View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Interview with Jacob Mincer
By Claudia Goldin, Dept. of Economics, Harvard University and the NBER
New York City
July 26, 2002
Note: Jacob Mincer asked not to be photographed. The camera was focused on a sofa
and a painting. At times, Flora (Jacob’s wife) was photographed and at the end, various
paintings in the apartment done by Jacob’s and Flora’s son Daniel, who died 20 years
before, were photographed.
Claudia: I am at 448 Riverside Drive, a beautiful place, with Jacob and Flora Mincer and
it is July 26, 2002, in the morning. Jacob is going to tell us about his time at the Bureau
and how he got into economics. Why don’t you start with that?
Flora: July 26th is a special day for him.
Claudia: It is?
Jacob: It is my “second birthday,” the day I arrived in the U.S. in 1948.
Claudia: That is wonderful. This is very meaningful.
Jacob: The history of my studies—before the war [WWII] I studied engineering for about
one year and then the war broke out.
Claudia: You studied engineering in Poland?
Jacob: No, in Czechoslovakia. I was not accepted in Poland. I applied to the Institute
of Technology but they didn’t accept Jews. They accepted 1 out of 100, or something
like that. But I had admission to the School of Engineering in Brno, Czechoslovakia. I
went there in the fall of 1938 and a few months later the Nazis came in, so I did not
continue my studies until 1948 — an interruption of 10 years. In 1948, I got here on a
Hillel Foundation Scholarship. At the time I did not know what I was going to study
because I lost interest in engineering. So I decided to sort of shop around at Emory
[University] for various courses and I thought maybe the social sciences were
meaningful. One thing about the social sciences is that I thought I understood much of
it but one subject about which I understood nothing was economics . . . that was a black
box. That was the reason that I decided to go for it and especially because the
economics teacher at Emory was a very good teacher. He was the one who pushed me
to do graduate work in economics. What he said was: “You either go to Chicago where
you will study with Milton Friedman, who is not yet known but who will be known, or if
you don’t go to Chicago, go to Columbia because they have a linkup with the NBER.
That is the only place that does empirical work in economics.
Claudia: That person was Swenson and his field in economics was what?

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02

1

Jacob: Yes, Swenson. [His field was] price theory. His prediction, his wishes for me
both materialized. First I went to Chicago. But Milton was not there. He was away for
the year. However, Flora was there. That is where we met.
Claudia: [takes a video of Flora.] So you met Flora.
Jacob: She got an offer of residency in radiology at New York in Montefiore e Hospital.
So I had to make a choice—either to study at Chicago and forget about Flora, or go to
New York with her. Of course, the answer is obvious and not just in retrospect. So,
when I got to Columbia I immediately started finding out something about the NBER
and, of course, I needed a job anyway. I found out who in the department was working
at the NBER and who was a staff member. There was Frederick Mills, a statistician,
and I asked him if it was possible to get a job as a research assistant at the NBER. And
he said “I’ll find out about it.” And the next day he told me, “Yes, Ruth Mack is looking
for a research assistant.” And I made an appointment to meet with Ruth Mack. She
was not on the staff of Columbia University; she was full-time at the NBER. At that time,
a lot of people were full-time at the NBER and did not teach.
I came to the interview at the NBER; it was at Columbus Circle on a very high
floor. But despite being on a high floor, it was very dark there. Anyway, I came to Ruth
Mack’s office and what do I see? The whole floor was covered in graphs, and sitting in
the center was a very beautiful woman with a corncob pipe and she asked me a number
of questions. And I asked her a question: “What are these lines on the floor?” She
said: “These are business cycles.” I said: “I don’t see any cycles. I see wiggles that go
on the cycles.” Anyway, she hired me.
Claudia: Even though you were dubious about the way in which they did business
cycles?
Jacob: I didn’t have any idea what was being done so I was very curious and besides I
needed money. But she was very nice and I spent several years working for her.
Claudia: This began in 1951?
Jacob: No, spring of 1952. I think I worked 3 or 4 years for her.
Flora: Our first vacation as a married couple — one week — was occupied by Jacob
going up to her farm in Vermont and leaving me stranded.
Jacob: She had a big barn and a desk for me to work on and she went horseback riding.
She was nice.
Claudia: So this was her project on leather, and boots and shoes?

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02

2

Jacob: Yes, that is right. I was at that point already accustomed to think in terms of
price theory and I couldn’t find any theory in what she was doing. So I kept criticizing
her but she was appreciative.
Claudia: Did you meet others doing similar work on business cycles in the “business
cycle shop” at the NBER?
Jacob: Victor Zarnowitz worked there.
Claudia: Victor arrived in 1952 from Germany where he got his undergraduate and
graduate degrees. [Ed.: Victor Zarnowitz was also a concentration camp survivor.] He
gained entry to the United States fairly late. And others? Who else was at the NBER
then?
Jacob: Don Jacobs — who was not long ago the dean of the Kellogg School [Ed.:
Northwestern]. He worked on financial aspects of business cycles with [Raymond]
Steve Saulnier. He was the research assistant to Saulnier. There was a bunch of other
people.
Claudia: Did you see Simon Kuznets?
Jacob: I was thinking of the research assistants. But, yes. As far as the staff was
concerned, Simon was an important figure.
Flora: You had something to say about Simon Kuznets the other day to me.
Jacob: What was it?
Flora: That you spoke to the Swedes.
Jacob: I can’t take credit for his Nobel but I spent a semester in 1971 in Sweden
teaching labor economics and I talked to the people on the Nobel committee. At that
point they had given the prize only a few years and they gave it to theoreticians and
econometricians. I told them there is a vast field of empirical economics, national
income accounting — a whole new way of thinking about the economy. Of course
Simon got the Nobel Prize, but I am not going to take credit for it.
Of course, Arthur Burns was the ruling dictator.
Claudia: Tell me a bit about Burns, your recollections.
Jacob: Burns, of course, was teaching at Columbia and he was a protégé of Wesley
Mitchell, who was the founder of the Bureau. When I got to Columbia, Mitchell was
either retired or not alive.
Claudia: He wasn’t alive; he died in 1947, I believe.

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02

3

Jacob: So Burns was the head of the Bureau and his right hand was Fabricant and the
second hand was Geoffrey Moore, and that was the troika that ran the Bureau but there
was no question that Burns had the primary power. I will never forget the time when the
article by [Tjalling] Koopmans came out, “Measurement without Theory.” Well, it didn’t
take long for Arthur to write the rebuttal, which Arthur called “Theory without
Measurement.” Before that happened, he invited Koopmans to the NBER for a
conversation. Everybody knew what was going to happen. And when Koopmans
came, people were standing in the corridor, the hallway and trying to listen, to catch the
conversation. They didn’t catch the conversation, but they did catch the tremendous
yelling by Arthur, who completely intimidated Koopmans.
Claudia: Arthur had a way of intimidating people.
Jacob: He tried to intimidate me too.
Claudia: What do you remember about that?
Jacob: In 1960, the Bureau promoted me to staff member and Arthur Burns immediately
offered me a vice presidency. I rejected it because he needed help. I think that Victor
Fuchs accepted it at that point. Anyway I didn’t want any headaches.
Claudia: There would have been administrative responsibilities.
Jacob: And I would have shied away from it.
Claudia: That’s right. Victor headed many things at the Bureau. When you arrived at
the Bureau I think that Burns was still in Washington, because he was in the
Eisenhower administration. He left the Bureau and left Fabricant more in charge. Prior
to that Burns was the director of research, but when he returned Burns became
president and Fabricant was made director of research.
Jacob: [I want to say] something about Burns’s teaching. He was an excellent speaker.
I took his course. That was the year when Hicks’s demand theory came out. So he
used that as a basis for reviewing macro-economic demand theory, which includes
Keynes, Hicks, and a variety of people who published at that time. It was a terrific
lecture course, the first semester. The first semester he didn’t criticize anything. He
just reported and did an excellent job. In the spring semester he criticized everything
from A to Z, all the things he covered in the fall semester. I was tempted to ask him for
my money back. One thing cancelled out the other … it was a very interesting
experience.
Claudia: You know that Friedman was a student of Arthur’s when Burns was at Rutgers
and Milton has enormous respect for Arthur’s mind although he had a slight falling out
with him over wage and price controls.

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02

4

Jacob: Well, the story about Burns and Milton was that Burns was teaching elementary
statistics and at some point Milton pointed out that what he was saying was wrong and
Burns dropped out of teaching statistics.
[all laugh]
Claudia: You said something about the famous piece “Measurement without Theory”
and the rebuttal, “Theory without Measurement.” What did you think of this, as
someone who combined, at the Bureau, theory with measurement? Was there
measurement without theory or not?
Jacob: I felt there was an imbalance. But I couldn’t put my finger on it because I wasn’t
familiar with the theory of business cycles. There was no confrontation of theory with
empirical measurement. There was no support for the empirical … theory wasn’t being
mobilized to attack the data.
Claudia: People weren’t distancing themselves from the data first, and then looking at
these very chaotic series . . . Burns’ books and Mitchell’s books do have nascent
theory, but it wasn’t formalized.
Jacob: It was ad hoc.
Claudia: So, you begin in 1952 working for Ruth. In 1954 were you still working for
Ruth?
Jacob: I was working for her only.
Claudia: Did you get to speak to the others or was there a gulf between the senior
people and the research assistants.
Jacob: They were not inaccessible but I was shy.
Claudia: But you weren’t very shy when you told Ruth that the lines were just a bunch of
squiggles.
[all laugh]
Jacob: And I wasn’t very shy when she didn’t theorize enough, she didn’t put things in a
theoretical framework.
Claudia: At that time did you come across the work of Friedman and Kuznets and
Friedman’s work by himself? You must have had a nascent interest in distribution.
Was it sparked by their work?
Jacob: Their work had a very big impact on me.

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02

5

Claudia: Tell me about it.
Jacob: At Columbia my interest was in wage determination. Why do people have
different wages? Why were there wage differentials? I was approaching it like a
Bureau person by looking at various comparisons — by industry, occupation, age, sex,
race. I had chapters along those lines. There was a fellow student of mine, named Al
Patrinas. He didn’t work at the Bureau but he was a very smart guy and we used to
discuss our dissertations in progress (I forget what he did). But when I told him what I
was doing he said, “That isn’t the way you should do it; you should look for a unifying
theory.” He also suggested looking up the book by Kuznets and Friedman which was
Friedman’s dissertation [Ed.: Income from Independent Professional Practice]. So
when I read this book it took me back to Adam Smith and then I realized that all the
comparisons I was making had as a basic principle education and age. If you pushed
the comparisons, each one of them had underlying differences in human capital.
Claudia: Would you have used that term, “human capital” at that point?
Jacob: Yes, I used it immediately.
This is quite interesting. This was like a revelation. That same afternoon we met
again after I read the book and I had this principle established, written out and shown
with empirical data. My sponsor, [Harold] Barger, immediately said “this is great” and
sent a copy to Ted Schultz. I didn’t know there was a whole industry brewing in
Chicago involving economic growth and human capital. He [Schultz] was looking at
wage differentials over time and I was looking across people. It is basically the same
subject. I had tremendous satisfaction writing it. It took me a few days to turn around
all the material I had into an organized analysis of wage differentials. I then got the offer
from Ted Schultz to come to Chicago for a post-doctoral fellowship
Claudia: What year was that?
Jacob: 1957. Then I immediately went to Chicago.
Claudia: So, you were working on this dissertation for a fairly long time and then you
saw the light and suddenly all these chapters moved around and had an organizing
structure. That is a wonderful thing to remember this moment of seeing the light.
Jacob: Absolutely. But when I got to Chicago Gregg Lewis took me under his wing,
proclaiming that I was a labor economist. I was very insulted because labor economics
had a very bad reputation as a subject that never touched economics.
Claudia: Because it was institutional, labor unions.
Jacob: Right. I think that Samuelson made some crack about labor economics “the last
refuge of the scoundrels.” I was taken aback when Gregg Lewis told me I was a labor
economist. I never took a course in labor economics.

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02

6

Claudia: So, prior to that you thought of yourself as an economist who knew theory.
How would you have described yourself?
Jacob: Applied price theory — whatever the topic might be. But then the book by Milton
on the Consumption Function was a tremendous revelation as well — how to do
empirical research. Very different from what the Bureau was doing. Setting up your
model and milking the various implications, and the principle I got out of that was that
empirical work isn’t just estimating a parameter, but drawing out implications that are
apparently completely unrelated yet are caught in the net of that particular model. And
that has been my procedure ever since.
Claudia: So, you go to Chicago and Gregg takes you under his wing and declares that
you are a labor economist. Then what happens?
Jacob: Then I decided to sit in the courses of labor economics. Gregg Lewis was very
enlightening, the way he tackled various questions and Al Rees taught at the same
time. And Al Rees spent that particular quarter reporting on the book by Clarence Long.
Claudia: I’m glad we have gotten up to that part because Clarence Long was part of the
NBER and he was very different from what was generally done at the Bureau.
Jacob: He was different but his empirical work didn’t have a theoretical background. It
was interesting, very interesting. One of the questions that Al Rees kept coming back to
was the labor force participation of women, because there was this paradox that if the
husband’s income was high the wife was unlikely to be in the labor force but over time
income grew, for both husband and wife, and there was an increase in participation
rather than a decrease, as you would have expected. Neither Gregg nor Al Rees had
answers to this question. They kept on coming up with all kinds of hypotheses that
partially illuminated the story but basically they did not have an answer. Again, there
was one particular day when I was sitting in Al Rees’s class and I asked myself, “What
about taking two variables rather than one?” We had income and prices or wages.
Shouldn’t that tell what was going on? It could in principle, if the price effect was
stronger than the income effect, but then you have to bring in the family. So after a few
weeks I had a rough model and I looked at the data and it looked very promising. So I
went to Gregg Lewis and I told him what my approach would be and Gregg didn’t take
long to say “this is the right approach.” He immediately invited me to a conference,
NBER, which took place at Princeton in 1960.
Claudia: That was the 1962 volume.
Jacob: Yes. Clarence Long was my discussant and he was the most complimentary
discussant I ever experienced.
Claudia: He was a very nice person.

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02

7

Jacob: Yes. In general everybody was very positive about my findings. Everybody was
happy about them. In fact, when I finished I got a standing ovation, I mean applause.
Claudia: Any reaction would be very good. Now, we are going to come back to the
NBER in part because you then come back but I want to point out that you go to
Chicago in 1957 and Gary goes to Columbia in 1957. Here you are the two people who
will come back together. ... You hadn’t met him at Chicago. Had you met him before?
Jacob: No. But his reputation preceded him. I was told all kinds of stories about Gary,
about his approach to demographic economics, something completely new to me, and
the fact that he had already written two published articles while an undergrad and the
other fact that when Gary applied to Chicago for graduate work, [Jacob] Viner, who was
his sponsor, wrote a letter to the people at Chicago saying “Gary is the best student I
have ever had,” which insulted a lot of people.
[laugh]
Claudia: One has to be very careful.
Jacob: Anyway, I almost stayed at Chicago because … I was made an offer during that
fellowship year but I ran into competition with Zvi Griliches.
Claudia: I’m glad that we are bringing up Zvi’s name because I wanted to do that. Tell
me about that.
Jacob: Zvi didn’t believe my dissertation at first and then he didn’t believe that I would
get an offer with approximately the same salary that he had and he protested to Gregg
Lewis, who was in charge of these matters, and it boiled down to half a thousand or a
thousand a year
Claudia: That was a lot at that time.
Jacob: So Gregg Lewis … I told him how much I wanted, which was something like half
a thousand, similar to Zvi, higher or lower I forget. And Gregg said he was constrained,
he couldn’t offer me more. So, I thought if they couldn’t offer me more it wasn’t worth
my while. I took it as a vote of no confidence. Under those conditions, I didn’t want to.
Claudia: So Gregg was chair of the department? No Schultz?
Jacob: Schultz was chair of the department and Gregg did the dirty work.
Claudia: Gregg did a lot of dirty work; what I mean is that he spent a lot of time with
students, even with those whom no one else wanted. He took all the dissertations and
made them one notch better. We’re all grateful to Gregg for that. He was wonderful to
all of us. So you spent this wonderful year at Chicago. Flora, were you there too?

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02

8

Flora: Yes. I wasn’t working full time then. I had finished my residency. I worked for
one year at an enormous salary for that time, $10,000.
Jacob: The work on participation of women benefited from my observing Flora.
Claudia: Very good. Your salary went up, but her salary went up even more so she was
pulled back into the labor force. Very good. Then there was this decision, and your
mind is thinking about female labor supply and households and how they interact. Then
the year is over.
Jacob: Yes, and we go back to New York. And I immediately made an appointment to
see Gary.
Claudia: You are at City College as an associate professor. You had been an
instructor.
Flora: An unknown.
Jacob and Flora: I had the longest title, assistant substitute tutor, renewable monthly,
which I didn’t know.
Claudia: So you come back to New York and you are at City College and Columbia
makes you an offer and you go in 1959.
Jacob: Again I run into competition with Zvi. Columbia made him an offer but he didn’t
accept. So I owe him two decisions.
Claudia: You come back to Columbia and renew your relationship with the NBER.
Jacob: Yes. The Bureau promoted me to staff member. I was very eager to meet Gary
because I had heard all these things about him. So I met him for lunch and we made it
a custom to meet for lunch once a week, each week. The first thing I was very curious
about was his reaction to my dissertation. He was already planning a project on
investment in education. He had an article in 1960. The first thing he told me was that
there were a lot of weak spots in my dissertation that could benefit from a lot more work.
[laugh]
Claudia: I’m laughing because Gary never holds anything back.
Jacob: It was an eye-opener to me because I thought I had finished it. And then our
conversation revolved around research in that area. There was another NBER
conference on investment in human capital where Gary had his theoretical chapter
unifying education and job training and I had an empirical part on job training using his
theory at that point, and [George] Stigler had economics of information.

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02

9

Claudia: Stigler was at Columbia and also at the NBER. Stigler had done nascent work
on human capital at the NBER and something on education. There was also his work
on wage differentials for teachers and professors, and his work on domestic servants. I
say nascent because he was asked to do these projects, but his heart doesn’t appear to
have actually been in it. It was flat.
Jacob: Didn’t have much of an impact. Incidentally, Stigler was my ally. It should be
known that Stigler never complimented a student for his work. He always looked for
criticism. He was on my dissertation committee. He read the draft of my dissertation.
Ruth Mack told me that George said it was a “very good dissertation.” He wouldn’t say
it to your face.
Flora: He did, 50 years later.
Jacob: In 1991, when I got an honorary doctorate from Chicago, we had a big party at
Bob Fogel’s apartment. George came over and said “that was a great dissertation.”
During the defense of the dissertation one of the people on the committee was a
mathematical statistician named … I forget the name … he immediately launched an
attack against me saying that he didn’t find any tests of significance in any of the
statistics. First of all I was using Census data. But even if I were using a sample it
would always be significant because of the large sample size. George said, “When you
take on a dissertation you should read it first.” The guy got so insulted he walked out.
Claudia: So you come back and there was a veritable human capital team meeting up at
Columbia and also at the Bureau/ Gary had a position at the NBER, you are just getting
a position at the NBER, Stigler is at the NBER. Victor Fuchs is at the NBER. Who am I
missing in 1961? Tom Juster?
Jacob: Finis Welch, Sherwin Rosen. Sherwin was in NYC for a while—a year, then he
would come during the summer. I was just about finishing my book Schooling,
Experience, and Earnings, and Sherwin was the main reader for the Bureau, also
Welch. There were lots of discussions going on.
Claudia: But that brings us a decade later.
Jacob: The late 1960s.
Claudia: This group working on human capital—it constituted the founding of human
capital at the NBER. You were working on these various subjects having to do with
education, training, the female labor force, family decisions, all coming together very
nicely. Gary is working on similar topics.
Jacob: It is not correct to say that I was working alone. I had discussions with Gary
every day. He was bouncing ideas off me and vice versa. There was one joint article,
which got lost. It was on rational expectations. In 1963 there was a memorial book for
Yehuda Grunfeld. In that book there is an article by Milton on the consumption function

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02 10

where he uses the kinds of weights that [Philip]Cagan uses, backward expectations and
he was trying to get the consumer discount rate out of this. Gary and I asked: “Why go
backwards, why not go forwards?” Let’s assume that people on average have the right
guesses. That was in the1960s. We divided the job into two parts. One by me and one
by him. I finished my part and sent it to Gary and that was the last I heard of it. I asked
Gary where it was and he said he didn’t have it. It took several decades for Gary to find
it in his files. He found my part and he sent it to me. But it was no longer of interest
because Bob Hall had done something similar. That was the only article we tried to
write jointly and it didn’t work out. There is some message there. I don’t know what.
Claudia: I take from reading the annual reports that Gary was made the head by Sol
Fabricant of the project on education and you had money from Carnegie.
Jacob: I don’t think I got money.
Claudia: I think you thank Carnegie in some of your papers, maybe for research
assistants. Every year people, such as Gary, write in the annual reports that they thank
a foundation and they promise various things. Every year they promise the same thing.
There weren’t many people he [Gary] reported on. For example, Al Fishlow, who was
doing a historical study that Al never really finished. Tell me a bit about human capital
at the NBER. Who else was working on human capital? Did you feel that Fabricant,
Geoff Moore, and Burns were pleased about the human capital group?
Jacob: Fabricant and Moore were open-minded. Burns was a little bit dissatisfied
because he felt it was a move toward theory. He felt unhappy about it. Exactly why, I
don’t know.
Claudia: Maybe it wasn’t his agenda. His agenda was macro and business cycles.
Jacob: Maybe that is right.
Claudia: Who else was there?
Jacob: I mentioned before, Sherwin Rosen.
Claudia: Do you remember Tom Juster having any importance in the group?
Jacob: Tom Juster was doing consumer expectations. It is interesting. In 1960 when I
was appointed to the staff I replaced a statistician name Millard Hasting. So my initial
task as a staff member was to help people who did statistical procedures. That’s how I
got involved with Tom Juster. He was doing things on consumer expectations.
Claudia: You edited a volume on Economic Forecasts and Expectations. That seems a
little odd. Right?
[laugh]

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02 11

Jacob: Yes. It came out of consulting at the NBER including students of mine, like
Stanley Diller on the term structure of interest rates and Rosanne Cole on measurement
of GNP where she was looking at the revisions.
[Claudia turns off tape and gets a new one]

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02 12

Claudia: I’m back with Jacob and Flora Mincer and some delicious apricots and we are
into the 1960s and the beginnings of human capital. This was a vibrant time, a change
at the NBER. There was still the business cycle shop, people working on productivity,
but now there is also a group working on theory with measurement, training, education,
human capital, the labor force, bringing people in because of money from the Carnegie
Foundation. You had wonderful students at Columbia. Think back and tell me how
often you went to the Bureau.
Jacob: We [Gary and I] went every day. Every day that was free of teaching, but even
days when we taught, we often went to the Bureau. This was a wonderful period and
we had conversations with people in the group every day.
Claudia: When you say the group, this is you and Gary. This is around 1964. Who else
is in the group? Is Victor in the group?
Jacob: Victor wasn’t doing work on this precise topic. He did it in terms of health
economics, but it was part of human capital too. I mentioned before Sherwin [Rosen].
Claudia: Then there are students. Who do you think about in the 1960s as being the
students who were working at the Bureau?
Jacob: I should have that list.
Claudia: Reuben [Gronau]?
Flora: I could get the list from the conference.
Claudia: Yes. Bob Michael?
Flora: We were living in Mount Vernon at the time and we went on our five-month trip in
1964 with the three children to Israel, Greece, Johannesburg, and South America. You
[Jacob] actually went a month earlier to Argentina and then we met at the airport. It was
a double purpose. One, to see the diaspora of Jacob’s family and the other, to
coordinate it with meeting economists, and working and teaching in different places.
Claudia: I see. Very meaningful trip.
Flora: We took a boat across the South Atlantic from Capetown to Rio.
Claudia: So you never saw Kuznets at the Bureau then?
Jacob: No. Kuznets was at Hopkins and then he went to Penn. He had contact with
Dick Easterlin.
Claudia: Did you see Dick at all?

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02 13

Jacob: Yes.
Claudia: Did you talk to Dick about human capital, demography?
Jacob: He was more interested in demography. He was not quite sympathetic to the
framework that Gary and I used on the family. But he was interested and interesting.
Claudia: In many ways, it was you, Gary, students, and a couple of visitors. What is
interesting is just how large a change there was at the NBER on the basis of two large
figures.
Jacob: It was basically an addition to what they [NBER] used to do before because they
didn’t stop.
Claudia: Right. Did you get together with others at the NBER at the time and was there
any cross-fertilization of ideas? I’m trying to understand how the NBER was functioning
then as this business cycle shop and this other group. Did you get together? Did you
have lunch with various people? Did you meet Arthur?
Jacob: We always had lunch in a group and discussed all these things. At the moment,
I don’t remember all the names.
Claudia: Did you talk a lot to Fabricant about what you were working on? Did he give
you ideas or was there somewhat of a divide between the people who did business
cycles and productivity and human capital?
Jacob: Fabricant was interested in my labor supply studies and I was interested in his
productivity studies, so we used to discuss these things. What came of it, I don’t know.
Zvi Griliches spent a year there.
Claudia: Before we end, let me just ask you one other question. We’re in the 1960s and
big changes are going to happen at the end of the 1960s at the NBER. You were
interested in what you were doing, what Gary was doing, what this group was doing. I
don’t know if you took a larger interest in what was happening at the Bureau about the
fact that there was a sense that Arthur was losing his hold on the NBER and its
direction. Were you concerned and interested in that?
Jacob: I felt that the Bureau was losing its character. It was going to be doing what all
the other economists were doing in various universities, except they’re going to try to
monopolize the market. To me, it looked like the end of what was characteristic to the
NBER.
Claudia: How would you define what was characteristic of the NBER?
Jacob: Large-scale empirical work.

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02 14

Claudia: Also, many people have told me and in recollections that I have read, that the
beauty of the NBER was that you could work on what you wanted to work on and for a
long time. It wasn’t like working in the government or a private concern. It was serious.
Jacob: Yes. Projects could go on for a very long time.
Claudia: Right. Something is happening and you sense it. There’s something fading at
the Bureau. How did you sense that? What seemed to be the problem?
Jacob: It simply meant that the Bureau was going to consist of individuals doing their
own work and there was no plugging in into something bigger. The style would be
model building, both theoretical and econometric. In other words, there was no unity
anymore.
Claudia: You date this somewhere around 1966?
Jacob: No. It was much later.
Claudia: If it’s later, it’s after Burns leaves. Burns leaves in 1967, 1968. This was the
transition to John Meyer. Did the switch mean anything to you or was it meaningless?
Jacob: We felt it was the end of the Bureau as we knew it. You were on your own. The
NBER is helpful as an overhead infrastructure, but there is no such thing as NBER
style, purpose. It just became individualized.
Claudia: This is with the transition to John that something was lost. Then we move to
John and something was perhaps further lost. It’s an interesting transition.
Jacob: John Meyer was an imperialist trying to expand the Bureau to its maximum, not
in terms of content.
Claudia: He had grand visions. He is an extraordinary person, an entrepreneur in many
ways. He has had many different scholarly lives.
You have been extremely helpful, Jacob.
Jacob: Not really because I don’t remember a lot of things.
Claudia: Nobody remembers everything. That’s the point. It’s a collective. That’s what
the NBER is. No one’s an individual at the NBER.
[laugh]
Let me end by thanking you very much and Flora for having me in this beautiful house.

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02 15

Flora wanted me to take some of the wonderful pictures in their house. Tell me a little
bit about the picture I am focusing on.
Flora: It happens to have a cat skull, which I got from my father. It went through the
family.
Claudia: That is Felix domesticus?
Flora: Well it’s a cat skull that was in the family. Not our own cat, just a skull. It’s the
painting I like but it also has the connection.
[camera moves to another painting]
I like this switch.
Claudia: A piece of very interesting realism. Should I follow you around?
Flora: Just in here.
[moves to kitchen]
These are his self-portraits. This is my favorite self-portrait.
Claudia: So tell me his name.
Flora: Daniel Mincer. He was probably around 20 here. This was after his heart
operation.
[camera moves to another painting]
This is one of our family favorites. He did all of them. Since you were taking the ones
in the other room which are less unusual, I wanted you to have a little bit of this.
Claudia: I like this very much.
[Claudia turns off tape]

Goldin interview with Jacob Mincer 7/26/02 16