn harvests are far more variable than oil import volumes (Eaves
and Eaves, 2007). Even if that were not the case, price volatility does
not suggest a market failure. If ethanol were more commercially
attractive because its price were more stable, refiners would take
that into account when making decisions about optimal motor fuel
blends. The claim that oil price volatility imposes an externality on
third parties does not comport with the standard definition of market failure in that the same would hold true for all price changes
anywhere in the economy (economists refer to this phenomenon as a
“pecuniary externality”; Huntington, 2002).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

two years examined in the analysis). If U.S. motor
vehicles did not consume any oil at all, military
expenditures would have, oddly enough, gone
down by far less: by $5.8 to $25.4 billion in 2004.
The “best guess” of this analysis is that, if U.S.
gasoline consumers were forced to pay for the U.S.
oil mission, gasoline prices would increase by
$0.03 to $0.15 per gallon.
Simple economics, however, suggests that the
oil mission—however large it may be—is unnecessary, regardless of what Congress may think. Oil
producers will provide for their own security needs
as long as the cost of doing so results in greater
profits than equivalent investments could yield.
Because Middle Eastern governments typically
have little of value to trade except oil—oil revenues,
for instance, are 40 to 50 percent of Iranian government revenues and 70 to 80 percent of Saudi government revenues—they must secure and sell oil to
remain viable (EIA, 2006). Given that their economies are so heavily dependent on oil revenues,
Middle Eastern governments have even more incentive than do consuming states to worry about the
security of oil production facilities, ports, and
shipping lanes (West, 2005).
In short, whatever security our military presence provides (and many analysts think that our
presence actually reduces security; see Jervis, 2005)
would be provided by incumbent producers were
the United States to withdraw. That Saudi Arabia
and Kuwait paid for 55 percent of the cost of
Operation Desert Storm suggests that keeping the
Strait of Hormuz free of trouble is certainly within
their means.
The same argument applies to al Qaeda threats
to oil production facilities. Producer states have
such strong incentives to protect their oil infrastructure that additional Western assistance to do
the same is probably unnecessary. Although terrorists do indeed plot to disrupt oil production in
Saudi Arabia and elsewhere, there is no evidence
to suggest that producer-state security investments
are insufficient to protect their interests.
The U.S. oil mission is thus best considered a
taxpayer-financed gift to oil regimes (and, perhaps,
the Israeli government) that has little, if any, effect
on the security of oil production facilities or, correspondingly, the price of oil. One may support or

oppose such a gift, but our military expenditures
in the Middle East are not necessary to remedy a
market failure.

Foreign Policy Distortions
Many foreign policy analysts believe that U.S.
oil imports are dependent on friendly relationships
with oil-producing states. The fear is that unfriendly
regimes might not sell us oil—a fear that explains
why former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan
Greenspan supported the two Gulf Wars against
Iraq (Woodward, 2007). Others believe, however,
that maintaining good relations with oil producers
interferes with other foreign policy objectives—
such as the defense of Israel and the pursuit of
Islamic terrorists—and increases anti-American
sentiment in oil-producing states with unpopular
regimes (Scheuer, 2007 and 2008). The problem
with this argument, however, is that its fundamental premise is incorrect. Friendly relations with
producer states neither enhance access to imported
oil nor lower its price (Adelman, 1995).
Selective embargoes by producer nations on
some consuming nations are unenforceable unless
all other nations on Earth refuse to ship oil to the
embargoed state or a naval blockade is used to prevent oil shipments into the ports of the embargoed
state. That is because, once oil leaves the territory
of a producer, market agents—not agents of the
producer—dictate where the oil goes, and anyone
willing to pay the prevailing world crude oil price
can have all he or she wants. The 1973 Arab oil
embargo is a perfect case in point. U.S. crude oil
imports actually increased from 1.7 million barrels
per day (MBD) in 1971 to 2.2 MBD in 1972, 3.2 MBD
in 1973, and 3.5 MBD in 1974 (EIA, 2004). Instead
of buying from Arab members of the Organization
of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), the
United States bought from non-Arab oil producers.
The customers displaced by the United States
bought from Arab members of OPEC. Beyond the
modest increase in transportation costs that followed this game of musical chairs, the embargo
had no impact on the United States (Fried, 1988,
Parra, 2004, and Adelman, 1995). In short, all that
matters for the majority of consumers is how much
oil is produced for world markets, not from whom
the oil was initially purchased.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

83

Panel Discussion

Do oil-producing nations allow their feelings
toward oil-consuming nations to affect their production decisions? Historically, the answer has
been “no.” The record strongly indicates that oilproducing states, regardless of their feelings toward
the industrialized West, are rational economic
actors. After a detailed survey of the world oil
market since the rise of OPEC, oil economist M.A.
Adelman concluded, “We look in vain for an
example of a government that deliberately avoids
a higher income. The self-serving declaration of
an interested party is not evidence” (Adelman,
1995, p. 31). Philip Auerswald of George Mason
University agrees, stating “For the past quarter century, the oil output decisions of Islamic Iran have
been no more menacing or unpredictable than
Canada’s or Norway’s” (Auerswald, 2007, p. 22).
If energy producers are wealth maximizers,
what do we make of countries that are selling oil
and natural gas to others at below-market rates? For
instance, Russia sold oil to Cuba at below-market
prices during the Cold War; Russia has long sold
natural gas to Ukraine at below-market prices but
has ended its natural gas subsidy to Georgia as
relations have soured; and China sells oil to North
Korea at low rates and used this as leverage to
induce North Korea to bargain over its nuclear
weapons program.
Two conclusions seem reasonable. First, sellers
have leverage in natural gas markets that is not possible in oil markets because oil can be transported
easily, whereas natural gas is shipped through
pipelines. Buyers have few near-term alternatives
if natural gas sellers reduce shipments. As liquefied
natural gas gains market share, however, natural
gas markets will look increasingly like world crude
oil markets, and the ability of Russia or other
states to extract concessions from consumers will
dissipate.
Second, the Russia-Cuba and China–North
Korea cases involve poor countries receiving foreign
aid in the form of low-priced oil. We are unaware
of any wealthy Western countries receiving such
in-kind aid from oil-producing countries.
What if a radical new actor were to emerge on
the global stage? For example, if the House of Saud
were to fall and the new government consisted of
Islamic extremists friendly to Osama bin Laden,
84

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

the new regime might reduce production and
increase prices. But that scenario is by no means
certain given that Iran—despite all its anti-Western
rhetoric—has not reduced oil output.7
Regardless, the departure of Saudi Arabia from
world crude oil markets would probably have
about the same effect on domestic oil prices as the
departure of Iran from world crude oil markets in
1978. The Iranian revolution reduced oil production by 8.9 percent, whereas Saudi Arabia accounts
for about 13 percent of global oil production today.
Oil prices increased dramatically after the 1978
revolution, but those higher prices set in motion
market supply-and-demand responses that undermined the supply reduction and collapsed world
oil prices eight years later (Adelman, 1995). The
short-term macroeconomic impacts of such a supply disruption would actually be less today than
they were then, given the absence of price controls
on the U.S. economy and our reduced reliance on
oil as an input for each unit of gross domestic
product (Dhawan and Jeske, 2006, Walton, 2006,
and Fisher and Marshall, 2006).
So while it is possible that a radical oilproducing regime might play a game of chicken
with consuming countries, producing countries
are very dependent on oil revenue and have fewer
degrees of freedom to maneuver than consuming
countries. Catastrophic supply disruptions would
harm producers more than consumers, which is
why disruptions are extremely unlikely. The best
insurance against such a low-probability event is
to maintain a relatively free economy where wages
and prices are left unregulated by government.
That would do more to protect the West against an
extreme production disruption than anything else
in government’s policy arsenal.

Oil Profits for Terrorists
Does Western reliance on oil put money in the
pocket of Islamic terrorists? To some degree, yes.
Does that harm Western security? Probably not—
at least, probably not very much.
7

While it is true that oil production in Iran was about twice as high
under the Shah than it has been under the Islamic Republic, almost
all analysts agree that this reflects the damage to the oil infrastructure
during the 1980-88 war with Iraq, the “brain drain” that has occurred
in response to the revolution, and poor state management of Iranian
oil assets—not the intentional result of state policy.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

Before we go on, it is worth noting that only
15.5 percent of the oil in the world market is produced from nation-states accused of funding terrorism (Lundberg Survey, 2006). Hence, the vast
majority of the dollars we spend on gasoline do
not end up on this purported economic conveyer
belt to terrorist bank accounts.
Regardless, terrorism is a relatively low-cost
endeavor and oil revenues are unnecessary for terrorist activity. That a few hundred thousand dollars
paid for the 9/11 attacks suggests that the limiting
factors for terrorism are expertise and manpower,
not money.
This observation is strengthened by the fact
that there is no correlation between oil profits and
Islamic terrorism. In Taylor and Van Doren (2007),
we estimated two regressions using annual data
from 1983 to 2005: the first between fatalities
resulting from Islamic terrorist attacks and Saudi
oil prices and the second between the number of
Islamic terrorist incidents and Saudi oil prices. In
neither regression was the estimated coefficient
on oil prices at all close to being significantly different from zero.8
During the 1990s, inflation-adjusted oil prices
and profits were low. But the 1990s also witnessed
the worldwide spread of Wahhabi fundamentalism,
the buildup of Hezbollah, and the coming of age
of al Qaeda. Note too that al Qaeda terrorists in
the 1990s relied on help from state sponsors such
as Sudan and Afghanistan—nations that are not
particularly known for their oil wealth or robust
economies.
Producer states do use oil revenues to fund ideological extremism. Saudi financing of madrassas
and Iranian financing of Hezbollah are good examples. But given the importance of those undertakings to the Saudi and Iranian governments, it is
unlikely that they would cease and desist these
activities simply because oil profits were down.
They certainly were not deterred by meager oil
profits in the 1990s.9
The futility of reducing oil consumption as a
means of improving national security and energy

independence is illustrated by the fact that states
accused of funding terrorism earned $290 billion
from oil sales in 2006 (Lundberg Survey, 2006).
Even if that sum were cut by 90 percent, that would
still leave $29 billion at their disposal—more than
enough to fund terrorism given the minimal financial needs of terrorists.

8

9

Unit root tests suggested that fatalities and Saudi oil prices had unit
roots but terrorist incidents did not, so the former were first differenced before the regressions. Even after first differencing, autocorrelation existed, so autoregressive terms were added to each regression,
which further weakened the insignificant relationships.

Rents to Bad Actors
When oil prices are high, so too are oil profits
for inframarginal (low-cost) producers. Even if
those profits do not find their way to international
terrorists, they prop up many regimes we find distasteful. Oil producers in the Second and Third
worlds often use their robust flow of petrodollars
to squelch human rights at home and to menace
neighbors abroad. Many foreign policy elites argue
that oil consumption thus harms our national
security by strengthening these bad international
actors (Lugar and Woolsey, 1999, and Council on
Foreign Relations, 2006).
It is unclear to what extent oil profits are associated with human rights abuses or militaristic
activity. Examples abound: Relatively long-lived
regimes with terrible human rights records—such
as North Korea—have no oil revenues to speak of,
and this is the case even within the same socioeconomic region. Denuding Iran and Libya of oil
revenues might produce a government that looks
a lot like Syria, and denuding Venezuela of oil
revenues might produce a government that looks
a lot like Cuba. After all, most of the “bad acting”
petrostates that foreign policy elites worry about
yielded unsavory regimes even when oil revenues
were a small fraction of what they are today.
The claim that oil revenues increase the threat
posed by such regimes to their neighbors seems
reasonable enough, but again, the extent to which
this is true is unclear. Pakistan is a relatively poor
country with few oil revenues but it has still managed to build a nuclear arsenal and is constantly
on the precipice of war with India. Impoverished,
oil-poor Egypt and Syria have at various times been
Although little is known about funding trends associated with Iranian
support for Hezbollah, the Iranian government probably spends no
more than $25 to $50 million on Hezbollah a year (Cordesman, 2006).
Less is known about Saudi contributions to Islamic extremism
(Prados and Blanchard, 2004).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

85

Panel Discussion

the most aggressive anti-Israeli states in the Middle
East. Russia launched its war with Chechnya before
oil revenues engorged its treasury.
While I have little doubt that—all other things
being equal—a rich bad actor is more dangerous
than a poor bad actor, the marginal impact of oil
revenues on “bad acting” might well be rather small.
That unsavory petrostates have been fully capable
of holding on to power, oppressing their people,
and menacing their neighbors during a decade
associated with the lowest inflation-adjusted oil
prices in history (the 1990s) suggests that nothing
short of rendering oil nearly valueless will have
any real effect on regime behavior.
For the sake of argument, however, let us
assume that there is some incremental benefit
associated with reducing oil revenues to bad-acting
oil producers. Unfortunately, we have only very
blunt and imperfect instruments at hand to achieve
that end. Policies that might reduce oil consumption would reduce oil demand—and thus, reduce
revenues—for all oil producers, regardless of
whether they are bad actors. Producers in the North
Sea, Canada, Mexico, and the United States (which
collectively supplied 20.1 million barrels of oil per
day in 2006, or 24 percent of the world’s crude oil
needs that year) would be harmed just as producers
in Venezuela, Iran, Russia, and Libya (which collectively supplied 20.3 million barrels per day in
2006) (EIA, 2007).
Given bad acting aplenty in 1998 with the
lowest real oil prices in world history, it is unlikely
that even the most ambitious policies to reduce
oil consumption would have much effect on bad
acting. Accordingly, there is good reason to doubt
that the foreign policy benefits that might accrue
from anti-oil policies would outweigh the very real
costs that such policies would impose on both consumers and innocent producers. There are certainly
better remedies available to curtail bad behavior
abroad.

The Ethanol Remedy
If significant national security externalities did
exist and were, as a result, significantly affecting
gasoline prices, the most direct and efficient remedy
would be a tax on oil imports. That would get gasoline prices “right” and lead to optimal motor fuel
86

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

consumption patterns. Countervailing ethanol subsidies are an extremely inefficient means of remedying the problem given the deadweight losses
and inefficiencies associated with most forms of
subsidy. They also substitute prospective market
judgments regarding appropriate motor fuel consumption with political judgments that are unlikely
to prove correct.
Regardless, ethanol production cannot displace
significant amounts of gasoline consumption
(Akinci et al., 2008). Even if the entire U.S. corn
harvest were dedicated to ethanol production, only
3.5 percent of current gasoline consumption would
be displaced (Eaves and Eaves, 2007). All available
cropland in the United States would have to be
dedicated to corn production if all U.S. vehicles
were powered by fuel composed of E85 ethanol.
By 2036, all rangeland and pastureland would have
to be added to that total to maintain adequate production. By 2048, all land outside of urban centers
would be required for corn production (Dias de
Oliveira, Vaughan, and Rykiel, 2005). Thus, no
matter one’s opinions about the dangers of oil
dependence (foreign or otherwise), corn ethanol
cannot displace enough oil to matter.

ENVIRONMENTAL EXTERNALITIES
Many believe that gasoline consumers are
being subsidized because they are not required to
compensate third parties for the air pollution
associated with gasoline consumption. If those
environmental externalities were “internalized”
via regulation or taxes, gasoline prices would be
far higher, gasoline consumption would be consequently lower, and ethanol production would be
far greater. Ethanol subsidies are defended as the
second-best means of improving market efficiency.
There are three difficulties with this argument.
First, it is very unclear how large the externalities
are in monetary terms, making it impossible for
analysts to know whether interventions to correct
those externalities are actually improving or worsening market efficiency. The best available evidence,
however, suggests that the air emissions externalities are probably so low that internalizing them
via the first-best policy avenue—a pollution tax—
would not affect gasoline prices enough to sig-

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

nificantly affect the motor fuels market. Second,
ethanol’s environmental advantages relative to
gasoline are greatly overstated. The negative environmental externalities associated with ethanol may
well be even greater than those associated with
gasoline.10 Even if they are not, ethanol’s environmental advantages are almost certainly not large
enough (in monetarized terms) to significantly
alter the fuel mix in motor fuels markets. Third,
ethanol subsidies are an extremely inefficient means
of addressing the environmental externalities of
gasoline; far better means of addressing this market
failure exist.

Conventional Air Pollutants
It is unclear to what extent there are uninternalized externalities associated with conventional
air pollutants from gasoline. A recent review of the
peer-reviewed literature suggests that monetized
damages from the same might range from $0.016
to $0.184 per mile, which translates into $0.36 to
$4.20 per gallon (Parry, Walls, and Harrington,
2006). A frequently cited “best guess” regarding the
cost of the conventional air emissions generated
by gasoline consumption is $0.16 per gallon (Parry
and Small, 2005).
The biggest problem with the above exercises—
beyond the uncertainty associated with the human
health impacts of exposure to small doses of potentially dangerous air contaminants—is that these
studies do not consider the extent to which existing
regulation imposes costs on gasoline consumption
and the extent to which those costs function as a
tax. If, for instance, the conventional air emissions
externality were $0.16 per gallon but regulatory policy reduced emissions to where they would have
been had a $0.16 per gallon tax been imposed in a
world without regulation, then there would be no
10

Although I only examine conventional air and greenhouse gas
emissions in this paper—the main environmental advantages that
subsidy proponents allege for ethanol—ethanol has a number of
other environmental disadvantages relative to gasoline. The main
issues include groundwater contamination (Niven, 2005), water
resource use and surface water pollution (National Research Council,
2008; Donner and Kucharik, 2008; and Nassauer, Santelmann, and
Scavia, 2007), soil erosion (Patzek, 2004), and habitat destruction
(Nassauer, Santelmann, and Scavia, 2007, and Dias de Oliveira,
Vaughan, and Rykiel, 2005). Whatever advantages ethanol may have
with regard to air emissions (which I believe to be, at best, nonexistent) must outweigh the environmental harms it creates.

externality: The consumer would, in a sense, be
paying for the pollution costs associated with gasoline consumption (albeit indirectly). Accordingly,
the above calculations provide limited guidance
to policymakers seeking to promote optimal gasoline prices (Nye, 2008).
Regardless, ethanol is a poor remedy for whatever externalities may exist in this arena. A review
of the academic literature finds that, when evaporative emissions are taken into account, ethanol in
fuel blends sold on the market today
• increases emissions of total hydrocarbons,
nitrogen oxides, nonmethane organic compounds, and air toxics (particularly acetaldehyde, formaldehyde, ethylene, and methanol)
relative to conventional gasoline; but
• decreases emissions of carbon monoxide
(Niven, 2005; other studies broadly consistent with Niven’s findings include
von Blottnitz and Curran, 2007, and U.S.
Environmental Protection Agency [EPA],
2007).
We pause here to note that carbon monoxide
emissions are only a very modest problem in the
United States today. Because few areas of the United
States violate federal air quality standards for carbon monoxide, ethanol provides little benefit on
that front. The other pollutants at issue, however,
worsen urban smog and the concentration of dangerous air toxics—far more serious human health
matters.
Ethanol proponents often argue that stronger
ethanol blends—like E85—are cleaner. Those contentions are not consistent with the reviews of the
literature cited above. Nor are they consistent with
a recent study concluding that universal use of E85
would increase ozone-related mortality, hospitalization, and asthma by 9 percent in Los Angeles
and 4 percent in the United States as a whole relative to a world in which the auto fleet were powered entirely by conventional gasoline (Jacobsen,
2007).

Air Toxics
The above studies explicitly consider toxic air
emissions in their analyses, but a recent paper for

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

87

Panel Discussion

the Energy Future Coalition (Gray and Varcoe, 2005)
argues that the environmental costs of gasolinerelated air toxic emissions total approximately
$250 billion per year. Although their paper has
received little attention in academic circles, it has
received modest attention in policy circles, so a
brief discussion is in order.
Gray and Varcoe (2005) argue that the direct
harms from the various toxic emissions from aromatics in gasoline total about $64 billion a year. But
those aromatics also contribute to the formation of
particulate matter (PM) in the atmosphere, and the
harms from PM that can be traced back to aromatic
gasoline emissions are said to equal at least $200
billion a year. Gray and Varcoe round the total sum
to $250 billion a year (which was equal to about
$1.78 a gallon in 2005) and argue that “leveling
the playing field” would justify an equivalent subsidy to the ethanol industry.
The $64 billion estimate for the benefits associated with reducing aromatic emissions, however,
is derived from the costs associated with reducing
toxic air emissions in the industrial sector. Yet there
is little reason to believe that the costs of emission
controls equal the benefits from the same. Gray and
Varcoe (2005) justify this leap of faith by citing EPA
contentions that the benefits from the regulation
of industrial air toxic emissions have in the past
exceeded the costs of doing so. But even if the EPA
is correct, there is no reason to assume that the cost
of reducing toxic air emissions from point sources
x years ago has relation to the costs (or benefits) of
reducing toxic air emissions from automotive tailpipes today.
Gray and Varcoe’s (2005) estimate for the costs
associated with PM formation that can be traced
back to gasoline aromatics likewise emerges from
a problematic set of assumptions. They posit that
40 percent of all PM 2.5 is carbon based and then
assume that half of this mass (when adjusted for
population exposures) can be attributed to gasoline
emissions.11 The latter claim appears to be incorrect; their own footnote suggests that only 4 to 33
percent of PM 2.5 can be traced back to tailpipe
emissions.
11

PM 2.5 means particles less than 2.5 micrometers in aerodynamic
diameter.

88

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

Using the benefit estimates associated with
ambient PM concentration reductions from the
recently established off-road diesel fuel regulations,
Gray and Varcoe (2005) arrive at about $200 billion
in benefits. It is unclear, however, how they trace
those costs to aromatic tailpipe emissions from the
total universe of motor vehicle tailpipe emissions.
Gray and Varcoe (2005), however, well understand the limitations of their analysis: “We emphasize that these are, necessarily, speculative estimates,
based on various heuristic assumptions that cannot
easily be proven (or refuted, given basic uncertainties)” (p. 52). Normally, claims that cannot be
proven or disproven are called “opinions” or,
alternatively, “religious beliefs.” Let us posit that
we should not use either as the basis for public
policy.
If Gray and Varcoe (2005) were familiar with the
literature on tailpipe emissions, they would not
need such analytic contortions. A review of the
literature finds that the environmental costs associated with toxic air emissions from gasoline is likely
$0.087 to $1.62 billion annually in 1991 dollars, a
tiny fraction of the $64 billion estimate laboriously
forwarded by Gray and Varcoe (McCubbin and
Delucchi, 1996). While it is unclear to what extent
harm from PM 2.5 can be traced back to gasoline
aromatics, the published literature suggests that the
environmental costs associated with all particulate
emissions from motor vehicle tailpipes (not just the
aromatics targeted by Gray and Varcoe) is $16.7 to
$266.4 billion. The authors who reviewed that literature, however, note that “We are uneasy with
this result, even as an upper-bound” (McCubbin
and Delucchi, 1996, p. 212) because it is heavily
weighted by one study in the literature (Pope et al.,
2002) and that study is both anomalous and methodologically problematic (Schwartz, 2006). Likewise,
a recent study (Hill et al., 2009) examines the emissions of greenhouse gases (GHGs) and PM 2.5 from
gasoline and corn ethanol. It finds that, for each
billion gallons of ethanol-equivalent fuel, gasoline
emissions cost $469 million and corn ethanol emissions $472 to $952 million.
There is little reason to accept the $250 billion
externality estimate by Gray and Varcoe (2005)
and to reject the more careful work in the peerreviewed literature cited above. Even were we to

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

do so, however, it is worth remembering that the
toxic air emissions associated with ethanol are even
greater than the toxic air emissions associated with
conventional gasoline. Hence, even if Gray and
Varcoe were correct, it does not justify countervailing subsidies for ethanol.

Greenhouse Gas Emissions
It is difficult to know for certain how ethanol
compares with gasoline with regard to GHG emissions because the data required to perform a satisfactory energy life-cycle analysis simply do not
exist. Four fundamental problems exist (Delucchi,
2004 and 2006).
First, limited field and facility data are available. Aggregated data are thus required to fill in
the holes, and many data points are based on estimates, not observations. Unfortunately, those estimates are frequently only loosely grounded in
reality (Liska et al., 2009).
Second, some important disagreements about
methodology cannot be easily resolved. For
instance, how far back in the production chain
should we go in the course of tallying energy inputs? What is the best way to disentangle the energy
inputs and GHG outputs associated with ethanol
production from the energy inputs and GHG outputs associated with other coproducts (primarily
distillers’ grains for livestock feed) associated with
ethanol production?
Third—and most important—dynamic variables
can significantly affect the life-cycle analysis but
are generally completely ignored in the literature
because they are difficult to model properly. For
instance, how and to what extent will the contemplated policy change prices for millions of goods
and services (both directly and indirectly), and
how will those price changes affect consumption
patterns and, thus, GHG emissions?12 Answering
such complex questions requires a rather sophisticated global general equilibrium model, but none
have been produced or used in the life-cycle analyses of ethanol that have appeared in the literature.
12

“Whatever the exact magnitude of these price effects, they are potentially important enough that they ought to be taken seriously in an
evaluation of the impact of transportation policies on climate. There
is no way to escape this conclusion. We cannot dismiss the effects
because they occur outside of the U.S., or outside of the transportation

Fourth, even if done well, the life-cycle models
produce findings that are less relevant to policymaking than advertised. For example, what exact
policy is being suggested by the life-cycle analysis
and is that policy realistic? How does the execution
of that policy impact the dynamic economic factors
mentioned above? What are the opportunity costs
of the contemplated policy? What are emissions at
the margin in response to policy-induced change?
Nonetheless, dozens of studies and several
computer models exist to partially inform analysis
(for instance, Liska et al., 2009; Adler, Del Grosso,
and Parton, 2007; Wang, Wu, and Hong, 2007;
Groode and Heywood, 2007; Hill et al., 2006; Farrell
et al., 2006; Nielsen and Wenzel, 2005; and Patzek,
2004).13 The best is a recent study from researchers
at the University of Nebraska (Liska et al., 2009).
That analysis used the most recent data available
on individual facility operations and emissions,
observed corn yields, nitrogen fertilizer emissions
profiles, and coproduct use; all of which prove
important because of improved energy efficiencies
associated with ethanol production over the past
several years. The authors found that the total lifecycle GHG emissions from the most common type
of ethanol processing facility in operation today
are 48 to 59 percent lower than gasoline, one of the
highest savings reported in the literature. Even
without subtracting the GHG emissions associated
sector, because in an analysis of global warming, we care about all
emissions, everywhere. We cannot dismiss price effects on the
grounds that a policy will not really affect price, because in principle
even the smallest change has a nonzero probability of leading to a
nonzero effect on price. (In any event, if the price effects are really
so small, then the policy must be so unimportant or ineffective as to
have no affect on climate worth worrying about anyway.) And we
certainly cannot argue that all such price effects are likely to be substantially ‘similar’ for all policies, and hence of no importance in
comparison of alternatives, because this clearly is not the case”
(Delucchi, 2004, p. 10).
13

I am interested only in those studies that attempt to quantify GHG
emissions, not in those studies exclusively concerned with the net
energy balance of ethanol. The latter issue is theoretically interesting
but it asks a question that is not particularly relevant for policy analysis. Even if ethanol has a negative energy balance (more energy inputs
were required to produce ethanol than is yielded by ethanol on
combustion), if the energy inputs were relatively abundant but the
energy displaced by ethanol were relatively scarce, ethanol could
have a net negative energy balance but still prove profitable and
efficient. Likewise, if the energy inputs have modest GHG emissions
but the energy being displaced by ethanol had significantly larger
GHG emissions, a negative energy balance might still translate into
a net reduction of GHG emissions.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

89

Panel Discussion

with ethanol coproducts (which accounted for 19
to 38 percent of total system emissions), ethanol
would still present GHG advantages relative to
gasoline.
Although the study by Liska et al. (2009)
appears to offer the best current analysis on this
question, many problems remain, rendering policy
analysis problematic. First, the study examines only
a subset of corn production operations and ethanol
processing facilities: dry-mill ethanol processors
fired by natural gas in six Corn Belt states. Together,
those facilities accounted for 23 percent of U.S.
ethanol production in 2006. This approach makes
the study stronger because the authors are not
forced to rely as heavily on estimates and aggregated
analysis, but the downside is that the study ignores
a large number of older, less-efficient ethanol processing facilities and thus cannot be used to assess
the GHG balance of the ethanol industry as a whole.
While the findings may well point to where the
industry will be in the future as older, less-efficient
facilities lose market share and are upgraded or
retired (Groode and Heywood, 2007), the bankruptcies that are shuttering many newer facilities at
present caution against certainty on this point.
Second, estimates regarding emissions are still
relied on to some degree, and one of those estimates
in particular—the estimate pertaining to the release
of nitrous oxide (N2O) from fertilizer use in corn
production—is problematic. Although the study
comports with convention in that it relies on emission estimates offered by the Intergovernmental
Panel on Climate Change (IPCC, 2006), a recent
study (Crutzen et al., 2007) finds that the IPCC estimates pertaining to N2O release from fertilizer does
not comport with the observed data. Crutzen et al.
(2007) find that N2O emissions from fertilizers used
in biofuel production are three to five times greater
than assumed by the IPCC and that, if we use those
higher emissions in the ethanol life-cycle models
(as Crutzin et al. did using the openly accessible
EBAMM model constructed by Farrell et al., 2006),
“the outcome is that the production of commonly
used biofuels, such as biodiesel from rapeseed and
bioethanol from corn (maize), can contribute as
much or more to global warming by N2O emissions
than cooling by fossil fuel savings” (p. 389). Given
that the lead author of the study—Paul Crutzen—
90

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

is a Nobel laureate chemist who has specialized in
fields related to atmospheric science, his findings
cannot be lightly dismissed.
Third, Liska et al. (2009) acknowledge the
importance of the impact of ethanol production on
crop prices and, thus, on global land-use patterns,
but they do not account for the GHG emissions
associated with those changes. Those emissions
are substantial, and no life-cycle analysis of ethanol
can credibly ignore them.
A worldwide agricultural model constructed by
Searchinger et al. (2008) finds that the increases in
crop prices that follow the increased demand for
ethanol will induce a global change in the pattern of
land use. Those land-use changes produce a surge
in GHG emissions that is dissipated only by conventional life-cycle emissions savings many decades
hence. Although the study modeled ethanol production increases that were beyond those mandated in
existing law, “the emissions from land-use change
per unit of ethanol would be similar regardless of
the ethanol increase analyzed” (p. 1239).
While critics of Searchinger et al. (2008) rightly
point out that (i) the agricultural model employed
in the study was crude, (ii) much is unknown about
the factors that influence global land-use decisions,
(iii) improved yields are reducing the amount of
land necessary to meet global crop demands, and
(iv) any land additions to crop production do not
need to come from forests or other robust carbon
sequestration sinks (Renewable Fuels Association,
2008), none of those observations is sufficient to
reject the basic insight forwarded in Searchinger
et al. (2008). If ethanol demand increases corn and
other crop prices beyond where they otherwise
would have been, profit incentives will induce
investors to increase crop production beyond where
production would otherwise have been. If that
increased production comes in part from land-use
changes relative to the baseline, then significant
volumes of GHG will likely be released and those
emissions will threaten to swamp the GHG savings
found elsewhere in the life-cycle analysis. Even if
the upward pressure on crop prices as a consequence of ethanol consumption is more than offset by downward price pressures following from
other factors, crop acreage retirement will not be
as large as might otherwise have been the case

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

and terrestrial sequestration will be lower as a
consequence. Every link in that chain of logic is
unassailable.
Changing global land use is but one of the
many impacts that ethanol might have on hundreds
of industrial sectors worldwide. The work of
Searchinger et al. (2008) is ultimately unsatisfying
because it is only a crude and partial consideration
of those impacts, many of which might indirectly
affect global land-use patterns. For instance, if
ethanol consumption reduces the demand for—
and thus the price of—crude oil in global markets,
how much of those “booked” reductions in oil
consumption will be offset by increased demand
induced elsewhere by the lower global crude oil
prices that follow (known as a “rebound effect” in
economics)? How might that rebound effect influence all sorts of GHG emissions vectors? None of
these types of questions are asked in ethanol GHG
life-cycle analyses, but they are clearly crucial to
the analysis.
To summarize, a narrow, conventional consideration of the GHG emissions associated with ethanol
suggests that ethanol reduces climate change harms
relative to gasoline. If the IPCC has underestimated
N2O emissions from fertilizer—as appears to be
the case—then ethanol probably is at best a “wash”
with regard to GHG emissions. Even if that is not
the case, consideration of secondary and tertiary
emissions impacts strongly suggests that most, if
not all, advertised GHG gains are lost in the changes
in land-use patterns that follow increases in ethanol
production relative to the baseline. Other changes
in anthropogenic emissions—positive and negative—would almost certainly follow as well, but
existing models do not bother to search for them
and thus we do not know enough to say much
beyond this with confidence.

First versus Second-Best Remedies
If there are in fact uninternalized environmental
externalities associated with gasoline consumption,
the most direct and efficient remedy is to impose
a tax on emissions (or a cap-and-trade program
that functions like a tax) to correct prices accordingly. Countervailing ethanol subsidies are a much
less-efficient remedy because they create deadweight losses, do not correct gasoline prices or

ethanol prices for environmental externalities, and
impose a market share for ethanol that might not
have arisen in equilibrium.
One might argue that emissions taxes on conventional pollutants in motor fuel markets are
impractical and/or unlikely and that ethanol is a
necessary second-best alternative. But even if so,
tighter regulation of motor fuel emissions is almost
certainly more efficient than ethanol subsidies if
government intervention is warranted. This is particularly true given that ethanol has substantial air
emissions of its own. Nondiscriminatory emission
regulations that apply regardless of fuel source are
a far more defensible intervention.
Price internalization exercises to address GHG
emissions, however, are not only conceivable, they
are probable in the near term given the current political makeup of Washington and voter sentiment.
Once a federal cap-and-trade program is in place,
ethanol proponents will lose the argument that
gasoline prices are suboptimal because they do not
consider the cost of GHG emissions. Of course, one
might always argue that the permit prices yielded
from such a regime are too low to adequately reflect
the damages, but a recent “best guess” about those
damages based on the literature suggests that the
uninternalized GHG externalities associated with
gasoline amount to only about $0.05 per gallon
(Parry and Small, 2005).
If the displacement of gasoline with ethanol is
in fact among the most cost-effective means of
reducing GHG emissions, ethanol producers should
be able to prove that fact in a carbon-constrained,
cap-and-trade market without government subsidy.
But even if we posit the lowest-bound estimate for
total ethanol subsidies and divide that figure by
the GHG savings reported in Wang, Wu, and Hong
(2007; a 19 percent reduction of total life-cycle GHG
emissions relative to gasoline), we find that $300
of subsidy is necessary to displace a metric ton of
GHG emissions from gasoline. “Based on historical
prices for carbon offsets, this same investment could
have purchased 90-120 times as much displacement on the CCX [Chicago Climate Exchange], the
most appropriate benchmark for the U.S. carbon
market. Even on the more expensive ECX [European
Climate Exchange], the subsidies could have purchased 11 metric tonnes of offsets” (Koplow, 2007,

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

91

Panel Discussion

p. 35). If we instead use the high end of the GHG
savings reported in Liska et al. (2009) those figures
could be cut by two-thirds—still yielding costs that
could not be sustained if market actors, rather than
political actors, were deciding how best to respond
to a carbon-constrained world.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF
SUBSIDY
Although there has long been a debate about
the merits of ethanol subsidies, most parties in the
discussion accepted without question the idea
that subsidizing ethanol reduces oil consumption.
How much, of course, was open to debate. Yet a
rigorous examination of the existing subsidies in
place by Cornell economists Harry de Gorter and
David Just (2007a) finds that one of those subsidies—the blenders’ tax credit—actually subsidizes
gasoline consumption within the context of the
current regulatory regime.
The conclusion is counterintuitive but the
analysis is sound. The explanation is as follows. By
itself, the blenders’ tax credit ensures that ethanol
is often cheaper than gasoline from the refiners’
perspective. Refiners will thus compete to secure
that ethanol, which results in the price of ethanol
being “bid up” until it is above the market price
of gasoline by at least $0.51 per gallon (the size of
the tax credit). In a world with the blenders’ tax
credit at the 2006 level, retail fuel prices are lower
by 1.9 percent ($2.32 per gallon rather than $2.36
per gallon). Ethanol production increases from
653 million gallons to 6.67 billion gallons while
gasoline production declines from 141.2 billion
gallons to 135.7 billion gallons. The credit serves
as an ethanol consumption subsidy with most of
the benefits going to ethanol producers and the
remainder to motorists.
By itself, the Renewable Fuel Standard (which
mandates specified levels of ethanol consumption)
produces motor fuel costs that are a weighted average of the cost of ethanol and the cost of gasoline.
In a world with the consumption mandate at the
2006 level, retail fuel prices are 0.48 percent lower
($2.31 per gallon rather than $2.32 per gallon).
Ethanol production increases from 6.67 billion
92

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

gallons (assuming a nonbinding mandate in the
form of the ban on methyl tertiary-butyl ether as a
fuel additive) to 10 billion gallons while gasoline
production falls from 135.7 billion gallons to 132.5
billion gallons. The mandate, like the credit, serves
as an ethanol production subsidy with almost all
of the benefits captured by ethanol producers.
When a tax credit is added to a consumption
mandate, however, there is no incentive for refiners
to bid up the price of ethanol; the mandated demand
for ethanol ensures that ethanol (even with the tax
credit) is more costly than gasoline. Because competition in the refining sector is relatively intense,
refiners cannot capture the full benefit of the tax
credit. Instead, it is passed on to consumers. Using
the 2006 blenders’ tax credit, this produced retail
fuel prices 1.42 percent lower than they would have
been without the tax credit but with the mandate:
$2.31 per gallon rather than $2.34 per gallon.
Ethanol production increases a wee bit—from 9.99
billion gallons to 10 billion gallons—but gasoline
production increases even more—from 132.1 billion gallons to 132.5 billion gallons. The combined
policies are, in effect, a direct gasoline consumption subsidy with all of the benefits captured by
motorists.
Such analyses highlight the difficulty of accepting claims about the impact of ethanol production
on foreign oil imports or GHG emissions without
careful consideration of the indirect impact that
subsidies have on the market. Unfortunately, this
is an exercise rarely performed in the literature pertaining to the advertised benefits of ethanol (and,
implicitly, government preferences for the same).

CONCLUSION
Why should taxpayers subsidize ethanol? The
most commonly offered rationales—that ethanol
reduces harm caused by our reliance on foreign
oil and a host of air pollution problems—do not
hold up to scrutiny. Foreign oil dependence is not
a substantial foreign policy or economic problem,
and ethanol offers little remedy for any problems
that might exist. Environmental gains are likewise
unclear. The balance of the evidence suggests that
ethanol worsens conventional air pollution and

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

offers no net reductions in GHG emissions. In fact,
there is good reason to believe that GHG emissions
might well go up as we displace gasoline in favor
of ethanol.
Even if we were to accept the national security
and environmental benefits claimed most frequently for ethanol in the literature, in 2012 ethanol
subsidies would still cost $3 billion more than the
monetized benefits delivered (Hahn, 2008).
Other justifications for subsidy have even less
merit. There is little evidence to suggest that “Big
Oil” is strangling ethanol for competitive advantage
or that ethanol on balance reduces motor fuel prices
by any consequential amount. Ethanol subsidies
may in some periods reduce net federal subsidies
to corn producers, but the deadweight losses associated with ethanol subsidies more than offset this
savings to the taxpayer. Finally, they do not “level
the playing field.” In fact, they distort the playing
field and produce inaccurate price signals which,
in turn, lead to less economic efficiency and, by
force, less overall wealth creation.
Whatever problems exist in motor fuel markets
are better remedied by direct interventions to
address identified problems. Ethanol subsidies are
extremely poor remedies for those alleged problems.

REFERENCES
Adelman, M.A. The Genie Out of the Bottle: World Oil
Since 1970. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1995.
Adler, Paul R.; Del Grosso, Stephen J. and Parton,
William J. “Life-Cycle Assessment of Net GreenhouseGas Flux for Bioenergy Cropping Systems.” Ecological
Applications, April 2007, 17(3), pp. 675-91.
Akinci, Berk; Kassebaum, Paul G.; Fitch, Jonathan V.
and Thompson, Robert W. “The Role of Biofuels in
Satisfying U.S. Transportation Fuel Demands.”
Energy Policy, September 2008, 36(9), pp. 3485-91.
Auerswald, Philip. “The Irrelevance of the Middle East.”
American Interest, May/June 2007, 2(5), p. 22.
Baumol, William J. “Contestable Markets: An Uprising
in the Theory of Industrial Structure.” American
Economic Review, 1982, 72(1), pp. 1-15.

Baumol, William J. and Panzer, John C. Contestable
Markets and the Theory of Industrial Structure. New
York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1982.
Bohi, Douglas R. and Toman, Michael A. Economics of
Energy Security. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Academic
Publishers, 1996.
Borenstein, Severin. “The Evolution of U.S. Airline
Competition.” Journal of Economic Perspectives,
Spring 1992, 6(2), pp. 45-73.
Chouinard, Haley H. and Perloff, Jeffrey M. “Gasoline
Price Differences: Taxes, Pollution Regulations,
Mergers, Market Power, and Market Conditions.”
B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 2007,
7(1), pp. 1-26.
Cooper, Mark. “Over a Barrel: Why Aren’t Oil
Companies Using Ethanol to Lower Gasoline Prices?”
Consumer Federation of America, May 2005;
www.ethanolrfa.org/objects/documents/113/
consumerstudy.pdf (accessed January 29, 2009).
Cooper, Mark. “Big Oil vs. Ethanol: The Consumer
Stake in Expanding the Production of Liquid Fuels.”
Consumer Federation of America, July 2007;
www.consumerfed.org/pdfs/Ethanol.pdf (accessed
January 29, 2009).
Cordesman, Anthony H. “Iran’s Support of the
Hezbollah in Lebanon.” Center for Strategic and
International Studies, July 15, 2006.
Council on Foreign Relations. National Security
Consequences of U.S. Oil Dependency. Washington,
DC: Council on Foreign Relations Press, October 2006.
Cowen, Tyler, ed. The Theory of Market Failure: A
Critical Examination. Fairfax, VA: George Mason
University Press, 1988.
Cowen, Tyler and Crampton, Eric, eds. Market Failure
or Success: The New Debate. Cheltenham and
Northampton, UK: Edgar Elgar, 2003.
Crutzen, P.J.; Mosier, A.R.; Smith, K.A. and
Winiwarter, W. “N2O Release from Agro-Biofuel
Production Negates Global Warming Reduction by
Replacing Fossil Fuels.” Atmospheric Chemistry and
Physics Discussions, 2007, 7, pp. 11191-205.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

93

Panel Discussion

de Gorter, Harry and Just, David R. “The Law of
Unintended Consequences: How the U.S. Biofuel Tax
Credit with a Mandate Subsidizes Oil Consumption
and Has No Impact on Ethanol Consumption.”
Working Paper 2007-20, Cornell University,
September 2007a (updated February 2008).
de Gorter, Harry and Just, David R. “The Welfare
Economics of an Excise-Tax Exemption for Biofuels
and the Interaction Effects with Farm Subsidies.”
Working Paper 2007-13, Cornell University, September
2007b (updated January 2008); http://aem.cornell.edu/
research/researchpdf/wp0713.pdf.
Delucchi, Mark A. “Conceptual and Methodological
Issues in Lifecycle Analyses of Transportation Fuels.”
Paper prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection
Agency Office of Transportation and Air Quality,
UCD-ITS-RR-04-45, October 2004.
Delucchi, Mark A. “Lifecycle Analyses of Biofuels.”
Draft Report, Institute for Transportation Studies,
University of California, Davis, UCD-ITS-RR-06-08,
2006.
Delucchi, Mark A. and Murphy, James J. “U.S. Military
Expenditures to Protect the Use of Persian Gulf Oil
for Motor Vehicles.” Energy Policy, June 2008, 36(6),
pp. 2253-64.
Dhawan, Rajeev and Jeske, Karsten. “How Resilient Is
the Modern Economy to Energy Price Shocks?”
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review,
Third Quarter 2006, 91(3) pp. 21-32.
Dias de Oliveira; Marcelo E.; Vaughan; Burton E. and
Rykiel, Edward J. “Ethanol as Fuel: Energy, Carbon
Dioxide Balances, and Ecological Footprint.”
BioScience, July 2005, 55(7), pp. 593-602.
Donner, Simon D. and Kucharik, Christopher J. “CornBased Ethanol Production Compromises Goal of
Reducing Nitrogen Export by the Mississippi River.”
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences,
March 18, 2008, 105(11), pp. 4513-18.
Du, Xiaodong and Hayes, Dermot J. “The Impact of
Ethanol Production on U.S. and Regional Gasoline
Prices and on the Profitability of the U.S. Oil Refinery
Industry.” Working Paper 08-WP 467, Center for

94

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State
University, April 2008.
Du, Xiaodong; Hayes, Dermot J. and Baker, Mindy.
“A Welfare Analysis of the U.S. Ethanol Subsidy.”
Working Paper 08-WP 480, Center for Agricultural
and Rural Development, Iowa State University,
November 2008.
Eaves, James E. and Eaves, Stephen. “Neither Renewable
Nor Reliable.” Regulation, Fall 2007, 30(3), pp. 24-27.
Energy Information Administration. Annual Energy
Review 2004. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of
Energy, 2004.
Energy Information Administration. “Country Analysis
Briefs”; www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/cabs/contents.html
(accessed November 14, 2006).
Energy Information Administration. “International
Petroleum Monthly.” May 8, 2007.
Energy Information Administration. “Federal Financial
Interventions and Subsidies in Energy Markets 2007.”
SR/CNEAF/2008-01, April 2008.
Farrell, Alexander E.; Plevin, Richard J.; Turner,
Brian T.; Jones, Andrew D.; O’Hare, Michael and
Kammen, Daniel M. “Ethanol Can Contribute to
Energy and Environmental Goals.” Science,
January 27, 2006, 311(5720), pp. 506-08.
Fisher, Eric and Marshall, Kathryn G. “The Anatomy
of an Oil Price Shock.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland Economic Commentary, November 2006.
Fried, Edward. “Oil Security: An Economic
Phenomenon,” in Edward Fried and Nanette Blandin,
eds., Oil and America’s Security. Washington, DC:
Brookings Institution, 1988, pp. 56-59.
Gholtz, Eugene and Press, Daryl G. “Energy Alarmism:
The Myths That Make Americans Worry About Oil.”
Policy Analysis 589, Cato Institute, April 5, 2007.
Gray, C. Boyden and Varcoe, Andrew R. “Octane, Clean
Air, and Renewable Fuels: A Modest Step Toward
Energy Independence.” Texas Review of Law &
Politics, Fall 2005, 10(1), pp. 10-62.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

Greene, David L. and Leiby, Paul N. “The Oil Security
Metrics Model: A Tool for Evaluating the Prospective
Oil Security Benefits of DOE’s Energy Efficiency and
Renewable Energy R&D Programs.” ORNL/TM-2006/
505, prepared by the Oak Ridge National Laboratory
for the U.S. Department of Energy, May 2006.
Groode, Tiffany A. and Heywood, John B. “Ethanol:
A Look Ahead.” LFEE Working Paper 2007-02 RP,
Laboratory for Energy and the Environment,
Massachusetts Institute of Technology, June 2007.
Hahn, Robert W. “Ethanol: Law, Economics, and
Politics.” Working Paper 08-02, Reg-Markets Center,
American Enterprise Institute, January 2008.
Hill, Jason; Nelson, Erik; Tilman, David; Polasky,
Stephen and Tiffany, Douglas. “Environmental,
Economic, and Energetic Costs and Benefits of
Biodiesel and Ethanol Biofuels.” Proceedings of the
National Academy of Science, July 25, 2006, 103(30),
pp. 11206-10.
Hill, Jason; Polasky, Stephen; Nelson, Erik; Tilman,
David; Huo, Hong; Lindsay, Ludwig; Neumann, James;
Zheng, Haochi and Bonta, Diego. “Climate Change
and Health Costs of Air Emissions from Biofuels and
Gasoline.” Proceedings of the National Academy of
Science, February 10, 2009, 106(6), pp. 2077-82.
Huntington, Hillard. “Energy Disruptions, Interfirm
Price Effects and the Aggregate Economy.” OP 51,
Energy Modeling Forum, Stanford University,
September 2002.
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change: Eggleston;
Simon; Buendia, Leondro; Miwa, Kyoko; Ngara, Todd
and Tanabe, Kiyoto, eds. “2006 IPCC Guidelines for
National Greenhouse Gas Inventories.” National
Greenhouse Gas Inventories Programme, 2006.
Jacobsen, Mark Z. “Effects of Ethanol (E85) Versus
Gasoline Vehicles on Cancer and Mortality in the
United States.” Environmental Science and
Technology, April 18, 2007, 41(11), pp. 4150-57.
Jervis, Robert. “Why the Bush Doctrine Cannot Be
Sustained.” Political Science Quarterly, Fall 2005,
120(3), pp. 351-77.

Koplow, Douglas. “Biofuels—At What Cost? Government
Support for Ethanol and Biodiesel in the United
States: 2007 Update.” Global Studies Initiative of the
International Institute for Sustainable Development,
October 2007.
Koplow, Douglas and Martin, Aaron. Fueling Global
Warming: Federal Subsidies to Oil in the United
States. Washington, DC: Greenpeace, June 1998.
Liska, Adam J.; Yang, Haishun S.; Bremer, Virgil R.;
Klopfenstein, Terry J.; Walters, Daniel T.; Erickson,
Galen E. and Cassman, Kenneth G. “Improvements
in Life Cycle Energy Efficiency and Greenhouse Gas
Emissions of Corn Ethanol.” Journal of Industrial
Ecology, January 21, 2009.
Lowe, John E. Testimony before the U.S. Senate
Judiciary Committee hearing on “Exploring the
Skyrocketing Cost of Oil.” May 21, 2008.
Lundberg Survey, Inc. “Fatally Flawed Premise: Why
Anti-Oil Weapon in War on Terror Won’t Work.”
Energy Détente, November 30, 2006, 27(11).
Lugar, Richard G. and Woolsey, R. James. “The New
Petroleum.” Foreign Affairs, January/February 1999,
78(1), pp. 88-102.
Metcalf, Gilbert E. “Federal Tax Policy Towards Energy.”
NBER Working Paper 12568, National Bureau of
Economic Research, October 2006.
McCubbin, Donald R. and Delucchi, Mark A. “The
Social Costs of the Health Effects of Motor Vehicle
Air Pollution,” in “The Annualized Social Cost of
Motor Vehicle Use in the United States, Based on
1990-1991 Data.” Report 11. UCD-ITS-RR-93-3(11),
Institute for Transportation Studies, University of
California, Davis, August 1996, pp. 169-209.
Nassauer, Joan Iverson; Santelmann, Mary V. and
Scavia, Donald, eds. From the Corn Belt to the Gulf:
Societal and Environmental Implications of
Alternative Agricultural Futures. Washington, DC:
Resources for the Future, 2007.
National Research Council of the National Academies
Press. Water Implications of Biofuel Production in
the United States. Washington, DC: National
Academies Press, 2008.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

95

Panel Discussion

Nielsen, Per H. and Wenzel, Henrik. “Environmental
Assessment of Ethanol Produced from Corn Starch
and Used as an Alternative to Conventional Gasoline
for Car Driving.” Institute for Product Development,
Technical University of Denmark, June 2005.
Niven, Robert K. “Ethanol in Gasoline: Environmental
Impacts and Sustainability.” Renewable & Sustainable
Energy Reviews, December 2005, 9(6), pp. 535-55.
Nye, John V.C. “The Pigou Problem.” Regulation,
Summer 2008, 31(2), pp. 32-37.
Parra, Francisco R. Oil Politics: A Modern History of
Petroleum. London: I.B. Tauris, 2004.
Parry, Ian and Small, Kenneth. “Does Britain or the
United States Have the Right Gasoline Tax?”
American Economic Review, September 2005, 95(4),
pp. 1276-89.
Parry, Ian W.H.; Walls, Margaret and Harrington,
Winston. “Automobile Externalities and Policies.”
Discussion Paper 06-26, Resources for the Future,
June 2006.
Patzek, Tad. “Thermodynamics of the Corn-Ethanol
Biofuel Cycle.” Critical Reviews in Plant Sciences,
2004, 23(6), pp. 519-67. July 22, 2006, online version;
http://petroleum.berkeley.edu/papers/patzek/
CRPS416-Patzek-Web.pdf.
Pope, C. Arden et al. “Lung Cancer, Cardiopulmonary
Mortality, and Long-Term Exposure to Fine Particulate
Air Pollution.” Journal of the American Medical
Association, March 6, 2002, 27(9), pp. 1132-41.
Posner, Richard A. Natural Monopoly and Its
Regulation. Washington, DC: Cato Institute, 1999.
Prados, Alfred B. and Blanchard, Christopher M.
“Saudi Arabia: Terrorist Financing Issues.” RL32499,
CRS Report for Congress, Congressional Research
Service. December 8, 2004, online version.
Renewable Fuels Association. “Understanding Land
Use Change and U.S. Ethanol Expansion.”
November 20, 2008.
Rosen, Harvey and Gayer, Ted. Public Finance. Eighth
Edition. New York: McGraw-Hill, 2008.

96

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

Scheuer, Michael. Imperial Hubris: Why the West Is
Losing the War on Terror. Washington, DC: Potomac
Books, 2007.
Scheuer, Michael. Marching Toward Hell: America
and Islam after Iraq. New York: Free Press, 2008.
Schwartz, Joel A. “Comments on the EPA’s Proposal to
Tighten the Fine Particulate Matter Standard.”
Testimony before the U.S. Environmental Protection
Agency, EPA-HQ- OAR-2001-0017, April 17, 2006.
Searchinger, Timothy; Heimlich, Ralph; Houghton,
R.A.; Dong, Fengxia; Elobeid, Amani; Fabiosa, Jacinto;
Tokgoz, Simla; Hayes, Dermot and Yu, Tun-Hsiang.
“Use of U.S. Croplands for Biofuels Increases
Greenhouse Gases Through Emissions from LandUse Change.” Science, February 29, 2008, 319,
pp. 1238-40.
Shore, Joanne and Hackworth, John. “Challenging
Times for Making Refinery Capacity Decisions.”
Presentation at the National Petroleum Refiners
Association, Energy Information Administration,
March 2004; www.eia.doe.gov/pub/oil_gas/petroleum/
presentations/2004/npra2004/npra2004_files/
frame.htm.
Taylor, Jerry and Van Doren, Peter. “Economic Amnesia:
The Case against Oil Price Controls and Windfall
Profit Taxes.” Policy Analysis 561, Cato Institute,
January 12, 2006.
Taylor, Jerry and Van Doren, Peter. “Don’t Increase
Federal Gasoline Taxes—Abolish Them.” Policy
Analysis 598, Cato Institute, August 7, 2007.
Tiffany, Douglas G. “Economic Consequences of Corn
Ethanol as a Fuel Source.” Presented at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis; Washington University in
St. Louis Wiedenbaum Center for the Economy,
Government, and Public Policy; and International
Center for Advanced Renewable Energy and
Sustainability conference Economics of Ethanol,
November 14, 2008.
Tyner, Wallace and Taheripour, Farzad. “Biofuels,
Policy Options, and Their Implications: Analysis
Using Partial and General Equilibrium Approaches.”

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

Journal of Agriculture & Food Industrial Organization,
2008, 6(20), pp. 1-18.
Urbanchuk, John M. “Ethanol and Gasoline Prices.”
LECG, May 26, 2004;
www.ethanolrfa.org/resource/facts/consumers/
documents/EthanolandGasolinePrices-LECG.pdf
(accessed January 28, 2009).
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Regulatory
Impact Analysis: Renewable Fuel Standard Program.
EPA 420-R-07-004, 2007.
von Blottnitz, Harro and Curran, Mary Ann. “A Review
of Assessments Conducted on Bioethanol as a
Transportation Fuel from a Net Energy, Greenhouse
Gas, and Environmental Life-Cycle Perspective.”
Journal of Cleaner Production, 2007, 15(7), pp. 607-19.

The Future of Biofuels
Rick Tolman

CORN SUPPLY AND DEMAND

A

ccording to the U.S. Department of
Agriculture (USDA), U.S. corn growers
produced 12.1 billion bushels of corn in
2008, the second-largest crop ever. This harvest
reflects the increasing ability of growers to produce higher yields, measured in bushels per acre
(bu/acre), due to improvements in agronomic practices and biotechnology that improve the corn
seed itself. The 2008 national average yield, 153.9
bu/acre, is the second-largest on record.

Walton, David. “Has Oil Lost the Capacity to Shock?”
Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Spring 2006,
46(1), pp. 105-14.
Wang, Michael; Wu, May and Hong, Huo. “Life-Cycle
Energy and Greenhouse Gas Emission Impacts of
Different Corn Ethanol Plant Types.” Environmental
Research Letter, 2007, 2(2).
West, J. Robinson. “Saudi Arabia, Iraq, and the Gulf,”
in Jan Kalicki and David Goldwyn, eds., Energy
Security. Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center
Press, 2005, pp. 197-218.
Woodward, Bob. “Greenspan: Ouster of Hussein
Crucial for Oil Security.” Washington Post,
September 17, 2007, p. A3.

As high as this yield is (by comparison, the
1988 yield was only 84.6 bu/acre), many in the
corn industry expect it to nearly double well before
mid-century. In fact, many growers who take part
in the National Corn Growers Association (NCGA)
National Corn Yield Contest routinely score yields
much higher than the national average.
Since 1994, corn productivity per acre has
accelerated as a result of advances in markerassisted breeding, biotechnology, and improved
farming practices. Growers are harvesting considerably more corn without significantly increasing
acreage. Based on past performance, average production per acre is projected (following a 15-year
trend) to hit 180 bu/acre by 2015. Some seed

Rick Tolman is the chief executive officer of the National Corn Growers Association.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economic Development, 2009, 5(1), pp. 97-102.
© 2009, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced,
published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

97

Panel Discussion

researchers foresee corn production near 300
bu/acre by 2030.
Modern farm management practices play an
important role in increased productivity, along
with new and improved production tools, such as
global positioning systems, yield mapping, and
precision nutrient-application methods. Nationwide, corn growers are harvesting more corn per
acre while making great strides in efficient input
use. This is resulting in a more sustainable environmental footprint.
Although corn production is expanding, some
uses for it are not expanding at the same rate. Other
corn demand categories, such as livestock production and exports, have shown limited future
growth—meaning that increased corn supplies
will result in more corn available for biofuel production. Demand for corn in the livestock and
poultry sectors has been relatively flat in the past
10 marketing years. The amount of raw field corn
fed to livestock is expected to decline slightly as
more corn is displaced by distillers’ grains, a coproduct of ethanol production. Furthermore, the
amount of corn used for human food has been flat,
and corn exports have trended up only slightly.
Even as corn use for ethanol has risen dramatically over the past 10 years, American farmers have
continued to be the world’s top exporter of corn—
satisfying the demands of foreign customers. Corn
exports have remained steady or expanded slightly
and, through exports of distillers’ grains, the ethanol
sector is helping satisfy foreign demand for highprotein, high-energy livestock feed. The United
States exported about 2.4 million metric tons of
distillers’ grains in 2007.
The Food and Agricultural Policy Research
Institute’s (FAPRI) 2008 U.S. and World Agriculture
Outlook (Carriquiry et al., 2008) provides projections for agricultural commodity production and
disappearance. It considers average weather patterns, existing farm policy, current trade agreements,
and customs unions.
FAPRI projects that the nation’s corn growers
will harvest 15.2 billion bushels in 2015. This is
congruent with NCGA’s vision of corn growers being
able to harvest 15 billion bushels by 2015. FAPRI
projects corn volume to produce ethanol to reach
5.2 billion bushels in 2017. This increase will result
98

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

in 10 billion bushels of corn for all non-ethanol
use categories. And this is projected to be accomplished with only a limited increase in planted
acres over the 93.6 million acres used in 2007.
The growing demand for ethanol is projected
to keep pace with the projected increases in total
corn production into 2017. FAPRI projects that most
of the historic non-ethanol uses of corn will provide little growth. Given the rising cost of production, absent a market for ethanol the nation’s corn
producers would once again face marginal profits
from high production and insufficient demand.

THE VALUE OF ETHANOL
Ethanol is a significant market for U.S. corn,
but its value goes far beyond its role as a major use
of corn. Developing this new value-added industry
not only creates a new market for our corn producers, it lessens our dependence on foreign oil
and helps revitalize rural America.
Ethanol plants are helping rejuvenate rural
communities across the country by creating highpaying jobs, boosting local tax revenues, and creating partnership opportunities for local businesses.
Rural communities across America face an increasing challenge (brain drain) as they strive to create
opportunities for their youth to remain in their local
communities. The ethanol industry is the single
most important industry created by the agricultural
sector in decades allowing rural American communities to continue to remain economically viable.
The demand for corn ethanol production was
originally created in response to the oil crisis of
the 1970s. After the crisis was resolved, oil prices
dropped to a level that challenged the economic viability of biofuels. This situation has now changed,
however, as oil prices have moved erratically and
the viability of biofuels has strengthened. In conjunction with positive economics, public policy
initiatives have helped break oil companies’ control
of the liquid transportation distribution systems.
Even with the Renewable Fuel Standard
passed by the U.S. government and the subsequent
rise in the demand for corn, the long-term economic
health for corn producers is far from secure. With
the production efficiency increases stated above
combined with the steady acreage dedicated to

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

corn production, supply will either continue to
match demand or problematically outpace demand.
According to the USDA’s pricing models based
on more than 30 years of data, corn prices over the
next 10 to 15 years will reach a new plateau, but
farm profitability will remain tight mainly because
of increases in input costs driven by the price of oil.
Raw material costs for inputs like nitrogen fertilizer
are reaching record gains and do not move through
the distribution system as quickly as, say, conventional gasoline, while other inputs like diesel fuel
are already affecting producers. Thus, the rise in
corn prices had a positive impact on corn growers
in 2007-08, but the long-term reality in the current
environment is that producers will see very tight
to negative margins.
Continued strong growth in the ethanol sector
will keep corn producers viable, which can keep
oil consumption in check while continuing to provide a substantial amount of feed to the livestock
industry through distillers’ grains. This will be a
challenge in the current economic environment,
where the subprime mortgage crisis had increased
the cost of capital. Farming is a capital-rich proposition and producers now require two to three times
more capital just to produce a crop.
Ethanol has revitalized the rural landscape,
provided a new market for domestically produced
grain, and dented our need for imported oil, but it
has not done so irresponsibly. Corn to ethanol is—
and will remain—a healthy economic growth tool,
not a get-rich-quick scheme for producers, and the
ripples from this positive market will reach those
beyond the farm gate to benefit anyone who uses
energy and eats food.

RESPONDING TO THE
MYTHMAKERS
Food versus Fuel
Diverting agriculture crops from the table to
the fuel tank has been the focal point of critics
stirring the so-called food-versus-fuel controversy.
Any discussion of corn ethanol, however, must
consider two factors: the shifting nature of our
country’s crops and the price of corn (specifically,
its impact on overall food prices).

Farming acreage has been trending downward
during the past few decades. In 1932, when corn
reached its highest acreage count, 320.4 million
acres of farmland were under cultivation countrywide; in 2007 total acreage under cultivation was
an estimated 278.1 million. The development of
suburban communities in the second half of the
twentieth century was a major contributor to the
decrease of both farmland and parkland acreage.
Crop production, however, is an even more
significant issue regarding demand for certain crops
and how it is met: Corn yield increased more than
fivefold between 1932 and 2007. The average yield,
represented as bu/acre, grew from 26.5 bu/acre in
1932 to an estimated 151.1 bu/acre in 2007, and
experts believe average yield can increase to 180
bu/acre or more over the next decade, as noted
above.
As consumers, we all understand the pinch
to our pocketbooks when food prices increase.
Grocery shoppers and restaurant diners need to
understand that the cost of food ingredients in
products they buy represents less than one-fifth of
the price at checkout. So how much of an impact
do rising corn prices have on overall food prices?
Food prices are largely determined by costs and
profits after commodities leave the farm. On average, only about 19 percent of the price of food can
be attributed to ingredients. Marketing and transportation costs comprise a much higher portion of
total costs. For example, consider the impact of
rising corn prices on a box of corn flakes as outlined in Table 1 and the following significant facts
about food production.
About 50 percent of the corn crop is used for
animal feed. Corn makes up a relatively large share
of the product prices of eggs, pork, and poultry.
Beef and dairy products also contain significant
costs for corn, but the prices of processed foods are
largely determined by the cost of other components:
• International demand for dairy products has
outstripped international supply. Moreover,
the world demand for dairy products has put
U.S. products onto world markets, thereby
raising prices.
• Agriculture is playing a large role in the
supply of U.S. fuel. Agriculture’s involvement will help offset any increase in food

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

99

Panel Discussion

prices, with lower fuel costs and cleaner,
less-polluting renewable fuels. Moreover,
government payments to farmers will be
reduced as a result of higher crop prices, for
example, they were $6 billion less in 2007.
• Combining the efficiencies at the farm with
increased ethanol yields from grain, an acre
of corn can produce more than 400 gallons
of ethanol, compared with 320 gallons only
10 years ago. With the implementation of
biomass conversion and increased grain
yields, the grain ethanol industry is expected
to reach 600 gallons of ethanol per acre in
the next decade.

Net Energy/Liquid Petroleum
Displacement
A key metric for judging the success of alternative fuels is whether the product supplies more
energy than is needed to produce it. This may seem
like a straightforward calculation, but it has been
hotly debated because of different methods of quantifying energy value. Another layer of complexity
is that today’s accounting for energy inputs versus
outputs is no longer satisfactory. One must also
look at the quality of that energy in terms of nonrenewable carbon dioxide (CO2 ) and CO2 equivalents generated in fuel production and use. The
common terms used for these analyses are “net
energy” and “liquid petroleum displacement.”
First, a few clarifying points will aid the discussion of ethanol and liquid petroleum displacement. The common metric of British thermal units
(BTUs) per gallon is used when measuring the total
energy content of a liquid fuel. Analysis of current
transportation fuels—mainly conventional gasoline—yields a value of approximately 110,000
BTUs per gallon.
Ethanol, by comparison, yields only 84,000
BTUs per gallon. This fact is interpreted by many
to imply that ethanol is a lesser energy product than
gasoline. In reality, all this shows is that ethanol
has a lower energy density than gasoline. Depending on the engine using the ethanol and ethanolblended fuels, efficiencies in converting the liquid
potential energy into kinetic energy can be almost
on par with each other. Today the engines in the
100

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

North American fleet capable of burning the higherblend ethanol fuel, E85, are not yet optimized for
ethanol. They run more efficiently on conventional
fuel. As flexible-fuel vehicle (FFV) adoption
increases and ethanol availability becomes more
widespread, this performance discrepancy will be
addressed.
Understanding the energy density discrepancy
between the two fuels is necessary to better understand the second part of this issue, net energy balance. The core of net energy balance is this: How
much energy do you get out compared with how
much energy you put in? Since the late 1980s,
more than 25 studies have examined the energy
balance of ethanol. Only six have shown ethanol
to have a negative energy balance (more energy
used in production than is delivered to the vehicle).
The most recent study (Liska et al., 2009) reviewed
several different ethanol production examples,
and found that eight corn-ethanol scenarios had
net energy ratios from 1.29 to 2.23. For the most
common biorefinery types, the net energy ratio
ranged from 1.50 to 1.79.
Nevertheless, media outlets have consistently
cited both sides of this argument in an attempt to
be “balanced”—while not informing the public of
the discrepancy in study results. It frustrates the
ethanol industry that media outlets continue to
focus on studies that cite a negative energy balance
for ethanol even though these studies are few in
number. Beyond the net energy argument, it
becomes exceedingly clear that the net CO2 emissions for biofuels such as ethanol are significantly
lower than petrochemicals, which are nonrenewable CO2 sources in and of themselves.
It does take energy to produce ethanol: Natural
gas and electricity are used to power ethanol plants,
and fertilizer and diesel engines are needed to
grow and harvest corn. Studies repeatedly have
shown the energy required to produce ethanol is
less than the energy ethanol delivers for personal
vehicle use. Moreover, most critics of ethanol on
net energy grounds fail to perform similar analyses
of petroleum-based gasoline’s net energy. In fact,
petroleum performs worse than ethanol under this
direct comparison. Ethanol’s biggest advantage is
that it can continue to use less and less fossil energy
for production through greater efficiencies, as well

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

Table 1
The Impact of Rising Corn Prices on a Box of Corn Flakes
Corn costs
Item
Corn Flakes cereal,
18-oz box: 12.9 oz of
milled corn produces
one 18-oz box (USDA)

Estimated retail price

$2/bu =
$0.035/lb

$4/bu =
$0.07/lb

$6/bu =
$0.107/lb

As of April 2008

Increase (%) in the
past 17 months

Increase (%) due to
corn costs

$0.028

$0.056

$0.086

$3.69

$1.06 (40%)

$0.06 (6%)

as the use of other renewable sources of energy to
power ethanol plants.

POLITICAL ISSUES
Two salient political issues will have a tangible
impact on the future of ethanol: higher blends and
FFVs.

Higher Blends
With the passage of the 2007 energy bill, the
Renewable Fuel Standard will require the United
States to use 36 billion gallons of biofuels by 2022.
With this schedule now law as of January 1, 2009,
major infrastructure changes must take place to
facilitate implementation of the standard.
Moving to higher blends of ethanol will be critical to the industry. The United States uses roughly
145 billion gallons of gasoline each year. By 2015,
ethanol will comprise at least 15 billion gallons,
or roughly 10 percent of the fuel market. Because
the highest level of ethanol certified for conventional automobiles is currently 10 percent (E10),
the industry must move rapidly to secure certification for higher blends (such as E20) for the market
to readily absorb the increasing volumes of ethanol
available beyond a nationwide 10 percent blend.
Otherwise, the ethanol industry will likely hit a
“blend wall” at 10 percent.

Flexible-Fuel Vehicles
Currently, most American, Japanese, and
European auto manufacturers allow only 10 percent
ethanol to be blended into gasoline because of the

composition of rubber sealing joints in fuel systems.
These joints can become compromised with higher
ethanol blends, leading to engine damage. Engine
manufactures will void engine warranties if higher
blends are used. However, technology now exists
to use up to 100 percent ethanol in automobiles—as
has been implemented in Brazil for several decades.
In the United States, auto manufacturers produce FFVs that can use E85 (a gasoline blend that
is 85 percent ethanol). The incremental cost of
building a FFV versus a non-FFV is estimated at
approximately $150. Once a conventional vehicle
has been manufactured, however, the conversion
to flexible-fuel can cost much more.
The reality is that FFV technology is readily
available at a low cost and has been implemented
in Brazil by the same auto manufacturers that produce cars in the United States. The issue of fuel
flexibility is not technological—rather, it is political. The current U.S. fuel infrastructure (which is
owned by oil producers and refiners) widely resists
energy products not manufactured from within the
petroleum system. It also is clear that in the current
economic environment, the oil network is well
funded to keep allies aligned with its interests.
Because of the political barriers to expanded
use of ethanol, the NCGA supports the open fuel
standard. Enabling biofuels to break the current oil
monopoly may require even more than that effort.
It may, for example, require “legislation requiring
all major oil companies to convert pumps for E85
at 50 percent of their owned or branded stations”
(Sandalow, 2007, p. 93) or “legislation prohibiting
franchise agreements that limit pumps for biofuels
at service stations” (p. 94)—as Brookings Institution

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

101

Panel Discussion

energy and environment scholar David Sandalow
recommends in his important book, Freedom
from Oil.
Biofuels are already ready to play an important
role in freeing us from our dependence on foreign
oil, and the relevant technologies are only going
to improve. But political action is clearly needed
to allow them to reach their potential.

The future for corn ethanol in the United States
is bright. The trends in the cost of production,
productivity, and sustainability are all moving in
a positive direction. Corn ethanol is the bridge to
second- and third-generation biofuels, but it will
continue to play a key role for the foreseeable future
as we develop alternative sources to petrochemical
feedstocks.

CONCLUSION

REFERENCES

Ethanol sourced from corn has become the
primary and most successful biofuel to date. As
such, it has generated the most focus, criticism,
and scrutiny. It is important to realize that corn
ethanol is still a formative and nascent industry
that is undergoing rapid transformation and technological change.
Critics tend to focus on old metrics and unequal
comparisons. The future of ethanol sourced from
cellulosics1 is bright and necessary, but it is theoretical at this point. Cellulosics will evolve from
the success of corn ethanol, not as a revolution
displacing it. Cellulosic ethanol will not occur
without the technological advances developed in
current plants that are producing corn ethanol.
The biofuels market is broad and wide, requiring both corn ethanol and sugar-based ethanol as
well as other sources of cellulosics. Sources are
complementary and should not be cast as competitors, particularly in an unequal fashion.

Carriquiry, Miguel et al. FAPRI 2008 U.S. and World
Agriculture Outlook. FAPRI Staff Report 08-FSR 1,
Food and Agricultural Policy Research Institute,
Iowa State University and the University of MissouriColumbia, 2008; www.fapri.missouri.edu/outreach/
publications/2008/OutlookPub2008.pdf.

1

Liska, Adam J.; S. Yang, Haishun; Bremer, Virgil R.;
Klopfenstein, Terry J.; Walters, Daniel T.; Erickson,
Galen E. and Cassman, Kenneth G. “Improvements
in Energy Efficiency and Greenhouse Gas Emissions
of Corn-Ethanol.” Journal of Industrial Ecology,
February 2009, pp. 1-17; http://ncesr.unl.edu/docs/
09-1_improvementsincornethanol.pdf.
Sandalow, David B. Freedom from Oil. New York:
McGraw-Hill, 2007.

Cellusosic ethanol is produced from a wide range of biomass, such
as agricultural plan waste (e.g., corn stover—the leaves and stalks
of corn plants left in the field after harvest) or “energy crops” (e.g.,
switchgrass).

102

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

Long-Term Sustainability in the
U.S. Corn Ethanol Industry:
Some Key Determinants
Nicholas Kalaitzandonakes, James Kaufman,
Wyatt Thompson, and Seth Meyer

T

he U.S. ethanol industry has changed
dramatically in the past five years. Driven
by the need for national energy independence, concerns over air quality, and an interest in
rural development, a number of government policies were introduced within the span of a few years
and had significant impact. The 2004 ethanol tax
credits, the Energy Policy Act of 2005, the 2006
ban of methyl tertiary-butyl ether (MTBE), and
later the Energy Independence and Security Act
of 2007 all significantly expanded the opportunity
for ethanol use in the United States.
A positive macroeconomic environment also
played a role. Robust global economic expansion
led to strong and sustained growth in the demand
for oil and gasoline for the better part of this decade.
Gasoline prices grew steadily in the United States
from 2002 on and along with them ethanol prices.
The fast-expanding market for ethanol and strong
prices led to large investments in new productive
capacity. From the beginning of 2002 to the end of
2008, the ethanol industry grew from 61 plants with
a combined capacity of 2.3 billion gallons per year
to 170 plants with 12 billion gallons of capacity
(Renewable Fuels Association [RFA], 2009a).
The decline of gasoline and ethanol prices from
their meteoric rise in the summer of 2008 and the
softening demand for fuels amid the worst recession
in decades have raised concerns about overcapacity
and the long-term sustainability of the ethanol
industry. Government policies and macroeconomic
conditions will continue to influence the future
profitability of the corn ethanol industry in the

United States, but so will the strategies that firms
pursue in the coming years.
This article examines the recent cyclical movements in the revenues and capital outlays of the
U.S. corn ethanol industry and evaluates their likely
trends and impacts on the industry’s sustainability.
It also examines the potential contribution of factors
under the control of ethanol firms: the pursuit of
efficiencies and technical innovation.

DRIVERS OF PROFITABILITY IN
THE ETHANOL INDUSTRY
Industry sustainability starts the drive for profitability at the ethanol plant. For any dry grind
ethanol plant, the bulk of the revenues comes from
two products: ethanol (85 percent) and coproduct
dried distillers’ grains with solubles (DDGS; 15 percent). Similarly, a single input—corn—accounts
for 65 percent of a plant’s variable costs (Hofstrand,
2008). Because DDGS are used as feed for livestock,
they can substitute for corn in animal rations. For
this reason, corn and DDGS prices tend to move
together. This correlation simplifies the calculation
of plant profitability.
Plant managers and analysts alike can approximate plant profitability with the simple calculation
shown in Table 1. For example, if corn were $3.25
per bushel and ethanol $1.80 per gallon, then a dry
mill’s return over operating costs would be $0.35
per gallon. A combination of corn at $3.25 and
ethanol at $1.60 would cut the per gallon return by
more than half, to $0.15. Assuming that the average
payment to capital invested is equal to $0.20 per
gallon, this net return would not attract investment.
Corn at $3.25 and ethanol at $1.40 or less would
result in outright losses per gallon of ethanol produced, likely leading to plant closures if such prices
and losses persisted.
A higher ethanol price or lower corn price
would tend to increase profitability. In 2006, for
instance, when ethanol was around $2.50 per gallon

Nicholas Kalaitzandonakes is a professor of agricultural economics, James Kaufman is a project director, Wyatt Thompson is an assistant professor,
and Seth Meyer is a research assistant professor in the department of agricultural economics at the University of Missouri.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Regional Economic Development, 2009, 5(1), pp. 103-115.

© 2009, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced,
published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts,
synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

103

104

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

0.06
0.11
0.16
0.21
0.26
0.31
0.36
0.41
0.46
0.51
0.56
0.61
0.66
0.71
0.76
0.81
0.86
0.91
0.96
1.01
1.06
1.11
1.16
1.21
1.26
1.31

81.83

2.25

0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
0.35
0.40
0.45
0.50
0.55
0.60
0.65
0.70
0.75
0.80
0.85
0.90
0.95
1.00
1.05
1.10
1.15
1.20
1.25

90.12

2.50

–0.07
–0.02
0.03
0.08
0.13
0.18
0.23
0.28
0.33
0.38
0.43
0.48
0.53
0.58
0.63
0.68
0.73
0.78
0.83
0.88
0.93
0.98
1.03
1.08
1.13
1.18

98.41

2.75

–0.13
–0.08
–0.03
0.02
0.07
0.12
0.17
0.22
0.27
0.32
0.37
0.42
0.47
0.52
0.57
0.62
0.67
0.72
0.77
0.82
0.87
0.92
0.97
1.02
1.07
1.12

106.69

3.00
123.27

3.50
131.56

3.75
139.85

4.00

–0.20
–0.15
–0.10
–0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
0.35
0.40
0.45
0.50
0.55
0.60
0.65
0.70
0.75
0.80
0.85
0.90
0.95
1.00
1.05

–0.26
–0.21
–0.16
–0.11
–0.06
–0.01
0.04
0.09
0.14
0.19
0.24
0.29
0.34
0.39
0.44
0.49
0.54
0.59
0.64
0.69
0.74
0.79
0.84
0.89
0.94
0.99

–0.33
–0.28
–0.23
–0.18
–0.13
–0.08
–0.03
0.02
0.07
0.12
0.17
0.22
0.27
0.32
0.37
0.42
0.47
0.52
0.57
0.62
0.67
0.72
0.77
0.82
0.87
0.92

–0.39
–0.34
–0.29
–0.24
–0.19
–0.14
–0.09
–0.04
0.01
0.06
0.11
0.16
0.21
0.26
0.31
0.36
0.41
0.46
0.51
0.56
0.61
0.66
0.71
0.76
0.81
0.86

Net returns over operating costs

114.98

3.25

–0.46
–0.41
–0.36
–0.31
–0.26
–0.21
–0.16
–0.11
–0.06
–0.01
0.04
0.09
0.14
0.19
0.24
0.29
0.34
0.39
0.44
0.49
0.54
0.59
0.64
0.69
0.74
0.79

148.13

4.25

–0.52
–0.47
–0.42
–0.37
–0.32
–0.27
–0.22
–0.17
–0.12
–0.07
–0.02
0.03
0.08
0.13
0.18
0.23
0.28
0.33
0.38
0.43
0.48
0.53
0.58
0.63
0.68
0.73

156.42

4.50

–0.59
–0.54
–0.49
–0.44
–0.39
–0.34
–0.29
–0.24
–0.19
–0.14
–0.09
–0.04
0.01
0.06
0.11
0.16
0.21
0.26
0.31
0.36
0.41
0.46
0.51
0.56
0.61
0.66

164.71

4.75

–0.66
–0.61
–0.56
–0.51
–0.46
–0.41
–0.36
–0.31
–0.26
–0.21
–0.16
–0.11
–0.06
–0.01
0.04
0.09
0.14
0.19
0.24
0.29
0.34
0.39
0.44
0.49
0.54
0.59

173.00

5.00

–0.72
–0.67
–0.62
–0.57
–0.52
–0.47
–0.42
–0.37
–0.32
–0.27
–0.22
–0.17
–0.12
–0.07
–0.02
0.03
0.08
0.13
0.18
0.23
0.28
0.33
0.38
0.43
0.48
0.53

181.28

5.25

NOTE: The table shows net returns over variable operating costs for various combinations of ethanol and corn prices. To calculate plant profits, capital and other fixed costs
would also need to be subtracted from these figures. In the area above the bold type, negative numbers indicate the average plant is not able to cover operating costs. In
the area with bold type, net returns over operating costs are less than $0.25 per gallon, which may be less than required to cover fixed costs. In the area below the bold
type, net returns over operating costs are more than $0.25 per gallon, thus likely exceed fixed costs. The matrix assumes DDGS prices change as a function of corn prices.
Other operating costs (fuel, electricity, labor, etc.) are included in the calculations. The matrix assumes a constant DDGS yield of 17 pounds per bushel of corn converted
to ethanol and a linear relationship between DDGS and corn prices.

1.25
1.30
1.35
1.40
1.45
1.50
1.55
1.60
1.65
1.70
1.75
1.80
1.85
1.90
1.95
2.00
2.05
2.10
2.15
2.20
2.25
2.30
2.35
2.40
2.45
2.50

0.13
0.18
0.23
0.28
0.33
0.38
0.43
0.48
0.53
0.58
0.63
0.68
0.73
0.78
0.83
0.88
0.93
0.98
1.03
1.08
1.13
1.18
1.23
1.28
1.33
1.38

73.54

DDGS ($/ton)

Ethanol($/gallon)

2.00

Corn ($/bushel)

Dry Mill Ethanol Plant Returns Over Operating Costs, 2008-09

Table 1

Panel Discussion

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

Figure 1
Ethanol and Gasoline Prices
$/Gallon
3.00
2.50

Gasoline
Ethanol
Energy-Equivalent Ethanol Price

2.00
1.50
1.00
0.50
0.00
1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008

NOTE: Prices are Omaha prices to fuel blenders; the energy-equivalent ethanol price is two-thirds the price of gasoline. Prices are not
adjusted for the ethanol tax credit.
SOURCE: Nebraska state government (www.neo.ne.gov/statshtml/66.html), with 2008 preliminary data from the Food and Agriculture
Policy Research Institute (FAPRI) at the University of Missouri–Columbia (MU).

and corn around $3.00 per bushel, average returns
over operating costs for a dry mill were $1.12 per
gallon—a rather hefty return to capital.
These calculations of operational profitability
illustrate a simple reality in the corn ethanol industry: Understanding the long-term sustainability of
ethanol requires knowledge of the factors that shape
the price of ethanol and its relationship to the price
of corn. Recent history provides some guidance.

The Price of Ethanol and the Factors
That Shape It
The ethanol market evolved quickly over only
a few years, often clouding the exact relationship
between ethanol prices and the market forces that
shape them. Historically, ethanol has been more
expensive than gasoline on a per-gallon basis
(Figure 1). However, an energy-equivalent price
reflecting ethanol’s energy content offers a better
comparison of value.1 The energy-equivalent price
1

Ethanol is not exactly the same as gasoline. One difference is energy
content. A gallon of ethanol has about two-thirds the amount of
energy as a gallon of gasoline, which implies that ethanol usually
propels a car only two-thirds of the distance of an equivalent volume
of gasoline.

of ethanol was also higher than the price of gasoline
during the 1980s and 1990s. Ethanol and gasoline
burn differently and as a result ethanol-blended
fuel improves the performance of some cars.
Accordingly, consumer demand for ethanol as a
fuel supplement resulted in price premiums over
the 1980-2000 period (Tyner, 2007).
As ethanol production capacity rose from less
than one billion gallons in the mid-1990s to almost
double that by 2000, ethanol price premiums
eroded, suggesting the fuel-supplement market
segment was more than saturated (see Figure 1).
As ethanol supplies mounted, with production
and imports growing to about four billion gallons
by 2005 (Figure 2), the energy-equivalent price of
ethanol began to lag gasoline prices. The price of
ethanol, however, did not fall during the early part
of the decade. Rather, it rose by more than 80 percent between 1999 and 2005—but it did not keep
pace with the price of gasoline, which nearly tripled
over the same period.
Then in 2006, regulatory changes led fuel
blenders to discontinue the use of MTBE in some
markets and replace it with ethanol (Westhoff et al.,
2007). Previously, MTBE had been required as a

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

105

Panel Discussion

Figure 2
U.S. Domestic and Imported Ethanol
Milions of Gallons
12,000
Imported
10,000

Domestic

8,000
6,000
4,000
2,000
0
1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

SOURCE: Data for 1993-2007 are from the Department of Energy (DOE), Energy Information Association (EIA); tonto.eia.doe.gov/dnav/
pet/pet_pnp_oxy_dc_nus_mbbl_m.htm). Data for 2008 are from FAPRI-MU baseline projections.

fuel additive to reduce certain pollutants emitted
by gasoline. Its use was concentrated in urban areas
and periods when air pollution levels were high.
MTBE replacement led to a sudden expansion in
the demand for ethanol that pushed the limits of
domestic production capacity. Ethanol prices spiked
in 2006 as blenders outbid one another for ethanol
to use as an additive (see Figure 1). Increased profitability in 2006 helped spur increases in production.
Additive use was met and quickly exceeded, so the
premiums associated with additive use once again
eroded, and analysts do not expect them to return
(de Gorter and Just, 2007; and Thompson, Meyer,
and Westhoff, 2008). The energy-equivalent price
of ethanol has since continued to lag the price of
gasoline as an increasing amount of ethanolblended fuel has been purchased simply as a substitute for gasoline.
A number of federal and state policies have
facilitated the expansion of corn ethanol from the
supplement, to the additive, and, more recently,
the fuel replacement market segment. Significant
policies include tax credits for fuel blenders ($0.45
per gallon of ethanol used), an import tariff ($0.54
per gallon of imported ethanol), and, more recently,
106

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

via the Renewable Fuel Standard (RFS) legislation,
a mandated volume of renewable fuel that must be
blended with gasoline (10.5 billion gallons of corn
ethanol for 2009). Both the tax credits and the RFS
mandate have expanded the demand for corn
ethanol, and the import tariff has maintained
ethanol prices at slightly higher levels.
Because of such structural shifts in the demand
and supply of ethanol, the exact ethanol price mechanism remains somewhat uncertain. For instance,
analysts disagree about how ethanol in E10 (fuel
that is 10 percent ethanol by volume) is effectively
priced. It could be reasonable to assume that the
price of ethanol is determined by the price of E10
relative to the price of gasoline and the energy content of E10 relative to that of gasoline. However,
two points may indicate otherwise. First, in areas
where air-quality regulations require that local fuels
contain an additive, consumers have no choice but
to buy fuel with ethanol. Second, consumers might
not realize the lower energy content of E10 because
it is still 90 percent gasoline, so the negative effect
on miles per gallon may be 3 percent or so. If this
reasoning holds, then ethanol is priced according
to the volume of gasoline it displaces (Tyner, 2007).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

Figure 3
Corn Prices in Nominal and Real Terms and Relative to Petroleum Prices
USD/Bushel (January 2009)
12.00

Divided by Petroleum Price per Barrel
0.40

10.00

Nominal Price (left axis)
Real Price (left axis)
Price Relative to Oil (right axis)

8.00

0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20

6.00

0.15

4.00

0.10
2.00
0.00
1960

0.05
0.00
1964

1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

2008

SOURCE: Average corn prices are from the USDA Economic Research Service; www.ers.usda.gov/data/feedgrains/FeedGrainsQueriable.aspx.
Petroleum prices are from the DOE EIA; tonto.eia.doe.gov/merquery/mer_data.asp?table=T09.01. The producer price index for finished
goods is from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/PPIFGS/downloaddata?cid=31.

The opposing view addresses both these points.
First, the ethanol market has expanded well beyond
the additive segment and the price of ethanol must
be low enough to induce demand in markets where
ethanol-blended fuels must compete with gasoline.
Second, because enough buyers are both informed
and discriminating, the price of E10 at retail should
be lower than the price of gasoline. This opposing
view, then, suggests that the price of ethanol is
increasingly set according to its energy content
(de Gorter and Just, 2007; and Thompson, Meyer,
and Westhoff, 2008).
Looking ahead and barring major changes in
the current policy environment, further expansion
in ethanol use beyond the E10 market is likely to
occur only by increasing sales of E85.2 This fuel,
which has as much as 85 percent ethanol, causes
a clear reduction in mileage, so it is likely to sell
in large volumes only if competitively priced on
an energy-equivalent basis with gasoline. Regard2

It is estimated that the current E10 market could be saturated by
approximately 15 billion gallons of ethanol a year.

less of their position on E10, analysts tend to agree
that a large expansion of the E85 market would
drive the price of ethanol to compete with the price
of gasoline on an energy-equivalent basis (Tyner,
2007; and Thompson, Meyer, and Westhoff, 2008).

The Relationship of Ethanol and Corn
Prices
The price of ethanol is an important determinant for the long-term profitability of the U.S. corn
ethanol industry, and its relationship to the price
of corn is as essential. For the most part, manufacturing industries that add value to agricultural commodities price their products based on processing
and marketing margins, which are added to the
price of the commodity feedstock. Accordingly,
their revenues and costs are closely linked. In the
case of ethanol production, such a link does not
exist because the bulk of revenue is determined in
the petroleum (gasoline) market, while most of its
cost is determined in the corn market—two markets
that have historically exhibited little association
(Figure 3). Wide fluctuations in corn and petroleum

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

107

Panel Discussion

Figure 4
Corn Stocks-to-Use Ratio
Percent
50

U.S. Stocks

45

World Stocks

40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5

19

60
19 /19
63 61
19 /19
66 64
19 /19
69 67
19 /19
72 70
19 /19
75 73
19 /19
78 76
19 /19
81 79
19 /19
84 61
19 /19
87 85
19 /19
90 88
19 /19
93 91
19 /19
96 94
19 /19
99 97
20 /20
02 00
20 /20
05 03
20 /20
08 06
/2
00
9

0

SOURCE: USDA Foreign Agricultural Service Production, Supply, and Distribution database.

Figure 5
Ethanol Dry Mill Costs and Returns per Bushel of Corn Processed
$/Bushel
9

Costs, Other

8

Costs, Energy

7

Costs, Corn

6

Returns

5
4
3
2
1
0
1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

NOTE: Returns include the value of ethanol and DDGS sold per bushel of corn.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations using various sources, including Nebraska state government ethanol plant price and USDA cost data.

108

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

prices in recent months have put this lack of association in sharp focus.
Petroleum price variability is not new, but it
may have been largely forgotten when the cost of
a barrel was $20 or less in the early part of this
decade. The runup to over $140 per barrel in 2008
ended any complacency. And the subsequent drop
to $40 per barrel shocked perhaps the ethanol
industry as much as anyone because ethanol prices
quickly followed suit.
Price swings in the corn market are similarly
not new (see Figure 3). Both demand and supply
factors influence corn prices over time. Changes
in the demand for corn are generally incremental
and anticipated; however, shifts in the supply due
to weather, pest infestations, and other shocks are
more abrupt and can have significant short-term
effects on corn prices. Demand and supply factors
and even speculators have been viewed as key
drivers of the recent volatility in corn markets (e.g.,
Sanders, Erwin, and Merrin, 2008; and Trostle,
2008). Moreover, the current environment of low
buffer stocks might also be playing a role because
demand and supply shocks are magnified under
such conditions (Figure 4).
If the prices of petroleum and corn moved in
concert, their variability would have limited effects
on the ethanol industry. Yet, historical movements
in corn and petroleum prices have been largely
unrelated (see Figure 3), leaving revenues and
costs in ethanol production unlinked and causing
large swings in the profitability of ethanol plants
(Figure 5). The magnitude of this problem is not
easily overstated. When the price of corn relative
to the price of petroleum has increased, ethanol
profitability has suffered. Further, this inverse
relationship has become progressively stronger as
ethanol has progressed from a supplement to an
additive to a fuel replacement. As price premiums
for the more inelastic supplement and additive segments eroded and corn prices increased relative
to gasoline, profitability declined more abruptly
(e.g., first in the early 1990s and more recently in
2008; see Figures 3 and 5).
The inverse relationship of corn and petroleum prices suggests that sustained high petroleum (ethanol) and low corn prices could yield
windfall profits for the ethanol industry. At the

same time, any random sustained confluence of
high corn prices and low petroleum (ethanol) prices
could be quite damaging to the U.S. corn ethanol
industry. Hedging could guard against some undesirable corn-to-ethanol (or petroleum) price spreads,
albeit at some cost. Nevertheless, such strategies
can provide only short-term relief because futures
contracts for certain commodities (e.g., corn and
ethanol) may not extend long enough to cover the
sustained trends in relative corn/petroleum prices
that have been observed in the past (see Figure 3);
and if they did, they could be quite costly.3
Probably the most significant “hedge” against
the possibility of unprofitably high relative corn
prices is currently provided by the renewable fuels
mandates. They indirectly link ethanol and corn
prices because blenders must use the required corn
ethanol irrespective of price.4 However, such a
hedge is generally most effective when the mandate
is greater than the productive capacity of the industry. Because the productive capacity of the U.S.
corn ethanol industry has exceeded the mandated
limits up to now, the level of protection afforded
by the RFS remains uncertain.

THE PURSUIT OF EFFICIENCIES
As the U.S. corn ethanol industry has grown
to its current capacity and increasingly competes
with gasoline as a replacement fuel, the pursuit of
efficiency and cost effectiveness has become central to its success and long-term sustainability.
The potential for efficiency gains can be evaluated
only through a careful assessment of the current
state of the industry and of the areas where gains
3

There are also some natural hedges in ethanol production that reduce
the industry’s risk exposure and are worth noting. DDGS and corn
are substitutes and as such their prices are closely correlated. Another
natural hedge, albeit a less pronounced one, is the link between
petroleum and ethanol prices, which helps to drive ethanol prices,
and the cost of natural gas and other fuels that fire ethanol plants.
While such prices tend to move together, the correlation between
petroleum and natural gas prices is not very strong, particularly for
short-term shocks.

4

Several factors may diminish the effective hedge provided by the RFS
against high relative corn prices in any given year. First, fuel blenders
can use renewable identification number credits from previous years
to meet up to 20 percent of the mandated quantities in subsequent
years and may be permitted briefly to fall short. Second, the legislation allows mandates to be waived if broad conditions are met.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

109

Panel Discussion

Figure 6
Industry Growth and Average Firm Size in the U.S. Corn Ethanol Industry
MGY
14,000

Facilities (number)/Average Facility Size (MGY)
200

Existing Capacity (left axis)

180

Average Facility Size (right axis)

12,000

160

Facilities (right axis)
10,000

140
120

8,000

100
6,000

80
60

4,000

40
2,000

20

0

0
1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

SOURCE: RFA, “Industry Statistics”; www.ethanolrfa.org/industry.statistics/.

might be possible. Nevertheless, some initial useful
observations can be made.
With the swift growth of the U.S. ethanol industry in the past decade, the average ethanol plant
size grew rapidly. Facilities built just 10 years ago
were comparatively small in size: The average
facility produced just over 30 million gallons per
year (MGY). A few large ethanol facilities, mostly
wet mills, pushed the average firm size upward.
The average facility size gradually increased until
the mid-2000s and then dramatically accelerated
(Figure 6). By early 2009, the average facility produced 72 MGY (RFA, 2009b), with at least 37 facilities topping 100 MGY (Ethanol Producer Magazine,
2009).
These newer and larger facilities were built to
take advantage of scale economies. Capital costs
per gallon of capacity for a 100 MGY facility are
20 percent lower than those for a 50 MGY facility
(Eidman, 2007). Larger facilities also have lower
operating costs. When corn was priced at $4 per
bushel, a 100 MGY facility had 3.5 percent lower
variable costs than a plant half that size—with the
variable cost savings increasing as corn prices
decreased (Eidman, 2007).
110

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

The continued entry of new ethanol firms during this period of fast growth also produced a dispersed and increasingly competitive industry, as
evidenced by a fast declining Herfindahl-Hirschman
Index (HHI; Figure 7). Much of the pre-2000 ethanol
production capacity was at large wet mills owned
by major agribusinesses. In this environment, the
industry was relatively concentrated, with an HHI
above 1,800 (U.S. Federal Trade Commission, 2008).
As new dry mills were built, the HHI fell rapidly,
ultimately bottoming out in 2007 at 292—indicating minimal levels of industry concentration and
disperse ownership of assets.
Not all ethanol firms have responded well to
the recent economic downturn. Many have experienced financial problems from eroding and even
negative margins and several have filed for bankruptcy, including a few large firms such as VeraSun
(filed in October 2008), Renew Energy (filed in
January 2009), and Panda Ethanol (filed in January
2009). As a result, by the end of 2008 roughly 1.8
billion gallons, or 16 percent, of total U.S. ethanol
production capacity had been idled (RFA, 2009a).
The need to improve the performance of existing
capital assets under the pressure of overcapacity,

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

Figure 7
Entry and Industry Concentration in the U.S. Corn Ethanol Industry, 1999-2008
MGY
16,000
14,000

Existing Capacity (left axis)

HHI
2,000

Capacity Existing and Under Construction (left axis)

1,800

HHI (right axis)

1,600

12,000

1,400

10,000

1,200

8,000

1,000
800

6,000

600
4,000

400

2,000

200
0

0
1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

SOURCE: Authors’ calculations and the U.S. Federal Trade Commission (2008).

uncertain demand, and weak processing margins
has fomented an environment ripe for industry
restructuring and consolidation that will ration
existing assets and capitalize on scale and scope
economies. Given the low level of industry concentration and the dispersed location and ownership
of capital assets, the potential efficiency gains are
large. Sources of such scale and scope economies
include (i) superior management and other human
capital; (ii) improved sourcing of inputs (e.g., yeast,
chemicals, and credit); (iii) centralized grain origination; (iv) advanced supply-chain management
through multiple plant locations; (v) improved
ability to market and price ethanol; (vi) enhanced
potential for development and commercialization
of coproduct value streams; (vii) centralized and
more sophisticated hedging of inputs, outputs,
and spreads; and (viii) increased capacity to manage research and development and regulatory
compliance.
Each of these factors can improve the operational effectiveness and profitability of ethanol
firms. For instance, optimal plant size and location
must account for distance to urban markets where
most ethanol is consumed and rural locations
where corn is sourced and DGGS are used. Consoli-

dation of multiple plants in selected locations
under common ownership could therefore yield
sizeable economic gains through improved market
access and supply-chain optimization. Similarly,
larger firms are generally better positioned to fund
and perform research and development, which
involves large up-front fixed costs. Already, many
of the larger U.S. ethanol firms have active research
programs, some cofunded by the U.S. government,
to develop and implement new technologies such
as cellulosics (which uses the non-starch, typically
fibrous, structural parts of plants to make ethanol)
and fractionation (a process that removes nonfermentable components from fermentable ones).
Consolidation into larger firms could therefore
accelerate innovation, improve efficiency, and
make the industry more competitive.
Industry consolidation has already started, but
at a slow pace. As tight credit markets continue in
the wake of the recent economic crisis, financing
for mergers and acquisitions remains constricted.
As credit markets begin to thaw, consolidation in
the industry could accelerate. The restructuring of
the corn ethanol industry could therefore occur
quite quickly. Efficiency gains from restructuring

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

111

Panel Discussion

and consolidation, however, would likely be
more gradual and ongoing and therefore take
longer to contribute to the competitiveness and
sustainability of the industry.

THE IMPACT OF INNOVATION
Another key source of sustained productivity
gains in the corn ethanol industry is technical innovation. Some of the innovations have been developed by the ethanol industry while others by allied
industries. Indeed, corn has been an attractive
ethanol feedstock due, in large part, to an advanced
and efficient system of breeding, production, and
handling. Between 1980 and 2008, the average U.S.
corn yield rose from 104 bushels per acre to 153
bushels per acre (United States Department of
Agriculture [USDA], 2008a). Over the same period,
processing improvements at ethanol facilities produced steady efficiency gains, raising ethanol yields
from 2.5 gallons a bushel in 1980 to 2.8 gallons a
bushel in 2007 (Wu, 2008). These two improvements alone increased the amount of ethanol
derived from an acre of corn by 62 percent.
The pipeline of future technical innovations
that could improve the cost competitiveness of
corn ethanol production is even more promising.
Historically, farm-level improvements have come
from improved hybrids, precision agriculture,
improved machinery, integrated pest management,
reduced tillage, and other innovations. One recent
addition is biotechnology, which has already
demonstrated its ability to lower production costs,
increase yields, and reduce the environmental
footprint of corn production (Fernandez-Cornejo
and Caswell, 2006; and Kalaitzandonakes, 2003).
Because of such advances, in 2008 four of five corn
acres in the United States were planted with biotech
hybrids (USDA, 2008b). Continuing research and
development promises a burgeoning pipeline of
novel corn traits. While the pipeline builds on the
efficacy of first-generation offerings such as insect
and herbicide resistance, it also promises new traits
such as drought resistance, increased nitrogen
utilization, and improved yields. Ultimately these
technologies promise to accelerate the growth in
corn yields and productivity.
112

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

Innovative technologies that offer significant
productivity gains are also expected at ethanol
facilities and include the following:
• Corn Oil Extraction. With this technology, a
conventional dry mill will be able to remove
corn oil after the ethanol distillation process.
This will not only produce a second coproduct and revenue stream but also decrease
the costs associated with drying DDGS.
• Raw Starch Hydrolysis. With this technology,
increased/improved enzymes eliminate the
need for liquefaction and saccharification;
biotechnology facilitates the hydrolysis
process through corn engineered to produce
amylase enzymes in the seed. High-amylase
corn eliminates the need for additional
enzymes in raw starch hydrolysis.
• Dry Mill Corn Fractionation. This technology separates the starch from nonfermentable
portions of the corn. High-starch slurry
allows for increased ethanol yield and capacity utilization. Corn oil and fiber can also be
separated with this technology.
• Corn Kernel Fiber to Ethanol. In combination with fractionation this technology could
convert fiber to ethanol, further increasing
the ethanol yield.
• Highly Fermentable Corn. This biotechnology
produces corn hybrids with improved fermentation characteristics that allow ethanol
to be produced more efficiently. Existing
highly fermentable corn hybrids derived
from traditional breeding have, on average,
a 5 percent higher starch content, which can
result in a 2.7 percent increase in ethanol
yield (Haefel et al., 2004).
The potential effects of these and other technologies on the efficiency and profitability of
ethanol production is sizeable.
We now measure the potential effects of new
biotech corn traits and certain process engineering
innovations on ethanol production while accounting for all relevant market effects. We use two scenarios to evaluate the potential aggregate yield
effects of new biotech corn traits; however, we
ignore other potential efficiency gains from lower
input use (e.g., pesticides), changes in agronomic
practices (e.g., tillage), and the like.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

Table 2
Potential Impacts of Innovations in Ethanol Production and Operating Returns
Percent change with 1.8% corn
and 1% ethanol yield growth

Percent change with 3.0% corn
and 1% ethanol yield growth

Corn yield (bushels/acre)

2.5

10.2

Dry mill yield (gallons/bushel)

2.8

2.8

Planted area

–0.1

–0.6

Production

0.0

9.5

Total domestic use

Variable

Corn market

1.7

6.7

Fuel

1.9

8.2

Feed

1.9

7.2

Food

0.3

1.0

High-fructose corn syrup

0.0

0.2

4.7

17.4

–2.9

–11.7

Exports
Corn farm price
Ethanol Market
Production

4.4

10.8

–1.0

–2.5

Ethanol revenue

–1.0

–2.5

DDGS revenue

–7.2

–17.5

Corn cost

–5.4

–13.9

7.7

30.1

Ethanol price
Ethanol dry milling returns (per gallon)

Net operating returns

Prevailing long-term trends show that U.S.
corn yields have grown 1.35 percent per year for
the past 40 years (USDA, 2008a). Specific biotechnology innovations and experimental field data
indicate that 1.8 to 3.0 percent growth in yields
might be possible in the near future (e.g., Korves,
2008; and Edgerton, 2008). We use these figures as
the lower and upper bounds for our analysis. To
account for the efficiency gains from process engineering and other innovations that improve the
efficiency of the ethanol plant, we analyze the additional effect of 1.0 percent annual growth in the
ethanol yield per bushel of corn.
As corn innovations are introduced in the
market place, they change the relative productivity
of the crop, and farmers respond through their
planting decisions. These in turn shift the aggregate supplies of corn and other crops, change their
relative prices, and shift their demand. Similar,

though more limited, changes occur in response
to process innovations at the ethanol plant. To
account for such complex market changes, we use
the FAPRI-MU model of crops and biofuel markets
(Thompson, Meyer, and Westhoff, 2008). This
partial-equilibrium model covers supply and
demand quantities, including acreage planted,
production, other domestic uses, trade, stocks,
prices, and policies. In this context we evaluate the
economic implications of the innovation scenarios
discussed above for the 2009-18 period. This empirical analysis allows us to examine the potential
effects of innovation on the supply of ethanol and
the average profitability of the U.S. ethanol industry. The results are presented in Table 2 and are
expressed as changes relative to a baseline where
corn and ethanol yields grow at their historical
averages—1.35 percent and 0.5 percent per year,
respectively.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

113

Panel Discussion

The empirical results from the partialequilibrium analysis suggest that accelerating
corn and ethanol yield growth rates shift corn and
ethanol supplies upward. Given that aggregate corn
demand is somewhat inelastic, when corn prices
decline, demand increases. In domestic markets,
the use of corn for food, feed, and fuel all increases.
Exports of corn increase even faster as export markets respond to movements in U.S. corn prices. The
reduction in corn prices also reduces the cost of
ethanol production, lowering the price of ethanol
and increasing demand for the biofuel. The magnitude of the change is influenced by the responsiveness of demand in the ethanol market. Given that
the industry now supplies the supplement, additive, and the more responsive E10 markets, the outward shift is absorbed by an elastic demand and
the resulting effect on the price of ethanol is small.
The reduced input costs and relatively small
decline in output prices lead to a 7.7 to 30 percent
increase in net operating returns per gallon. It is
worth emphasizing that these effects are over and
above the improvements in operating returns that
are expected with the continued growth of corn
and ethanol yields at their historical rates.
The results of the partial-equilibrium model
illustrate the potentially significant impact of new
technologies on the level of efficiency and profitability of the U.S. ethanol industry. As firms continue to develop and adopt such new technologies,
the industry will become more competitive and
its sustainability will significantly improve.

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
Fueled by government policies and a positive
macroeconomic environment, the U.S. ethanol
industry has experienced strong and ongoing
growth since the turn to this century. Over this
nine-year period, the industry transformed itself
from a niche player to a significant supplier of fuel
to compete with gasoline in the U.S. market. As
the macroeconomic environment worsened in the
later part of 2008, the industry’s growth stalled
and the viability of some of the newly installed
capacity became uncertain as petroleum, ethanol,
and corn prices declined and ethanol processing
margins with them.
114

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

This last stage of the industry cycle has created
an environment where consolidation could follow.
Industry consolidation could yield sizeable efficiency gains from scale and scope economies, as
well as technical improvements and better allocation of resources. A full pipeline of innovations
could bring large productivity gains to the U.S.
ethanol industry—some targeting the operations
of the mill and some its key feedstock—corn.
Together, efficiency gains from industry consolidation and productivity growth from innovation
could strongly improve the competitiveness and
sustainability of the industry.
A possible threat to the stability and sustainability of the industry, however, is its unlinked revenuecost structure, which is increasingly driven by
changes in the relative prices of petroleum and
corn. A random and sustained low-corn, highpetroleum price combination results in windfall
profits for the industry. A similarly random and
sustained high-corn, low-petroleum price combination results in lasting losses. Given the wide
variation in the petroleum and corn markets, this
characteristic could make the industry prone to
boom-bust cycles. This issue has attracted little
attention so far, possibly due to the implicit “hedge”
currently offered by the RFS mandates. As the
industry continues to improve its competitive edge
and grow, effective means for linking costs and
revenues might become necessary to prevent this
subtle industry feature from becoming its Achilles’
heel.

REFERENCES
De Gorter, Harry and Just, David R. “The Economics of
a Biofuel Consumption Mandate and Excise Tax
Exemption: An Empirical Example of the U.S. Ethanol
Policy.” Working Paper 2007-20, Cornell University
Department of Applied Economics and Management,
October 2007.
Edgerton, Michael D. “Increasing Crop Productivity to
Meet Global Needs for Feed, Food, and Fuel.” Plant
Physiology, January 2007, 149, pp. 7-13.
Eidman, Vernon R. “Ethanol Economics of Dry Mill
Plants,” in Corn-Based Ethanol in Illinois and the

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

Panel Discussion

U.S.: A Report from the Department of Agricultural
and Consumer Economics, University of Illinois.
Urbana, IL: University of Illinois at UrbanaChampaign, November 2007; www.farmdoc.uiuc.edu/
policy/research_reports/ethanol_report/.
Ethanol Producer Magazine. “Plant List.” Accessed
January 2009; http://ethanolproducer.com/
plant-list.jsp.
Fernandez-Cornejo, Jorge and Caswell, Margriet. “The
First Decade of Genetically Engineered Crops in the
United States.” U.S. Department of Agriculture,
Economic Research Service Economic Information
Bulletin, 11, April 2006;
www.ers.usda.gov/publications/eib11/eib11.pdf.
Haefele, D.; Owens, F.; O’Bryan, K. and Sevenich, D.
“Selection and Optimization of Corn Hybrids for
Fuel Ethanol Production,” in Proceedings of the
59th Annual Corn and Sorghum Research Conference.
Alexandria, VA: American Seed Trade Association,
December 2004.
Hofstrand, Don. “Tracking Ethanol Profitability.” Ag
Decision Maker, January 2008;
www.extension.iastate.edu/agdm/articles/hof/
HofJan08.html.
Kalaitzandonakes, Nicholas, ed. Economic and
Environmental Impacts of Agbiotech: AP Global
Perspective. New York: Kluwer-Plenum Academic
Publisher, 2003.
Korves, Ross. “The Potential Role of Corn Ethanol in
Meeting the Energy Needs of the United States in
2016-2030.” Illinois Corn Marketing Board, ProExporter Network, October 2008.
Renewable Fuels Association. “Biorefinery Locations.”
Accessed January 2009a;
www.ethanolrfa.org/industry/locations/.
Renewable Fuel Association. “Statistics.” Accessed
January 2009b; www.ethanolrfa.org/industry/statistics/.

and Outlook Research Report 2008-02, Department
of Agricultural and Consumer Economics, University
of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, June 2008;
www.farmdoc.uiuc.edu/marketing/morr/morr_08-02/
morr_08-02.pdf.
Thompson, Wyatt; Meyer, Seth and Westhoff, Pat.
“Model of the U.S. Ethanol Market.” FAPRI-MU
Report 07-08, Food and Agriculture Policy Research
Institute, July 2008; http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/
bitstream/37971/2/FAPRI_MU_Report_07_08.pdf.
Trostle, Ronald. “Global Agricultural Supply and
Demand: Factors Contributing to the Recent Increase
in Food Commodity Prices.” U.S. Department of
Agriculture Economic Research Service Outlook,
May 2008, Report WRS-0801; www.ers.usda.gov/
Publications/WRS0801/WRS0801.pdf.
Tyner, Wallace E. “U.S. Ethanol Policy—Possibilities
for the Future.” Purdue University, Purdue Extension
BioEnergy, January 2007, ID-342-W;
www.ces.purdue.edu/extmedia/ID/ID-342-W.pdf.
U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural
Statistics Service. Quickstats. Washington, DC:
USDA, 2008.
U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural
Statistics Service. Acreage. Washington, DC: USDA,
June 30, 2008.
U.S. Federal Trade Commission. “2008 Report on U.S.
Ethanol Market Concentration.” November 2008;
www.ftc.gov/os/2008/11/081117ethanolreport.pdf.
Westhoff, Peter; Thompson, Wyatt; Kruse, John and
Meyer, Seth. “Ethanol Transforms Agricultural
Markets in the USA.” EuroChoices, 2007, 6(1),
pp. 14-21.
Wu, May. “Analysis of the Efficiency of the U.S. Ethanol
Industry, 2007.” Center for Transportation Research,
Argonne National Laboratory, March 27, 2008.

Sanders, Dwight R.; Irwin, Scott H. and Merrin, Robert P.
“The Adequacy of Speculation in Agricultural Futures
Markets: Too Much of a Good Thing?” Marketing

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . LO U I S R E G I O N A L E C O N O M I C D E V E LO P M E N T

V O LU M E 5 , N U M B E R 1

2009

115