View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
ON
HISTORICAL FACTORS IN LONG RUN GROWTH

THE MEANING OF MONEY IN THE
GREAT DEPRESSION

Hugh Rockoff

Historical Paper No. 52

NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
December, 1993

I must thank Andres Liivak for able research assistance and the Rutgers University Research
Council for financial support. The comments received at a seminar at Lehigh University and
at the Columbia seminar in economic history were extremely valuable. The remaining errors
are mine. This paper is part of NBER's research program in the Historical Development of
the American Economy. Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the
National Bureau of Economic Research.




NBER Historical Paper #52
December 1993

THE MEANING OF MONEY IN THE
GREAT DEPRESSION

ABSTRACT
The quality of the money stock declined during the banking crises of the early 1930s.
Bank deposits did not serve as a secure short-term store of purchasing power for use in an
emergency as well as they had previously, and during the periods of restricted deposits in late
1932 and early 1933, bank deposits could not fulfill their basic function of being a medium of
exchange. This paper presents some evidence to show that the decline in the quality of the
money stock contributed to the severity of the contraction.

Hugh Rockoff
Department of Economics
Rutgers University
New Brunswick, NJ. 08903
and NBER




2
Introduction
This paper argues that a neglected cause of the Great Depression was the decline in the
quality of the stock of money.1 In other words, it argues that part of the decline in velocity from
1931 to 1933 is a measurement error: the quality-constant stock of money declined more rapidly
than the measured stock, and the velocity of the quality-constant stock less rapidly. The idea that
the quality of the stock of money declined is in some ways so obvious that someone unfamiliar
with the debate over the causes of the Depression will wonder why it needs to be pointed out.
Comparisons with standard accounts of the Depression, however, show that the quality-of-money
factor has been neglected and, I believe, that as a result too much has been made of nonmonetary factors such as the availability of credit, and possible technological or trade shocks.
In principle the effect of an erosion in quality could be either a reduction in spending or
an increase. The direction of the effect depends on the availability of substitutes for bank
deposits, the time for adjustment, and so on. This is familiar. In the short-run a decline in the
quality of gasoline (fewer miles-per-gallon) might lead people to spend more on gasoline, but
in the long run, when more adjustments are possible (purchasing more fuel efficient automobiles,
moving close to public transportation, and so on), less might be spent on gasoline. Something
similar is true with money. In the short run a decline in the quality of deposits might lead people
to accumulate more cash, gold, or other safe assets. In the long run, however, they might find
ways to economize on their holdings of liquid assets.

1

I must thank Andres Liivak for able research assistance and the Rutgers University
Research Council for financial support. The comments received at a seminar at Lehigh
University and at the Columbia seminar in economic history were extremely valuable. The
remaining errors are mine.




3
A related distinction is between a once-and-for-all change in quality and a continuous
change. A change in quality that was assumed to be over and done would lead people to try to
rebuild their liquidity. But the same change in quality might operate in the opposite direction if
it was taken as part of an ongoing movement to lower and lower quality. Which type of change
characterized the Depression is an empirical issue. Did people imagine themselves, after each
banking crisis, on a lower floor (however shaky) or on an escalator moving steadily downward?
The argument sketched below assumes that in each phase of the banking crisis consumers
behaved as if they could restore their previous levels of liquidity by accumulating monetary
assets that appeared to be safe. In retrospect this behavior may have been a mistake, but ex-ante
these beliefs may have been rational.
The argument is developed in the following way. Section 1 describes Henry Simons's
theory of the Depression, the inspiration for my interpretation. Section 2 describes the nature
of the decline in the quality of deposits, and how economic activity was affected. Section 3
contains my preferred procedure for estimating the empirical magnitude of the quality effect. It
examines the growth of restricted deposits before the federal bank holiday, proposes a
conjectural adjustment to the stock of moeny[money]to account for restricted deposits, and tests the
adjusted money stock in equations designed to explain the Depression. Section 4 reports the
result of an alternative approach to estimating the effects of quality deterioration. It examines
the shift into safe alternatives to deposits and uses these shifts as proxies for quality
deterioration. Section 5 briefly assesses the consistency of a quality-decline interpretation of the
Great Depression with the experience in other banking crises. Section 6 compares and contrasts
the quality-decline interpretation with several well known accounts of the Depression. Section




4
7 is a brief conclusion. The appendix explores the divisia index and related indexes of the money
supply.

1. Henry Simons's Theory of the Great Depression
The argument made here is not a new one: it is an updated version Henry Simons's
theory of the Depression. Simons must be counted as one of the leading monetary economists
of the century. In particular, his famous essay on "Rules vs. Authorities" set in motion a long
train of research that continues to play a major role in monetary economics. The Depression
dominated Simons's view of how money worked and how the monetary system should be
reformed.
But despite his influence on monetary economics, his view of the causes of the Depression
receives almost no attention today.
Simons accepted the quantity theory of money. But he laid great stress on what he called
near moneys or practical moneys. His version of the quantity theory, I believe, could be written
as follows.2
(1)
where C is currency
TB is treasury bills
D is deposits
TD is time deposits

2

I provide a more detailed defense of this interpretation of Simons, and a sketch of the
relationship of it to his policy proposals in Rockoff (1993).




5
CP is commercial paper
and the

's are coefficients representing the moneyness of assets (a number

between 0 and 1 with

= 1 for cash).

I have listed here assets that Simons referred to explicitly in his writings (Simons 1948, 326),
but he might well have included other assets in his definition, hence the ellipsis at the end of the
parentheses.
The Depression, according to Simons, was caused by the banking crises and the
associated collapse in the quantity of money substitutes and near moneys and the collapse in the
"degree of their general acceptability," the betas in equation 1 (Simons 1948, 164). The decline
in conventionally measured stocks, such as Ml or M2, was, in Simons's view, only part of the
decline in liquidity that caused the Depression.
Simons's policy proposals, by the way, followed directly from this interpretation. Yet
few economists of similar persuasion pondering equation (1) would have been able, I suspect,
to make the leap that Simons made. He proposed reforms that would lead to a "financial good
society" by eliminating all of the terms in equation (1) that had caused trouble in the 1930s. His
proposed changes were as follows. (1) Eliminate TB. All debt issued by the government would
be in the form of cash or consols. (2) Eliminate CP and all similar forms of near money by
permitting only equity financing of private enterprises. (3) Then set

and

= 1, and hold

the sum of C and D constant through 100 percent bank reserves. In effect these reforms would
reduce the quantity equation from (1) to (2) HV = Py
where H is highpowered money, cash issued by the government.
The interpretation of Simons offered here differs somewhat from one interpretation that




6
has a strong claim to be authoritative. Don Patinkin (1972) depicts Simons as essentially a
"classical" quantity theorist in the Irving Fisher tradition and makes no mention of an expanded,
quality-adjusted definition of money. Possibly, Simons was concentrated on conveying the
received doctrine in the lectures from which Patinkin quotes because they were given in an
introductory course.3 My interpretation also differs, although in a smaller degree, from the
interpretation offered by Milton Friedman in his famous paper "the Monetary Theory and Policy
of Henry Simons" (Friedman, 1969). Friedman's point was that Simons had given too much
attention to the decline in the Beta's in equation (1) and not enough to the decline in
conventionally measured monetary aggregates and the associated decline in V. The empirical
work below would seem to be consistent with ranking the decline in the measured stock ahead
of the decline in quality. Friedman also emphasized that Simons had underestimated the perverse
behavior of the Federal Reserve.
In support of my interpretation, however, I can cite Roland McKean, who was a student
of Simons. According to McKean [1951, p. 66]"... in elaborating the quantity theory of money,
economists tended to obscure the other balance-sheet items and to focus attention on the
influence of one particular asset — money -- which had to be defined arbitrarily. Some — Henry
Thornton was one of the earliest, and Henry Simons one of the most persuasive — sought further

3

It is small jump from Fisher's equation to equation (1). Fisher wrote the quantity theory as
(1) MV + M'V' = PT
Divide through by V and we have
(2) M + M'(VVV) = (1/V)PT
Thus the betas in text equation (1) correspond to (V7V). In this context Simon's use of the term
"degree of effective circulation" to refer to (V7V) and an increase in "hoarding,"to refer to a
change in V, seems natural. Perhaps the major difference between Simons and Fisher was
Simons's willingness to expand the left side of (1) to include a wide variety of M's.




7
in the balance sheet for influences on the level of spending and emphasized that liquid assets
other than those defined as money were near-moneys or money substitutes." Indeed, McKean
[1951, p. 83] believed that Simons "may have exaggerated the significance of near-moneys."
Finally, I should note that Simons did not ignore the credit-intermediation function of
banks that has come to play an important role in recent interpretations of the Depression. Simons
argued that the Depression was aggravated by the "forced liquidation" of loans as banks
scrambled for liquidity. For that reason he advocated restricting banks to long-term investments,
thus freeing them from an "illusion of liquidity" (Simons 1948, 328). Simons, however, viewed
forced liquidation as part and parcel of the general destruction of the moneyness of near moneys:
Banks cut lending during the crisis in order to rebuild their liquidity position, the same reason
individuals cut their spending.
The notion that the quality of the money stock needs to be included in any full accounting
of monetary phenomena is not unique, of course, to Henry Simons. It is concern about quality,
for example, that has motivated many attempts over the years to compute weighted aggregates
of the money stock. Typically, however, concern about quality has surfaced in the context of
long-term changes in velocity. Bordo and Jonung (1987), for example, investigated a closely
related phenomena, the spread of commercial banking, in their international comparison of longterm changes in velocity. What is unique to Simons is his stress on rapid quality deterioration
during the banking crises of the 1930s.

2. Quality Decline and its Effect on the Economy
The decline in quality was produced by the waves of bank failures in 1931-1933. Its most




8
dramatic manifestation was a restriction on withdrawals. One way this occurred was through the
enforcement of a notice of withdrawal requirement on a time deposit that would not have been
enforced before the crisis. But during 1932 demand deposits were increasingly affected. A bank,
either on its own volition or under the shield of a local, state, or eventually, a federal
proclamation, would limit cash withdrawals or transfers according to some simple rule: say no
more than 5 percent of the account could be withdrawn until further notice.
The channel through which such restrictions would influence economic activity is
straightforward: money could not perform its basic function of mediating exchange. Here is how
H. Parker Willis and John M. Chapman (1934, pp. 11-12) described the effect of the
restrictions.
"It was speedily evident that, through lack of currency, the
business of several communities was likely to be brought almost
to a stop. The issue of some form of local medium of exchange
was thus essential, and such a medium was afforded by substitute
money of various classes, .... It remained true that, as the holiday
spread rapidly over the country, there was less and less possibility
of maintaining inter-community trading and exchange of goods. A
national currency was lacking."

One way of coping with the absence of a medium of exchange is for local communities
and private firms to issue scrip, and in fact this was done on a large scale. A number of
communities even tried Irving Fisher's plan for stamped money. In principle, the stock of money
is understated during this period by the omission of scrip from the standard statistics. But the
more important point is that these makeshifts are a sign of the inability of the banking system
to provide an adequate medium of exchange.
Although restricted deposits were the most dramatic manifestation of quality




9
deterioration, the phenomenon was more general. The threat of restriction or bank failure hung
over all deposits, especially those in western and midwestern banks, and reduced the value of
deposits as stores of purchasing power for use in emergencies. As a result money holders shifted
funds into safe alternatives to deposits.
There were a variety of safe alternatives. (1) Currency. The currency-deposit ratio started
to rise sometime after the first banking crisis. As a substitute for deposits, however, currency
had its limits. One was simply the limit on the number of safety-deposit boxes. Some depositors
withdrew part of their deposits in the form of cash and placed it in safety deposit boxes in the
same institution. Once the stock of safety deposit boxes was exhausted, withdrawing cash
became a less attractive alternative. Currency was also inconvenient as a substitute for very large
deposits in making transactions, particularly interregional transactions. (2) Postal Savings. The
ratio of postal savings to deposits behaved in a fashion similar to that of currency. Postal
savings, like currency, were an imperfect substitute for large active accounts because postal
savings were not subject to check. (3) Treasury Bills. The sharp decline in the yield on treasury
bills probably reflects, at least in part, the "flight to quality" as deposit holders attempted to
convert their assets into a safer form. The ratio of the yield on 3 month treasury bills to the
yield on 20 year treasury bonds fell from 1.4 in September 1929 (4.89 percent divided by 3.50
percent) to .56 in June 1930, to .20 in June 1931, to .07 in June 1933, and to .05 in June 1933.
The ratio remained low for the rest of the decade. In June 1939, the ratio was .02 (.05 percent
divided by 2.54 percent). (Cecchetti, 1988, 1131-35).
(4) Deposits in safe regions of the country or individual banks with a reputation for
soundness. Angell (1936, 66-68) notes that the New York and Philadelphia Federal Reserve




10
districts gained deposits relative to other districts after 1929. He attributes this to the movement
of funds from the interior seeking safety. According to Hoover and Ratchford (1951, 171) large
insurance and railroad companies transferred working balances from small local banks in the
South to larger safer banks nearer their home offices. In Chicago deposits flowed from suburban
banks into the Loop banks. To some extent, of course, even without these alternatives one could
achieve greater safety by diversify one's portfolio of bank deposits. Presumably, handling one's
transactions with accounts in a number of banks would be less convenient, and would require
a greater total amount of deposits.
(5) Gold. Even some apparently safe assets, such as federal reserve notes, might appear
to some money-holders as less desirable than gold, especially during the final phase of the
banking crises. For one thing the international value of federal reserve notes might depreciate.
The existence of these close but imperfect substitutes is adds an important dimension the
argument. If consumption was the closest substitute for bank deposits, depositors would increase
their spending on goods and services when the quality of deposits fell. If safe assets were a
perfect substitute for deposits, then a decrease in quality of deposits would simply produce a
one-for-one substitution of alternative assets for deposits. But if the alternatives were a close but
imperfect substitute then a decrease in quality would lead to an attempt to build up total liquid
balances putting downward pressure on spending.
The following example illustrates the kind of reaction necessary for the last argument to
go through. Someone living in the suburbs of Chicago held $5,000 in deposits in a local bank
and $1,000 in cash before the banking crises. After the crises they decided to move say $4,000
into a bank in the Loop (keeping $1,000 in the local bank) and to increase their cash holdings




11
to $2,000 to conduct local transactions and to provide additional safety. To accumulate the
additional liquid assets they had to cut back current consumption. Separate decisions to increase
cash balances then would have had a depressing effect on the economy, would have produced
a contraction of bank deposits, and might have prevented the intended accumulation of additional
liquid balances.
The story, as I have told it, is cast in terms of a householder; the same story could be
told about business deposits. Hoover and Ratchford (1951, 171) claim that it is well known that
"during depressions large industrial and commercial companies become more liquid as
inventories, receivables, etc. are reduced by conversion into cash." Part of this is explained by
an increased demand for money occasioned by the risk and uncertainty created by the
Depression. But part is explained by the failure of working balances in weak banks to supply
as much liquidity as they did before the banking crises.

3. Restricted Deposits: A Sensitivity Analysis
A rigorous application of Henry Simons's approach would include restricted deposits in
the definition of money, but at a reduced weight reflecting their reduced liquidity. The
conventional approach, which weights equally all assets within the monetary aggregate, that I
will follow, would exclude restricted deposits because they resemble risky long-term securities
more than they resemble deposits convertible on demand into cash.4 The standard estimates

4

The Commercial and Financial Chronicle (February 18, 1933, p. 1132) reported that in
Youngstown Ohio the passbooks of local building and loan associations that had restricted
withdrawals were being sold like stocks and bonds by licensed brokers. It was said that in
Cleveland unlicensed brokers had been buying passbooks at 25 cents to 75 cents on the dollar.
The passbooks were worth 100 cents on the dollar when applied to mortgages held by the




12
follow neither approach. They exclude restricted deposits after the federal bank holiday in March
1933, but include restricted deposits before that date. Friedman and Schwartz's decision to make
no adjustment for restricted deposits before the federal bank holiday is based on the lack of hard
numbers. Given the purpose of Friedman and Schwartz - to show that the decline in the stock
of money was a major causal factor in producing the Great Depression — including or excluding
restricted deposits before the federal bank holiday was of little moment. But that battle has been
won (at least to the satisfaction of most monetary historians). Attention has turned to secondary
and tertiary factors that may have made important but smaller contributions to the crisis. In that
context the treatment of restricted deposits before the holiday makes a difference.
Restricted deposits were a phenomenon of 1932, particularly in the Midwest, although
they might have appeared somewhat earlier, perhaps after Britain's departure from the gold
standard in October 1931. The Minneapolis Federal Reserve, for example, noted in its annual
report that
"During 1932 numerous banks in the district declared moratoria on payments to
creditors for varying lengths of time. During the moratorium period, agreements
were reached for the waiver of immediate payment of deposits, the waiver of a
portion of the book value of unsecured deposits, or a combination of these
methods of enabling banks to continue in operation." (Annual Report. 1932, 6).
Unfortunately, the extent of restriction, particularly in the early part of 1932, was not well
documented. H. Parker Willis and John M. Chapman (1934, p. 7) believed that the press
deliberately down played the situation, responding to pressures that Willis and Chapman dated
to the formation of the National Credit Corporation

(a device promoted by the Hoover

administration to provide for mutual aid among the banks).

association.




13
Nevertheless, it is possible to form a qualitative idea of the extent and timing of the
problem. Some figures are available for Wisconsin where a state law permitted banks to restrict
withdrawals or place part of their deposits in trusts or receivership if 80 percent of depositors
(fewer if the state banking commissioner permitted it) approved the plan. According to Andersen
(1954, p. 172) of the 962 banks existing in Wisconsin in 1929 (including mutual savings banks),
only 270, 28 percent, avoided any restrictions except during official banking holidays. Of the
remainder 20 percent imposed temporary restrictions, 34 percent placed part of their deposits
in trusts or receiverships, and 18 percent placed all of their deposits in receivership.
In May of 1932 the Indiana Study Commission on Financial Institutions, a response to
a serious situation in that state, surveyed state bank commissioners on the number of banks in
their state that restricted withdrawals. The results of the survey are reported in Table 1. About
3.5 percent of the banks reported restrictions on withdrawals on all accounts. The total rises to
5.3 percent if account is taken of restrictions on savings banks.5 The banks restricting deposits
were small rural banks so the percentage of total deposits restricted would be smaller if all other
banks were unrestricted. But banks and bank commissioners were reluctant to report restrictions.
The large number reported for Indiana (28 percent), for example, may reflect a special problem
in that state, but it may reflect a recognition by the Bank Commissioner that there was no point
in trying to make light of a situation that the Study Commission knew at first hand. Upham and
Lamke (1934, 12) concluded that "it is probable that the figures considerably understate the
extent of restrictions."

5

In general it appears that the second column was distinct from the first. But some states may
have misinterpreted the Commission's questions and included the column 2 banks in column 1.




14
Beginning in late 1932 the imposition of restrictions accelerated. This can be seen in
Table 2 which chronicles the state and local bank holidays. The first signs were municipal
holidays declared in the upper midwest. On November 1 came the first statewide moratorium
in Nevada, and on February 12, a one day holiday in Louisiana. The final dissolution of the
banking system was ushered in by the holiday declared in Michigan in mid-February. Most of
the larger Michigan banks belonged to one of two holding companies and the smaller Guardian
Detroit Union Group was teetering on the edge of bankruptcy. A desperate effort was launched
to save this group through a Reconstruction Finance Corporation loan combined with aid from
the Ford interests. But the plan foundered on demands that the Reconstruction Finance
Corporation hold adequate collateral for its loan and the unwillingness of Henry Ford to take
part.6
The final spurt of holidays was caused, in part, by the fear that holidays in neighboring
states would lead to unsustainable withdrawals in states that dared to keep their banks open.
Governor Ruby Lafoon of Kentucky undoubtedly spoke for many when he declared a bank
holiday on March 1, 1933. His proclamation, given here, also describes the nature of the
restrictions typically imposed.
"Whereas many banks in the cities and towns contiguous to the borders of the State of
Kentucky are closed or are only permitting limited withdrawals of their deposits.
"Whereas, a result of this situation will be that the funds of the banks of Kentucky will
be withdrawn to supply the needs of these other communities, thus weakening the resources of
the people of the Commonwealth, and,
"Whereas legal holidays may only be declared in the State of Kentucky by the Governor
appointing certain days as days of thanksgiving.
"Now, therefore in consideration of the nation-wide banking situation and in view of the

6

See, for example, Arthur A. Ballantine (1948). Ballantine, the Under Secretary of the
Treasury, took part in the negotiations with Henry Ford.




15
fact that the people of the State of Kentucky, though suffering from the general depression, may
perhaps in comparison with the people of other states have reason for thanksgiving.
"I as Governor of the State of Kentucky, appoint the days of March 1, 2, 3 and 4 1933,
as days of thanksgiving in the State of Kentucky and declare such days legal holidays and do
further provide as follows:
" (1) That during said holidays all banks and trust companies shall be closed in the State
of Kentucky for the regular transaction of business except.
"(a) Said banks and trust companies may during the ordinary business hours of said
holiday pay to their depositors (whether time or demand) not exceeding an aggregate of 5 %
of the respective deposits of such depositors at close of business on Feb. 28, 1933, provided that
such payments shall only be made on checks, drafts or receipts dated subsequent to Feb. 28,
1933.
"(b) During the banking hours of the last there days of the holiday period, said banks and
trust companies may accept new deposits but such deposits shall be held in trust funds and may
be insofar as they are represented by deposits of cash, withdrawn in full during said period.
"(c) During said holiday period, said banks and trust companies, may transact any and
all other business which does not involve the paying out of deposited funds other than herein
authorized.... (Commercial and Financial Chronicle. March 4, 1933, 1484-85).
It is obvious from table 2 that by late February or early March 1933 a large fraction of
deposits had been restricted by official actions and a good portion of the remainder had been
restricted in some measure by individual bank actions. Table 3, makes this point in a slightly
different way by showing a snapshot of the banking system on the eve of President Roosevelt's
announcement of the national banking holiday. Virtually all deposits in the country were subject
in some measure to restriction. It is clear that the meaning of money had changed a great deal
from 1929 when a dollar in bank deposits was as good as gold.
One way to take account of this history would be to add a series of dummy variables to
a regression explaining the Depression. Although this approach has the advantage that it sharply
separates the existing data, however imperfect, from my machinations, it has the disadvantage
that one would have to use a large number of dummies to incorporate all of the qualitative
information. As a result the regressions would be difficult to interpret. Instead, I have utilized
the qualitative information to make an experimental adjustment to Ml. Friedman and Schwartz




16
(1982, 217), to invoke the voice of authority, followed a similar approach for similar reasons
to take into account the growing financial sophistication in the United States after the Civil War
in their attempt to estimate the long-term demand for money.
My adjustment was based on two assumptions. (1) I assumed that the restricted deposits
recorded after the national bank holiday represented the statistical unveiling of a problem that
had grown throughout 1932. So I took the ratio of unrestricted to total deposits on March 29,
1932 (.88), projected this ratio back to 1 in January 1932 by increasing the ratio a constant
percentage each month, and then applied this ratio to the standard estimate of deposits.7 This
procedure, incidentally, yields a ratio of unrestricted deposits to total deposits of about .964 in
May of 1932, not far off the ratio of unrestricted banks to total banks (.965) estimated by the
Indiana Commission.
(2) To take account of the state and local bank holidays in February and March 1933 I
reduced the estimated ratio of unrestricted to total deposits further to .5 in those months. The
rationale was that since February began with a relatively modest fraction of restricted deposits
and ended with nearly all deposits restricted, an estimate of the ratio of restricted to total
deposits designed to simulate a daily average would fall about midway between 0 and 1. A
similar logic would apply to March. The monetary aggregate incorporating adjustments (1) and
(2) is referred to below as M1a.
While one could argue about the particular assumptions I have made — the results of
some more complicated alternatives are noted below - there can be little doubt that in a broad
sense Mla corresponds more closely to a meaningful economic total than does Ml. The money

7

Friedman and Schwartz (1963, 430).




17
stock was clearly smaller in February 1933, when nearly all deposits were frozen by the end of
the month, and when there was great uncertainty about whether there would ever be access to
those deposits, than it was in April 1933 when the amount of restricted deposits was smaller,
when it could be assumed that most of those deposits would soon be released, and when
confidence in the banking system in general had increased as a result of the measures taken by
the Roosevelt administration.
Because fluctuations in the macroeconomy were extremely violent in this period,
substituting M1a for Ml can make a noticeable difference in equations intended to explain the
interwar period. Precisely how to formulate such a regression, however, is a matter of
controversy. Rather than try to estimate my own equation from (my) first principles, I have
simply used the well-known equations estimated by Bernanke (1983) except that I have used the
actual growth in the money stock rather than an estimate of the unanticipated growth. As
Haubrich (1990, 234-35), who uses a similar approach, explains in his study of Canada, the need
for comparability with other studies suggests using simply the actual growth rate of money.
Bernanke attempted to explain industrial production and included as explanatory variables
lagged values of the rates of change of industrial production, current and lagged values of rates
of change of money, and variables intended to capture the increased costs of credit
intermediation. Anna J. Schwartz (1981) ran similar regressions to test whether money Grangercaused debits to deposit accounts, a proxy for nominal GNP. My procedure is to see whether
I can improve a base equation of this sort by taking the quality of the money stock into account.
Table 4 shows several tests of M1a. The first two columns show the effect of replacing
Ml with M1a in an equation that explains changes in industrial production with contemporaneous




18
and lagged values of changes in industrial production and money.8 The incremental R2 from
replacing Ml with M1A is .07 and an additional lagged change in the money stock is significant.
Column (3) adds two variables — DBANKS the change in the deposits of suspended
banks deflated by the wholesale price index and DFAILS the change in the liabilities of bankrupt
corporations deflated by the same index — that Bernanke introduced to measure the cost of credit
intermediation. (These variables, of course, may also be picking up the decline in the quality of
deposits.) These variables were included first because Bernanke's work and that of subsequent
researchers suggest that they belong there, and because they provide a basis for judging the
ability of a revised monetary series to improve the base equation. The incremental R2 from the
credit-intermediation variables is .02. The additional information appears to be carried by the
contemporaneous rate of business failure (DFAILS).
Column (4) uses an alternative index of industrial production constructed by Miron and
Romer (1990, 337). This variable is explained less well, the R2 is only .13, and the variables
representing the cost of credit intermediation don't add any information after my adjustments to
the money stock.
Industrial production, a real variable, is not entirely appropriate in a quantity theory
framework, and may not be representative of broader movements in real output. Bank clearings
(used by Schwartz) is normally highly correlated with GNP, but might be distorted in some
months by the bank crises. And personal income (an alternative nominal variable used by
Schwartz) is not available until 1929. So I experimented with a number of other dependent

8

Data on industrial production, wholesale prices, and department store sales is from Moore
(1961, 184-89, 144, 133). Monetary variables are from Friedman and Schwartz (1970, 16-33).




19
variables such as various indexes of economic activity, and Geoffrey Moore's index of
contemporaneous indicators. Column (5) reports results for one, department store sales. This
variable was chosen because it has the highest correlation at the quarterly level with nominal
GNP of all of the variables I tried. Although it would seem peculiar nowadays to use this
variable to represent broad movements in the economy, it must be remembered that department
stores played a more important role in the distribution system than they now do. It probably
corresponds to what is now called retail sales. Here again substituting M1a for Ml makes a
substantial difference. The incremental R2 from replacing Ml with M1a is about .13. Adding
the cost of credit intermediation leaves the R2 unchanged and only the lagged value of DBANKS
is significant.
Alternative assumptions about the behavior of restricted deposits produce similar results.
For example, it could be argued that since the Friedman and Schwartz estimates are centered
on the last Wednesday of the month during this period (1970, 499) it is inappropriate to adjust
the figures for March to reflect the bank holidays: unrestricted deposits are correctly measured
on the last Wednesday. But when the equations are re-estimated with a money stock that adjusts
for restricted deposits through February and then uses the standard Ml estimates for March and
succeeding months, the results are almost identical in terms of R2 and significance of the
coefficients.
It could be argued, along the lines suggested by Friedman and Schwartz (1963, 433), that
some of the deposits restricted after the federal bank holiday should be included in the monetary
aggregates. But an experiment in which I included one half of restricted deposits in the months
following the banking crisis again produced very similar results. The R2 was marginally higher,




20
.407 in the analog of equation (3) compared with .382. But the coefficients told a similar story;
among the credit-intermediation variables only the lagged value of DFAILS was significant.
Evidently, from a statistical point of view, my crude adjustment to the money stock has
much the same effect as the DBANK and DFAILS variables — to help the equation explain the
period around the federal bank holiday.9 If the regressions can be trusted -- and are not simply
picking up the effect of more fundamental variables on money, industrial production, etc. — then
it would be fair to conclude that both the decline in the quality of the money stock and the
increased cost of credit intermediation played some role in depressing the economy below the
level that could be explained by conventionally measured monetary aggregates.

4. Safe Substitutes for Deposits
My preference is for the estimates in section 3. But the importance of quality
deterioration can be confirmed in another way. A more conventional approach to measurement
error is to include additional variables in the regression that are thought to be correlated with
the error. In this section I use the ratio of safe monetary assets to deposits to proxy for quality.
The following theoretical rational helps to justify this approach. The standard quantity
theory asserts that people want to hold a certain fraction (k) of their nominal income (Y) in the
form of a simple sum of monetary assets (M). Assume instead that people want to keep a
fraction of their nominal income in the form of liquidity services generated by deposits (D) and
a safe alternative, say currency (C), and that liquidity services are generated by a constant-

9

I have not done any formal statistical testing of the residuals but it is evident from an
inspection that the residuals are far from white noise, and considerable room for improvement
in the explanatory regression remains.




21
elasticity-of-substitution production function. Then the modified quantity theory can be written
as
(3)
where

is an index of the quality of deposits, a number varying between 0 and 1, and
is the elasticity of substitution. The relationship to the standard version of the

quantity theory can be seen by noting that as o approaches infinity and <f> approaches 1 equation
(3) approaches
(4) C + D = kY
the standard Cambridge quantity theory. Taking logarithms of both sides of (3), taking
derivatives with respect to time, and rearranging terms yields
(5)
where g in front of a variable indicates its percentage rate of change.
To substitute out

we can make use of the assumption that people will try to minimize

the amount of monetary assets they purchase by setting the marginal product of currency equal
to the marginal product of deposits (assuming that they exchange at a price of one dollar of
deposits for one dollar of cash). This yields,
(6)
Taking the logarithmic time derivative of (6) and using the elasticity of substitution yields,
(7)
which shows that the decline in quality of deposits is a simple linear function of the increase in
the currency-deposit ratio.
Substituting (7) into (5), noting that the sum of currency and deposits is the measured




22
money stock, and rearranging terms yields,
(8)
So in this extension of the quantity theory the percentage growth of income will be a linear
function of the growth of the measured stock of money and the growth of the currency-money
ratio.
As noted in section 2, there were a number of safe alternatives to bank deposits that
could be used as the theoretical counterpart of C in equation (8). Figure 1 illustrates the behavior
of three ratios: currency to Ml, postal savings to Ml, and deposits in New York City banks to
Ml. As you can see, each ratio behaves in a broadly similar fashion. The main difference is that
the currency-money ratio drops off rather sharply after the federal bank holiday while the other
ratios remain on a higher plateau. Although I tried all of these variable, the basic story, as might
be expected from the figure, can be told by settling on one ratio. In the results reported in Table
5 I use one minus the ratio of currency plus postal savings to Ml to proxy for "quality."
Equation (2) adds quality and quality lagged one period to base equation (1). The incremental
R2 of the quality variables is .022 and contemporary quality is significant. The monetary
variables, however, are less significant than in (1), perhaps because of colinearity with the
quality variable. The incremental R2 from then adding the variables intended to measure the cost
of credit intermediation, as shown by equation (3), is .061 and contemporaneous values of both
proxies are significant. The quality of money variable remains only marginally significant.
Although, to reiterate a point made above the DBANKS variable may also be picking up the
decline in the quality of the money stock.
The Miron-Romer index of industrial production is the dependent variable in equation




23
(4). Here, as in the tests of the money stock adjusted for restricted deposits, the R2 is lower than
for the older index of industrial production. Neither the quality variables, nor the cost-of-creditintermediation variables are significant.
Department Store Sales is the dependent variable in equation (5). In this test the
contemporaneous values of both the quality variable and DBANKS are significant. DFAILS are
less significant in this equation. Also as might be anticipated from an equation more in the spirit
of equation (8) — the dependent variable is nominal -- the money variables are stronger.
During the final banking crisis depositors focussed not simply on converting deposits into
postal savings, federal reserve notes and so on, but more specifically on gold.10 Table 6 reports
regressions in which the quality variable is defined as the ratio of gold outside the Treasury to
the total money supply.11 It covers only the period up to December 1933 since there was
(officially) no gold held by the public after this date. The results are similar to those reported
in previous tables. Adding the gold-money ratio significantly improves the fit of the equation.
The credit-intermediation variables also come in strongly. Both quality and credit intermediation
help explain department store sales, although in this equation the business-failure variables do
not come in significant.
All in all I conclude that the evidence from regressions using ratios of safe money to total
money to capture the decline in the quality of deposits, like the evidence from experimental
adjustments to the money stock, show that quality deterioration depressed spending and added
to the magnitude of the contraction.

10

I am indebted to Michael Edelstein and Richard Sylla for pointing this out to me.

11

A more refined estimate would make an allowance for gold held by banks.




24
5. Consistency with the Experience in Other Financial Crises
If quality deterioration was important in the Great Depression we would expect to find
that it was important in other crises. This appears to be the case. Grossman (1993), who
investigated the late nineteenth century, finds that even a relatively small bank-failure shock
could lead to a 2 percent fall in real GNP and that a major shock could lead to a 20 percent fall.
Perhaps the most troubling cases from a quality-of-money perspective are those financial panics
(1890 and 1914) that accompanied relatively mild contractions in economic activity. (Cagan,
1965, 266).
In a number of nineteenth-century panics suspension of specie payments produced
markets in which specie was quoted at a premium in terms of deposits. In such cases a money
stock in which deposits were valued at their specie price, and would therefore be consistent with
the pre-panic money stock, would be smaller than the conventionally measured stock in which
both deposits and specie were counted at their nominal values. In their discussion of the Panic
of 1893 one such episode, although Friedman and Schwartz, although they do not advocate
adjusting the monetary aggregates for the currency premium, do argue (1963, 110) that
restriction "also reduced the usefulness of deposits," and that "this made the given nominal stock
of money equivalent to a smaller stock with free interchangeability."
Sprague (1977 [1910], 200) writes the following with reference to the crisis of 1893.
"suspension was a potent factor accentuating the depression in trade which
characterized the month of August. It increased the feeling of distrust ... A more
definite consequence was the difficulty in securing money for pay rolls which led
to the temporary shutting down of many factories. Finally, it deranged the
exchanges between different parts of the country, causing a slackening in the
movement of commodities and needless delays in collections which were already
slow on account of the general situation."




25
Note the similarity between Sprague's description of the effects of the Crisis of 1893 and the
Willis-Chapman description, quoted in section 2, of the problems generated even before the
federal bank holiday by restrictions on deposits — "A national currency was lacking."
Something similar seems to have happened during the Panic of 1907. Friedman and
Schwartz (1963, 157) note that
"In October [1907] came the banking panic, culminating in the restriction of
payments by the banking system ... The contraction simultaneously became much
more severe. Production, freight car loadings, bank clearings, and the like all
declined sharply and the liabilities of commercial failures increased sharply.
Restriction of payments by banks was lifted in early 1908, and a few month
thereafter recovery got underway."
Although Sprague argues that the derangement of the economy was less in 1907 than in
1893, in part because bankers had learned how to cope with restriction by introducing substitutes
for customary forms of money, he does note (1977 [1910], 302) that some of the same
difficulties emerged.
Recently Bernanke and James (1991) completed an international comparison of impacts
of the Great Depression. Here they introduced dummy variables for periods in which a country
experienced a banking crisis into regressions explaining industrial production.
They found that industrial production fell more in countries that experienced crises. Their
explanation stresses credit-intermediation effects. But it is possible that in some of these cases
a decrease in the ability of the money stock to satisfy the transactions and precautionary motives
for holding money may have played a role as well.

6. Contrasts with other Interpretations of the Great Depression
On a purely theoretical level bank failures play a surprisingly ambiguous role in




26
Friedman and Schwartz's account of the Great Depression. According to Friedman and Schwartz
there are two effects of bank failures, one on the supply of money and one on the demand for
money. Consider first the supply effect. A threat of bank runs and failures will induce the public
to convert deposits into currency, reducing the stock of money. The threat will also induce banks
to try to convert other bank assets into reserves. Again the effect will be to reduce the stock of
money. The effect of failures on the stock of money is to reduce it, thus putting a strong
deflationary pressure on the economy.
But now consider the effect on the demand for money. The threat of widespread failures
can be interpreted as an expected loss from holding money, so the rational response will be to
try to spend it as rapidly as possible, velocity will rise and the effect will be inflationary. Thus
the emergence of a threat to the safety and soundness of the banking system produces two
opposing effects: on the one hand it reduces the stock of money, but on the other it raises
velocity. From a purely theoretical point of view there is little we can say. We know that the
supply effects dominated the demand effects from empirical evidence. The period 1920 - 1933
was one of falling rather than rising real incomes and prices.

The

intuitive

appeal of the Friedman-Schwartz argument rests, I believe, on the fact that it can be verified in
a simple thought experiment. Suppose you go to sleep thinking that your bank deposits are
perfectly secure and wake up to learn that there is some risk, say 5 percent, that the bank in
which you hold your deposits may fail, and that if it does you will lose everything. What will
you do? One thing you might do is convert deposits into currency, hence the decline in the
deposit-currency ratio, and the downward pressure on the demand for money. The other thing
you might do is increase your purchase of goods and services; hence the positive effect on the




27
flow of spending.
But there are other possibilities. Suppose that by diversifying your deposits among a
number of banks (for this purpose currency can be considered another bank with no risk of
failure but rather inferior services) thus converting a gamble consisting of a probability of .05
of losing everything into a certain loss of 5 percent of capital. Then our representative individual
might behave much like an individual who had simply lost 5 percent of his deposits, by reducing
consumption in order to rebuild his cash position.
Friedman and Schwartz make their case primarily on the basis of a comparison with
Canada. (Friedman and Schwartz 1963, 352-53) The fall in the money stock was similar in the
U.S. and Canada, but the fall in velocity was less in the United States. Since Canada did not
suffer from bank failures Friedman and Schwartz concluded that velocity fell less in the United
States because people were forced to spend by a fear of bank failures. There may, of course,
be other explanations for the difference between the United States and Canada. For example, it
may be appropriate to view Canada as a small part of a large North American economy
dominated by the United States. Then it would not be surprising if the fall in GNP in Canada
and the United States were of roughly similar percentages, despite differences in the fall in
money, especially during the period of fixed exchange rates.
Haubrich's results for Canada support this explanation. Haubrich (1990, 250) found that
the "contraction of the Canadian banking system, whether measured by branches, [bank] stock
prices, loans, or commercial failures, did not significantly influence the Canadian economy."
This is consistent with the quality interpretation. There were no bank failures in Canada, and
no restriction of deposits. A dollar of deposits remained essentially equivalent to cash throughout




28
the 1930s.
After 1933 the quality of the money stock in the United States improved rapidly. One of
the most obvious changes was the introduction of deposit insurance. One could now afford, for
example, to consolidate and reduce deposit balances, spend hoarded currency, and still maintain
the same protection against a rainy day. Just as the decline in the quality of money contributes
to explaining the severity of the decline in income before 1933; the rise in the quality of money
can explain part of the rapid rebound.
In A Monetary History Friedman and Schwartz note that the (measured) stock of money fell
until 1934 while the economy rebounded rapidly. Friedman and Schwartz (1963, 433-34)
attribute this to a rise in velocity, prompted in part by the "confidence" generated by the
emergency revival of the banking system. But if the banking crisis raised velocity, why didn't
ending the crisis reduce velocity? By treating bank failures and deposit insurance as quality
determining variables we get an explanation that is consistent across the great contraction and
the rebound in 1933-1934.
In Lessons from the Great Depression Peter Temin (1989, 49-52) argues that the banking
crises did not contribute to the Depression through a monetary channel because interest rates
declined. If there had been a genuine shortage of money, people would have tried to rebuild
their cash balances, Temin argues, by selling securities such as treasury bills and this would
have produced an increase in yields.12
The quality perspective provides an explanation. The shortage was of liquid assets, not

12

Temin was writing particularly in the context of the First banking crisis; I am assuming
that the argument could be generalized to the whole of the period 1930-33.




29
deposits (which were no longer liquid) and so there was a flight to gold, treasury bills, and
similar assets. In other words, lower yields. The "flight to quality" has been noted by a number
of writers. The advantage of discussing it in terms of the quality of the money stock is that this
terminology helps to link the flight to quality to other aspects of the banking crisis. For example,
quality decline in the money stock also provides a simple way of explaining the otherwise
confusing high level of real balances observed in 1932 and 1933: measured real balances were
high but quality-constant real balances were low.
Ben Bernanke (1983), as we noted above, has offered a supplementary explanation for
the depths reached in the Depression. The banking crisis and the deflation damaged the main
source of credit for farmers and small businesses. Banks had information about specific
borrowers, a form of capital, and banks relied on collateral to overcome the asymmetric
information problem.13 The failure of banks, and the erosion of the net worth of borrowers,
made it difficult for traditional borrowers from banks to get credit. As a result such borrowers
were forced to cut back their spending. Bernanke, as we have seen, offered regressions in which
real deposits of failed banks and real liabilities of failed businesses were used to proxy for
damage to the credit mechanism. Recently, Grossman (1993), as we noted above, showed that
bank failures were important during the National Banking Era, and followed Bernanke in
interpreting this as a non-monetary credit intermediation channel.
Bernanke's regressions, however, can be regarded as reduced form equations. (Temin
1989, 53). It is conceivable that Bernanke's variables, in particular as we have noted above, the

13

(Calomiris 1992) is an excellent survey of the research that resulted from Bernanke's
paper.




30
real deposits of suspended banks, in part may be picking up other forces such as the decline in
the quality of the money stock.

7. Conclusion
In the end we reach a conclusion that seems obvious once attention is drawn to it: the
banking crises probably contributed directly to the depth and duration of the Great depression.
Both a transaction channel and a portfolio adjustment channel were involved. The restrictions
on withdrawals that proceeded the federal bank holiday destroyed the ability of the banking
system to provide a uniform national currency, disrupting commerce and industry. Moreover,
by reducing the ability of bank money to serve as a temporary abode of purchasing power, the
collapse of the banking system encouraged people to purchase safe assets (gold, national bank
notes, government bonds, deposits in well regarded banks, and so on). In attempting to do so
they reduced current purchases of real goods and services, putting downward pressure on real
output and prices.
The point, to put it slightly differently, is that the quantity theory needs to be modified.
Assume that people wish to hold a quality-constant money supply in proportion to their income.
Then we can view the quantity theory that applies in normal times as a special case of this more
general model, the special case where the quality index is one.
Our experience with severe banking and monetary crises is so limited that we will never
have an explanation of the Depression that can win out against all others on purely statistical
grounds. In the end we will have to be content with an explanation that best fits the facts, but
possesses other criteria — simplicity, plausibility, consistency with theoretical explanations, and




31
so on. On these grounds it seems to me that a monetary explanation, modified to take into
account the decline in the quality of the money stock, is still the most convincing explanation
of the Great Depression.

References
Amdersen, Theodore A. 1954. A Century of Banking in Wisconsin.
Madison: State Historical Society of Wisconsin.
Angell, James W.
1936. The Behavior of Money: Exploratory
Studies. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1936. Reprinted by Augustus
M. Kelley, 1969.
Ballantine, Arthur A. 1948. "When
Business Review 26: 129 - 43.

All

the

Banks

Closed."

Harvard

Bernanke, Ben. 1983. "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis
in the Propagation of the Great Depression." American Economic Review 73:
257-76.
Bernanke, Ben and Harold James.
1991. "The Gold
Standard,
Deflation, and Financial Crisis in the Great Depression: An International
Comparison." In R. Glenn Hubbard, ed., Financial Markets and Financial Crises.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 33-68.
Bordo,

Michael D. and Lars Jonung. 1987. The Long-run Behavior
the Velocity of Circulation: The International Evidence. New York: Cambridge
University Press.

Cagan, Phillip. 1965. Determinants and Effects of Changes in
Stock of Money, 1875-1960. New York: Columbia University Press, for the
NBER.
Calomiris, Charles W. "Financial Factors in the Great
(August 1992, forthcoming in the Journal of Economic Perspectives).

of

the

Depression."

Cecchetti, Stephen G. "The Case of the Negative Nominal Interest
Rates: New Estimates of the Term Structure of Interest Rates during the Great
Depression." Journal of Political Economy 12 (1988): 1111-1141.




32

Friedman, Milton.
1969.
"The Monetary Theory and Policy of Henry
Simons." In The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays. 81-94. Chicago:
Aldine Publishing Company.
Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz. 1963. A
the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Monetary

History

of

1970.
Monetary
Statistics
of the U n i t e d
States:
Estimates. Sources. Methods. New York: Columbia University Press, for the
NBER.

1982.
Monetary Trends in the United States and
United Kingdom: Their Relation to Income. Prices, and Interest Rates. 18671875. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

the

Grossman, Richard S.
1993. "The Macroeconomic Consequences of Bank
Failures under the National Banking System." Explorations in Economic History
30: 294-320.

Haubrich, Joseph G.
1990. "Nonmonetary Effects of Financial Crises:
Lessons from the Great Depression in Canada." Journal of Monetary Economics.
25: 223-52.
Hoover, Calvin B. and B.U. Ratchford.
1951. Economic
Policies of the South. New York: The Macmillan Company.

Resources

McKean, Roland.
1951. Liquidity and a National
Balance Sheet.
Readings in Monetary Theory, eds. Friedrich A. Lutz and Lloyd W. Mints, 6388. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc. Reprinted from The Journal of
Political Economy. 57 (1949): 506-22.

and

In

Miron,

Jeffrey A. and Christina D. Romer.
1990.
"A New Monthly
Index of Industrial Production, 1884-1940." Journal of Economic History 50
(June): 321-338.

Moore

Geoffrey
H.
1961. Business Cycle Indicators.
Volume
Basic Data on Cyclical Indicators. Princeton: Princeton University Press, for the
NBER.

Ninth

Federal
Reserve
District,
Minneapolis.
Annual Report to the Federal Reserve Board.




1932.

II,

Eighteenth

33

Patinkin,
Don.
1972.
"The Chicago Tradition,
The Quantity Theory,
and Friedman." In Studies in Monetary Economics. New York: Harper & Row.
Rockoff, Hugh. 1993. "Henry Simons and the Quantity Theory of

Money." (mimeo)

Schwartz,
Anna J.
1981. "Understanding
1929-33."
ed., The Great Depression Revisited. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff.

Karl

Brunner,

Simons,
Henry
C.
1948.
Economic
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Free

Society.

Policy

for

a

Sprague, O.M.W.
1977 [1910]. History of Crises Under the National
Banking Act. Fairfield, NJ: August M. Kelley; reprint, Washington: GPO,
National Monetary Commission.
Temin,
Peter.
1976.
Did
Monetary
Depression? New York: Norton.
.
1989.
MIT press.

Lessons

from

the

Forces

Great

Cause

Depression.

the

Great

Cambridge:

Upham,
Cyril B. and Edwin Lamke.
1934. Closed and Distressed
Banks: A Study in Public Administration. Washington D.C.: The Brookings
Institution.
Willis,

H. Parker and John M. Chapman. 1934. The Banking Situation:
American Post-War Problems and Developments. New York: Columbia
University Press.







34

Figure 1
Ratios of Safe Assets to Ml

D NYC Deposits + Postal Savings o Currency

35
Table 1
Banks Restricting Deposits, May, 1932 (a)
State

Number of Banks

Banks with Restricted
Withdrawals on all
Accounts

Alabama

220

1

Arkansas

329

2

1

Colorado

150

4

2

Connecticut

191

50

Delaware

45

(b)

Georgia

323

Idaho

96

Illinois (c)

1221

Indiana

705

Kansas

806

Kentucky

Banks with Restricted
Withdrawals on Savings
Accounts

1

200

(d)

419

20

20

Louisiana

191

1

2

Maine

79

Michigan

639

50

Minnesota

752

50

2

Mississippi

280

6

40

Missouri

1110

12

Montana

122

7

Nebraska

602

New Hampshire

65

New Mexico

27

New York

566

North Dakota

254

Oklahoma

320

Rhode Island

25

South Carolina

138

South Dakota

279

Tennessee

380




3

4

8

56
5

5

36
Texas

700

50

Vermont

58

1

Virginia

306

11

Washington

228

6

West Virginia (e)
19

Wisconsin
Wyoming

12465

210

58

TOTAL

19

448

781

Source: Upham and Lamke, p. 13.
(a) Report of the Indiana Study Commission for Financial Institutions, p. 83. Data compiled from
questionnaires sent to the 48 state banking departments. No replies were received from 13 states.
(b) Usual notice required.
(c) The Banking Department of Illinois could give no detailed information as to any restrictions but it is
known that some banks in that state took that step. Examples are the institutions of Urbana and Aurora.
(d) Uncertain.
(e) No definite information as to the actual number of banks on a restricted basis. Practically all the banks in
the Northwestern part of West Virginia adopted the rule of restricted withdrawals. All banks in Martinsburgh
adopted the rule; also banks in Parkersburg and Wheeling.

Table 2
Local Bank Holidays in 1932-33
Date

State

Action Taken

17 October

Minnesota

Municipal holidays declared

1 November

Nevada

12 day moratorium; twice renewed

January

Illinois
Iowa

Small towns declare local holidays

20 January

Iowa

One-day Bank Holiday

12 February

Louisiana

One-day holiday

14 February

Michigan

8-day holiday, renewed until federal
holiday

20 February

New Jersey

Legislature authorizes banking
commission to declare a moratorium
on February 21 this power is exercised
for one bank

Missouri

One bank restricts withdrawals after
mayor declares moratorium




37
23 February

New Jersey

Limited withdrawals authorized at two
banks

25 February

Maryland

3-day holiday, subsequently extended

Ohio

Banks self-declare holidays

Missouri

Banks granted right to restrict
withdrawals

27 February

Indiana
Ohio
North. Kentucky

Banks restrict withdrawals under the
authority of new banking laws

28 February

Arkansas,
Pennsylvania

Banks initiate restrictions

1 March

Philadelphia and Pittsburgh

Individual banks self-declare holidays

Kentucky
Mississippi Tennessee

Bank holidays

2 March

Alabama California
Georgia Louisiana Mississippi
Nevada, Oklahoma Oregon, Texas
Utah, Washington
Wisconsin

Bank holidays

3 March

Arizona, Georgia
Idaho, Illinois
New Mexico
North Carolina
Oklahoma, Virginia
Wyoming

Bank holidays

4 March

Colorado, Delaware
District of Columbia
Florida, Georgia
Kansas, Maine
Massachusetts
Minnesota
Missouri
Montana, Nebraska
New Hampshire
New Jersey
New York
North Dakota
South Dakota
Vermont

Virtually all remaining banks closed by
governor's proclamations at the request
of Treasury officials. New York holds
out for a few hours; They cannot get
hold of governor of Illinois

6 March

United States

Bank Holiday

Source: Commercial and Financial Chronicle and the New York Times Index, 1933, passim.




38

Table 3
State Bank Restrictions, Sunday, March 5, 1933
State

Description of Restrictions

Alabama

Closed until further notice

Arizona

Closed until March 13

Arkansas

Closed until March 7

California

Almost all closed until March 9

Colorado

Closed until March 8

Connecticut

Closed until March 7

Delaware

Closed indefinitely

District of Columbia

Three banks limited to 5%; nine savings banks invoke sixty days' notice

Florida

Withdrawals restricted to 5% plus $10 until March 8

Georgia

Mostly closed until March 7, closing optional

Idaho

Some closed until March 18, closing optional

Illinois

Closed until March 8, then to be opened on 5% restriction basis for
seven days

Indiana

About half restricted to 5 % indefinitely

Iowa

Closed "temporarily"

Kansas

Restricted to 5% withdrawals indefinitely

Kentucky

Mostly restricted to 5% withdrawals until March 11

Louisiana

Closing mandatory until March 7

Maine

Closed until March 7

Maryland

Closed until March 6

Massachusetts

Closed until March 7

Michigan

Mostly closed, others restricted to 5% indefinitely; Upper peninsula
banks open

Minnesota

Closed "temporarily"

Mississippi

Restricted to 5% indefinitely

Missouri

Closed until March 7




39
Montana

Closed until further notice

Nebraska

Closed until March 8

Nevada

Closed until March 8, also schools

New Hampshire

Closed subject to further proclamation

New Jersey

Closed until March 7

New Mexico

Mostly closed until March 8

New York

Closed until March 7

North Carolina

Some banks restricted to 5% withdrawals

North Dakota

Closed temporarily

Ohio

Mostly restricted to 5% withdrawals indefinitely

Oklahoma

All closed until March 8

Oregon

All closed until March 7

Pennsylvania

Mostly closed until March 7, Pittsburgh banks open

Rhode Island

Closed yesterday

South Carolina

Some closed, some restricted, all on own initiative

South Dakota

Closed indefinitely

Tennessee

A few closed, others restricted, until March 9

Texas

Mostly closed, others restricted to withdrawals of $15 daily until March 8

Utah

Mostly closed until March 8

Vermont

Closed until March 7

Virginia

All closed until March 8

Washington

Some closed until March 7

West Virginia

Restricted to 5% monthly withdrawals indefinitely

Wisconsin

Closed until March 17

Wyoming

Withdrawals restricted to 5% indefinitely

Source: Commercial and Financial Chronicle, March 11, 1933, p. 1670.




40

Table 4
Effects of Adjusting the Monetary Aggregates for Restricted Deposits
Sample Period = 1921.05 1940.12
(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

Dependent
Variable

IP

IP

IP

MRIP

DSS

Definition of Money

Ml

M1a

M1a

M1a

M1a

Dependent Variabie(-l)

.552
(8.81)

.550
(8.98)

.543
(8.46)

-.351
(5.36)

-.365
(5.53)

Dependent
Variable(-2)

-.3.43
(5.47)

-.369
(6.07)

-.358
(5.80)

-.084
(1.28)

-.162
(2.43)

Money

.416
(2.65)

.380
(6.16)

.294
(2.50)

.414
(1.09)

.363
(4.05)

Money(-l)

.298
(1.93)

.217
(3.23)

.359
(2.68)

.393
(.919)

.418
(4.10)

Money(-2)

.035
(.229)

.154
(2.25)

.126
(1.83)

.747
(3.50)

.132
(2.39)

Money(-3)

.058
(.368)

.062
(.963)

.054
(.860)

.711
(3.50)

.106
(2.28)

DBANKS

-.300
(.283)

.483
(.141)

.544
(.677)

DBANKS(-l)

1.608
(1.24)

-2.80
(.667)

1.66
(1.71)

DFAILS

-48.00
(2.57)

1.34
(.022)

-9.09
(.658)

DFAILS(-l)

11.4
(.599)

-5.46
(.092)

-8.75
(.634)

.390

.128

.271

Variable

Adjusted R2




.299

.372

41

Table 5
Adding a quality variable to the explanatory equation
Sample Period = 1921.05 - 1940.12
(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

IP

IP

IP

MRIP

DSS

Dependent Variable(-l)

.552
(8.805)

.559
(896)

.572
(8.89)

-.307
4.59

-.357
(5.36)

Dependent
Variable(-2)

-.343
(5.47)

-.356
(5.73)

-.348
(5.71)

-.039
.579

-.113
(1.76)

Ml

.416
(2.65)

.048
(.248)

.053
(.281)

-.768
(1.23)

.091
(.645)

Ml(-l)

.298
(1.93)

.311
(1.54)

.472
(2.35)

.133
(.198)

.524
(3.44)

Ml(-2)

.035
(.229)

.067
(.439)

.165
(1.11)

1.04
(2.14)

.228
(1.99)

Ml(-3)

.057
(.368)

.088
(.567)

.091
(.608)

.452
(.897)

.110
(.965)

QUALITY

1.30
(2.94)

.837
(1.92)

2.10
(1.44)

(.872)
(2.62)

QUALITY(-l)

-.035
(.075)

-.626
(1.20)

.826
(.474)

-.465
(1.13)

DBANKS

-2.83
(4.00)

-.309
(.131)

-2.46
(4.47)

DBANKS(-l)

-.850
(1.19)

-2.27
(.971)

-1.10
(196)

DFAILS

-45.7
(2.42)

-.129
(.210)

-8.41
(.603)

DFAILS(-l)

8.38
(.439)

-.180
(.296)

-.156
(1.12)

.382

.077

.257

Variable

•

Adjusted R2




.299

.321

42

Table 6
Adding the ratio of gold to money to the explanatory equation
Sample Period = 1921.05 - 1933.12
Variable

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

Dependent Variable

IP

IP

IP

MRIP

DSS

Dependent Variable(-l)

.487
(6.16)

.392
(5.05)

.505
(6.49)

-.252
(3.01)

-.413
(4.97)

Dependent
Variable(-2)

-.328
(4.12)

-.406
(5.17)

-.376
(4.78)

.058
(.708)

-.132
(160)

Ml

.397
(1.82)

.282
(1.33)

-.025
(.124)

-.575
(.921)

.096
(.606)

Ml(-l)

.245
(1.11)

.309
(1.43)

.377
(1.92)

-.303
(.492)

.109
(.678)

Ml(-2)

-.373
(1.71)

-.156
(.727)

.088
(.433)

.982
(1.55)

.506
(3.11)

Ml<-3)

.006
(.026)

.162
(.761)

.187
(.971)

.711
(1.18)

.483
(3.16)

GOLD-MI

-.065
(2.87)

-.149
(5.40)

-.119
(1.37)

-.047
(2.12)

GOLD-Ml(-l)

-.072
(3.03)

.089
(2.44)

.083
(.754)

-.051
(1.83)

GOLD-MI (-2)

-.030
(1.23)

-.020
(.513)

-.021
(.187)

.0004
(.015)

GOLD-Ml(-3)

-.041
(1.73)

-.042
(1.78)

-.186
(2.49)

-.040
(1.99)

DBANKS

-5.93
(5.62)

-5.21
(1.60)

-2.57
(3.12)

DBANKS(-l)

-1.96
(1.69)

-5.65
(1.68)

-2.08
(2.41)

DFAILS

-34.4
(1.65)

-34.8
(.534)

3.82
(.232)

DFAILS(-l)

2.79
(.134)

-55.0
(.859)

-1.49
(.092)

.468

.068

.331

Adjusted R2




.246

.336

(5)

Appendix
Divisia Monetary Aggregates During the Great Depression

The Divisia monetary aggregate, and related indexes, seem a
natural

way

to

allow

for

quality

effects

during

the

Great

Depression because they incorporate price information that might
measure
quantity

changes

in the monetary

of money.

services

Since they make use

produced
of

by a given

standard

formulas,

moreover, there is no need to estimate elasticities of demand or
substitution

in order to use them. A recent paper by Barnett,

Fisher, and Serletis

(1992) describes these indexes and makes a

strong case for them. Experiments with these indexes, however,
proved

disappointing

for

the

quality

interpretation.

I

am

unpersuaded, however, that the failure of these indexes to support
the quality interpretation should be considered decisive.
The

basic

idea

behind

indexes

of

this

sort

is that

the

monetary services produced by a dollar of deposits or other liquid
assets can be measured by the user cost of holding a dollar.
Suppose the rate of return on a corporate bond that produces no
monetary services is 8 percent, and that a bank deposit account
pays 5 percent. Then the opportunity

cost of the

nonpecuniary

services produced by a dollar of deposits is 3 percent per year;
for currency the opportunity cost would be the full 8 percent.14
Different

indexes make use

of

the user

cost

in slightly

different ways. The simplest idea is to view the user cost as an

14

We can ignore the distinction between real and nominal returns here, because subtracting
the inflation rate from both the corporate bond rate and the deposit account would leave the user
cost unchanged.



43

annual return and then to divide by the return on bonds to get the
present value of the monetary

services generated

by holding a

dollar of a particular asset. Thus, for deposits, 3 percent divided
by

8 percent

gives

$.38

in

monetary

services

per

dollar

of

deposits. We can then construct a weighted monetary aggregate by
weighting total currency by one and total deposits by .38. This is
the index recently proposed by Rotemberg, Driscoll, and Poterba
(1991). The formula would be
(Al) RDP Ml = C + {(rb-rd)/rb}*D
where C is currency, D is deposits, rb is the rate of return on
bonds, and rd is the rate of return on deposits. The formula could
be extended by adding additional liquid assets weighted by their
discounted user costs.
The Divisia index and the Fisher Ideal index make use of the
user cost in more complicated ways. The Divisia Index is easier to
understood in rate of change form.
(A2) log(Divisia Mt) - log(Divisia Mt-1) =
(1/2)(Sct + Sct-1)(log Ct - log Ct-1) +
(1/2)(Sdt + Sdt-1)(log Dt - log Dt-1)
where Sc = rb*C/[rb*C + (rb -rd)*D], is the share of the monetary
services

of

currency

in

total

monetary

services.

Thus,

the

percentage change in the Divisia index in each period is the sum of
the percentage changes

in each monetary asset weighted

by the

average shares of monetary services.
Fisher's Ideal index, in rate of change form, is given by
(A3)

log(Fisher's Mt) - log(Fisher's Mt-1) =
(1/2){log(Sct-l[Ct/Ct-l] + Sdt-l[Dt/Dt-l]) log(Sct[Ct-l/Ct] + Sdt[Dt-l/Dt])}
There

does




not

appear

to
44

be

an

equally

intuitive

interpretation of Fisher's index, but as you can see it also makes
use of the share of monetary services produced by a given asset for
weighting changes in that asset. I computed the value of each of
these indexes using the high-grade corporate bond rate (Friedman
and Schwartz, 1982, 124) for the benchmark rate, and the interest
rates on deposits from Cagan (1965, 318).
The results, however, were uniformly counterintuitive.
Figures Al, A2, and A3 compare percentage changes

in the

standard estimates of Ml with the corresponding percentage change
in the Rotemberg-Driscoll-Poterba

Ml, the Divisia Ml, and the

Fisher Ml, respectively. The Rotemberg-Driscoll-Poterba Ml index
shows decidedly less contraction than the standard Ml. Indeed, it
doesn't show any substantial declines before 1931. The other two
indexes track the standard Ml fairly closely, although there is a
small difference in 1931 and 1932
the Fisher

index fall slightly

when both the Divisia index and
less than the standard Ml. The

results for M2 were similar.
There are several possible interpretations of these results
(barring

the

simplest

one

that

I

have

gotten

a

sign

wrong

somewhere) . (1) There is some problem with the data used to compute
the indexes. But I know of no obvious bias in the data, at least
before

1933. After

1933

interest

payments

were

prohibited

on

deposit accounts, and there may have been some attempt to evade
this restriction, although one would not think this problem was
important given the depressed conditions of the 193 0s.
user-cost

formulas

(2) The

are telling us that my quality-argument

is

wrong, and that the monetary contraction argument as a whole is
weaker

than

contraction




previously
was

less

thought,

severe

than

45

because
standard

the

true

monetary

monetary
estimates

suggest in the crucial years of the Depression. But the fact that
the difference is not only small but goes in the wrong direction
suggests that the Divisia indexes are not adjusting for quality as
I have been defining it. (3) The user-cost formulas need to be
modified in some way to handle a banking crisis and Depression.
Risk neutrality, which may be an innocuous assumption in ordinary
circumstances,

may

Hopefully,

some

aggregates

to

need

way

the

can

to
be

Depression

be

modified

found
that

for
will

characteristic simplicity and objectivity.




46

for

the

adapting
not

Depression.
the

undermine

Divisia
their

APPENDIX REFERENCES
Barnett, William A., Douglas Fisher, and Apostolos Serletis. 1992.
"Consumer Theory and the Demand for Money." Journal of
Economic Literature. 30 (December): 2086-2119.
Cagan, Phillip. 1965. Determinants and Effects of Chancres in the
Stock of Money. 1875-1960. New York: Columbia U. Press,
for the NBER.
Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz. 1982. Monetary Trends in the
United States and the United Kingdom: Their Relation to
Income. Prices, and Interest Rates. 1867-1875. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Rotemberg, Julio J., John C. Driscoll, and James M. Poterba. 1991.
"Money, Output, and Prices: Evidence From A New Monetary
Aggregate." NBER Working Paper No. 3824.




47




Figure Al

Figure A2

Figure A3

48

Number

Author

Title

Date

10

Kenneth L. Sokoloff
B. Zorina Khan

The Democratization of Invention During
Early Industrialization: Evidence from the
United States, 1790-1846

12/89

11

Hugh Rockoff

The Capital Market in the 1850s

1/90

12

Robert W. Fogel

Modeling Complex Dynamic Interactions:
The Role of Intergenerational, Cohort,
and Period Processes and of Conditional
Events in the Political Realignment
of the 1850s

3/90

13

Lance E. Davis
Robert E. Gallman
Teresa D. Hutchins

Risk Sharing, Crew Quality, Labor Shares
and Wages in the Nineteenth Century
American Whaling Industry

5/90

14

Robert A. Margo

The Competitive Dynamics of Racial
Exclusion: Employment Segregation in
the South, 1900-1950

8/90

15

Jeremy Atack
Fred Bateman

How Long Was the Work Day in 1880?

8/90

16

Robert W. Fogel

The Conquest of High Mortaltiy and
Hunger in Europe and America: Timing
and Mechanisms

9/90

17

Robert A. Margo

Segregated Schools and the Mobilty
Hypothesis: A Model of Local Government
Discrimination

10/90

18

Robert A. Margo

The Microeconomics of Depression
Unemployment

12/90

19

Robert A. Margo

Wages and Prices During the Antebellum
Period: A Survey and New Evidence

12/90

20

Stanley Engerman
Claudia Goldin

Seasonality in Nineteenth Century
Labor Markets

1/91

21

Michael R. Haines
Allen C. Goodman

A Home of One's Own: Aging and
Homeownership in the United States in
the Late Nineteenth and Early Twentieth
Centuries

1/91

22

David W. Galenson
Clayne L. Pope

Precedence and Wealth: Evidence from
Nineteenth Century Utah

2/91

23

Thomas Weiss

Long Term Changes in U.S. Agricultural
Output per Worker, 1800 to 1900

2/91




Number

Author

Title

Date

24

Richard H. Steckel

Stature and Living Standards in the United
States

04/91

25

Jeremy Atack
Fred Bateman

Louis Brandeis, Work and Fatigue at the Start
of the Twentieth Century: Prelude to Oregon's
Hours Limitation Law

04/91

26

Robert W. Fogel

New Sources and New Techniques for the
Study of Secular Trends in Nutritional Status,
Health, Mortality, and the Process of Aging

05/91

27

Robert A. Margo

The Labor Force Participation of Older Americans
in 1900: Further Results

07/91

28

Kenneth Sokoloff
Georgia Villaflor

The Market for Manufacturing Workers During Early 07/91
Industrialization: The American Northeast, 1820 to 1860

29

Gary D. Libecap

The Rise of the Chicago Packers and the Origins
of Meat Inspection and Antitrust

09/91

30

Kenneth L. Sokoloff
David Dollar

Agricultural Seasonality and the Organization of
Manufacturing During Early Industrialization: The
Contrast Between Britain and the United States

09/91

31

Michael R. Haines

The Use of Historical Census Data for Mortality
and Fertility Research

10/91

32

Alan Taylor
Jeffrey Williamson

Capital Flows to the New World as an
Intergenerational Transfer

12/91

33

Jeremy Atack
Fred Bateman

Whom Did Protective Legislation Protect? Evidence
From 1880

12/91

34

Robert W. Fogel

Toward a New Synthesis on the Role of Economic
Issues in the Political Realignment of the 1850s

01/92

35

Robert L. Greenfield
Hugh Rockoff

Gresham's Law Regained

01/92

36

Jeffrey Williamson

The Evolution of Global Labor Markets in the First
02/92
and Second World Since 1830: Background Evidence and
Hypotheses

37

Kevin O'Rourke
Jeffery Williamson

Were Heckscher and Ohlin Right? Putting the
the Factor-Price-Equalization Theorem Back Into
History

06/92

38

Robert W. Fogel
Larry T. Wimmer

Early Indicators of Later Work Levels, Disease,
and Death

06/92

39

Richard H. Steckel
S. Nicholas

Tall But Poor: Nutrition, Health, and Living Standards 08/92
in Pre-Famine Ireland




Number

Author

Title

Date

40

Robert A. Margo

The Labor Force in the Nineteenth Century

08/92

41

Timothy J. Hatton
Jeffrey G. Williamson

International Migration and World Development: A
Historical Perspective

09/92

42

B. Zorina Khan
Kenneth J. Sokoloff

'Schemes of Practical Utility': Entrepreneurship
and Innovation Among 'Great Inventors' in the
United States, 1790-1865

11/92

43

Timothy J. Hatton
Jeffrey G. Williamson

What Drove the Mass Migrations from Europe in the
Late Nineteenth Century?

11/92

44

Robert A. Margo

Explaining Black-White Wage Convergence,
1940-1950: The Role of the Great Compression

3/93

45

T. Aldrich Finegan
Robert A. Margo

Added and Discouraged Workers in the Late 1930S:
A Re-Examination

4/93

46

Kevin O'Rourke
Alan M. Taylor
Jeffrey G. Williamson

Land, Labor and the Wage-Rental Ratio:
Factor Price Convergence in the Late
Nineteenth Century

5/93

47

Timothy J. Hatton
Jeffrey G. Williamson

Late-Comers to Mass Emigration: The Latin
Experience

6/93

48

Jeffrey G. Williamson
Kevin O'Rourke
Timothy J. Hatton

Mass Migration, Commodity Market Integration and
6/93
Real Wage Convergence: The Late Nineteenth Century
Atlantic Economy

49

Margaret Levenstein

Vertical Restraints in the Bromine Cartel: The Role
of Distibutors in Facilitating Collusion

7/93

50

Margaret Levenstein

Price Wars and the Stability of Collusion: A Study of
the Pre-World War I Bromine Industry

9/93

51

Dora L. Costa

Explaining the Changing Dynamics of Unemployment: 12/93
Evidence from Civil War Pension Records

52

Hugh Rockoff

The Meaning of Money in the Great Depression

12/93

Copies of the above Historical Papers can be obtained by sending $5.00 per copy (plus $10.00 per order fo
postage and handling for all locations outside the continental U.S.) to Working Papers, NBER, 1050 Massachuset
Avenue, Cambridge, MA 02138-5398. Advance payment is required on all orders. Payment may be made by check (
credit card. If paying by credit card, include the cardholder's name, account number and expiration date. For all ma
orders, please be sure to include your return address and telephone number. Historical papers may also be ordered b
telephone (617-868-3900), or by fax (617-868-2742).