The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
JAN UARY 1957 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT HEARINGS BEFORE THE JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE CONGRESS OE THE UNITED STATES EIGH TY-FIFTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION PURSUANT TO Sec. 5 (a) of Public Law 304 (7 9 th C o n g ress) JANUARY 28, 29,30,31, FEBRUARY 1, 4, 5, AND 6,1957 Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee JANUARY 1957 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT HEARINGS B EFORE T H E JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE CONGEESS. OF THE UNITED STATES EIGH TY-FIFTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION PU RSU AN T TO Sec. 5 (a) of Public Law 304 (79th Congress) JANUARY 28, 29, 30, 31, FEBRUARY 1, 4, 5, AND 6, 1957 Printed for the use o f the Joint Economic Committee F or sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U .S . Government Printing Office W ashington 25, D. C. - Price $2.25 (paper) JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE (Created pursuant to sec. 5 (a ) o f P ublic Law 304, 79th Cong.) W R IG H T PATM AN , Representative from Texas, Chairman JOHN SPARKM AN, Senator from Alabama, V ice Chairman HOUSE OF R E PR E SE N TA TIV E S R IC H A R D BOLLING, Missouri W IL B U R D. M ILL S, Arkansas A U GU STIN E B. K E LLE Y , Pennsylvania HEN RY O. T A LL E , Iowa THOM AS B. CU RTIS, M issouri CLARENCE E. K ILBU RN , New York SENATE PAU L H. DOUGLAS, Illinois J. W. F U LB R IG H T , Arkansas JOSEPH C. O’MAHONEY, W yom ing R A LP H E. FLAN DERS, Vermont A R TH U R V. W AT K IN S, Utah BA R R Y GOLDW A'TER, A rizona G r o v e r W . E n s l e y , E xecu tive D irector J o h n W. L e h m a n , Clerk CONTENTS Panel discussions and individual witnesses in order of appearance: Page Council of Economic Advisers______________________________________ 1 Raymond J. Saulnier, Chairman, Joseph S. Davis, member, Paul W. McCracken, member______________________________ 8 The Federal budget________________________________________________ 49* Percival F. Brundage, Director, Bureau of the Budget--------------50 Economic outlook for the coming year______________________________ 86 Labor force, hours, productivity, and potential output: Ewan Clague, Commissioner, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Department of Labor_______________________________ _ 86 Government demand for goods and services____________________ 118 Louis J. Paradiso, Assistant Director and chief statistician, Office of Business Economics, Department of Commerce.. 118 Business demand________________ ______________________________ 121 Martin Gainsbrugh, chief economist, National Industrial Conference Board________ _______ ______________________ 121 Consun er demand_____________ __________________________ 128 George Katona, program director, survey research center, University of Michigan_________________________________ 128 Agricultural outlook___________________________________________ 130 Oris Y. Wells, Administrator, Agricultural Marketing Service, Department of Agriculture______________________________ 130 Price changes and policy implications______________________________ 159 Recent price changes— Factors in price changes— Policy implica tions of price changes and prospects_________________________ 159 Leon H. Keyserling, consulting economist___________.______ 159 Jules Backman, professor, School of Commerce, Accounts, and Finance, New York University_____________ _______ 168 Otis Brubaker, research director, United Steelworkers of ISO America________________________________________________ Bradford B. Smith, economist, United States Steel Corp____ 299 George Hitchings, manager, economic-analysis department, Ford Motor Co________ __________________ ________ _ 301 Nat Weinberg, director, research department, United Auto Workers________________________________________ ____ 306 Karl Fox, professor, department of economics and sociology, Iowa State College of Agriculture and Mechanical Arts__ 313 Albert Rees, professor, economics department, University of 315 Chicago__ ________________________________ _____________ Fiscal and monetary policy for the coming year________ _____ 409 Impact of Federal fiscal and monetary policies on State and local governments______ _________________ ;________________________ 409 Walter W. Heller, professor, School of Business Administra tion, University of Minnesota-:_________________________ 409 Benjamin U. Ratehford, professor, department of economics, Duke University______________________ :_________________ 418 Recommended fiscal and monetary policy for 1957_____________ 423 Louis Shere, professor, department of economies, University of Indiana____^ _______ _________________________________ 423 Lester V. Chandler, professor, department of economics and sociology, Princeton University____________________ 472 Effectiveness and relationship of fiscal and monetary poliey____ 475 Alfred Neal, president, Committee for Economic Develop ment___________________________________________________ 475 Seymour E. Harris, chairman and professor, department of economics. Harvard University__________________________ 476 Fiscal and monetary policy for the coming year:________________ 533 George M. Humphrey, Secretary of the Treasury________ 533, 587 William McC. Martin, Jr., Chairman, Federal Reserve Board_____________________ _____________________________ 587 m IV CONTENTS Panel discussions and individual witnesses in order of appearance— Con. General views and recommendations of economic interest and research Page groups----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------633 General__________________________ _____ ___ _____________________ 634 Ralph Watkins, chairman of the board of trustees, Federal Statistics Users’ Conference_____________________________ 634 Agriculture____________________________________________________ 638 W. E. Hamilton, director of research, American Farm Bu reau Federation_____ _______ ___________________ _______ 638 Herschel D. Newsom, master, the National Grange______ 646 John A. Baker, coordinator of legislative matters, National Farmers Union_________________________________________ 650 Business___________________ _____________________ ______________ 702 Walter D. Fackler, economist for the Chamber of Commerce 702 of the United States of America_________________________ Frazar B. Wilde, chairman, research and policy committee, Committee for Economic Development__________________ 709 719 Labor_________________________________________________________ Peter Henle, assistant director, research departirent, Ameri can Federation of Labor and Congress of Industrial Organ izations_________________________________________________ 719 Don Mahon, National Independent Union Council_________ 727 Statements and exhibits: Backman, Jules, professor of economics, New York University_______ 168 Exhibits: Changes in the major groups of the wholesale price index, June 1955-December 1956____________ _________________ 178 Changes in the major groups of the wholesale price index, December 1955-December 1956_________________________ 179 Corporate profits before taxes and national income, 1946-56_ 388 Daily index numbers and spot primary market commodity prices, May 31, 1955, January 10, 1956, and January 10, 1957____________________________________________________ 180 Relationship of compensation of employees to total national income, 1929-56________________________________________ 396 Wage-productivity comparisons___________________________ 372 Wholesale price indexes by economic sector, June 1955, December 1955, and December 1956____________________ 179 Baker, John A., coordinator of legislative matters, National Farmers Union______________________________ _____________________________ 650 Exhibit: Legislative analysis memorandums____________________ 655 Brubaker, Otis, research director, United Steelworkers of America___ 180 Exhibits: Comparative changes in materials and employment costs in United States Steel Corp-----------------------------------------------298 Facts on Steel: Profits, Productivity, Prices and Wages, 1956— Steel and the National Economy, 1956____________ 187 Brundage, Percival F., Director of the Bureau of the Budget (ac companied by Robert E. Merriam, Assistant Director; Ravmond T. Bowman, Assistant Director for Statistical Standards; William F, McCandless, Assistant Director for Budcret Review; and Samuel M. Cohn, Chief of Fiscal Analysis of the Office of Budget Review).. 50 Exhibits: Analysis of surplus personal property disposal other than scrap, Department of Defense___________________________ 65 Balances carried forward, by type of authority, at end of year, fiscal years 1954 through 1958_____________________ 60 Budget authorizations ceasing to be available, fiscal vears 1953-56____________________________________________*____ 61 Budget comparison, 1957-58______________________________ 54 Budget receipts, by source_________________________________ 82 Budget trends_____________________________________________ 52 Estimated holdings of United States Government bonds and notes by foreign countries_______________________________ 74 Expenditures for land and water resources included in nat ural resources function of the budget____________________ 72 Federal budget expenditures_______________________________ 53 Items listed in budget schedules under the heading “ Recovery of Prior Year Obligations” in 1958 budget......... .................. 63 CONTENTS V Statements and exhibits— Continued Chandler, Lester V., professor, department of economics and sociology, Page Princeton, University______________________________________ ____ 472 Exhi nt: Letter to Chairman, February 4, 1957________________ 530 Clague, Ewan, Commissioner of Labor Statistics, United States Department of Labor____________________________________________ 86 Exhibits: Annual changes in total labor force, by sex________________ 105 Average hourly earnings in selected durable goods industries. 110 Average hourly earnings in selected nondurable goods industries_______________________________________________ 111 Average hourly earnings of production workers or nonsupervisory employees in selected industries, annual averages, 1955 and 1956, and November 1955 and 1956________ 98 109 Average hourly earnings in selected industries_______ _ ____ _ Average weekly earnings and real weekly earnings in manu facturing_______________________________________________ 113 Comparison of actual and projected total labor force_______ 106 Consumer price index for wage earner and clerical-worker 116 families in United States cities, 1947-49=100___________ Consumer price index, special groupings, 1939= 100________ 117 Deferred wage increases scheduled to go into effect in 1957 in situations affecting 1,000 or more workers in manufac turing and selected nonmanufacturing industries_________ 101 Deviation of actual from trend labor force, by age and sex, annual average, 1951-56________________________________ 91 Employed persons with two or more jobs__________________ 142 Employees in nonagricultural establishments_______________ 107 Employment and average weekly hours of production workers in durable and nondurable goods manufacturing-_ 108 Estimated number of workers covered by cost-of-living esca lator clauses, January 1, 1957___________________________ 102 Factory weekly earnings, gross and net spendable compared with real net spendable earnings expressed in 1947-49 dollars__________________________________________ _______ 112 Full-time and part-time workers in nonagricultural industries and in agriculture, by sex, annual average 1956,1955,1947. 142 Hours worked in nonagricultural industries------------------------93 Number of workers who will be affected by deferred increases in selected union wage scales in the construction industry due in 1957____________________________________ ________ 102 Part-time employment___________________________ _______ 141 Percentage distribution of changes in union wage scales in seven construction trades in major cities, 1955 and 1956__ 99 Primary market price indexes for major community groups, highs and lows, 1954-56__________________________ ______ 103 Weekly hours of wage and salary workers in agriculture and nonagricultural industries______________________ ________ 93 Response to question by Chairman Patman on the effect of agricultural price movements on the consumer price index___________________________________________________ 598 Wholesale price index, economic sector indexes, selected groups, 1947-49= 100^............... .............................................. 115 114 Wholesale prices, 1947-49= 100_ _____________ _____________ Fackler, Walter D., economist for the Chamber of Commerce of the United States_______________________________________ ___ ____ ____ 702 Fox, Karl, head, department of economics and sociology, Iowa State College of Agriculture and Mechanical Arts_____________ ________ 313 Gainsbrugh, Martin R., chief economist of the National Industrial Conference Board_______________________________________________ 121 Exhibit: United States exports and imports of goods and services and net foreign investment, 1952-57__________________ _____ 126 Hamilton, W. E., director of research, American Farm Bureau Fed eration_____________________________ _________________ _____ _____ 638 Harris, Dr. Seymour, chairman and professor, department of eco nomics, Harvard University__ ________________________ ._____ _____ 476 Exhibit: Supplemental statement______________________ ____ ___ 495 VI CONTENTS Statements and exhibits— Continued Heller, Walter W., professor, School of Business Administration, University of Minnesota________________________________ ____________ 409 Henle, Peter, assistant director, research department, American Fed eration of Labor and Congress of Industrial Organizations________ 719 Exhibit: Comparison of increase in average hourly earnings and wholesale prices, selected manufacturing industries, October 1955 to October 1956_____ __________________________________ 756 Hitchings, George, manager, economic analysis department, Ford Motor C o_______________________________________________________ 301 Exhibit: Distribution of national income in manufacturing, 1948-56_____________________________________________________ 305 Humphrey, Hon. George M., Secretary of the Treasury, accompanied by: W. Randolph Burgess, Under Secretary; Dan Throop Smith, deputy to the Secretary; William T. Heffelfinger, Fiscal Assistant Secretary; and Robert P. Mayo, Chief, Analysis Staff, Debt Di vision___________________________________________________________ 533 Exhibits: Annual changes in private debt____________________________ 540 Annual changes in public and private debt_________________ 541 Calendar year income levels assumed in the revenue esti mates for fiscal 1957 and fiscal 1958____________________ 20 Letter to Hon. Paul II. Douglas, January 16, 1957, and enclosure_______________________________________________ 19 Liquid assets of individuals________________________________ 542 Ownership of the public debt______________________________ 542 Personal saving, percent of savings to disposable personal in come_________________________________ _________________ 541 Principal trust funds that invest in public-debt obligations. _ 563 Public and private debt___________________________________ 540 Katona, George, director of economic program, survey research center, and professor of economics and of psychology, University o f Michigan_______________________________________ _____________ ! 128 Keyserling, Leon II., consulting economist__________________________ 159 Exhibits: Balance was better in 1947-53_____________________________ 164a Labor and farm incomes, 1953-56 grew too slowly relative to other incomes to sustain full prosperity__________________ 164a Mahon, Don, executive secretary, National Independent Union Council__________________________________________________________ 727 Martin, William McChesney, Jr., Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, accompanied by Ralph A. Young, Director, Division of Research and Statistics!__________________ 587 Exhibit: Answers to supplemental questions addressed to the Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System______________________________________________________ 591 McDonald, David J., president, United Steel Workers of America____ 181 Meany, George, president, American Federation of Labor and Con gress of Industlial Organizations_________________________________ 719 National Association of Manufacturers_____________________________ 742 Exhibit: Money supply, goods, and services____________________ 746 Neal, Alfred, president, Committee for Economic Development______ 475 Exhibit: Letter to Hon. Joseph C. O’ Mahoney, February 5, 1957. 510 Newsom, Herschel D., master, the National Grang;e_________________ 646 Paradiso, Louis J., Assistant Director, and chief statistician, Office of Business Economics, Department of Commerce__________________ 118 Exhibit: Letter from M. Joseph Meehan, Director, Office of Business Economics, Department of Commerce, to Hon. Paul H. Douglas, January 18, 1957, transmitting table on Federal Government receipts and expenditures: administrative budget, cash budget and national income and product account: 1956-58. 121 Ratehford, Benjamin U., professor, department of economics, Duke University__ ____________________________________________________ 418 Exhibit: Letter to chairman, February 4, 1957_________________ 530 Rees, Albert, associate professor of economics, University of Chicago. 315 Saulnier, Dr. Raymond J., Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers; Joseph S. Davis, member of the Council; and Paul W. McCracken, member of the Council________________ ______ ______ 8 CONTENTS Statements and exhibits— Continued Saulnier, Dr. Raymond J.— Continued Exhibit: Letter to chairman, December 19, 1956_______________ Shere, Louis, professor, department of economics, University of Indiana__________________________________________________________ Exhibits: Comments on questions by Representative Patrnan________ Federal tax revision to promote economic growth and sta bility___________________________________________________ Smith, Bradford B., economist, United States Steel Corp__________ Watkins, Ralph J., chairman of the board of t rust ees, Federal Statistics Users’ Conference___________________________________ ____________ Exhibit: Description of the conference_________________________ Weinberg, Nat, director, research department, United Auto Workers. Exhibit : United States Oil Output Sets A New High, Gasoline Inventories Increase: and Gasoline Prices Will Rise Today, Articles from New York Times, January 10, 1957____________ Wells, Oris V., Administrator of the Agricultural Marketing Service, Department of Agriculture_______________________________________ Exhibits: Factors in farm production per unit of farm output_________ Farm capital expenditures, 1939, and 1946-56_____________ Farm output and population______________________________ Farmers’ prices___________________________________________ Prices received by farmers, prices paid or parity index, and parity ratio, United States, by months, February 1951January 1957, 1910-14=100____________________________ Response to question by Chairman Patman on the effect of Agricultural price movements on the Consumer Price Index___________________________________________________ Selected data relating to agriculture, United States, 1939, and 1946-56......... - ___________________________ _____ ____ Wilde, Frazar B., chairman, Research and Policy Committee, Com mittee for Economic Development_______________________________ Additional information: Address by Arthur F. Burns, Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers, before the National Federation of Financial Analysts Societies, Boston, Mass., May 21, 1956___________________________ Average prices paid by farmers at independent stores December 15, 1956, compared to December 15, 1947____________________________ Average prices received by farmers for farm products in United States, January 15, 1957, compared to January 15, 1948_________________ Bond yields and money market rates 1947, and each week ending February 2, 1957________________________________________________ Budget estimates for 1956__________________________________________ Chronology of budget estimates for 1956____________________________ Comparison of estimates and appropriations by sessions of Congress (fiscal years 1946-57)____________________________________________ Eisenhower Planning Special Program of Tax Aid, Other Relief for Small Business for Next Congress, article in the Wall Street Journal, October 22, 1956_________________ ________ ______________________ Implications of recent expansion of special amortization program____ Information re consumer price level, submitted by Representative Curtis___________________________________________________________ Letter of Hon. Wright Patman, chairman, to Dr. Raymond J. Saulnier, chairman, Council of Economic Advisers, December 19, 1956....................... .................................................................................... Reply................................................... .................................................... Press release and schedule of hearings______________________________ Progress report by the Cabinet Committee on Small Business, August 7, 1956__________________ _____ __________________________ Questions posed by the January 1957 Economic Report of the Presi dent, prepared by the staff of the Joint Economic Committee______ Report of the United States delegate to the meeting of the Economic Commission for Asia and the Far East Working Party on Economic Development and Planning, Bangkok, Thailand, September 17-29, 1956-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- vn Page 48 423 532 424 299 634 636 306 390 130 137 132 136 135 158 598 134 709 618 529 530 529 762 763 567 569 764 623 46 48 1 571 40 776 y in CONTENTS Additional information— Continued Report on the working group on short-term indicators of economic changes of the Conference of European Statisticians______________ Selected economic indicators 1947-56 with percentage changes_____ Speech by Raymond T. Bowman, Assistant Director for Statistical Standards, Bureau of the Budget, at the annual dinner meeting of the Washington Statistical Society, January 28, 1957_____________ Steel’s depreciation problem, address of Benjamin F. Fairless, Ameri can Iron and Steel Institute______________________________________ Summary of the economic situation and outlook, prepared by the committee staff on the basis of information contained in Economic Indicators, April 1956____________________________________________ What Price Enough Steel? by Roger M. Blough, chairman of the board, United States Steel Corp__________________________________ 785 528 697 341 616 336 JANUARY 1957 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT MONDAY, JANUARY 28, 1957 C o n g r e ss o f t h e U n it e d S t a t e s , J o in t E c o n o m ic C o m m it t e e , Washington, D. C. (This hearing was held in executive session o f the committee, but is made a part o f the printed record by mutual consent.) The committee met at 10 a. m., pursuant to call, in the District Com mittee Room of the Capitol, in executive session, Hon. Wright Patman (chairman) presiding. Present: Representatives Patman (presiding), Bolling, Mills, Talle, Curtis, and Kilburn and Senator Watkins. Present also: Dr. Grover W. Ensley, executive director of the joint committee, and John W. Lehman, clerk of the joint committee. Chairman P a t m a n . The committee will come to order. On January 23, the President transmitted his Economic Report to the Congress, and it was referred to this committee for study as pro vided by the act of 1946. Senate Joint Resolution 2, passed by the Congress in the opening days of this session, authorized the President to transmit the report this year, 3 days after the statutory deadline of January 20. The Joint Economic Committee is to advise the Congress with re spect to the main recommendations contained in the President’s report, on or before March 1. As chairman of the committee I know I speak for all members of the committee in hoping that we again this year can transmit a construc tive report to the Congress before that deadline. At its organization meeting of January 22, the Committee unani mously approved the procedure for hearings which will be followed during the next 8 days. Without objection, I will insert in the record at this point the schedule of hearings agreed upon, and which I released on January 25. (Information referred to follows:) [F o r release F riday a. m., January 25, 1957] C O N G R E S S O F T H E U N IT E D S T A T E S J O IN T E C O N O M IC C O M M IT T E E C h a i r m a n P a t m a n A n n o u n c e s H e a r in g s o n t h e P r e s id e n t ’ s E c o n o m ic R epo rt Representative Wright Patman (Democrat, Texas), chairman o f the Joint Economic Committee, has announced plans of the joint committee to hold 8 days of hearings, commencing January 28, on the President’s Economic Report which was transmitted to Congress on Wednesday (January 23). 1 2 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Under the Employment Act of 1946, the President’s Economic Report is re ferred to the Joint Economic Committee, which is to review it and “ * * * file a report with the Senate and the House o f Representatives containing its find ings and recommendations with respect to each of the main recommendations made by the President in the Economic Report * * At its organization meeting on January 22, the committee unanimously ap proved the procedure for hearings set forth in the attached schedule. A 2-page summary o f the hearings is shown first. This is followed by a detailed list o f witnesses, topics and questions. All o f the hearings will be held in the old Supreme Court Chamber, Senate wing o f the Capitol, starting at 10 a. m. each day. J o i n t E c o n o m ic C o m m itte e W RIGHT PATMAN, Representative, Texas, Chairman JOHN SPARKMAN, Senator, Alabama, Vice Chairman HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES SENATE RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri W ILBUR D. MILLS, Arkansas AUGUSTINE B. KELLEY, Pennsylvania HENRY O. TALLE, Iowa THOMAS B. CURTIS, Missouri CLARENCE E. KILBURN, New York PAUL H. DOUGLAS, Illinois J. W . FULBRIGHT, Arkansas JOSEPH C. O’MAHONEY, Wyoming RALPH E. FLANDERS, Vermont ARTHUR V. WATKINS, Utah BARRY GOLDWATER, Arizona G rover W. E n sl e y , Executive Director Clerk J ohn W. L e h m an , H e a r in g s o n t h e P r e s id e n t’s 1957 E c o n o m ic R e p o r t 1 S u m m ary January 28 (Monday)— (executive session): Council o f Economic Advisers: Raymond J. Saulnier, Chairman. Joseph S. Davis, member. Paul W. McCracken, member. January 29 (Tuesday)—The Federal Budget: Percival F. Brundage, Director, Bureau o f the Budget. January 30 (Wednesday) : Panel: Economic Outlook for the Coming Y ear: Labor Force, Hours, Productivity, and Potential Output: Ewan Clague, Commissioner, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Department o f Labor. Government Demand for Goods and Services: Louis J. Paradiso, Assistant Director and Chief Statistician, Office o f Business Economics, Department of Commerce. Business Demand: Martin Gainsbrugh, Chief Economist, National Industrial Conference Board. Consumer Demand: George Katona, program director, survey research center, University of Michigan. Agricultural Outlook: Oris V. Wells, Administrator, Agricultural Marketing Service, Depart ment of Agriculture. January 31 (Thursday)—Panel: Price Changes and Policy Implications: Recent Price Changes. Factors in Price Changes. Policy Implications o f Price Changes and Prospects. Leon H. Keyserling, consulting economist. Jules Backman, professor, school o f commerce, accounts and finance^ New York University. Otis Brubaker, research director, United Steelworkers o f America. Bradford Smith, economist, United States Steel Corp. 1 Hearings will be held in the old Supreme Court Chamber, Senate wing, United) StatM Capitol. All sessions are open to the public except on January 28. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 3 January 31, etc.— Continued ; i George Hitchings, manager, economic analysis department, Ford Motor Co. Nat Weinberg, director, research department, United Auto Workers. Karl Fox, professor, department of economics and sociology, Iowa State College of Agriculture and Mechanical Arts. Albert Rees, professor, economics department, University o f Chicago. February 1 (F riday)— Panel: Fiscal and Monetary Policy for the Coming Y ear: Effectiveness and Relationship o f Fiscal and Monetary P olicy: Alfred Neal, President, Committee for Economic Development. Seymour E. Harris, chairman and professor, department of economics. Harvard University. Impact of Federal Fiscal and Monetary Policies on State and Local Govern ments : Walter Heller, professor, school o f business administration, University o f Minnesota. Benjamin U. Ratchford, professor, department o f economics, Duke University. Recommended Fiscal and Monetary Policy for 1957: Louis Shere, professor, department of economics, University o f Indiana. Lester V, Chandler, professor, department o f economics and sociology, Princeton University. February 4 (Monday)— Fiscal and Monetary Policy for the Coming Y ear:, George M. Humphrey, Secretary of the Treasury. February 5 (Tuesday)—Fiscal and Monetary Policy for the Coming Year: William McC. Martin, Jr., Chairman, Federal Reserve Board. February 6 (Wednesday)—Invited Panel: General Views and Recommendations o f Economic Interest and Research Groups: 2 Agriculture: Charles B. Shuman, president, American Farm Bureau Federation. Herschel D. Newsom, master, the National Grange. James G. Patton, president, the National Farmers Union. Business: John S. Coleman, president, United States Chamber o f Commerce. Ernest S. Swigert, president, National Association of Manufacturers. Frazar B. Wilde, Chairman, Research and Policy Committee, Committee for Economic Development. L abor: George Meany, president, American Federation o f Labor and Congress o f Industrial Organizations. John L. Lewis, president, United Mine Workers o f America. G. E. Leighty, chairman, Railway Labor Executives Association. Don Mahon, executive secretary, National Independent Union Council. General: Ralph Watkins, chairman o f the board o f trustees, Federal Statistics Users’ Conference. HEARINGS ON THE PRESIDENT’S 1957 ECONOMIC REPO R T8 D e t a il d a t e s , w it n e s s e s , t o p ic s , a n d q u e s t io n s January 28 (M onday)— Council o f Economic Advisers (executive session): Raymond J. Saulnier, Chairman, accompanied by Joseph S. Davis and Paul W. McCracken, members. 1. What are the levels of employment, production, and purchasing power needed in 1957 to carry out the objectives o f the Employment Act? 2. What are the current and foreseeable trends in employment, produc tion, and purchasing power? a Written statements of other groups will be received. 8 Hearings will be held in the old Supreme Court Chamber, Senate wing, United States Capitol. All sessions are open to the public except on January 28. 4 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT January 28, etc.— Continued 3. What assumptions with respect to prices, national income, personal income, corporate profits, and the like, underlie the President’s Economic Report? 4. Review the effects o f present Federal economic programs on employ ment, production, and purchasing power. 5. How will the recommendations set forth in the President’s Economic Report contribute to achieving the objectives o f the Employment Act? January 29 (Tuesday)— The Federal Budget: Percival F. Brundage, Director, Bureau of the Budget. 1. What are the major changes in expenditures and revenues contem plated in the President’s budget for fiscal year 1958? 2. What assumptions with respect to prices, national income, personal income, corporate profits, and the like, underlie the President’s budget? 3. What commitments extending beyond fiscal year 1958 are contemplated by the budget? 4. How will these changes in the budget affect the economy in the year and years ahead? 5. Elaborate on the provisions in the budget for improving the Federal statistical program during the coming year. How far will these improve ments take us toward the goal of an integrated Federal statistical system? January 30 (Wednesday)—Panel: Economic Outlook for the Coming Year Labor Force, Hours, Productivity, and Potential Output: Ewan Clague, Commissioner, Bureau o f Labor Statistics, Depart ment o f Labor. 1. Compare actual changes in the labor force, hours o f work, pro ductivity, and output during 1956 with long-run trends. 2. How would these long-run trends works out in 1957? 3. What is the present outlook for prices—consumer, wholesale, con struction, etc. in 1957? Are these indices good measures o f inflation? Government Demand for Goods and Services: Louis J. Paradiso, Assistant Director and Chief Statistician, Office of Business Economics, Department o f Commerce. 1. Translate the budget estimates into expenditures for goods and services and incomes from national product for calendar 1957, com parable with past periods as published by the Department of Commerce. 2. W h a t are the likely trends in receipts and expenditures o f S tate and local governm ents in 1 9 5 6 -5 7 in term s o f the national incom e and prod uct accounts? 3. What is the present outlook for prices, as reflected in the value o f total national product in 1957? Business Demand: Martin Gainsbrugh, Chief Economist, National Industrial Confer ence Board. 1. On the basis o f surveys, how much investment are businessmen planning for 1957? I-Iow would this compare with 1956 in terms o f the national product categories in dollar values and in real values? 2. What is the consensus concerning spending in 1957 for residential construction? For inventories? For net private foreign investment? 3. What is the outlook for financing this investment from internal and external sources? Consumer Demand: George Katona, program director, survey research center, Univer sity of Michigan. 1. What evidence is available as to consumer plans and expectations for 1957? What will likely be the rate of personal savings? What do consumers anticipate with respect to price movements? 2. Translate these expectations into estimates o f consumer spending in 1957. Agricultural Outlook: Oris V. Wells, Administrator, Agricultural Marketing Service, De partment o f Agriculture. 1. What is the outlook for farm production, price, and income in 1957? 2. How will this affect the farmer’s spending on new construction and farm machinery? ECONOMIC REPORT OP THE PRESIDENT 5 January 31 (Thursday)—Panel: Price Changes and Policy Implications: Recent Price Changes: 1. What significance do you attach to recent price developments? What is the import of the differences in movements during recent years o f the index o f wholesale prices, consumer prices, construction, pro ducers’ equipment, and of the implicit deflator for gross national product? 2. T o what extent do retail prices now reflect the changes that have taken place in 1956 at the raw material and manufacturing levels? Do recent changes in wholesale prices foreshadow further rises in retail prices in 1957 ? I f so, by how much ? 3. What implications for wage changes in 1957 are contained in present labor contracts and in trends in prices ? 4. Can you differentiate between price movements in “ competitive” areas and in the so-called administered price areas; between relatively big and relatively small business; in industries showing relatively high profits and in industries with relatively low profits; in industries with increasing demand and in industries with declining demand? Factor in Price Changes: 1. What are the most significant factors responsible fo r recent price changes? 2. To what extent do you believe these will continue to exert an upward influence on prices? For how long? Policy Implications o f Price Changes and Prospects: 1. Are fiscal and monetary policies sufficiently stringent to prevent general price increases consistent with maintaining present low levels of unemployment? Can fiscal and monetary policy stem inflationary trends which result from cost-price pressures? 2. What changes in other economic policies—private as well as pub lic—would increase the effectiveness of restraints on inflationary price increases? Leon H. Keyserling, consulting economist. Jules Bachman, professor, school of commerce, accounts and finance, New York University. Otis Brubaker, research director, United Steelworkers o f America. Bradford Smith, economist, United States Steel Corp. George Hitchings, manager, economic analysis department, Ford Motor Co. Nat Weinberg, director, research department, United Auto Workers. Karl Fox, professor, department o f economics and sociology, Iowa State College o f Agriculture and Mechanical Arts. Albert Rees, professor, economics department, University of Chicago. February 1 (F riday)—Panel: Fiscal and Monetary Policy for the Coming Year: Effectiveness and Relationship o f Fiscal and Monetary P olicy: Alfred Neal, president, Committee for Economic Development. Seymour E. Harris, chairman and professor, department of eco nomics, Harvard University. 1. Are we currently relying too heavily on monetary policy in lieu o f fiscal policy for restraining inflationary pressures? What standards would you suggest for determining the relative emphasis which should be placed on use o f monetary policy and of fiscal policy for stabilization purposes? 2. Are fiscal and monetary policy working together or at cross pur poses with respect to economic stabilization? 3. Are fiscal and monetary policies sufficiently stringent to prevent general price increases consistent with maintaining present low levels o f unemployment? Can fiscal and monetary policy stem inflationary trends which result from cost-price pressures? Impact o f Federal Fiscal and Monetary Policies on State and Local Govern ments : Walter Heller, professor, school of business administration, Univisity of Minnesota. Benjamin U. Ratchford, professor, department o f economics, Duke University. 6 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT February 1, etc.— Continued 1. Have recent monetary policy developments significantly affected the volume of State and local government construction programs? 2. What are the problems of improving the relative financial position o f State and local governments during periods of inflationary strain? Can these problems be solved at the State and local level or do they call for Federal action? 3. Evaluate the financial resources o f State and local governments for meeting their long-range responsibilities. In general terms, what type o f long-range adjustments in Federal, State, and local government revenue systems may be called for by currently projected demands for public services? Recommended Fiscal and Monetary Policy of 1957: Louis Shere, professor, department of economic, University of Indiana. Lester V. Chandler, professor, department o f economics and sociol ogy, Princeton University. 1. What recommendations for general or structural revisions in fiscal and monetary policy would you make at this time? 2. Should the scope of general credit controls be broadened to include financial intermediaries other than commercial banks which are members o f the Federal Reserve System? 3. What devices would you suggest to direct a larger proportion o f the available credit supply to certain purposes with a high social priority, e. g., school construction, while retaining general credit restraint? February 4 (M onday)—Fiscal and Monetary Policy for the Coming Year. Con tinued. George M. Humphrey, Secretary of the Treasury. 1. Do you have any recommendations for general or structural revisions in tax policy at this time? Do you have any long-range recommendations for tax revision for promoting steady economic growth? 2. Could we have improved upon the division o f labor between tax policy and monetary policy as instruments of restraint during the past year? 3. If inflationary pressures abate during the year, would you recommend priority be given to fiscal or to monetary easing? 4. What do you foresee as the Treasury’s principal debt management problems in the year ahead, assuming the continuation of tight money? February 5 (Tuesday)— Fiscal and Monetary Policy for the Coming Year, Con tinued : William McC. Martin, Jr., Chairman, Federal Reserve Board. 1. What information do you have about the impact of so-called general credit controls upon small business as compared with big business? Upon State and local governments as compared with nongovernmental credit users ? 2. Are present statutory provisions governing reserve requirements satis factory and desirable? 3. Is the breadth of direct control (now limited to member banks) suffi cient for the workings o f general monetary controls, or should the direct influence o f central bank operations be extended to cover other financial intermediaries, such as insurance companies, savings and loan associations, installment credit institutions, nonmember banks, etc.? 4. Is there any acceptable way of restraining the demand for loans without raising the interest rates? 5. Have you any general suggestions for revision o f the present institu tional arrangements in the field o f money and banking, which would facili tate the use of general credit controls for economic stabilization? February 6 (Wednesday)— Invited Panel: General Views and Recommendations of Economic Interest and Research Groups: 4 * Written statements of other groups will be received. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 7 February 6, etc.— Continued Agriculture: American Farm Bureau Federation, Charles B. Shuman, president, 2300 Merchandise Mart, Chicago 54, 111. The National Grange, Herschel D. Newsom, master, 744 Jackson Place, NW., Washington 6, D. C. The National Farmers Union, James G. Patton, president, 1404 New York Avenue, NW., Washington 5, D. C. Business: Chamber of Commerce o f the United States of America, John S. Coleman, president, 1015 H Street, NW., Washington 6, D. C. National Association of Manufacturers, Ernest S. Swigert, president, 2 East 48th Street, New York 17, N. Y. Committee for Economic Development, Frazar B. Wilde, chairman, research and policy committee, 1729 H Street, NW., Washington, D. C. L abor: American Federation of Labor and Congress of Industrial Organizations, George Tvlcauy, president, S15 10th Street, NW., Washington 6, D. C. Railway Labor Executive Association, G. E. Leighty, chairman, 1001 Connecticut Avenue, NW., Washington 6, D. C. United Mine Workers of America, John L. Lewis, president, 900 15th Street, NW., Washington 5, D. C. National Independent Union Council, Don Mahon, executive secretary, Warner Building, Washington 4, D. C. General: Federal Statistics Users’ Conference, Ralph J. Watkins, chairman, board of trustees, 1741 K Street, NW., Washington, D. C. Chairman P a t m a n . This morning in executive session the com mittee will hear from the Council of Economic Advisers. At this point, I would like to insert in the record an exchange of correspond ence between the Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers and myself last December with respect to the manner in which this par ticular hearing will be held. ( See p. 40.) I am happy to say the proposed compromise was unanimously agreed to by the Joint Economic Committee at its organization meet ing on January 22. The agreement is as follows: This meeting will be in executive session with a transcript taken of those parts of the meeting which the Council feels will not jeopardize its position. At any point in the hearing when the Council feels it is entering into an area where it wishes to “ roll up its sleeves,” it will be given permission to go off the record with no stenographic notes made. Upon completion of this portion, it will go back onto the record. The Council will be given the privilege of editing the transcript and of providing addi tional elaborations or deletions. This edited transcript will then be made a part of the printed hearings for the benefit of the committee members, the Congress, and the general public. I know that all present today hope that this procedure will work well. I am sure that it will. Our first witness this morning is Raymond J. Saulnier, Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers. Dr. Saulnier, will you introduce your two colleague Council mem bers and proceed with any introductory remarks that you may care to make preliminary to questions from the committee. 8 ECONOMIC REPORT 0 1 THE PRESIDENT STATEMENTS OF DR. RAYMOND J. SAULNIER, CHAIRMAN OP THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS; JOSEPH S. DAVIS, MEMBER OF THE COUNCIL; AND PAUL W. McCRACKEN, MEMBER OF THE COUNCIL Dr. S a u l n i e r . Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have with me this morning my two colleagues on the Council of Economic Advisers, Dr. Joseph S. Davis, and Dr. Paul McCracken. I want to say at the outset that I appreciate very much the courtesy you have shown the Council in arranging for the procedures under which we are here this morning, and under which we are to discuss with you the major findings of the Economic Report. Chairman P a tm a n . For the Chair, I will state that we are pleased with your attitude, and we are glad to know that you are working with us. Dr. S a u l n i e r . Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman P a t m a n . It is a very fine and cooperative way. Dr. S a u l n i e r . We recognize your interest in an objective discussion of these questions, and we want to do everything we can to advance a better understanding of our Nation’s economic problems. I have no prepared statement, Mr. Chairman, and I would be glad to proceed at once with any questions that you want to put before me or my associates on the Council. I should like to feel, Mr. Chairman* that I may, from time to time, refer to my colleagues any questions that are beyond my competence. Chairman P a t m a n . I would like to ask you 1 or 2 questions, and then I will yield to Mr. Bolling who must go to another committee meeting. The discussion of the tight credit policy on pages 42 and 44 acknowl edges that the effects have been highly uneven, with small business and the home-building industry being adversely affected. Moreover, it is conceded that moderate restraints are not sufficient to deal with the recent price pressures, while stronger restraints would injure innocent bystanders, and risk the possibility of a recession. What, then, are the benefits of a policy of general credit control? Dr. S a u l n i e r . Mr. Chairman, this is an aspect of economic policy that is of very special interest to me. I have no quarrel, really, with the policy that has been followed—one which since late 1954 has been moving toward greater tightness. But certain aspects of that policy seems to me to have been undesirable. Now, two, in particular, have been mentioned directly. One is the effect on housing, on home build ing and home purchase; the other is the effect on small business. It was already becoming evident in late 1955 that small-business concerns were having rather special difficulty in satisfying their credit needs. We saw this m a rather rapid pickup in the volume of applica tions for credit to the SB A. Another aspect of that interested us. Without changing their credit standards at all, SBA was finding that an increasing proportion o f its applications qualified for loan assistance. This meant that the average quality of the risks that were coming to SBA was improving. What this suggested to me was that, increasingly, small-business con cerns—not concerns in trouble, but concerns of pretty good quality— ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 9 were finding it difficult to meet their credit needs through the private banking system. One of the first things we did, therefore, was to propose a supple mentary appropriation for SBA. Chairman P a t m a n . It was $20 million. Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is right. Chairman P a t m a n . That is the part that I could not understand. I f you were disturbed at all, $20 million for the whole United States would not mean too much. Dr. S a u l n i e r . Well, we made a proposal for a sum which in our judgment would enable the SBA to take care of the flow of applica tions that was coming to it at the time. Chairman P a t m a n . I f you do not mind, let me ask a question there. The objection of the tight money policy was to restrain house build ing because it was inflationary, was it not ? Dr. S a u ln i e r . That was one of the objects. Chairman P a t m a n . It was the principal object, I would assume. Dr. S a u l n i e r . I would not say, Congressman Patman, that it was the principal object. Chairman P a t m a n . It was a major objective? Dr. S a u ln i e r . It was one of the objectives. Chairman P a t m a n . N o w , that being true, you had 2 ways to do it; 1 is to use the interest rate which would affect everybody, and the other was to use powers that you had to increase the downpayment and shorten the term of payment which would have restrained home building effectively, which I assume you will admit? Why did you not use the latter instead of the former ? Dr. S a u l n i e r . We did use the latter, as you know. Chairman P a t m a n . Only to a very limited extent; was it not? Dr. S a u l n i e r . We used it to the extent that we thought, judging the situation as best we could, was needed. We added 2 percent to the downpayment requirements for both FH A and Y A loans. We shortened the maximum permissible maturity from 30 to 25 years. I think it is, if I may say so, not correct to interpret the general monetary policy as having been designed exclusively to cut back home building. That was not the case. Chairman P a t m a n . It may not have been so designed, but it was one of the ends you had in mind, because in home building there would be increased competition for scarce materials and labor and, for that reason, it would be inflationary. Dr. S a u l n i e r . This was, Congressman Patman, I believe, one of the considerations they had in mind; but only one. Let me reiterate that if the problem put on me had been “ How should we restrain home building?” and if I understood that that was the only problem, I would never propose general monetary restraints. Chairman P a t m a n . I am glad to hear you say that. Dr. S a u l n i e r . I would do it through the selective devices available to the Federal Government. Chairman P a t m a n . That is what I was getting to. Dr. S a u l n i e r . In connection with its mortgage guaranty and in surance programs. Chairman P a t m a n . I will yield to Congressman Bolling, as he has to go to another meeting. ------ 2 87624— 57 10 ECONOMIC REPORT OP THE PRESIDENT Eepresentative B o l l i n g . I regret very much that I do have to leave, and if I was going to stay I would question along somewhat different lines. On this particular subject, one of the other areas that has disturbed me in regard to the effect of a tighter money policy has been the impact that this policy has had on municipalities, school boards, and other problems. It raises, again, a question which has been in my mind ever since I have had the privilege of participating in the Patman subcommittee deliberations on general credit control and debt management some years ago. That is the question as to whether or not very serious consideration needs to be given to achieving a more flexible instrument than the instruments available to us presently. I approach that question with no preconceptions, and I have no notion as to what the more flexible instrument might be or could be or should be. When I see that the interest rate on tax-exempt municipals is some where around 5 percent that may be a little high, but it is in that eneral area—and I translate this back into what it means to a school istrict trying to float bonds, I am concured. Dr. S a u l n i e r . Y o u mean b y a more flexible instrument, a more selective instrument, or general credit restraint ? Representative B o l l i n g . Yes. Dr. S a u l n i e r . I must confess, Congressman Bolling, that my in stinctive preference is for the general controls. I prefer them because they seem to me to hold a promise, at least, of getting the job done, and of holding back the pressures and demands that make for price in creases and inflation, with a minimum of intervention into the daily lives of people and the daily business of concerns. I prefer that as a method of control. Now, I recognize that it does not work evenly, and it does not work perfectly. To an extent, we have to step in and try to ease the pressure here and ease the pressure there in order to make it work better. In the specific case you have in mind, in the financing of municipali ties, of school districts, and so on, there are, after all, certain things which these communities and these jurisdictions can do for themselves. Some of them are still operating with limitations on interest rate, and limitations on debt amount, which tend to impair their ability to finance their own operations. Some modification of these limitations would help. But I should like to say with all candor that at a time like this there is no real escape from a higher level of interest rates than we have been accustomed to when our economy was less fully employed, and when the demand for funds was less than it is now. Representative B o l l i n g . Of course, this gets a little out of the field of economics, but what disturbs me is that we hear on the one hand quite an outcry that our school system is in one sense degenerating, whichl think is accurate, and then on the other hand the best we can come up with in the economic field, perhaps for very valid reasons, is a situation which tends to further that degeneration. I think it is not unreasonable for the average prudent school board to be a little f ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 11 bit disturbed about the prospects of its being able to manage the kind of interest rate that it would have to pay, even if it made the local tax changes required to be able to pay it. It seems to me that this is that cloudy area where we run into the question of social objectives versus sound economics. Dr. S a u l n i e r . I think one of the things which a high interest rate and a generally tight money market is going to do is to cause the post ponement of some projects. I trust that they will be the projects with the lowest priority in the communities, and I expect they will be. Secondly, higher money costs will encourage people to plan their projects on a little simpler and less expensive basis. At a time like this, it strikes me that that is probably good economics. Representative B o l l i n g . I have no objection to that, but the thing that disturbs me is that in every study that I have seen we are short a great number of schoolrooms. How much of this is the responsi bility of extravagance in the past is a question. Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is true, Congressman, although we must not overlook the fact that expenditures in this area are very high, and are rising, and were higher in 1956 than in 1955. And 1955 was substan tially above 1954. It is not that we are not spending money for schools. Indeed, we are spending money faster than we have for many, many years. I think we are making real progress. I hope that under the school bill—which I trust will be passed this year—we can expedite that. Representative B o l l i n g . That raises another question that may seem a little fanciful, but I do not think it is. I suspect that the pres sure for the school bill will be greater as a result of tight money than it would have been without it—an interesting economic twist. I apologize for having to leave. Chairman P a t m a n . I just want to enlarge on his question briefly, and then I will yield to the other members of the committee. Your recommendation is that the school district change their consti tutional or local barriers and permit the interest rate to rise ? Dr. S a u l n i e r . I would say, Congressman Patman, that where a local school district or other jurisdiction has an interest-rate limita tion that is impairing its ability to raise funds at competitive rates in the market, there is an adjustment called for, and promptly. Chairman P a t m a n . Does it not seem to you almost against con science for people to have to pay 5 percent on tax-exempt securities? That means a person with a million dollars can buy a million dollars’ worth of Memphis, Tenn., bonds paying 4% percent and go to Florida or any place they want to, and then from here on out they can collect nearly $4,000 a month and, having no taxable income, pay no taxes. Dr. S a u l n i e r . Tax exemption, of bond investment, Congressman Patman, is a feature of our tax laws for which I have never had any enthusiasm. Chairman P a t m a n . I think that is a rather mild statement. I think we ought to be for them or against them. Congressman Curtis. 12 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Representative C u r t i s . I would like to pick up on that one thingI appreciate the opportunity to inquire because I have to leave pretty promptly. I just had an unusual situation occur and so I have to leave. On that point of the tax exemption of these municipalities, I think* in the recommendations on page 49 at the top, there is a proposed amendment to the Internal Revenue Code to extend the conduit prin ciple. It points up a very important fact that the municipals are not tax exempt to one of the main markets for this kind of security. That is your investment trust, where you can have a spread in your port folio. It is true that a very rich individual who can spread his port folio over a number of municipals can get the tax exemption, but it is not available to your investment trusts and others, which are one o f the main markets. That is one reason, I suspect, if this amendment were to go through, and I am interested in talking to Representative Mills about it, you could get a bigger market and actually lower the interest rates. But I want to pick up one thing. The very thing I wanted to bring out was really in the nature of a comment and then to have your comment. It was right along these lines. I have felt for some time that our committee or some committee should make an objective study of the effects of inflation. In our tax study 2 years ago, I made a statement in some supplementary views that I felt a good bit of our troubles in our tax laws arose from the effects of inflation. I want to particularly point out the effect that it has had on local governments, school boards, and sewer districts,, and so forth, who are dependent upon real-estate property taxation* which, in turn, is based upon an assessment of real estate. I f you get into the mechanics of assessing real estate, you find that of course the assessment has occurred over a period of years, and most of the assessed property was put on the boots in the thirties, before inflation. You attempt to correct the situation by increasing the rate, and you hit unduly the new property that has gone on the books since inflation. It has presented an almost impossible situation politically and practi cally to every county, every school district, in the United States. I think there lies one of the basic situations that has caused this difficulty that our school boards are involved in, and that our local taxing authorities find themselves in. That is one aspect of the results of inflation in the past. It seems to me with our concern for inflation in the future it might have been well to have spelled out some of the economic results of inflation. Another area that I think should be pointed up is corporate in vestment. What the companies are trying to do is replace the machin ery and the equipment or utility, such as the telephone poles that they have. The effect inflation has brought to them is terrific. They have set up their depreciation accounts based upon a cost in the 1930 dollar, and have to replace it with the 1956 dollar. That lies at the base o f a great deal of this capital investment difficulty that is spelled out in here, as I see it. I was a little disappointed, and this is not adverse criticism because probably this report is not the place to put it, but I would have thought it was. Somewhere we ought to spell out, or the economists ought to ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 13 spell out, if they will, the real damage that inflation has caused in the past so that we, the people and the Congress, will realize the real dangers of inflation for the future. As I say, I threw that out as my ^comment for your comment. Dr. S a t t l n ie r . I think it would be entirely appropriate for the Economic Report to expand in some detail on the dislocations that Ven our price level moves from It has not been done in an' detail in this Economic Report or in any of the preceding ones. It seems to me a perfectly appropriate subject for attention. We could discuss the dislocations caused by inflation, of which you have given two good illustrations. Representative C u r t i s . I wanted to emphasize that point. There was one other point that I would like to call attention to. Chairman P a t m a n . May I interrupt you briefly? Do you not think it is just as important in pointing out the evils •of inflation to point out the evils of depression ? Representative C u r t i s . Those are a little more apparent, I think. I think we have seen it. Inflation is an insidious thing, and it is something that occurs gradually and no one exactly sees how it operates. Chairman P a t m a n . I ii the depressions I have gone through, I have seen it. Representative C u r t i s . The people have seen depression because they were out o f work. In this thing, our pensioners know that they ^cannot buy as much, but they do not quite understand why they •cannot. The second thing I wanted to mention is that throughout this report, just as other economic reports, there has been a presumption which I wish did not exist. It is that tax take is the same thing as the tax rate. In other words, the recommendations are that the tax rates should remain the same in order that the revenue can come in. I "believe that any tax has a point of diminishing return, and I think that in many instances, and this is my own reasoning, we have gone beyond that point of diminishing return. I think a good example was the excess-profits tax, where I am satisfied the elimination of that tax, which was mainly a tax on growth businesses and small businesses, actually produced more revenue to the Government through the regular corporate tax. I just wish it were not always presumed that just preserving a particular tax rate is going to preserve your revenue. I want to go on to illustrate that. For example, I am convinced that probably from a psychological standpoint, if we reduced the •corporate tax of 52 percent to 49 percent, just so that the private enter prise was getting 51 cents out of the dollar, and the Government only 49 percent, some of these rather extravagant and I would say, uneco nomic expenditures of corporations would not be made. I f that theory is at all right, we would increase our tax take by reducing the tax rate. I think it is worth exploring. We would probably have a bigger tax take at 49 percent than we would get at 52 percent. But the main point I want to make is that I wish we would not assume that the tax rate is the thing that is going to give us the greater tax take. 14 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TIJE PRESIDENT Finally, on this same subject, I notice there is no recommendation in regard to this device we had in the law, the stock dividend credit* Yet the purpose the Ways and Means Committee had at the time that was put in the law was trying to relieve a tax on a certain type o f corporate investment device. That is equity capital as opposed to bank borrowings and as opposed to corporate bonds. It is a difficult thing to prove, and I doubt if you really can prove it economically, but there is no question of the fact that if we were able to switch $1 billion of investment from bonds to stock, we would get a better tax take? even allowing for the dividend credit. The tax on equity earnings is subject to the 52 percent corporate tax, while the interest paid on bonds and bank borrowings is deductible from the 52 percent tax. Then there is the other feature on corporate investment of retained earnings. We have also seen here, in the Economic Report in spite of the fact that corporations earned less, the amoirnt of dividends to the people was more. In our subcommittee hearings on the eco nomic effect of our tax structure we received some advice from some of our witnesses that there would be a psychology with a tax dividend credit to encourage management to declare dividends instead of hold ing the earnings for reinvestment. Again, if that is done, and if that was the cause-and-effect relation ship, which is difficult to say, we would gain in tax take because the corporation pays the 52-percent tax all right, but no individual pays the individual tax on retained earnings. But if the corporations declare its earnings as a dividend, then it becomes subject to the in dividual tax, too. But in this area where so much emphasis has been placed in this Economic Report on our need for capital investment, I regretted that more attention was not paid to that. Also, I regretted that there were no recommendations in the area whether or not the Con gress might with the executive suggestion explore further whether we can release investment capital, so that we can lower the interest rates. It is the shortage of mvestment capital, as the report points out, that lies at the base of the increase in the interest rates. It is market demand. Now, having made that speech, in effect, I would appreciate any comments. Dr. S a u l n i e r . I just have two comments. First, in my own think ing about tax matters I do not asume that a tax rate reduction will produce a proportionate reduction in revenues. On the contrary, it is quite conceivable that a reduction in the tax burden, by stimu lating greater economic activity, may in the end produce a higher tax take, as you put it. I think we all understand it is very difficult to make a judgment on these things. It is difficult to anticipate what the specific effect will be. Furthermore, I think one gets an ex pansive effect from tax reduction only if you make a pretty goodsized tax reduction. A nibbling away at the tax rates would prob ably, over a short run, have little tendency to increase the tax take. With your comments on the dividend credit and the possibility that some measures might be taken that would expand the use of equity funds in the capital markets at this time, I have a good deal of.sympa ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 15 thy. I think you will probably agree, however, that the effect would be more to substitute one type of financing for another. That is, it possibly would not create new savings. Primarily, I think, the effect would be to channel investment funds more along the equity route than along the debt route, which in my judgment would be a good thing. Representative C u r t i s . Would you not say that the source of funds of equity capital is pretty much different from your source of bank borrowing, and even bonds? You have a different market. Dr. S a u l n i e r . Certainly. Eepresentative C u r t i s . So that the shortage seems to be in bank borrowings, as much as anything. Am I right in that presumption? There seems to be the squeeze, it seems to me. Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is certainly where the squeeze is most evident. That is right, sir. Eepresentative C u r t i s . Thank y o u , Mr. Chairman. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Mills. Representative M ills . M r. Chairman, for a moment I want to pur sue the question that M r. Curtis propounded. Is it not true that the level of employment would largely determine the effect upon the economy of a tax reduction? I f you have full employment and have a tax reduction on either business or individuals, is it not true that you may well bring about a condition of greater demand for resources and therefore increasing prices rather than an increase in production ? I am assuming that under a condition of full employment, your resources might oe pretty generally utilized at that point, so that through tax reduction you would not bring into existence any greater amount of productive facilities. There just would not be the addi tional facilities to meet the increased demand from the tax reduction. It does not always follow, that is what I am saying. I think that might as well follow as any other development. Would you think that I am right on that point? Dr. S a u l n i e r . Certainly in appraising the probable effects on our economy of a reduction in tax rates, we have to take account of the level of employment and production. When that level is as high as it is now, we have to take account of the likelihood of the tax reduction increasing the demand for resources, and pushing our economy into the inflationary zone. Another aspect that one would want to take into account, and I think Congressman Curtis has this in mind, is the possibility that savings would be increased by some form of tax reduction. Savings would be made that would not otherwise be made, and those addi tional savings would help in our fight against inflation. Eepresentative M ills . But they would not necessarily contribute to increased production, if you reached that level in your cycle of complete, full employment. Dr. S a u l n i e r . What I have in mind is just this: I f you were to make by dividend credit, for example, the investment in equities much more attractive for me, I might on the basis of that decide to forego some consumption to a greater degree and make funds available for investment that would not otherwise have been available, and enable us to finance a larger volume of investment activity without recourse to inflationary methods. 16 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT That is entirely hypothetical. Representative C u r t i s . Would you yield there? I f the money went into plant expansion or new machinery, you would increase productivity. At least that is a possibility. I am not saying it would happen, but I say if that did happen then you would be assisting production. Representative M i l l s . It would be a possibility, but it is always hard for me to visualize a situation wherein you increase production at a time when you have no employees available for that increased activity. Representative C u r t i s . An improved machine will do it. Representative M i l l s . That is technological development. R e p r e s e n t a t iv e C u r t i s . That is where you need your money. Representative M i l l s . Certainly I would not disagree with your thought that there would be a conversion in type of investment from borrowing to equity capital, but I did not intend to get into that. I wanted to ask Dr. Saulnier a question about what levels of pro duction and what levels of employment, and what levels of purchasing power are needed in 1957 to carry out the objectives of the Employ ment Act. Dr. S a u l n i e r . Mr. Mills, the Economic Report does not specify levels in quantitative terms. We have attempted in the report to describe the levels that prevail at this time. We have done that in terms of “employment and of production, and of purchasing power, and income, and disbursements, and consumption expenditures. We have then stated that in our judgment there is ground for confidence that these levels, these high levels of employment and production, will be extended into the months ahead. R e p r e s e n t a t iv e M il l s . Y ou m e a n b y t h a t f u r t h e r r a is e d ? Dr. S au ln ie r . Further raised, yes, or raised in a manner, at least, that would give us as good a record in the months ahead in terms of employment, unemployment, and production as we have now. O f course, our economy will be larger. That is larger in terms of our labor force. But how much larger it is really impossible for us to say with any precision. We have not, therefore, attempted to specify the level of employ ment or the level of production in quantitative terms which we would either expect to prevail so many months ahead, or in our judgment is needed so many months ahead. Representative M i l l s . My point is this: Did the budget message or the material used in the budget message which apparently reflects, as I read it, the attainment of sufficient levels of production, employ ment, and purchasing power to carry out the objectives of the Em ployment Act, not come from the President’s economic advisers? Dr. S a u l n i e r . I would not say that it came directly from the Council of Economic Advisers; no. Representative M i l l s . I did not see anything in the economic re port, in other words, that would verify the budget estimates. Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is correct. Just let me state, Mr. Mills, that the Treasury, the Bureau of the Budget, and the Council of Economic Advisers have, in my experience down here, worked very closely with one another in working out bases for estimating the probable revenues in the fiscal period ahead. That is done on the basis of estimates of the economic situation. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 17 Now, we do this independently. These are matters about which the professional estimators will have differences of opinion. They make estimates that vary over a range. Sometimes the range is rather wide. The estimates that we have independently made vary little from the estimates that the Treasury has made. And those variations are quite well within the range of estimating error. I have no quarrel with the estimates that underly the Budget Bureau’s revenue estimates. Eepresentative M i l l s . I am trying to understand, M r . Saulnier, if I can, what the underlying basis of these estimates for fiscal 1958 are. Now, the Secretary of the Treasury transmitted to Senator Douglas by letter dated January 16 a basis for his revenue estimates based upon calendar years 1956 and 1957. Personal income in calendar year 1956 is estimated at $325*4 billion. In calendar year 1957, it is $340 billion or almost $15 billion additional. Corporate profits for the calendar year 1956 are $43 billion, and for the calendar year 1957, $44 billion. Now, those changes could result from more than two things, but cer tainly two things. You could have more personal income in 1957 than in 1956 because more people were employed at better jobs, or you could have that increase reflecting increased wages and with respect to corporations increased unit profits rather than profits based upon an increased number of units of production. I f I understand the situation, the budget message itself must deem that one or the other of those two situations will come into existence, or exist during calendar year 1957. That is, either that we will have more inflation or else there will be more people employed in better jobs in 1957. Do you have any information that would be of help to me in getting me on which of the two tracks I should be on to properly understand and evaluate the budget message and the economic report? I wanted to throw this one additional thought in that is disturbing to me. As the President said in his economic message, he trusted that the leaders of labor and of business would use voluntary restraints as they go forward into the months ahead. It indicated to me that he wanted them to exercise those restraints for the purpose of holding down inflationary trends in the months ahead. That throws me, then, into believing that he anticipates, or the budget message anticipates that these increases can come through in creased employment of people in better positions. Dr. S a u l n i e r . I think that is a correct inference. Eepresentative M i l l s . That is the actual correct inference? Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is the correct inference, yes. Eepresentative M i l l s . Does the economic message, then, carry out that thinking with respect to the question I asked originally ? ^ : ^ Dr. S a u l n i e r . The economic message, while it does not do it in quantitative terms, contemplates an expansion of the economy in 1957 over 1956, which would justify these higher estimates of personal in come and of corporate profits, without price effect. Now, of course if we are unsuccessful in holding the line on prices and have rising prices with the present levels of employment and of income, that will, of course, yield a higher volume of tax revenues. We would hope that that would not happen. 18 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Representative M i l l s . N o w certainly the Secretary meant to con vey the thought that you have when he wrote his letter, because he says in this letter “ We do not assume any change in prices from the present.” Now, is this projection into calendar year 1957 sufficient to carry out the objectives of the Employment Act ? Dr. S a u l n i e r . In my judgment, it is. Representative M i l l s . In other words, those estimates are based upon what you would deem to be the desirable growth which you foresee occurring in calendar year 1957, to maintain the objectives of the Employment Act? D r . S a u l n ie r . A s w e ll a s w e c a n f o r e s e e th e m . I would like to say, Mr. Mills, that at this time it is exceedingly difficult, and perhaps more difficult than usual, to estimate the amount of growth in our labor force that can be anticipated over the next calendar year. This is a short period of time, and it is difficult always to make estimates for such a short period. But we have just gone through a period in which labor-force participation has been very high. Young people have been coming into the labor force in large num bers. Women have been coming into the labor force at unusually high rates. This has increased the volume of people wanting ana seeking work. Whether that will continue at quite the same rate for another year is, I think, a very real question. Representative M i l l s . I want to ask you the $64 question: What ure your views with respect to the relationship of the objectives of the Employment Act and economic stability ? Are they reconcilable? Can you have both, economic stability and the objectives of the Employment Act being carried out at the same time? Dr. S a u l n i e r . Let me answer that question this way, Mr. Mills: I am an enthusiast for the objectives of the Employment Act. Representative M i l l s . Permit me to interrupt long enougjh to say that I am, too. Dr. S a u l n i e r . I would like to call attention to the fact that the Employment Act is silent on price stability. I have over a long number o f years interested myself in this question of just how specific one should be in laying down the rules for economic stabili zation policy, primarily in connection with the Federal Reserve Act. I have, myself, by and large, been on the side of a pretty vague kind, or pretty general, let me put it that way, general kind of a mandate. It has been asked from time to time whether the Employ ment Act ought to be amended to incorporate a price stability dimension. Representative K i l b u r n . What do you understand to be the objectives of the Employment Act, just in two sentences? Dr. S a u l n i e r . The objectives of the Employment Act, sir, are that the Federal Government should use its full resources to promote high levels of employment and production and purchasing power, and that it should do this within the framework of a private enterprise system. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 19 Representative K i l b t t r n . Thank y o u . Dr. S a u l n i e r . A s I say, it has been asked whether the act might be amended to include a price stabiilty criterion or price stability objective. As I would try myself to administer my responsibilities under the Employment Act, to have price stability in the act, specifically stated in the act, would not make any difference. I regard price stability as a major objective of economic stabilization policy. All I can say, Mr. Mills, is that I would strive to achieve both high employment and price stability. We have put it in the economic report a dozen or more times as “ prosperity with price stability.” I hope we can attain this objective. Let me say that over the last few years we have done, I think, more than just moderately well. We have had high employment, and we have had high production, and we have made perfectly enormous improvements in our productive plant. We have sustained a very, very heavy Federal budget with a very large component in that Fed eral budget of defense expenditures. With all of this, we have had price increases—and these have come mainly in the last 12 months— of something less than 3 percent. Now, that 3 percent I wish had never happened. I hope that we can move into a period of greater price stability. I am an optimist about being able to reconcile these objectives. Representative M i l l s . Certainly the administration spokesmen ought to be taken at their word, and I am perfectly willing to do that. The last thing that would be desired would be very much inflation. But in the zeal that we all have to carry out the objectives of the Em ployment Act, I am beginning to wonder just a little bit if those ob jectives can be carried out without some moderate amount of inflation. Chairman P a t m a n . May I interrupt you to suggest that I hope you make a distinction between a necessary expansion and inflations I am afraid that oftentimes people fail to make that clear. Representative M i l l s . Normal growth should be distinguished from inflation, which would mean growth as a result of increases in price and not necessarily in numbers of units. I am glad that you point that out. Now, Mr. Chairman, I would like to include this letter in the record. Chairman P a t m a n . Without objection, it is so ordered. (Letter and attachment referred to follows:) T h e S ecretary of t h e T r e a s u r y , Hon. Paul H. Washington, January 16,1957 . D o u g la s , Chairman, Joint Economic Committee, United States Senate, Washington, D. C. D e a r S e n a t o r D o u g l a s : in accordance with your request of January 7 for t h e assumptions underlying the 1958 budget estimates, I enclose a table showing t h e assumed figures for personal income and corporate profits for the calendar y e a r s 1956 and 1957. We do not assume any change in prices from the present. Sincerely yours, (Signed) G. M. H u m p h r e y , Secretary o f the Treasury . 20 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT B a s is op R e v e n u e E s t im a t e s Calendar year income levels assumed in the revenue estimates for fiscal 195T and fiscal 1958 are as follows: [In billions] Calendar year 1956 Personal income_______________________________________________________ Corporate profits______________________________________________________ $325.5 43.0 Calendar year 195T $340.0 44. a Chairman P a t m a n . I would like at this point to bring out one addi tional thing. In your report on page 50 you state: I f a vigorous rate of economic growth is to be realized without recourse to inflationary finance, the supply of savings must be sufficiently high to meet the heavy demands for funds for private, State, and local undertakings. The Federal Government is releasing funds for such purposes by a budgetary sur plus and reduction in its debt. Now, you believe, do you not, Mr. Saulnier, that if we operate on a balanced budget and have a surplus, as we pay on the national debt and reduce it, it is perfectly all right to increase private debt? Dr. S a u l n i e r . Y ou say “ perfectly all right.” Chairman P a t m a n . Without any danger of inflation. I am looking at it strictly from an inflationary standpoint. In other words, we have a debt now aggregating about $700 billion: $275 billion of that is the national debt. Now, if we paid $5 billion down on that debt and reduced our agregate to $695 billion thereby, do you not think that we could safely increase the private $5 billion without any danger of inflation ? Dr. S a u l n i e r . We could safely increase private investment by that amount. Whether it would have to be in the form of debt or not is; another matter. Thus, if I own a Government bond, let us say $10,000, and the Government pays that bond off and I find myself with $10,000 in cash, I can spend it on consumption or I can invest it in more debt securities, or I might buy equities. S o the reduction of national debt may make it possible to have an expansion in equity investment. I personally would prefer that. Chairman P a t m a n . I am looking at it solely from the standpoint of creating money. Now, if we reduce the national debt, as we reduce it, it is perfectly all fight for commercial banks to increase their deposits, we will say, by making loans because as the national debt goes down, private debt can go up. That is, generally correct; is it not? Dr. S a u l n i e r . I f the Federal Government pays off some debt that was held by the banking system—you see in my earlier example they were paying off some debt held by me and that is a different thing— then the banking system can increase its credit to individuals and to* business concerns or to State and local governments without there having been an increase in the money supply. That is correct, sir. Chairman P a t m a n . Do you not think it is time, now, for us to have a definite program for reducing the national debt? l)r. S a u l n i e r . I have advocated for many years the use of every resource possible to reduce the national debt. Chairman P a t m a n . N o w , Mr. Humphrey keeps saying that if we do not reduce Government expenditures, we will have a severe de ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 21 pression. He must mean that if we have deficit financing, it will prob ably result in a depression. He could not mean that expenditures themselves will cause a depression if the budget is balanced. You would not say that we are in any danger of a depression as long as we have a balanced budget; would you ? Dr. S a u l n i e r . I would prefer to let Secretary Humphrey expand on that for himself. Chairman P a t m a n . Disassociating the question from my remarks about Secretary Humphrey, do you see any danger of any depression as long as we have a balanced budget? Is it not only when we have an unbalanced budget that we &r6 in a dangerous position as far as depression is concerned? Dr. S a u l n i e r . In the present situation, Congressman Patman, I would not say that the present level of Federal expenditures and the prospective budgetary surplus for our Federal budget is in and o f itself a factor likely to produce depression conditions in this country in the immediate run. Chairman P a t m a n . Would you answer be the same if our budget were $10 billion more, if the prospective receipts would cover it? Dr. S a u l n i e r . My answer would be the same, but I would be un happy over the fact that the Federal Government was for any reason absorbing that much larger part of the resources of the country. That is for reasons which, important as they are to our national security, are not in the immediate situation making goods and services available to satisfy consumer wants. Chairman P a t m a n . I am only asking you that to get your answer as to what effect on inflation it would have. I am not advocating it or suggesting that we should have it. I am just asking you what the effect would be as long as we had a balanced budget. Dr. S a u l n i e r . In the present situation, Congressman Patman* a balanced budget is an anti-inflationary element in our program. Chairman P a t m a n . Certainly, and I am all for it. Representative K e l b u r n . Could I clarify that? I do not under stand why you say it would not affect inflation. Suppose instead of $10 billion, it was $100 billion that the Government was going to spend, even though they get it back in taxes and balance the budget. That $100 billion goes into the bloodstream of this country, and could cause inflation, in my opinion. Representative M i l l s . I f you will yield to me at that point, I do not desire to presume to be able to read the mind o f the Secretary of the Treasury, but I think that I have had sufficient conversations with him to reach a conclusion, perhaps, as to what he had in the back of his mind when he said that these expenditures could bring about a depression. I think what he is thinking about is the effect upon public confi dence of continued Government spending at a high level, either bring ing about overconfidence or underconfidence that could set off the chain reaction resulting in deflation and depression. I intend to ask him if that is not his thinking when he comes to the committee. Chairman P a t m a n . D o you want to answer Mr. Kilburn’s question Dr. S a u l n i e r . Would you be good enough to rephrase it for me? Representative K i l b u r n . As I understood Mr. Patman’s statement* it was that even though the Government increased its spending by $10 22 ECONOMIC REPORT OF T H E , PRESIDENT million, if the taxes received also rose so that the budget was balanced there would be no inflationary effect. Chairman P a t m a n . That is right. Representative K i l b u r n . I should think to the contrary that when you have $10 billion being spent by somebody, in this case the Govern ment, going into the economy of this country, it is bound to be in flationary. Dr. S a u l n i e r . Let me put it this way. We are assuming in this case that we are going to increase our tax take by $10 billion. W e are taking $10 billion away from the people and reducing their con suming power. Then we are making that $10 billion available for the. production of goods and services important to the Federal Govern ment, and in this case let us assume that they are defense goods. The net effect of this on our economy is that we have a reduced output o f consumer goods and larger production of defense goods. More of our resources, in other words, are going into the production of military goods, and less into the production of consumption goods. Representative K i l b u r n . I am new to this Committee, but I should think that the difference in that case would be that the $10 billion is being spent, regardless of whether it was defense or not. I f it was being saved, it would help prevent inflation, but as long as it is being spent it helps inflation. Chairman P a t m a n . And velocity enters into the problem, too. I am not quite satisfied with the answer to my question about the na tional debt. I f I understand the capitalistic system, a system which I am highly in favor of, it is a system based on debt. In other words, we must have debt in order to have money. In order to have debt, we must have a good commercial banking system. I think we have the best in the world and I want it to continue that way. I believe in both the capitalistic system and the private commercial banking system, and I oelieve in a bank making good profits because it cannot serve the people to the maximum extent unless it is a profit-making enter prise. But, it being true that our money is based on debt, as we pay off that debt, whether it is national debt or private debt, it cancels that much money. That is correct; is it not? Dr. S a u l n i e r . I f the debt is held by the banking system. Chairman P a t m a n . Regardless of who holds it, if you pay off $5> billion of the national debt, you have reduced the money supply $5 billion over the Nation. Dr. S a u l n i e r . Only if the debt was held by the banks and not if i t was held bv an individual. I f the Federal Government comes to you and takes $1,000 away from you and then comes over to me with that $1,000 and says, “We would like to have you give us the bond that you have in your pocket for $1,000 and we will give you this $1,000 which formerly was Congressman Patman’s money,” I give up the bond and I take the money that formerly was yours. The transaction has been completed. You are the taxpayer and I am the investor. I am now in liquid funds. There has been no change in the money supply. Chairman P a t m a n . I f I borrowed the money from a commercial bank, that would still be the same thing; would it not ? That would not enter into the transaction ? Dr. S a u l n i e r . N o w , this is getting a little more complicated. I f we can somehow trace this into the banking system, we can find, I am sure, some means by which we can produce a reduction in the ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 23 money supply. But it must eventually be traced there in order to produce that result. Chairman P a t m a n . I recognize that only in the banking system where the fractional reserve system is used does this operate to create money when loans are made, and to destroy money when loans are paid. Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is right. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Talle. Representative T alle . As has been pointed out, the purpose of the committee is to make a continuing study of employment, production, and purchasing power. Employment suggests jobs and wages, and production suggests plant and output and purchasing power sug gests real wages and consumer behavior. IIow good are our statis tics in those three fields? Dr. S a u l n i e r . Well, you have asked me a question, Congressman Talle, on matters on which I am far from expert. Employment sta tistics present a difficult technical problem from the purely statistical viewpoint. I am no expert on that. As you may know, my own field of work has been primarily in finance. But I will say that our em ployment statistics are pretty good. They are really outstandingly good as measured by the employment statistics of many other coun tries of the world. Our production statistics are pretty good, too, although if you get a real technician answering your question he would inundate you in no time with reservations and qualifications about the various indexes that we have of industrial production. But, by and large, they are tolerably good. I must confess that I have never been quite clear what the Employ ment Act refers to when it refers to “purchasing power,” but you can interpret that as meaning the amount of funds becoming available to individuals for expenditure. That is personal income. Or you can interpret it perhaps as the amount of money which individuals are expending. On both of those, we have pretty good statistics, and in recent years, the last 10 or 15 years, we have made very striking im provements in them. But I would be making unjustified claims if I claimed to be an expert on any one of these specific fields of statistics. Representative T a l l e . The term “ real wages” means purchasing power; does it not ? Dr. S a u l n i e r . Real wages represent to us our measure of what the individual is able to buy in goods and services with the wage pay ment he receives. Representative T a l l e . That leads me to my next question. There seems to be an increasing tendency to include escalator clauses not only in labor contracts but in some other contracts, too. There is evidence of this in France, in Germany, in Great Britain and in some other countries. People who draw pensions would like to have escala tor clauses to ensure that their pensions will have constant purchasing powder. Does that complicate your calculations ? Dr. S a u l n i e r . Well, I am not sure what you mean by “complicating the calculations.” These are devices by which we get automatic ad justments of income payments to individuals in line with changes in some specified index of prices. To a certain extent they do not com plicate the problem, but rather they make quite obvious and explicit some of the implications of a price rise. Thus one reads that the 24 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT consumer price index goes tip by point something or other in the last month, and that this automatically means a wage increase of 1 cent or 2 cents or 3 cents an hour for X number of workers. That becomes quite explicit and well understood. But that is a different matter, of course, from the judgment we might make as to whether this is good for our economy or not. Eepresentative T a l l e . Take, for instance, this situation: It is not unusual for employees whether on the job or retired to want more income. An illustration would be social security benefits. Now, it is a tedious process, probably, to come to Washington to ask Members of Congress to supply something more by specific laws. It would be far easier to get it by using escalator clauses. They are automatic and tied to cost-of-living indexes. From the recipients’ point of view these clauses may seem rather desirable, but I am wondering what effect they have on calculations, if they became general. Suppose everyone’s income were tied to a purchasing power index. Dr. S a u l n i e r . I must say that I have many misgivings about the escalator clause. Eepresentative T a l l e . I do, too. Dr. S a u l n i e r . One of my misgivings is that at the present time we have some people on an escalator while others are still puffing up the stairs. Eepresentative T a l l e . And that is unfair. Certainly a lot of people feel it is unfair. I f some have it, why should not all? You could wind up with everybody having it, and I wonder how you would pro ceed under a general escalator situation? Dr. S a u l n i e r . I doubt that as a practical matter we could get our economy thoroughly escalated. But even assuming for the moment that we could, I must say that the prospect of such an economy just moving up its collective escalator frightens me. I would much prefer a world in which we have to make our adjustments piece by piece, and in which our economic policy can be directed to maintaining a stable price level within a full employment context. Eepresentative T a l l e . I have been and am very much interested in improving economic statistics. There is nothing romantic about that, but I think it is a bit of drudgery that needs to be done. I believe firmly it is something that the world needs. Dr. S a u l n i e r . We in the Council have been very appreciative of the work that this committee has done in working toward improve ments in our statistics. We appreciate that very much and we want to be just as helpful as we can in connection with it. There are a good many areas in which we need far better statistical information than we have now. Eepresentative T a l l e . I would think, for instance, in the field of production that it would be very important to have reliable economic statistics because if, as is claimed, wages are paid on the basis of pro ductivity, you must have reliable data as to productivity or you will not know whether you are paying proper wages or not. Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is correct, sir. Eepresentative T a l l e . That is all, Mr. Chairman. Chairman P a t m a n . Before yielding to you, I would like to make one observation. Senator W a t k i n s . Go ahead. I have not been here long enough to get oriented up to this point. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 25 Chairman P a t m a n . We were talking about the national debt and a balanced budget, and I suggested that we should not pay off the national debt too fast because it would be deflationary. I also made the point that if we paid off some of the national debt, we could, I thought, increase other debts in proportion and it would not be infla tionary. Mr. Saulnier suggested if the Government took $1,000 away from me in taxes and then took that $1,000 and gave it to him in pay ment of a bond, it would not be deflationary because the money would still be in circulation. Of course I agree with him. But, if it were paid to a commercial bank that has the power to expand through the fractional reserve system, it would be deflationary because it would extinguish that much of a debt. Let us take that $1,000 debt, Mr. Saulnier, that I paid the taxes and the Treasury pays to you for the bond. I f you owe that money or if you borrowed the money to buy bonds like many people do and you immediately paid the bank the $1,000, it would have the same effect; would it not? Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is right. I f I had been holding that bond with a $1,000 secured loan from a commercial bank and I retired that loan when my bond was retired, it would have the same effect. It would have the same effect as if the bond had been held directly by the commercial banks. Chairman P a t m a n . Would you like to ask any questions^ Senator Watkins? Senator W a t k i n s . Not at this time; no, sir. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Kilburn, have you any questions? Eepresentative K i l b u r n . A s I said, I am new to this committee, Mr. Saulnier, and I wanted to try to get clear in my mind a couple* df basic things that are confusing me a little. Do you think that we are in an inflationary period and do we want to stop this inflation? Dr. S a u l n i e r . Well, Congressman Kilburn, when an economy is operating as close to the ceiling of capacity as ours is, and when confidence on the part of business concerns and of individuals is as high as it is now, and when you have as large a backlog of demands for community improvements as we have now, there is a more or less persisting danger that the economy will pass into the inflationary zone. Eepresentative K i l b u r n . As I understand it, the cost-of-living index has gone up 3 percent in the past 12 months. Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is right. Eepresentative K i l b u r n . Is that not inflation? Dr. S a u l n i e r . We ordinarily define inflation as an increase in the price level. There is no question, therefore, but what we must record this as having been a year of moderate inflation. Eepresentative K i l b u r n . So that the value of the dollar has gone down? Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is correct, sir. Eepresentative K i l b u r n . And that is inflation, in any book, I think. Dr. S a u l n i e r . You are correct, sir. But let me say, Congressman, that if you take the price increase of 2.9 you will find that it is made up of increases of a number of different kinds. Let us take rent as an example. We have many communities in New York—I do not know how many—in which rent control still exists. Why do we have that rent 87624— 57—pt. 1------ 3 26 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT control? We have it because during* World War II and during the Korean conflict period there was a great pressure or demand for housing space, tending to push rents up. These laws were put into effect to hold rents at what was regarded as a proper level. Now, some of them are still there. I f they had not been there, rents would have gone up long ago. The fact that these laws are on the books has suppressed that move ment. Now, little by little, these laws are being terminated, little by little those rents are rising. Now, what does a rent increase that occurs in 1956 or 1957 as a result of the termination of a rent-control law really mean as regards the pressures of inflation in 1956 or 1957? It seems to me that what it means is that you are getting a belated, a late, or deferred manifesta tion of some inflationary developments which occurred in an earlier period. Eepresentative K i l b u r n . I can understand that. That is just the same as when your prices went up after price control. Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is right, and we have to bear these things in mind when we interpret the price history of recent months. Eepresentative K i l b u r n . One thing that has confused me a little is our respected chairman’s statement that I read, in which he stated we have to do something about interest rates so that we will not have a recession. It seems to me that the problem now is inflation. Chairman P a t m a n . Would you consider an increase in interest rates inflationary? Eepresentative K i l b u r n . I would answer that this way. It seems to me, and that was going to be the point of my next question to the witness, that the increase in interest rates is the law of supply and demand operating. Chairman P a t m a n . That does not answer the question, though. Eepresentative K i l b u r n . Let us get the answer to this, first. Dr. S a u l n i e r . That is correct, and I think that while it is true that an increase in interest rates is an increase in the cost of doing business for a concern and may be reflected in a higher price for whatever it is the business concern is producing, the higher interest cost is an antiinflationary measure in the sense that it tends to restrain demands for credit. Let me add this one sentence. By restraining credit, it helps avoid the price increases that we call inflation. Chairman P a t m a n . Do you believe that the interest rate restrains borrowers to any great extent? Dr. S a u l n i e r . Yes; I think it does. I think it is having that effect on a good many borrowers. Chairman P a t m a n . I want to ask you one more question. How much of this 2.9-percent increase in the past year is due to increased interest rates ? Dr. S a u l n i e r . Y ou would have to take several steps to the righthand side of the decimal point, in my judgment, before you could get the cost allocable to higher interest. Part of it is agricultural prices, and part of it is increases in rents, and part of it is increases in the cost of personal services. In these, I think, Mr. Chairman, the interest cost has been a very minor item. Eepresentative K i l b u r n . It seems to me that anything that dis courages borrowing, like higher interest rates, stops inflation. That would be my guess. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 27 Now, the next question that I would like to ask you is this: With interest rates going up due to the law of supply and demand, then is it not true that about the only thing that the Government or the Con gress can do in such a situation is to make the loans themselves just like they did in the veterans loans. They made more and more money available for veterans housing directly from the Government because the banks would not loan the veterans mortgage money because the interest rate was not in the market range. As soon as they made a loan of 100 cents on the dollar, the best they could get for it was 90 cents on the dollar. Consequently, they did not want to make the loan. So then Congress and the Federal Gov ernment stepped in and created or allowed the Veterans5Administra tion to make direct loans. I f we let the law of supply and demand operate in money rates, then the only way to overcome it is to have the Government loan it directly. Dr. S au ln ie r . It is certainly true that in a situation of this kind, where important classes of borrowers are finding it not only more costly to borrow but in some cases are finding it impossible to borrow, there is a great temptation to come to the Federal Government and say, “ Won’t you lend the money to us directly?” I must say in all candor to you, Congressman Kilburn, and to Chair man Patman and members of this committee, that while I have sub scribed to the steps that were taken, modest steps they were, to assist small business through SBA and to assist the mortgage market through the Federal National Mortgage Association, I have sought all along to keep those measures at a minimum level and to avoid taking the route of direct Federal lending as a means of avoiding the pressures that a tight money policy imposes on our economy. Representative T alle . I f we do that, do we not run into the same thing that we have run into with the escalator clause? I f one group can get it directly from the Government, why not everybody, and we have socialized credit. Dr. SAtJLNiER. We do not solve the inflationary problem this wav. Representative K ilbu rn . When you say the “ tight money policy,” is not the tight money policy the result of the law of supply and demand ? Dr. S a u ln ie r . Y ou are absolutely right, and I am glad that you have commented on what was really a misstatement of mine. When I said that this is the result of the tight money policy, I really should have said, that this is the result of an economic situation in which the demand for funds is running ahead of the available supply* Representative K ilb u r n . There is nothing that the Federal Reserve can do or this committee can do or Congress can do to stop high interest rates caused by the law of supply and demand, is that right? Dr. S a u ln ie r . That is right. Nothing in my judgment that would be appropriate. Representative K ilb u r n . I would presume, Mr. Chairman, that one o f this committee’s objectives is to halt inflation. Chairman P a t m a n . We are not for inflation. We are against it. Representative K ilb u r n . Our alternative basically is to either let the law of supply and demand operate-----Chairman P a t m a n . But the Federal Reserve makes the law of sup ply and demand. I think Mr. Saulnier agreed with me when he said that they could not properly do anything more because he intimated that the evils would overbalance the good. 28 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Representative K ilb u r n . Y ou mean to say in your opinion that the Federal Reserve by lowering their rediscount rate could lower the demand for money ? Chairman P a t m a n . Yes, and the Open Market Committee would be the most feasible way to do it. You see, they are meeting today, the Open Market Committee is meeting today, for all practical purposes to do just that. Representative K ilb u r n . With all due respect, you and I have a very basic difference here. I think the Federal Reserve policies on rediscount rates follow the money market. Chairman P a t m a n . I know your sincere and honest views but I cannot agree. We just have a difference of opinion on it. Representative K ilb u r n . There is no use pursuing that part of it, but I wanted to get straight in my mind that the purpose of this com mittee or one o f the purposes of this committee is to try their best to be helpful in stopping inflation. Does the Council of Economic Ad visers feel that we have either to let the law of supply and demand work in money rates or the Government has to make the loans ? Dr. S au ln ie r . My own feeling, as I say, is that we have to resist the temptation to try to evade the operation of these money market forces by direct Government lending. Representative K ilb u r n . Of course if the Government did go into the loaning business even more than they are now, and are there not about 18 different agencies now making loans—— Dr. S a u ln ie r . I regard myself as something of an authority on this subject. The last time I tried to make a listing of them, it took so many pages that it must have added up to more than that. Representative K ilbu rn . They are in the money lending business? Dr. S au l n ie r . That is correct, sir. Representative K ilbu rn . I f this practice continued to grow would it not be inflationary ? Dr. S au ln ie r . It could be. Representative T alle . Have we not overlooked one point? We have been talking about demand and the rising rate, but if the rates are higher people are encouraged to save, and there is more saving which results in larger supply of loanable funds. Dr. S a u ln ie r . That is correct. That is the classical formula for bringing a lack of balance under control. Representative T alle . John Suart Mill stressed “ The savable fund and the effective rate of accumulation.” Dr. S a u ln ie r . As I say, this is the classical means for bringing into balance the demand for funds on the one hand, and the supply of funds on the other. A rising interest rate will both tend to reduce the level of demand, and increase the level of savings supply. Representative M ills . I wanted to get back to the point I was pur suing earlier. ^My curiosity to ask the question stems from language in the Economic Report on page 44, and I wanted to read a few lines in the second paragraph. The sentence begins: When production, sales, and employment are high, wage and price increases in important industries create upward pressures on costs and prices generally. To depend exclusively on monetary and fiscal restraint as a means of containing the upward movement of prices would raise serious obstacles to the maintenance o f economic growth and stability. In the face of a continuous upward pressure on costs and prices, moderate restraints would not be sufficient; yet stronger re straints would bear with undue severity on sectors of the economy having little if ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 29 any responsibility for the movement toward a higher cost-price level and would court the risk of being excessively restrictive for the economy generally. These are not acceptable alternatives to stable and balanced economic growth. The American economy possesses the potentials for expansion and improvement. If these potentials are supported by proper fiscal and monetary policies on the part of Government, and by appropriate private policies, our economy can achieve and maintain high levels of production, employment, and income with stable prices. It was because of that language that I asked the question whether or not the objectives of the Employment Act and our overall objective of a stable economy are always consistent. We have had now for the last few months, as you have pointed out, some increases that of course have been reflected in this increase in the indicators of production. We have pretty well carried out the objectives during that period of time of the Employment Act. Now, I am always curious when I am talking to economists to get their opinion as to whether or not these objectives could have been carried out when maintaining com plete stability in the overall price level. Dr. S a u l n ie r . The price index you are thinking of is the consumer price index? Representative M il l s . Yes, which has gone up only about 4 to 5 percent in the period of the last 4 years. Dr. S a u l n ie r . It is perfectly conceivable, Congressman Mills, that with a different behavior of farm prices in this period, we might have had roughly the same levels of overall employment and of production and income with less price increases than we have had. It is perfectly possible. Now, if in past years we had had less of a buildup of carryover stocks in agriculture and had had less of a decline in farm prices, and if we had had a more stable farm price index in the last 3 or 4 years, and continuing through 1956, the consumer price index would have looked appreciably different. That would not in itself have affected the ability of our economy to attain high levels of employment and production. It is perfectly conceivable, also, that if it were not for the great inflationary forces that were at work in our economy during the two war periods, we would have avoided these deferred price changes of which I was speaking earlier. We would have had less inflation of prices in 1956 than we did have. Yet this would not have impaired appreciably our ability to achieve high levels of employment and production. In other words, the price increases of 1956 were not essential to high employment and produc tion. Representative M il l s . I am still thinking in terms o f the relation ship of these objectives to the budget which has been suggested and the justification for the Congress going along with the budget on the assumptions which are made with respect to the budget. Now, the President refers in this language that I have quoted to the so-called cost-price push. Let us see whether or not this cost-price push can occur without an accommodating expansion in aggregate demand which, of course, is money. Dr. S a u l n ie r . Can it occur without an accommodating demand; is that your question? Representative M il l s . Yes. 30 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Dr. S a u ln ie r . A change either in the money supply or in the rate of turnover of money and thus in aggregate demand, is im plied if you have a fairly general increase in prices resulting from a wage-cost push. Representative M ills . I s it not important that we know whether it comes from a more rapid turnover or a more accommodating supply of money ? Dr. S a u ln ie r . It is important, analytically, to know whether it comes from one or the other. In 1956 it came primarily from the more rapid turnover of our money supply. Representative M ills . Is it contemplated that there will be an even more rapid turnover in 1957? Is that the basis that is used ? Dr. S a u ln ier . I would doubt it and I would doubt it for this reason: The* more rapid turnover of money in 1956 was due in part, I think, to a drawing down of cash balances by corporations and to a more rapid turnover by the corporations of their cash funds. Now, there is kind of a saturation point here, I think. A busi ness concern can increase the volume of its business on a given dollar volume of cash and perhaps go to a still higher level, but there is a question as to how far that can go. There must come a point at which a further increase or further decrease in its liquidity position is not practicable. I think we must be closer to that point now than we were at the beginning of 1956. Let me put it this way: The prospect for a more rapid turnover of money in 1957 is relatively slight. Representative M ills . Does this present budget that we are work ing on actually hold out the possibility of an increase in prices from a continuation of this “cost-price push,” as a matter of fact? Does it not create more pressures in that direction? Does it not mean, therefore, that we must have more restraint in our Federal Govern ment fiscal and monetary policies to accommodate that expenditure by the Government? Dr. S a u ln ie r . In the present situation, Congressman Mills, I would prefer a larger budgetary surplus than is contemplated. Representative M ills . Actually, what I am disturbed about is whether or not the Congress is safe in assuming such growth as you have indicated is the basis for assumptions with respect to the budget for purposes of making expenditures by Government for months ahead. Now, in order to justify these expenditures and for the Government to remain on a balanced budget, it is absolutely essential that 1 o f 2 things occur that we talked about a few minutes ago: Either it is more inflation or an actual increase in production and personal income based upon more employment in better jobs. Then we must, if we justify the appropriation of the funds con templated in this budget with the expectation of doing that and end ing with a balanced budget which would not adversely affect our eco nomic stability, come to the conclusion that this growth will occur. Normally we do not make our appropriations depend upon assump tions about changes in levels of economic activity. But this time we are being asked to assume this increased growth which we all want and which we all say is necessary in order to end up with a balanced budget after making these appropriations. ECONOMIC REPOET OF THE PRESIDENT 31 Senator W a t k in s . A s a practical matter, do we not make our ap propriations largely on the pressures that are put on us ? Representative M ills . I fear, Senator, that one of the great pres sures we have is the fact that it is in the budget. Senator W a t k in s . There was probably a pressure to put it in the budget, too. Representative M ills . I am concerned with what one of your very eminent Members of the Senate said with respect to this budget. He said that in his opinion it reflected a contemplation of more inflation. You have said that the budget is not predicated upon inflation. I am glad to hear that it is not in your thinking predicated upon inflation. What I am fearful of is that we will create the situation through ap propriation of the funds involved in this budget, to make it impossible to avoid additional inflation except if we utilize even greater re straint in Government fiscal and monetary policy. I do not see where we can obtain the additional restraint in fiscal policy that we might need to utilize after making the appropration. Representative C u rtis . Would you yield for a clarification there? You said Dr, Saulnier had said that this was not predicated upon in flation. Did you mean by that that the budget is going through as is, or was there a comment on that? Was there a comment to the effect that the budget as is would not create inflation? Representative M ills . N o. What I had tried to develop earlier with Dr. Saulnier was whether or not this budget and economic mes sage and these things that are coming to the Congress are predicated upon more inflation or continuation of inflation. Or whether or not they are predicated upon increases in income and productivity at fixed prices. He said it is the latter that they are predicated upon. Dr. S a u ln ier . I might say in that connection, Mr. Mills, that it is my understanding that the estimates of revenue for a fiscal period ahead have in the past, as well as in this budget, been based on some assumptions as to the growth of the economy. The estimates which we have for revenues for fiscal 1958 do predi cate a growth in the economy at a normal long-term rate. But to make an assumption on growth is not an innovation in budget-making. Representative M ills . It may well be that some allowance has been made with respect to Government estimates, in estimating them at least, for some growth. However, we found it to be the situation normally when we have been in a rising economy that the Treasury has underestimated revenues far more often than it has overestimated revenues. We do have that situation. But here we have this decided jump between calendar 1956 and calendar 1957 with respect to personal income on which the revenues in part are based, of $325^ billion in 1956 to $340 billion in 1957. That is a $141^ billion increase. Now, do we have some criteria to go by in terms of the historical record that would indicate that the recommendations contained in the budget and the overall economic situation justify our assumption that a balanced budget wil be attained? Dr. S a u ln ier . Our own calculations of what would be involved in terms of increased production, employment, and income, if we expand in 1957 at about a normal historical rate, correspond roughly with what has been estimated by the Treasury. 32 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Eepresentative M il l s , N o w , let me get it down to figures. Do you mean to say then, that if we have in the calendar 1957 an increase in our overall national production of 3 or 3y2 percent, which is I under stand about the normal increase or normal growth, that increase will reflect this addition in personal income? Dr. S a u l n ie r . That is right. Eepresentative M il l s . So then we do get down to this point, that the budget receipts are predicated upon a growth in overall gross national product of around 3 or 3^ percent ? Dr. S a u l n ie r . It would be in that neighborhood, that is right. That is, a growth that would be consistent with the objective of the Em ployment Act to maintain a level of employment that will provide jobs ior those who can be expected to come into the labor force in 1957. Eepresentative M il l s . What are the factors that presently exist, Doctor, that give rise to the conclusion for these purposes that this rate of growth will occur in our overall national product in 1957? Dr. S a u l n ie r . Well, I can run down the major sectors of our econ omy. As to capital expenditures and business, I think there is no expectation that they would increase in 1957 at as rapid a rate as they increased in 1956 but a further increase is anticipated. There are, as you know, some areas of capital investment, notably public utilities, where the rate of growth is anticipated to be quite high. Secondly, we can take State and local units. It is, I think, not un reasonable to anticipate that the overall volume of activity in that seg ment of our economy will increase in 1957 over 1956. As you know, expenditures there have been stepping up fairly regularly and per sistently over some period of time. The consumer is always the mystery man in this drama. It is im possible to tell precisely what is going to happen there. Eepresentative M ills . Judging from recent situations with respect to the consumer, I think it would cause us to feel that his confidence has not diminished to any extent. Dr. S a u l n ie r . That is correct. Eepresentative M il l s . I think that you are pretty safe in assuming a continuation o f consumer confidence underlying a pretty high level of consumer demand. Eepresentative T a l l e . Would you yield to me for just a moment? Turning back to local expenditures which you just mentioned, most of the State legislatures are meeting this month and no doubt a good share of their work will be to pass laws that have to do with meeting local obligations in order to share in Federal funds under various Federal-State matching plans. Dr. S a u l n ie r . As I said earlier, I trust that some of their activities will be directed toward facilitating the raising of funds independently of the Federal Government. Eepresentative T a l l e . I share your hope, sir. Eepresentative M il l s . There are two points that I am concerned about, Doctor, not as an economist of course, because I am not, but as I had looked to the future and tried to determine whether we can have this rate of growth in 1957. There are two questions always in my mind. One is in respect to what inventory policies will prevail in 1957 and the other, because I have realized that much of our growth in 1956 was based upon enlarged shipments overseas, what our situation in 1957 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 33 may be with respect to imports, particularly in the light of the develop ments that are now plaguing us in the Middle East. Do we have any information upon which we can safely predict for the future with respect to inventory policies and positions? Dr. S au ln ie r . Well, inventory accumulations were fairly high in 1956 and I think it is reasonable to expect further accumulations in 1957. Representative M ills . What was the rate of accumulation last year? Dr. S au ln ier . It was somewhere in the neighborhood of $3.5 billion in 1956. That is, the addition to the dollar volume of inventories of all sorts in our economy. Representative M ills . I s it essential now, in order to carry out these objectives and these predictions, that inventory accumulations in 1957 only be $3^ billion, or must they not be at a greater rate than that? Dr. S au ln ier . I don’t recall the figures precisely, but I feel quite certain that I am correct in saying that inventory accumulations in 1957 at a lower rate than prevailed in 1956 are not inconsistent with these budgetary assumptions. Representative C u rtis . Could I ask one question just for clarifica tion? In your inventory figures, you said it runs the gamut and that includes raw materials as well as finished products. Dr. S au ln ier . That is right. Representative M ills . What about the possibilities of exporting goods overseas for 1957 compared to 1956? Dr. S au ln ier . What we call net foreign investment was a fairly substantial element in the economic expansion of 1956. I believe it was under $2 billion, but it is an important factor because it was a substantial increase over the previous year. Now, this represented two major factors—the very rapid rate of economic expansion abroad, and the rather sharp revival of private foreign investment. As you know, in many cases when there is private investment abroad this means that the funds invested are spent in this country to buy equipment of one sort or another, which does in volve an increase in exports. Senator W a t k in s . H ow do you determine the investment abroad? How do you find out how much private investment there is ? It seems to me if it is a private affair, there would not be any public figures on it. Dr. S au ln ier . I am afraid that someone more expert than I is going to have to give you the details of making these estimates of foreign investment. There is, as you may know, a special unit in the Department of Commerce that puts together regularly our balance of payments figures, and makes estimates on private investment abroad. While I would be glad to supply you with a technical memorandum on that subject, I think I would probably confuse you more than help you if I tried personally to give you the information. Senator W a t k in s . I just wanted to be informed. Representative M ills . I had in mind more the export of goods produced in the United States than the export of dollar investment abroad. I was thinking in terms of the remarkable increase that occurred this year in the exportation of American made and grown 34 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT goods, particularly farm products overseas. In order for us to con tinue even at the present rate of production here in the United States, I would think we would almost have to maintain those levels ot export. I f we are going to grow, a part of that growth must be reflected, as I see it, in increased shipments overseas. With the disturbances that presently exist, I have been thinking that it would be very difficult for us to enjoy in 1957 the same rate of export that we enjoyed in 1956. I wondered if those things were considered and to what extent they affected the determinations that were made here for purposes of this economic report and the budget. Senator W a t k in s . Will you yield to me at that point? Would you not expect that the present rate would continue, particularly with the stimulation given to the export of oil and petroleum products? Representative M ills . I would hope that our overall exports might be greater than they were in 1956 but I had some degree o f caution in my own mind with respect to them being as great, even with this exportation of oil. Senator W a t k in s . This will be caused not by economic causes, but by international affairs that have no relation to economics. Representative M ills . The difficulty as I pointed out in our expor tation of as much, if that is the case, in 1957 as in 1956 would certainly be due to these disturbances over there. But they would directly affect our economic conditions here with respect to this anticipated growth. Senator W a t k in s . I would agree with you on that. It seems to me that no matter how well we plan at home, we are governed almost entirely by whatever happens in the foreign field. We can plan and we can lay out our plans as to what we want to do and we can set out our economic program and all of a sudden something happens over there and knocks it into a, cocked hat. Representative C urtis . Y ou mentioned the bulk of the farm prod ucts m there. The countries abroad are claiming that we achieved that figure through a sort of force-out and they allege that we are dumping. Representative M ills . Y ou ran into it on that subcommittee that you are on. Representative C urtis . I was a congressioal adviser to our delega tion over there at GATT and that was on the tongues of most of the representatives of the GATT countries. With that kind of pressure from them and these allegations, I think that we are going to run into increased difficulties in being able to dispose of as much surplus agricultural products. Representative M ills . I am glad to know that you have the same concern I do about that. Representative C urtis . I do. Representative M ills . I was somewhat surprised as I read the Eco nomic Report that there is not any information in it, as I read it, on this point. Dr. S a u l n ie r . Do you mean on surplus sales ? Representative M ills . N o, on the relationship of our exports to this growth that we are contemplating. Dr. S a u ln ie r . The Economic Report merely states on page 46, at the top of the page, “While the factors influencing our markets ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 35 abroad are complex and diverse, foreign trade and investment on balance appear likely to remain high.” Representative M ills . I read that but that still does not mean to me that it will remain as high as it was in 1956 or it could still be high and not be as high as it was in 1956. I f it is only as high as it was in 1955 we will have to look somewhere else than to export of goods to find the basis for tie increase in overall activity here at home. Dr. S a u ln ie r . We have identified this as one of the areas o f un certainty in the economic picture. Representative M ills . I s it just an uncertain area or is it an area of weakness as we approach 1957 ? Dr. S a u ln ie r . I think it is better described as an area of uncer tainty than an area of weakness. I think we must also bear in mind that, important as this is, not only for our economic life and for the prosperity of the rest of the world, it is far from being a major item in the aggregate economic accounts of our country. We could have a very substantial decline in net foreign investment— say 30, 40, or 50 percent—and dollarwise it would involve something in the neighborhood of half a billion dollars. Representative M ills . Perhaps I am wrong in this, Doctor, in the assumptions that I make with respect to what must exist for this rate of Sy2 percent of growth to occur. It seems to me that we must have, in order for that rate of growth to occur in the 12 months* period, very, very favorable economic conditions along most lines of activity. You cannot have very many reversals of what took place in 1956 without losing that rate of growth. In order to have a rate of growth of Sy2 percent in other words, you must have some degree of growth all along the line in these factors contributing to the whole. Now, you have considered all of them as you have reached these conclusions and I am merely, because of the lack of anything really specific in here on that, raising the point as to what effect and in fluence you anticipate from that failure of one activity on the overall ? Dr. S a u ln ie r . T o get this result, you have to have pluses in some areas of the economy and if you have minuses in other areas, your growth, where growth does occur, must be greater than the average or the aggregate in order to carry its extra burden. Representative Mjlls . Y ou could have a complete cessation of ex ports if you compensated for that loss in increased military growth or in some other growth, perhaps ? Dr. S au ln ie r . That is correct. Representative M ills . Y ou are talking about foreign investments? Dr. S a u ln ie r . I am talking about our net foreign investment figure. Representative M il l s . I am talking more about our export of goods rather than the dollars now. Dr. S au ln ie r . This encompases that. Representative M ills . I know, but our exports of goods far ex ceeded $1,400 million in 1956. Dr. S a u ln ie r . That is correct, and they are offset in our national accounts by our imports. Representative M ills . We have a surplus still of exports over im ports ; is that right ? Dr. S au ln ie r . Yes, which we make up for with our investments. 36 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Representative M ills . We partly make up for it with our invest ments abroad. Dr. S a u ln ie r . Yes; partly. Representative C u rtis . On this same point I just wanted to develop a few things that were mentioned because I had a question along this line. I had one with regard to this foreign investment. Actually, in the long run, is that the kind of thing that helps balance any dollar gaps? It is perfectly true that the immediate process of investment is involved and it will bring in money, but as that capital investment in turn earns over the long range, it will work the other way. Am I right about that ? Dr. S au ln ie r . It does work the other way, as income has to be re paid to the investor in this country. Ultimately one would hope the investment itself would be returned. But, of course, the ability of foreign countries to make those income payments implies prosperity on their part and economic expansion, and one would expect the de mand abroad for funds to grow. Representative C urtts. On this point of how much we can antici pate next year, using the combination of foreign trade and investment, this is based upon the discussions of the subcommittee I am on, of for eign trade, with the governmental officials and business people in the Western European countries. Many of these countries are relaxing the barriers that they have against our investing in their countries because now they are anxious to encourage it. So it would look like foreign investment will be maintained, if not increased, because a great deal of it has been going to Western Europe. Now, on that I was going to ask the same question that Senator Wat kins asked about the accuracy of our estimates of capital investment abroad, and in particular whether or not we included m it the plowing back of earnings in the investment that we already have. I was amazed in talking with our movie industry in Britain to find that they have earned so much money on their original investment, and because taking those earnings out of Britain would have caused Britain considerable economic strain, they agreed to just reinvest. They put in around 50 or 60 million dollars and went into some areas over there that they never intended to. There is a lot or that kind of reinvestment going on and I do not know how our Department of Commerce would catch those figures. Maybe they could, but I am curious to know if we do know the extent to which our figures on our foreign investments are reliable. Dr. S a u ln ie r . I would not be able to say how satisfactory the esti mating methods are, but I am sure that an effort is being made to encompass the degree of reinvestment of earnings in these estimates. I can say only that I am confident that a good job is being done—as good as is practicable at this time. There are excellent people working on it* Representative C urtis . We have another thing that pertains to that. Western Germany now is in a creditor position and it is appar ently investing money over here. I understand France is, too. I know of no way of measuring the amount of flow of foreign investments. Dr. S a u ln ie r . I think the net is the other way. There will always be some individuals abroad who will have the resources available for investment and will find the United States an attractive place in which to place their funds. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 37 Representative Curits. I asked the French people if they had any way of estimating how much French capital might be coming into the United States for investment. They indicated that they could not tell very well. There were supposed to be restrictions on it, but they rather frankly admitted that these negotiations were handled through the Swiss and they had no way of measuring it. Dr. S a u ln ie r . Y ou inspire me to make a special effort to find out how these estimates are made. Representative M ills . Doctor, I have just 1 or 2 other thoughts. I had recently been told, and I notice that it is somewhat expressed here in the President’s economic message, that the drive is being made by some foreign countries to obtain treaties with the United States that will recognize the going rate of tax in the foreign countries rather than the actual amount of tax paid by the business in the foreign country. They say it is necessary that we recognize the going rate of tax if we do not nullify tax concessions which these foreign countries may make for purposes of obtaining outside capital. I can understand their point of view. But since the matter is referred to in the economic message, has full consideration been given to the possible consequences here at home, to the effect on the use of resources here under such a program if it should become widespread and be included in several treaties with several countries ? Are we putting ourselves then in the position in which we may lose the use of facilities and resources that would otherwise be available to us and are we thereby in the long run diminishing the possibility of economic growth here at home in keeping with the purposes o f the Employment Act ? Dr. S au ln ie r . Another alternative that you should include in that list is the possibility that this would help us to substitute private investment for public investment abroad. Representative Mims. It may do that; but the point I am getting at is this: Would it in any way jeopardize the accomplishment in the long run of the objectives of the Employment Act here at home to pursue a program which grants this concession to foreign investment of American capital and resources? Is it worthy of consideration? Dr. S au ln ie r . It is an economic problem. I f the attractiveness of foreign investment increases, and such tax treaties would increase the attractiveness of foreign investment by giving effect to the tax privi leges accorded investment abroad, it would tend to draw investment funds from our own economy. Other things being equal, it would make the balance between the supply of available funds for investment here and the demand for them a little less favorable. Other things being equal—and we have to make that assumption in order to reason about this at all—it would tend to cause investment costs and interest rates to be a trifle higher in the domestic market. Representative M ills . Is there occasion then, to have us hold up a flag of caution to the adoption of such a program and its widespread utilization ? Dr. S a u ln ier . Being as uncertain as I am about the immediate im pact of such treaties, and being as keen an advocate as I am for measures that would increase the flow of our funds abroad for pur 38 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT poses of economic development, I would hesitate to say that we ought to hold back on tax treaties at this time. Representative M il l s . Even though it means supplanting the sig nals of the market place with concessions and subsidies ? Dr. S au ln ie r . Even though it might mean at this time a little heavier demand for investment funds in our market than prevails currently. Eepresentative M ills . I had one other thought. I am a little bit concerned about language which the President uses in his economic message: Reliance for stability in economic growth cannot be placed exclusively on the fiscal and monetary policies of Government. A little further down he says: Of particular importance in a prosperous economy is the responsibility of leaders of business and labor to reach agreements on wages and other labor benefits that are consistent with productivity prospects and the maintenance of a stable dollar. Now, that causes me to feel that there must be some method in mind whereby these leaders will be asked to assume this responsibility. I wonder if you could describe the mechanism that you envision by "which these leaders of business and labor can assume this responsi bility. Dr. S au ln ie r . I would just like to make two comments on that, Mr. Mills. First, there was no intention in the economic message of the President to take the position that the full burden “ could not” be placed on monetary and fiscal controls. The economic message merely says that we court certain risks “ if” we place the full burden on monetary and fiscal controls. Eepresentative M ills . I read that a little earlier. Dr. S au ln ier . I think that is rather an important point. It is rather an important interpretation or understanding of the language to have in mind. Eepresentative M ills . Then this language should be understood to mean “shall not” rather than cannot. Dr. S a u ln ie r . And that it could not do it without producing certain other results which one would regard as undesirable. Eepresentative M ills . In other words, it is better not to rely ex clusively upon fiscal and monetary policies of Government. It is better, according to this report, for us to rely to some extent upon that, and at the same time for us to obtain recognition of the respon sibility of leaders of business and labor that they have a chore to perform in this connection if we are to remain economically stable. Now, what I am getting at is this: I think if that is the procedure that we are following, we must sometime or other obtain recognition of that responsibility from them during the year 1957. Now, first of all, what is the mechanism that is contemplated for getting the picture over to them and then, secondly, the mechanism by which the leaders of business and labor can assume this responsibility? Dr. S au ln ie r . I think the first and fundamental requirement is that we understand the problem and get a broad public understanding of it. It is my hope that the economic messages—this economic message and also that portion of the state of the Union message that deals with this—will help to communicate to the public generally the nature o f these responsibilities. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 39 Representative M ills . Frankly, can we expect them to assume the responsibility that we say is theirs and which we desire them to assume, unless we ourselves in Government set an example that the assumption of their responsibility would require them to follow ? Dr. S au ln ier . I think the example that Government sets is enor mously important. Representative M il l s . Then does it come to this, that if we expect them to do what we want them to do this year, we must steer away from increases in salaries of Government employees during the year 1957? The President’s Economic Report does not say that there should be any, but there is a drive underway already. Dr. S au ln ie r . That is correct, sir. Representative M ills . It is quite a strong drive, I think, for about $800 per employee. Now, does this suggest that if we want business and labor to assume responsibility for holding back on price and wage increases, we must do the same in the Government ? Is that the case ? Dr. S au ln ie r . That is correct. Representative M ills . So that in order for us to expect the maxi mum out of them, we will have to do the maximum here to keep them from having such increases occur during the year 1957 ? Dr. S au ln ie r . That is right. Representative M ills . Does this recommendation mean that in wage negotiations in the steel industry, for example, agreements should be based on the productivity prospects for the steel industry or for the economy as a whole? Dr. S a u ln ier . Well, that is a hard question. Representative M ills . I f it is agreeable to the other members of the committee, and particularly to the members of the President’s Economic Council, I would like to submit to them some questions which they may answer and return for the record. Use your own judgment as to what you would say and what you should not answer, if you want to do that. Dr. S au ln ie r . We would be glad to do that. Representative M ills . I have no desire to do anything more than just to have the information. Representative C urtis . Are they along these lines? Representative M ills . These are the questions submitted to all members of the committee. Dr. S aulnter . We would be glad to do that, Mr. Chairman, but I would only ask that, in making such requests, you will bear in mind that the Council has many duties to perform. One of the very heavy ones that we have to perform is the preparation of the Economic Report. We have been hard at work on the preparation of the Economic Report since the 1st of November. Three long months have gone by and the Council has devoted just about its full resources to this task. I hope that we will not now be called upon to write another Economic Report. Representative M ills . I would not have any such thought in mind. Dr. S a u ln ie r . Might I say that, in making that request, I have just this in mind, and I feel very strongly about this: I am an enthusiast about the Employment Act and about the possibilities of service that the President can get from the Council of Economic Advisers. I feel 40 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT very definitely that the service that we can render to the President and to the Government and to the public in this matter is very much affected by the kind of homework that we inherit. We can sit down and turn ourselves into just a guild of writers, but I think we would be less useful than if we can turn ourselves to the practical day-to-day problems of Government. Representative C u rtis . What you are saying in effect, is that this series of questions, if answered fully, would be almost another economic report. I am inclined to agree with you. Representative M ills . I doubt that they would. Have you seen the questions ? Dr, S au ln ie r . I have not seen the questions. Representative M ills . We could sit here and go through those ques tions for the remainder of the day if it was the will of the committee, but I thought that it could be just as productive, if the questions were susceptible of answers for them to be submitted for the record rather than keeping these gentlemen here later. I know all of us have other things to do. Representative C urtis . I have not gone through all of these ques tions but I have seen some of them. They certainly are questions that require lengthy and statistical answers. Dr. S a u ln ie r . This presents a very real problem for the Council of Economic Advisers. Frankly, I would rather come up here and spend 2 or 3 days talking with you gentlemen about them, than to prepare written responses. I am quite frank about that. I would be glad to come up here and talk for 2,3, or 4 days. Representative M ills . I will certainly withdraw my request if it means that much of a burden to you. Dr. S a u ln ier . I have done a good deal of writing in my day on finance and economic stabilization, and it comes hard to me. When the Council of Economic Advisers prepares a document of this kind, it has to be done with very great care and I can foresee weeks and weeks of work in that document. Representative M ills . Let me, then, put the questions in the record at this point and just go ahead ana get your answers to this one question if it is possible. (The questions referred to by Representative Mills are as follows:) S om e Q u e s tio n s P osed b y t h e J a n u a r y Prepared by th e Staff 1957 E c o n o m i c R e p o e t o f t h e P r e s id e n t o f th e J o in t E c o n o m ic C o m m itte e I . PROBLEMS OF ECONOMIC STABILIZATION The President, in his letter of transmittal, states: “ Reliance for stability in economic growth cannot be placed exclusively on the fiscal and monetary policies of Government. * * * Of particular importance in a prosperous economy is the responsibility of leaders of business and labor to reach agreements on wages and other labor benefits that are consistent with productivity prospects and with the maintenance of a stable dollar.” A. Can you describe the mechanism by which leaders of business sind labor can assume this responsibility? B. Does this recommendation mean that in wage negotiations in, say, the steel industry, agreements should be based on the productivity prospects for the steel industry, or for the economy as a whole? C. Assuming that the wage agreements are to be based on the productivity prospects of the particular industry, can the “leaders of business and labor’’ in that industry be expected to be able to obtain the required information ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 41 about “productivity prospects” and wage levels in that industry, consistent with “maintenance of a stable dollar” ? D. Suppose that, given demand conditions, a particular industry can increase the prices of its products without loss of sales. Does this recom mendation, quoted above, suggest that the industry should refrain from raising its prices to a level at which the prices will serve to “clear the market” because of considerations of overall economic stabilization? E. Doesn’t this recommendation presuppose that business and labor leaders can evaluate the impact of wage and price changes in their particular industries on the economy as a whole? Can we place any reliance on this supposition as a basis for labor’s and management’s contributions to economic stabilization? The President’s report states, on page 2, that the management of business concerns have the responsibility for administering “ their affairs so as to help avoid economic imbalance and dislocation.” It also states that “ * * * the increasing practice of planning expansion programs well into the future and organizing operations with a view to greater stability of employment” are evidence of business’ acceptance of this responsibility. The report states that “business management has a clear responsibility * * *” to avoid excesses in the management of inventories, in the expansion of facilities, and in the use of credit and “* * * carry out its plans so as to contribute to steady economic growth.” A. Can you suggest the standards or guides which the management of any given business should use to determine whether it is carrying out its plans so as to contribute to steady economic growth? How is any given business management to know whether, from the point of view of overall economic stability, its plans and actions with respect to inventories, expan sion of facilities, and use of credit are “excessive” ? B. Most businesses, presumably, will be guided in their management of inventory, facilities expansion, and credit-use policies by considerations of minimizing their costs and maximizing their profits. The free enterprise system is based on such motivations. Are actions so motivated necessarily consistent with steady economic growth? If not, do these assertions in the report recommend that business management permit considerations of economic stabilization to outweigh those of cost reduction and profit maximizing in their own companies? n . GOVERNMENT STABILIZATION POLICIES On page 48 the report states that “ * * * the financial affairs of government should be so administered as to help stabilize the economy and to encourage sound growth. The principle of flexibility in fiscal policy calls for relating the budget as far as feasible to economic conditions, helping to counteract infla tionary or deflationary tendencies as the situation requires.” A. Would you elaborate on this in detail? 1. In the context of an inflationary situation, what does this principle call for with respect to— (а ) Government spending; (б) Government revenues—tax reductions or increases, general or otherwise; (c) Net budgetary situation; (d) Debt management? 2. In the context of a recession, what does this principle call for with respect to— (a ) Government spending; (&) Government revenues—tax reductions or increases; (c) Net budgetary situation; (d) Debt management? If we were to face a recession in fiscal 1958, would you recommend tax reduc tions, even if they meant an increase in the debt? The President’s report states on page 2 that government must “ * * * take in taxes no more than absolutely necessary of the incomes of individuals and businesses.” How do you define and measure the amount of taxes that are absolutely necessary? Is this amount related to the use of government fiscal powers for purposes of economic stabilization? How? The report notes (p. 32) that rising costs, particularly after the middle of the year, underlay the rise in the prices of most commodities and services during 1956. 87624— 57—pt. 1------4 42 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT The report describes this “cost-price push” (p. 44) as follows: “When produc tion, sales, and employment are high, wage and price increases in important in dustries create upward pressures on costs and prices generally. To depend ex clusively on monetary and fiscal restraints as a means of containing the upward movement of prices would raise serious obstacles to the maintenance of economic growth and stability. In the face of a continuous upward pressure on costs and prices, moderate restraints would not be sufficient; yet stronger restraints would bear with undue severity on sectors of the economy having little if any responsibility for the movement toward a higher cost-price level and would court the risk of being excessively restrictive for the economy generally.” A. Can this “cost-price push” occur without an accomodating expansion of aggregate (money) demand? Could this “cost-price push” be prevented by making Federal Government fiscal and monetary policies sufficiently restraining? B. If fiscal and monetary restraints adequate to prevent price rises would “ * * * court the risk of being excessively restrictive for the economy generally,” doesn't this imply a conflict between the objectives of price level stabilization (i. e., preserving the value of the dollar), and maintaining high levels of employment and production? C. If such a conflict does exist, in the present context, should Federal Government economic policies give priority to price level stabilization or to maintaining high employment? D. The report observes (p. 46) that “ * * * the moderate upward drift of the price level may not yet have run its course * * Does this mean that we may expect further increases in the price level in 1957 over the end of 1956? Does the language on page 44, quoted above, imply a recommenda tion that if such price increases materialize—or threaten to occur—the Federal Reserve should not impose “stronger restraints” ? I I I . ECONOMIC SIG NIFIC AN C E OF PRESIDENT’S MID-EAST PROPOSALS The report is virtually silent on the consequences of developments in the MidEast in 1956 for the American economy. Does this imply that these consequences are insignificant? If not, will you elaborate in detail on the impact on the United States economy of the closing of the Suez Canal, the military interven tion in Egypt, etc. ? The report is entirely silent with respect to the President’s proposal for eco nomic assistance in the Mid-East. Will this program, if adopted, be incon sequential so far as the United States economy is concerned? If not, will you discuss the problems and types of adjustments involved? IV. AGRICULTURAL SECTOR OF T H E ECONOMY The report states on page 12 that “in general, adjustments have been in the direction of a better balanced farm economy. Most of the decline in the total number of farms has been among units that yield inadequate income to their operators; the number of moderate-sized family farms has increased; and the proportion of farms owned in whole or in part by the farm operator has risen.” Can you provide us the detailed data showing (1) the distribution of the de cline in the number of farms by size of farm or by amount of farm operator’s income from the farm ; (2) the distribution by size and by type, family or com mercial, of the present number of farms; and (3) distribution of operator owner ship of farms by size of farm? Representative M ills . Does this recommendation mean that nego tiations in, say, the steel industry should involve agreements based on productivity prospects for that particular industry or the economy as a whole. What are we talking about in the report there? Dr. S au ln ie r . Let me see if I can answer the question this way. I am an old college professor and I could do this a little better if I had a blackboard. Lacking a blackboard, let me draw some pictures on this pad. I f you take all the industries in our country today—if we knew the productivity prospects for each of them—we would find that they ranged from some very high prospects—I am talking now about the prospects for the next year or 2 years—all the way down to those ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 43 having no prospects for increase at all, and to those industries where the prospect may be for a loss of productivity. Now, we could take our little mass of companies and order them according to their productivity prospects. I f we did that, we might find that the data would tend to concentrate around a prospective productivity gain of say 2% percent or 2 percent, or some such figure. Let us say 2% percent. There would be some companies with much brighter prospects, but fewer than those that concentrate at the norm. Then there are some that have very little prospect of gain. You would get a spread something like this. All that the economic report says is that if, on the average, wage increases go beyond what is indicated at this concentration point, that is a factor making for general price increases. That is a general proposition and refers to averages and not to specific industries and still less to specific companies. Now, let me turn to the other question. Let us suppose that you are in an industry that has very very bright productivity prospects and your company happens to be one of those with the brightest prosects of all. You are away out here and you have been told by someody, or you have reason to believe, that the average gain is 2% per cent, but you can expect a lot more in your industry. Now, what will happen? In negotiating a wage agreement you will, of course, take account of the situation in your own industry, as will those who represent labor. But, you will not pay a wage in that industry which is exactly in line with the productivity prospects for your industry. You will pay perhaps somewhat higher than the average because of the bright prospects of your industry, but only “ somewhat” higher than the average. Indeed, there is no reason why you should pay more than that. The bright productivity prospect in your industry is not attributable to the qualities of labor working in your industry because if they do not work for you they go into some other industry where productivity prospects are less bright and, therefore, by inference, their efficiency is less. Representative M ills . That is what I was getting at. This plan does contemplate enough flexibility for me as the management of a concern to come to the President with a wholesome desire of assuming thi& responsibility and doing what is suggested and still permit me acting under that responsibility to retain my work force and to ac commodate their needs for increases if those needs exist even though my immediate prospect for increase in production is not in keeping with that which they and I might agree would be a reasonable figure for their wages for the future. Dr. S a u ln ier . I think that is a correct statement. Representative M ills . I think that that is all I have. Are there any xurther questions ? Representative C u rtis . I have a question. I think this has been explained but I have a note on this sentence here that Mr. Mills was attaching much importance to: E Reliance for stability in economic growth cannot be placed exclusively on the fiscal and monetary policies of Government. Frankly, I was very much disturbed at that sentence because I read into it the overtones that I think are not there but I want to be sure. 44 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT The stability and economic growth in my judgment, cannot even be placed primarily on fiscal and monetary policies of Government. In our system of private enterprise it is bound to be in private enterprise and at most, all the Government can do, as the rest of the report indicates, is create good climate. Yet this sentence was worded in such a way that it stated: Reliance for stability and economic growth cannot be placed exclusively— and it implied that it could be primarily placed on it. I do not think even that can be done. Dr. S a u ln ier . That interpretation should not be placed on that sentence. The reference is primarily to the efforts that must be made by Government and by individuals to control inflationary develop ments. Representative C u r t i s . The dollar value is what you had in mind? Dr. S au ln ier . That is right. Representative C urtis . I wanted to make it clear that the overtones I read into it are not in there. I get your point about what you were referring to and the fact that that applied to the dollar value more than anything else. Representative M ills . I have just one further thing. This is not a question prompted by me but prompted by two conflicting state ments that I have read by reporters skilled in interpretation of lan guage. It had to do with one sentence of that paragraph which I read to you earlier on page 44. In the face of a continuous upward pressure on costs and prices, moderate restraints would not be sufficient; yet stronger restraints would bear with undue severity on sectors of the economy having little if any responsibility for the movement toward a higher cost-price level and would court the risk of being excessively restrictive for the economy generaUy. One writer said that the President here is telling the Federal Reserve System to lay off and not impose any greater monetary re strictions. Another writer is saying just the contrary. Which of the two have properly interpreted what is meant by this language? Is this an instruction by the President to the Federal Reserve not to impose greater restraint in monetary policy ? Dr. S a u ln ie r . I think both reporters were wrong. Representative M ills . They are going to be disappointed. Dr. S au ln ie r . The President in this section of the Economic Report is not speaking directly to the Federal -Reserve and not giving instrucr tions to the Federal Reserve. This section of the Economic Report is making an important ob servation on some of the implications of monetary policy and mone tary restraints. I think these are observations on the implications of money policy with which most students of our financial markets would agree. It is not necessary to tell the Federal Reserve System that they should avoid monetary restraints that are so severe as to produce a contraction or recession in the United States. I think they under stand what they are doing well enough, and they have a keen enough appreciation o f their public duties, to avoid such policies. Representative M ills . I do not mean to say this about the present members, but long ago they did not always act in such a way as to leave me certain that they were justified with that degree of confidence, ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 45 I am not criticizing anything that they are doing now and I know they are very sincere in what they do. What you are saying, I assume, would apply to the present members and not to all the members that have ever been on there. Dr. S a u ln ie r . I am talking about the present Federal Reserve Board and present policy, altogether without prejudice to history. I have my own views about history. Representative M ills . I felt that these two writers were wrong my self. I had a different impression from what you stated though. It was my thought here that the President was making an observation that in order to completely control this inflationary spiral it is neces sary to have more restraints than we have today. But, because greater restraints than we have today would bring about severity of treatment in certain sectors, we probably would not be justified in imposing those greater restraints and, therefore, we are going to countenance con tinuation of just a wree bit of inflation in the months ahead. That was my reaction to it. Dr. S au ln ie r . I would not read it that way. Representative M ills . I hope your conclusions are correct. Representative C urtis . I hate to prolong this, but there was a basic question that I have been meaning to ask. It is a general impression that I have received over what is called the tight-money picture. It seems to me that in the situation there, tight consumer credit made sense, but it seemed that the tightness on the money was actually in investment money rather than in consumer money. Now, that seemed to me to be the reverse process. I f we have a situation that is inflationary, it is certainly to our advantage to in crease production. Production is increased through additional in vestment expenditures. Representative M ills . Through savings. Representative C urtis . Yes, through savings, but also if you have a small business, for example, that is legitimately expanding its pro duction because the market is there and it finds that it cannot expand because it cannot get the normal, or what was normal before, bank loans that it was getting for that very operation, or they are re quired to use money that they had used for operating expenses investmentwise for capital outlay, they then cannot meet the increased demands of the consumer. Dr. S au ln ier . That is true. On the other hand, we must recognize that in the last 2 years, notably in the last 2 years, credit demands have risen to a very large degree from expansions of plant and equipment, which will enable consumer goods to be increased in the future. Representative C urtis . Take the cement industry. Everyone knows the demand for cement due to the home-building program, even though there has been some cutback, and the St. Lawrence seaway project and the big highway program. We are going to have to have increased production of cement. That is the kind of business that lends itself to smaller businesses rather than large operations because there is an advantage economi cally to being well located due to freight cost. That is the type area where they are feeling this shortage of investment capital and bank borrowings. 46 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT It is hampering their ability to expand in order to meet the known demand for cement. That is bound to increase the cost of cement, I would think. Dr. S au ln ie r . That is right. It does contribute to price increases. Eepresentative C urtis . In that instance, it would seem that a little laxity, or perhaps not laxity but liberalization on investment credit where it is known to be going into productivity on the part of the banks, would be beneficial. Yet, it almost seems that it is the other way around. It has not been consumer credit that we are receiving complaints on, but it is in this area of investment dollars. Dr. S au ln ier . There has been little complaint in 1956 over the use o f credit in the consumer area. Credit use there has been only a frac tion of what it was in 1955. Whether 1957 will see an increase in de mand in that area or not is another matter although there are some indications now that increased demands will come from the consumer area. Let me say, Mr. Chairman, that one of the tasks to which the Council has to turn $t once, and must give close attention, is the study of the very large investigation which has been completed for us at our request by the Federal Reserve Board on consumer credit. As soon as we can, we must reach a conclusion on whether the Con gress should be asked to grant the President standby authority to control consumer credit. That is something which I anticipate will occupy us fully for some weeks. Eepresentative M ills . There are some factors to consider in con nection with a study of that kind. Permit me to thank each of you for being with us this morning, and contributing to our understanding of the message of the President,, known as the Economic Eeport. We thank you very much. Dr. S a u ln ie r . Thank you very much. Let me say, Mr. Chairman* that at this late moment I have deep feelings of regret that throughout this period of questioning I have not called on my two colleagues to share my task. I should have done so. There are many points on which they are far better qualified than I am to answer your questions and I hope you, and they, will forgive me. Eepresentative M ills . I f they feel any degree of mistreatment by the Committee, we will grant them the right to extend their remarks in the record. Without objection the Committee will adjourn until 10 o’clock in the morning. (The correspondence referred to on p. 7 follows:) C o n g r e s s o p t h e U n it e d S t a t e s , J o in t E c o n o m ic C o m m i t t e e , December 11, 1956. Dr. J. S a u l n i e r , Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers , E xecutive Office o f the President, Washington , D. C. D e a r D r . S a u l n i e r : We are pleased to learn of your appointment to the chairmanship of the Council of Economic Advisers. I congratulate you on this appointment and look forward to close working relationships between the Council and this committee. R aym ond ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 47 Grover Ensley has reported to me your feelings with respect to meeting with the joint committee in late January at hearings reviewing the President’s Eco nomic Report As you know from previous discussions and correspondence, this has been a matter which has resulted in confusion and strong feelings over the years. In the past, 1 of 2 procedures has been followed: 1. An executive session with no transcript made. This was the procedure followed last year except that stenographic notes were taken but not typed. I gather from Grover that this is the arrangement you would prefer in the future, in that you believe it would give you greater freedom to talk frankly and in detail with respect to the assumptions and background under lying the President’s Economic Report with those members of the committee who are able to attend the meeting. 2. An executive session with a transcript made which, after editing, is printed as part of the committee hearings. This was the procedure, for example, in January 1955. From the standpoint of the committee, I think it is correct to say that this is the most useful procedure in that it makes the record available to those members of the committee who of necessity are absent from the executive session. It also helps document the com mittee’s own report to the Congress, and thus tends to be of maximum bene fit to the President’s legislative program in the Congress. The question now becomes one of reconciling two logical and understandable positions in the interest of carrying out the objectives of the Employment Act by assisting the Congress in its consideration of the recommendations of the Presi dent, and at the same time preserve the unique position, objectivity, and frank ness of the Council of Economic Advisers. Would you consider the following compromise procedure which I would hope might satisfy both of these objectives: An executive session at which a transcript would be taken of those parts of the meeting which the Council felt would not jeopardize its position of anonymity. At any point in the hearing when the Council felt it was get ting into an area where it wished to “roll up its sleeves” it would be given permission to go off the record—with no stenographic notes made. Upon completion of this delicate point the discussion could go back on the record. The part of the hearing that was transcribed could then be typed, and the Council could edit it to provide additional elaborations or to delete por tions that on further consideration were felt to jeopardize its position. This could then be made a part of the printed hearings for the benefit of the members, the Congress, and the general public. As I have indicated above, this proposed procedure would mean that absent members would not have the benefit of parts of the discussion. They, never theless, would have benefit of that part of the testimony which was more or less routine. At the same time it would protect the Council against stenographic notes and a record being made of any portion of the testimony which might jeopardize the Council’s position. I have just looked over the public record of the Council before the House Appropriations Committee on February 16, 1956, and this suggested compromise procedure, as I understand it, follows the practice which has been prevailing between the House Appropriations Committee and the Council. I am writing you at this time in order to do all we can to avoid the confusion and misunderstanding that developed last year. At the committee’s organization meeting next month, when there will undoubtedly be a discussion of plans for the hearings on the President’s report, the committee will want to decide whether or not it wishes to invite the Council to testify and on what basis. This decision of the committee on whether or not the Council should be invited will, of course, depend upon the conditions under which the Council is willing to testify. While I am not sure that all members will be entirely happy with the compromise I have proposed I will do my best to have it accepted by the committee if it meets with your approval, recognizing that in your case, as in ours, it is a second choice—a compromise. I know this is getting into your busy time but I would like to have some indica tion from you on this matter before our committee meets in early January. I am sure that you will find that this committee will be more than cooperative with you in seeking to protect the proper position of the Council. Sincerely yours, W r ig h t P a tm a n , Vice Chairman. 48 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT T h e C h a ir m a n o f t h e C o u n c i l o f E c o n o m ic A d v is e r s , Hon. Washington, December 19,1956 . W r ig h t P a tm a n , Vice Chairman, Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, Washington, D. C. D e a r M r . P a t m a n : Thank you very much for your December 11 letter on the subject of procedural arrangements for testimony before the Joint Economic Committee by the Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers. Although I would prefer to testify before the committee in executive session with no transcript, I appreciate your need for a record and I think your sugges tion for obtaining it is a fair and workable one. My understanding of your pro posal is that stenographic notes would be taken except where the testimony is given “ off the record,” and that a transcript would be prepared from these notes and printed in the proceedings of the committee after editing by the Chairman of the Council, such editing to permit the deletion or revision of substantive matter as well as purely literary changes. Unless some change is made in the proposed arrangement in the interim, and I see no need for any change, I will assume that my testimony before the Joint Economic Committee will be given on this basis. It was good of you to write me as fully as you did, and I am pleased to have had this opportunity to reach a mutually agreeable arrangement well in advance of the committee’s hearings. I look forward with pleasure to the opportunity which these hearings will provide to discuss the President’s Economic Report with the committee. Cordially, R a y m o n d J. S a u l n i e r . (Whereupon at 1:10 p. m., the hearing in the above-entitled matter was recessed to reconvene at 10 a. m., Tuesday, January 29,1957.) JANUARY 1957 ECONOMIC REPORT OP THE PRESIDENT T U E S D A Y , J A N U A R Y 29, 1957 C ongress of t h e U nited S tates , J oin t E conomic C om m ittee , W a sh in gton , D . G . The committee met at 10 a. m., pursuant to adjournment, in room P-63 of the Capitol, Hon. Wright Patman (chairman of the joint committee) presiding. Present: Representatives Patman (presiding), Mills, Talle, Curtis, and Kilburn; and Senators O’Mahoney, Flanders, and Watkins. Present also: Dr. Grover W. Ensley, executive director of the joint committee, and John W. Lehman, clerk of the joint committee. Chairman P a t m a n . The committee will please come to order. The hearings on the President’s Economic Report started yesterday when the committee held an executive session with members of the Council of Economic Advisers. I might say to the public that a transcript was taken of yesterday’s testimony which will be edited and released to the public as soon as possible. We are happy that this year we will be able to publish the testimony received from the Council members. Today our hearing centers on the Federal budget. The President transmitted to the Congress on January 16 a Federal Budget totaling $71.8 billion, an increase of $3 billion from the current year and over $5 billion from fiscal year 1956. These increases in estimated budget expenditures must be viewed in the setting of a high-employment economic situation, in which prices are rising and the value of the dollar is decreasing. An im portant question of Government economic policy under the Employ ment Act is the influence of the budget on problems of economic stablization and growth. It is logical, therefore, to have as our witness today the Director of the Bureau of the Budget. As we all know, the Bureau of the Budget is located in the Office of the President of the United States. The Budget Director is the chief administrative arm of the President. He prepares the budget for the President. The Director of the Bureau of the Budget is Percival F. Brundage. Mr. Brundage, we are glad to have you and your associates with us today and invite you to make any opening remarks that you may care to before we go into the question period. 49 50 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT STATEMENT OF PERCIVAL F. BRUNDAGE, DIRECTOR OF THE BU REAU OF THE BUDGET (ACCOMPANIED BY ROBERT E. MERRIAM, ASSISTANT DIRECTOR; RAYMOND T. BOWMAN, ASSISTANT DI RECTOR FOR STATISTICAL STANDARDS; WILLIAM F. McCANDLESS, ASSISTANT DIRECTOR FOR BUDGET REVIEW, AND SAMUEL M. COHN, CHIEF OF FISCAL ANALYSIS OF THE OFFICE OF BUDGET REVIEW) Mr. B rundage . Mr. Chairman and members o f the committee, it is a pleasure to have the opportunity to discuss the budget with you today. I have a summary statement and a few charts on the budget for the fiscal year 1958, which begins July 1 next, and then I shall be glad to answer your questions. budget policies There seems to be broad general agreement on the budget policy which should be followed at a time like the present when the economy is operating at a very high rate and is subject to inflationary pres sures. Government should seek to alleviate rather than aggravate those pressures. Of course, there is never general agreement on whether the size and contents of a recommended budget are proper. I do not suppose that any budget has ever been submitted which was not criticized by some for being too large and by others for being too small. Usually, the budget is criticized both for being too large in total and at the same time for excluding or allowing too little for each person’s pet project or activity. This year has been no exception. The task of formulating a budget is never an easy one, particularly for a period so far in advance. It is an exercise which tries to bring into reasonable balance demands and objectives which may be con flicting. On the one hand, it would certainly be desirable to reduce total Government spending so that a larger portion of national pro duction could be used in accordance with individual, private decisions and so that inflationary pressures would be minimized. But on the other hand, it may be desirable to increase spending to secure still stronger defenses and to meet such urgent needs as more schools and better highways. Looking at the budget from the revenue side, it would be desirable to reduce taxes so as to remove present restraints on incentives, to simplify collections, to lessen temptation for avoid ance or evasion, and to make more money available for long-run eco nomic growth through private investment. However, it is essential that we help preserve financial stability by keeping taxes high enough to produce some budget surplus for reduction of the public debt and the lessening of inflationary pressures. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 51 Last fall the outbreaks of fighting in Hungary and the Middle East illustrated the tensions and uncertainties that abound in the world today. They emphasized the necessity for our own military strength for the defense of this Nation and the free world. This year we have reached a stage of transition where a large variety of new weapons have been developed with greatly increased effectiveness which are in part replacing the more conventional types of weapons on which we have heretofore relied. The cost of these new weapons is several times the cost of the old, but their effectiveness has increased many times. The tactics and strategies that may be employed in future wars, if they should occur, will be entirely different from the old. On the other hand, we cannot abandon the conventional type of weapons, because localized conflicts are still breaking out for which we must maintain a readiness in all branches of the service. The assumptions with respect to economic conditions which underlie this budget are that the Nation will continue to have a high rate of business activity with increasing national income and with prices relatively stable at about current levels. Secretary Humphrey has already transmitted to the committee the assumptions as to personal incomes and corporate profits which were used in making the revenue estimates. It is assumed that personal income will rise from $325 billion in the calendar year 1956 to $340 billion in the calendar year 1957—that is a little less than 5 percent—and that corporate profits before taxes will rise from 43 to 44 billion dollars for the same periods. I am sure that Secretary Humphrey will be glad to discuss these assumptions further when he appears before you. The expenditure estimates in the 1958 budget are consistent with the economic assump tions used with respect to the revenue estimates. BUDGET SURPLUS The recommended budget for 1958 is balanced. This will be the third successive budget with a surplus. The actual surplus for the fiscal year 1956, which ended June 30, was $1.6 billion. The current estimate for the fiscal year 1957, which is now at its midpoint, is that the surplus will be slightly higher, $1.7 billion. The estimates for 1958 show a surplus of $1.8 billion, based on the continuation of current tax rates. Thus the Federal budget will continue to contribute to the Nation’s financial stability and to the preservation of the purchasing power of the dollar. The prospective budget surplus in the fiscal year 1958 will reinforce the restraints on inflation of present credit and monetary policies. But, as the President pointed out in his messages on the state of the Union, the budget, and the economic report, business and labor leadership must earnestly cooperate with the Government if inflation is to be prevented. 52 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT BUDGET RECEIPTS I f we turn now to chart I, we can see the comparison of the budget totals for 6 years. C hart I 1953 1954 1955 1956 Fiscal Years 1957 1958 -— Estimate — Executive Office of The President • Bureau of The Budget The budget estimates show rising receipts since 1955, which was the low point, to $68.1 billion in the fiscal year 1956, $70.6 billion in 1957, and $73.6 billion in 1958. In addition to an increasing national income, these estimates assume that the existing tax rates on corpora tion incomes and on excises will be extended for another year beyond ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 53 April 1. The extension of these rates will provide $2.3 billion of the total revenues estimated for 1958—without which there would be a budget deficit. Since Secretary Humphrey is scheduled to appear before you, I will not go into any detail about revenues, but will move on to expenditures. BUDGET EXPEN DITU RES Referring again to chart I, you can see that expenditures are also estimated to rise. They were $66.5 billion for the fiscal year 1956, which ended last June 30. For the current year, they are now esti mated to be $68.9 billion. In the coming fiscal year, 1958, total expenditures are estimated at $71.8 billion. I should point out that the estimates of budget receipts and expendi tures for the years 1957 and 1958 are not entirely comparable to the actual figures for previous years. Under the provisions of legislation enacted last year, the financial transactions of the extended Federalaid highway program are included in a self-liquidating trust fund and are not in the budget totals. I f the highway transactions and the budget transactions were combined, the total receipts in 1958 would be larger? $75.8 billion, and the total expenditures would be $73.6 billion, yielding an estimated surplus of $2.2 billion, instead of $1.8 billion. The excess of receipts over expenditures of the highway fund in 1958 of $400 million is not available for general purposes but is re served for future highway expenditures. This is why we have not combined it with the regular budget figures, but have carried it as a separate trust fund. The broad purposes for which Federal expenditures will be made in the fiscal year 1958 are summarized in chart II. C habt II K5.3: FEDERAL BUDGET EXPENDITURES $ Billions 7.4 Protection Civil Benefits Merest Executive Office of The President • Bureau of The Budget X .S sm l Operations 54 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Protection accounts for 63 percent of the total. This is $45.3 bil lion. This category includes the military functions of the Depart ment of Defense, the military and economic parts of the mutual se curity program, the Atomic Energy Commission, stockpiling and de fense production expansion, the United States Information Agencyr and civil defense. Budget expenditures in 1958 for civil benefits, which include most of the domestic programs except central administrative and mainte nance activities, are estimated to be $16.9 billion, which is 24 percent o f the total. Interest is 10 percent of the total. Civil operations and administration, which might be called the real cost of carrying on our Government, will require a little over 2 percent, or $1.8 billion. In addition to the 4 broad purposes shown on this chart, the budget total includes an allowance tor contingencies amounting to $400 mil lion. An estimate for contingencies is included in the budget totals each year as a matter of sound budgeting, to make allowance for probable future requests which may arise—including some relatively small amounts for present legislative proposals for which the timing of expenditures is uncertain. The Congress is not being asked to appropriate this item, but as needs arise, specific requests for funds will be made. I have a table here, chart III, which shows at a glance how the expenditures for protection, interest, and all other purposes in the fiscal year 1958 will compare with those for the current year. C h a rt III Budget comparison, 1951-58 1 [Fiscal years; in billions of dollars] New obligational authority 1957 Protection: Department of Defense: Military................................................................ Mutual security: Military................................................................ Economic..... ........—............................................ Atomic Energy Commission..................................... Other........................................................................... 1958 Expenditures 1957 1958 $36.4 $38.5 $36.0 2.0 1.8 2.0 .2 2.4 2.6 2.0 2.5 .4 $38.0 2.6 1.8 1.5 1.9 2.3 .6 .6 Total protection....................................................... Interest............................................................................... All other............................................................................. Contingency...................................................................... 42.4 7.3 20.6 .2 45.8 7.4 19.6 .5 42.7 7.3 18.8 .2 45.3 7.4 18.7 .4 Total......................................................................... 70.5 73.3 68.9 71.8 1 Estimate. N o t e — Detail for 1957 expenditures does not add to total because of rounding. The two columns on the right are for expenditures. The two on the left are for new obligational authority. You will see that the increase from 1957 to 1958 is concentrated in the programs for pro tection, most of it in the Department of Defense military functions. There are, of course, substantial increases in some civil activities and decreases in others. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 55 The rise of $2 billion for the Department of Defense results from several factors. One I have already mentioned—that we are in a transition stage where guided missiles and other new weapons are beginning to come into production but we must at the same time main tain our current readiness with more conventional weapons. Expendi tures for missiles are estimated to be $533 million higher while the total of all other expenditures for major procurement is the same. Another reason for the increase is that costs of maintenance and operation increase as our weapons systems become more complex. The newer planes take a lot more fuel and they are more costly to operate. Similarly, these more modern weapons require additional construction: for example, new launching sites, improved and dis persed airfields, warning networks for the continental defense system, and facilities in support of antisubmarine warfare and large aircraft carriers. Increases in expenditures from 1957 to 1958 are also esti mated for military personnel and for reserve forces, reflecting the growing number of trained specialists rather than an increase in total numbers of personnel. The “All other” item shown on the table includes both civil benefits and civil operations. The decrease estimated between 1957 and 1958 reflects the recommendation for adjustment of postal rates. We are actually recommending an adjustment of something over $600 million. An adjustment in rates was approved by the House of Representatives just before adjournment last summer, and I certainly hope that one will be approved by both Houses of Congress this session. An important new program of civil benefits which is recommended in the 1958 budget is the proposal for general assistance in school construction over a 4-year period. The budget includes recommended appropriations of $451 million and estimated expenditures of $185 million for this purpose in the fiscal year 1958. This was covered by the special message yesterday. Another new program which the President recommended again is the proposal to assist communities with persistent unemployment to expand economic opportunities. This involves appropriations of $53 million and expenditures of $10 million in 1958. The President has made several other legislative recommendations which are of interest to this committee. Many of these recommenda tions, such as improvements in antitrust and merger legislation, im provements in labor standards legislation, and broadening of unem ployment compensation coverage, either will not require additional budget expenditures or will require relatively small amounts which the allowance for contingencies should be more than adequate to cover. Thus, all the legislative proposals of the President which were made in the state of the Union message, the budget message, or the Economic Report are covered in the budget, either by specific amounts or by the general allowance for contingencies. Where we had a pretty detailed or a large program, it is included under the particular department headings. The general contingency allowance includes smaller proposals which had not been definitely defined. The budget also provided for a number of significant changes in existing programs. For example, there is an estimated increase of $108 million in the expenditures of the Civil Aeronautics Adminis tration, primarily for establishment and operation of improved air 56 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT traffic control facilities. That is looking toward the future greater use of jets, and the congestion in the air. Expenditures for public assistance grants are estimated to rise $100 million as a result of the amendments to the social-security legislation enacted last year. Re adjustment benefits for veterans are estimated to decrease $44 million, while compensation and pensions increase $107 million under existing legislation. The budget provides $100 million to cover the 1958 cost of possible proposals which the President may make in a special message dealing with our system of veterans benefits. While in creasing immediate costs, these improvements should, I hope, lead to long-run savings. Largely because of commitments previously made, expenditures for loans for college housing, for rural electrification and telephones, and for farm operation and ownership will rise. Carrying out previous commitments will also lead to an increase in expenditures by the Corps of Engineers and the Bureau of Rec lamation. Together, their expenditures are estimated to be $91 mil lion more than in 1957, of which $10 million is for the 1958 outlays on new projects to be started. c The National Park Service, which started its 10-year program of improvements this year, is budgeted to maintain the same rate of expenditures next year. Payments under the various conservation programs of the Depart ment of Agriculture are estimated to be $56 million more than in 1957. Most of the rise is for the soil bank and the Great Plains pro gram. Grants for construction of waste treatment works under legislation enacted last year will grow from 7 to 62 million dollars. Other ex penditures for the Public Health Service are estimated to increase $47 million, primarily for research. Another change in expenditures which should be mentioned in this quick review of the budget is that for interest. These expenditures are estimated to be $100 million more in 1958 than in 1957, reaching a total of $7.4 billion. This estimate does not reflect any further tightening of money, but simply the refinancing of maturing securities at present rates* RECEIPTS FROM A N D P A Y M E N T S TO T H E P U B L IC When I reviewed the budget totals earlier in this statement, I men tioned the highway trust fund. As this committee is aware, the flow of cash between the public and the Government is obtained by a consolidation of the transactions of the budget, the trust funds, and certain Government-sponsored (mixed-ownership) enterprises. This consolidation eliminates interfund transactions and such noncash transactions as accrued interest expenditures. Because of the interest of economists in the consolidated cash statement, I thought it might be helpful to summarize for you the major differences between the estimated budget surplus and the excess of cash receipts from the public for each of the fiscal years 1957 and 1958. In the fiscal year 1957, the budget surplus is estimated to be $1.7 billion and the trust fund accumulations are estimated at $2.4 billion. These two together amount to $4.1 billion, but the excess of cash receipts from the public over cash payments will be $3.5 billion. This ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 57 difference is due almost entirely to two factors. First, the anticipated payment in cash of $1 billion of Treasury notes held by the Inter national Monetary Fund and second, the partly offsetting difference between accrued interest and interest payments largely on series E bonds of $340 million. In the fiscal year 1958, the estimated budget surplus, $1.8 billion, is somewhat larger than for 1957 but the trust fund accumulations are estimated to be considerably smaller than in 1957—$1.5 billion. This is primarily due to the liberalization of social security enacted last year resulting in higher benefit payments without completely offsetting increases in receipts. The total of the budget surplus and the trust fund accumulations is again expected to be reduced by the net effects of accrued interest between the beginning and end of the year and of another payment on notes to the International Monetary Fund. In the fiscal year 1958, this redemption is estimated at $500 million. The United States subscription to the International Monetary Fund was made in the fiscal year 1947. Part of the subscription came from the exchange stabilization fund and part of it was a general fund expenditure which was then included in the budget. A large part of the subscription was in the form of non-interest-bearing notes, and did not involve substantial cash payments in the years up to 1956. The large estimated redemptions (and resulting cash payments) of $1 billion in 1957 and $500 million in 1958 are mainly because of the recent loan and cash advances which the fund made to the United Kingdom. It may be, of course, that the actual amount of loans will be less than these estimates. In such a case the excess of cash receipts from the public will be that much greater than estimated in the budget. I am sure that this committee is also interested in the expression of the 1958 budget figures in terms of the national income and product accounts. While the budget was being prepared and printed, the Bureau of the Budget made the various proofs available to national income experts in the Office of Business Economics of the Department of Commerce. It is my understanding that with this early start, the Department of Commerce was able to give this committee a translation of the budget figures into the Government sector of the national income and product accounts. PROSPECTS FOR T H E F U TU R E It is difficult to describe in a few words the many ways in which the specific recommendations in the budget may affect the economy in the budget year and the years ahead. However, I believe the budget as a whole will continue to be an influence for economic growth and reasonable price stability. Economic growth will be fostered through the recommended investments in transportation, conservation, health, and education and through the provision of credit for housing, agri culture, small business, and foreign trade. Price stability will be helped through the recommended continuation of a budget surplus. The budget will also foster economic stability through the recom mendations for safeguarding our citizens against economic and physi cal hazards. The committee has asked me to discuss the commitments extending beyond the fiscal year 1958 which are contemplated in the 1958 budget. 87624— 57------ 5 58 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT The gravest commitment for the future is the reasonable protection of this country against attack. Expenditures for protection must continue to be large, very large, until an agreement has been reached for reduction and regulation of armaments under safeguarded inspec tion guaranties. When that occurs, it should be possible to change the entire budget picture. In addition, there is some commitment, not necessarily binding, to complete various unfinished projects we have started. For example, we have started a 10-year program for the improvement of roads and facilities in our national parks and a 4-year program is proposed in this budget for assisting school construction. Other commitments are involved in natural resource projects which are already under way and in the limited number of projects for which starts are proposed in 1958. On the other hand, 38 natural-resource projects will be com pleted in 1958 and others, such as the St. Lawrence seaway, will be nearing completion. All of these commitments are not subject at this time to financial measurement. Perhaps, therefore, the best way to summarize our commitments for the future is to rexer only to budgetary commitments actually made, that is, to the balances of budget authorizations which will be available for expenditure after the fiscal year 1958. The total amount of authorizations carried forward at the end of the fiscal year 1956 was $72.9 billion. This included available balances of un expended appropriations, of authorizations to expend from public debt receipts, of contract authorizations, and of revolving ana man agement funds. It is estimated in the 1958 budget that by the end of 1957 the total available balances will have been reduced to $70 billion and that by the end of the fiscal year 1958 they will be $70.5 billion. In other words, the 1958 budget contemplates that the financial authorizations for future spending which will be available at the end of the fiscal year 1958 will be within $0.5 billion of those available at the end of the fiscal year 1957, and about $2 billion less than the amount available at the end of the fiscal year completed last June 30. The reduction since the end of the fiscal year 1953 will be $32.2 billion. This differs from the figures in the resume statement on page M4 of the budget as to the unexpected balances of appropriations carried forward, because it includes as well the unexpended balances of these other items of con tract authorizations, and authorizations to expend from debt receipts, and revolving and management funds. FEDERAL STATISTICAL. PROGRAMS One further point which the committee asked me to discuss con cerned the provisions in the budget for improving the Federal statis tical programs during the year. I am pleased to note the continuing interest of the committee in the adequacy of the Government’s statistical programs for the important purposes they serve. Recommendations for these programs are again set forth in a separate analysis in the 1958 budget^-special analysis J. As shown in this analysis, the budget includes estimates of $35.2 mil lion for principal current statistical programs in 1958, providing increases totaling about $3.4 million for specific programs. Among the recommended increases of particular interest to the Joint Economic Committee are provisions for improved monthly data ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 59 on manufacturers’ sales and inventories and for extension of the financial reports program to include trade and mining corporations, as recommended by the committee and its Subcommittee on Economic Statistics. Funds are also recommended to enable the Internal Reve nue Service to prepare preliminary tabulations of key financial item^ in the income tax returns, so that these important business indicators may be available a year earlier than at present to give a firmer current basis to the national accounts. Other recommended programs of direct interest to the Joint Economic Committee are improvement of the work on price indexes and foreign-trade statistics, expansion of the production economics program of the Department of Agriculture to provide economic data needed for the development and appraisal of farm programs, a study of the effects of tariff changes on employment, and publication of a new edition of the National Income Supplement. There are, however, a number of major steps yet to be taken to reach the goal of a better integrated Federal statistical system. In its work on programing the Government’s statistical activities, the Bureau?s Office of Statistical Standards, of which Ray Bowman is the head> is at present working on development of the most efficient programs pos sible to meet recognized needs for better statistics in several different areas. For example, a comprehensive review is being given to con struction statistics, directed toward reformulating a program to meet the needs for more accurate and more detailed data on this important segment of the economy. This is something that the Council of Economic Advisers was particularly interested in our doing, also. Similarly, the Bureau of the Budget has contracted with the National Buerau of Economic Research for an independent appraisal of the national income and product accounts, directed primarily (1) at deter mining specific needs for improvement in the underlying statistical series, and (2) at means of bringing about future integration of these accounts with other comprehensive national accounting systems, such as the Federal Reserve work on the flow of funds. Study is also being made of the requirements for improved measures of labor productiv ity, and of means of meeting these requirements. Although projects like these are not reflected in the 1958 budget, they may be of interest to this committee as evidence of our work toward an improved statis tical system. Mr. M ills . Does that complete your statement, Mr. Brundage ? Mr. B rundage . Yes; it does. Mr. M ills . Mr. Curtis of Missouri will inquire. Mr. C u rtis . I would like to first find out what figures you have on our carryover of unexpended funds as well as unobligated funds. I notice from your chart on page 4 you show us the new obligational authority and the expenditures, but what about carryover of unspent funds as well as unspent and unobligated funds ? Mr. B rundage . Well, the appropriations carried forward are in cluded in the resume of the budget. I do not know whether I brought that chart along. I f you have the budget document there, it is contained in that report. Mr. C urtis . I have it here; yes. Mr. B rundage . That will give you the whole story. I might say roughly that the amount of unspent and unobligated appropriations of the Department of Defense is slightly over $10 billion. That is the biggest item. 60 ECONOMIC EEPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Mr. C u r t i s . That is $10 billion? Mr. B r u n d a g e . It is a little more. It is estimated to be 10.6 billion at the start of the fiscal year 1958. Mr. C u r t i s . N o w let me ask you this: As I recall, and I am going by memory, the unspent funds—and you mean by that, the unobli gated ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . The unspent and unobligated funds. The total estimated unspent balances of appropriations of the Department are about $38 billion at the start of 1958. Mr. C u r t i s . The total funds that would be possibly obligated, but unspent? Mr. B r u n d a g e . Yes; they could obligate another $10 billion. The difference between that and the $38 billion is obligated but unspent. Mr. C u r t i s . A s I recall, that figure of unspent but possibly obli gated funds for the entire Government was over $90 billion in 1953. Do you recall what that carryover is? I am interested in seeing how we have been doing as far as knocking down on these charge accounts that we have. Mr. B r u n d a g e . The full detail is shown on table 7, on page A12. That only goes back to 1956, but I think that you are right. The total obligational authority carried over was over $100 billion at the end of fiscal 1953. It was $94 billion at the end of the fiscal year 1954 and is estimated to be down to $70 billion in 1958. I can submit details for the record. (The material referred to follows:) Balances carried forward, by type of authority , at end of year , fiscal years 1954 through 1958 In millions] Appropri ations Authori zations to expend from debt receipts Fiscal year 1954 (actual): Obligated.................... Unobligated................. . $42,808 24,943 $6,275 14,842 $1,064 1,413 i $1,209 4,107 $48,938 45,305 Contract authori zations Revolving and man agement funds Total Total......................... . 67,751 21,117 2,477 2,898 94,243 Fiscal year 1955 (actual): Obligated..................... . Unobligated................. . 31,773 20,322 4,798 14,765 1,175 1,412 77 5,316 37,823 41,815 Total.......................... 52,095 19,563 2,587 5,393 79,638 Fiscal year 1956 (actual): Obligated..................... Unobligated................. . 31,318 14,650 4,359 13,893 1,321 2,720 404 4,234 37,402 35,497 Total......................... . 45,968 18,252 4,041 4,638 72,899 Fiscal year 1957 (estimate) : Obligated. .................... Unobligated....... .......... 234,374 11,971 5,122 13,428 295 750 459 3,562 40,250 29,711 Total.......................... 46,345 18,550 1,045 4,021 69,961 Fiscal year 1958 (estimate): Obligated-----------------Unobligated................. 238,110 9,178 5,683 12,060 658 659 632 3,543 45,083 25,440 Total______________ 47,288 17,743 1,317 4,175 70,523 l Deduct, excess of receivables over obligations. a Includes allowances for contingencies: 1957, $50 million; 1958, $150 million. Jan. 25,1957. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 61 Mr. C u r t i s . Then looking at the budget, we have to look at the carryover of previous obligations, plus the new obligational authority in order to get a picture, plus our anticipated expenditures, in order to get a real picture of what the Congress might be doing in the way o f additional appropriations. Do you understand what I mean ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . Yes. Mr. C u r t i s . That is whether the appropriation is a new one, or whether it is simply a carried over appropriation, it still remains as a possible expenditure of this administration. Mr. B r u n d a g e . That is right. Mr. C u r t i s . S o what are our expenditures based upon then ? Your proposed expenditures in 1957 and 1958 ? Even if you have as much as $36 billion carryover, and another $70 billion additional obligational authority, making a total of $106 billion, and your estimated expendi tures are $68.9 billion. Mr. B r u n d a g e . The other page I gave you, A6, gives the total of budget authorizations available as $143 billion. Mr. C u r t i s . Now, I-----Mr. B r u n d a g e . I might say that a good deal of the current opera tions, expenditures and payrolls, comes out of current authorizations. It is more the deliveries of procurement and construction items and so on that are made out of prior authorizations and obligational authority. Mr. C u r t i s . Do you have any figures to show any expired obliga tions? That is, expired without expenditure and about what rate are they going? Mr. B r u n d a g e . On page A6, that was fairly substantial in the cur rent year, in 1957, because of the transfer of the Federal aid highway authorizations to the trust fund. But the total was a little over $5 bil lion. O f that, $3.1 billion was the highway fund. In 1958 we are Burning a termination of a little less than $1 billion, or $973 Mr. C u r t i s . H o w has that been running over the past few years, say the past 4 years ? That is the unexpired without being utilized obliga tions. Mr. B r u n d a g e . $3.6 billion in 1956. Mr. C u r t i s . I have that figure for 1956, but I was wondering about the other years. You said mat was a little unusual. Mr. B r u n d a g e . It was 1957 that was unusual. Mr. C u r t i s . I am thinking of going back to 1953, 1954, and 1955 to get a picture of what happens to these obligated funds that never actually get spent. Mr. B r u n d a g e . There is quite a little variation between years. I do not have the figures back of 1956. I will be glad to supply those for the record. Mr. C u r t i s . I would like to get that. (The material referred to follows:) Budget authorizations ceasing to be available Fiscal years: 195 3 $2,523 195 4 195 5 195 6 A m ount (in m illions} _ 4,279 3,656 62 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Mr. C u r t i s . N o w , do you have any figures showing the deobligated funds which get reobligated without coming back to Congress ? There is such a process, I know. It is deobligated for a particular thing. Let me illustrate: As I believe your budgetary procedures recognize, there can be a letter of intent to obligate, and that is considered an obligation. Now, a letter of intent is certainly not a firm contract, and after the magic date of June 30 passes these letters of intent get rewritten, or there is a contract that sometimes has little relation to the letter of intent that obligated the funds. That process has been called a deobliga tion and then a reobligation. I was wondering whether your depart ment followed that. Mr. B r u n d a g e . I don’t think that we distinguish that. Mr. C u r t i s . Would you know how much deobligating goes on, and then reobligating afterward, instead of allowing the authorization to expire or the appropriation to expire? Mr. B r u n d a g e . I don’t know. Mr. McCandless may be able to answer that. I don’t think that we distinguish that. M r . M c C a n d l e s s . We do follow that during the course of the year. Where it is significant, I think we have it identified back in the budget and that would be in the detailed part of the budget. It is largely in the Department of Defense where those things occur. Mr. C u r t i s . That is where most of this occurs. M r . M c C a n d l e s s . We d o t r y t o keep up w i t h i t . Mr. C u r t i s . Could you supply for this committee an annual figure going back 4 or 5 years as to the total amount of deobligation and reobligation ? Mr. M c C a n d l e s s . I am not sure that we could because we have only been identifying it, as I recall, in the last 2 or 3 years, and then only where it is a significant amount of money. We could pick out of put together for you what we have, of what we can identify, but the accounting system has only started picking that up in the last couple of years. M r. C u r t i s . I suggest if you went into it a little more thoroughly, you might find some real areas where considerable sums of money might be relooked at an area which the Congress really has never looked at, and I doubt if the Bureau of the Budget has ever really looked at it. There is a question of a deobligation, and then a re obligation. That always involves the point of whether the new program is really sufficiently similar to the original obligation to justify the new obli gation. Mr. B r u n d a g e . We look at all new requests for obligational au thority pretty carefully, whether it is a reobligation or a brand new one. Mr. C u r t i s . Do you ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . Yes, sir; those that come to us. Mr. C u r t i s . I would think then you would be able to get those figures and show what the total size is. We could confine it to the Defense Department, because that is what I am particularly inter ested in. 63 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT (The material referred to follows:) “Deobligation” and “reobligation” of funds are shown in the 1958 budget to the extent that (1) they have a material effect on the program, and (2) the accounting and reporting systems have thus far made such figures available. They are shown in the detailed schedules of part II (for budget funds) and part III (for trust funds) of the budget document under the heading “ Recovery of Prior Year Obligations.” A detailed listing of these items is given below. Since the accounting and reporting system of the Department of Defense does not provide most of the amounts in question, figures are shown for only five accounts in the Department. If further information is desired, a special effort on the part of the Department of Defense would have to be made to develop estimates for other accounts. There is no question, however, but that the amounts involved are much larger than the amounts shown in the following table: Items listed in "budget schedules under the heading “ Recovery o f prior year obligations” in 1958 budget 1957 1958 BUDGET FUNDS Legislative branch: Library of Congress: General increase of the Library of Congress................. Increase of the law library, Library of Congress.......... Funds appropriated to the President: Mutual security: Military assistance, Executive...... ................................ Other programs............................................................... Foreign currency............................................................ President’s special international program...... ................... . Expansion of defense production, investment in................ Independent offices: Atomic Energy Commission: Plant acquisition and con struction__________ _______________________ ____ ___ Commission on Organization of the Executive Branch of the Government: Salaries ani expenses ________ U. S. Information Agency: Salaries and expenses.............. Export-Import Bank of Washington fund......................... . Farm Credit Administration.................. ................... ...... Federal Farm Mortgage Corporation, investment in_. Federal intermediate credit banks................................ Revolving funds_________ ______ _________________ Small Business Administration, revolving fund............ General Services Administration: Repair and improvement of federally owned buildings___ U. S. courthouse and post office, Nome, Alaska................ Strategic and critical materials.......................................... . Housing and Home Finance Agency: Office of the Administrator: Investment in college housing loans.............................. Investment in public facility loans................................ Investment in urban renewal......... ............................... Capital grants for slum clearance.................................. Federal National Mortgage Association: Special assistance functions fu n d .............. ................... Management and liquidating functions fund............... Department of Agriculture: Research facilities, A R S..................................................... . Miscellaneous accounts, Forest Service..... .......................... FI >od prevention, S^il Conservation Service....... .............. Agricultural Conservation program. ...................... .......... Loans: R E A ______ ________________ ___________ ______ Farmers’ Home Administration: Disaster loans, etc., re volving fund____ ______________________ ___________ Removal of surplus agricultural commodities...... .............. : Commodity Credit Corporation_____ _____ ________ ____ Advances and reimbursements, Commodity Stabiliza tion Service........................................................................ Department of Commerce: Grants-in-aid for airports, C AA ........................................... Miscellaneous accounts, CAA_.___................................... Payments to air carriers, C A B .................................. ......... Ship construction (liquidation of contract authorization), Maritime activities............................................................. Inland Waterways Corporation fund.................................. $125,000,000 76,298 110,322,297 $67,822,000 15,201.000 53,992,744 56,240,895 30,000 2,700,000 30,000 10,135,000 11.360.000 6,500,000 755.000 1,160,600 58.846.000 250.000 650.000 1,546,550 80,334,100 400.000 580.000 944,507 25,464,000 2, 000,000 2, 000,000 5,000,000 5,000,000 9,596,224 100,660 166,660 64 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Items listed in "budget schedules under the heading **Recovery o f prior year obligations ” in 1958 budget—Continued 1956 b u d g e t funds— continued Department of Defense— Military functions: Shipbuilding and conversion, N a v y ... _ _ Construction of ships, N avy____________ ______________ Ordnance for new construction (liquidation of contract authorization), Navy________ ____ ___________ ______ Navy managp.mp.nt. fund Advances and reimbursements, Army_____ ____ ________ Department of Defense—Civil functions: Construction, general, Corps of Engineers.......................... U .S . Soldiers’ Home. ____ __________ _______________ Capital outlay, Canal Zone Government_______________ Department of Health, Education, and Welfare: Assistance for school construction, Office of Education___ Advances and reimbursemente, Office of the Secretary___ Department of the Interior: Miscellaneous accounts, Bureau of Indian Affairs________ Construction and rehabilitation, Bureau of Reclamation. _ Department of Labor: Advances and reimbursements: Bureau of Labor Sta tistics...___________________________________________ Department of State: International commissions: Restoration of Salmon Runs, Fraser River system, International Salmon Fisheries Commission________________________________________ Educational exchange: Educational aid for China and Korea__ ________________________________________-Treasury Department: Bureau of Accounts: Claims, judgments, and private re lief acts ___________________________________________ Office of the Secretary: Miscellaneous permanents_______ 1957 $9,593,208 629,993 1958 $7,440,000 365,774 139,602 46,375 5,201 7,443 681,132 5,233,606 200,231 76 1,936 253,003 41,000 680 73,470 22,314 9.341 2,057 27,105 TRUST FUNDS Gift and trust fund income accounts, Library of Congress....... Foreign currency, funds appropriated to the President_______ War claims, Foreign Claims Settlement Commission________ Railroad retirement account_______________________________ Railroad unemployment insurance administration fund. R R B . American National Red Cross. District of Columbia chapter building, public buildings, GSA __ ___________________ Advances for supplies and expenses, United Nations Korean Reconstruction Agency, GSA. _________________________ Other trust funds, GSA - . __ ______________ Defense-Civil: Trust funds, rivers and harbors and flood control _ _ ____________________________ Interior: Reclamation trust funds __ __________ Labor: Special statistical work __ ___________________ State: Trust funds, Educational exchange _____ District of Columbia: Grants by Public Health Service.......... 5.342 373,764 2,494 151,271 14,385 126 95,748 3,989 22,022 20 70 1,530 171 Mr. C u r t i s . N o w there is one other item, and I wanted to find out whether the Bureau of the Budget goes into this: Have you been following the amount of surplus property that the Military Establishment generates each year ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . We surely have. Mr. C u r t i s . I have received some hurried figures from some people who know about this and the indication is that it runs as much as 3 or 4 billion dollars a year in surplus properties generated by the Military Establishment. I think that we are averaging about 8 cents on the dollar in the sale of these surpluses. Would you know whether that estimate is within reason ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . That is both in supplies, materials, and equipment, and in buildings and in lands. It is handled separately, but the sur plus covers all of those areas. We have a special unit in the Bureau of the Budget that is following that. That amount is a little high. It is a very substantial figure, however. Mr. C u r t i s . I am giving it as an annual figure, and apparently a recurring one. I have gone through some of the details in the lists 65 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT of surplus goods that are made available, and a great deal of it is what we call common-use items—paper, paint, pencils, typewriters, flashlight batteries, and so on. It would immediately suggest to me, of course, if these amounts are that vast, that there might be something wrong in the procurement practices in the beginning that would create such an unused surplus. Mr. B r u n d a g e . Both procurement practices and inventory controls, and we have been working on that very assiduously. I think it is being improved all the time. Much of the surplus now being de clared reflects the efforts to clear out obsolete equipment and to dis pose of stocks carried over from the past. Mr. C u r t i s . I would like to get, if you can give it to me, what figures you do have on the amount of surpluses that are being gen erated, with particular emphasis on the common-use item field. I would also be interested in the general figure. Mr. B r u n d a g e . We will get you those figures. The surplus items are made available, of course, to the schools and to the States and to various purposes. Some of them have very little net return. Mr. C u r t t s . I would be interested in checking the figure that I estimated, about 8 cents to the dollar is what we get on this. (The material referred to follow :) Available reports do not give data on common-use items separately. General Services Administration reports on surplus disposal show the following: Analysis o f surplus personal property disposal other than scrap , Department of Defense [Fiscal years; in millions of dollars] 1954 1955 1956 Total acquisition cost of surplus property disposals, other than scrap i____________ ____________________ $1,273 $1,578 $1,497 Method of disposition: Abandoned or destroyed...................................................... Donated_____________________________________________ Sales other than scrap__________________ _______ _______ 25 64 1,184 53 118 1,407 55 159 1,283 Proceeds from sales other than scrap.......................................... 67 103 96 Percent proceeds to acquisition cost of property sold.................. 5.7 7.0 7.5 i In addition to the amounts shown, acquisition costs of excess property transferred to other Federal agencies was $53 million in 1954, $109 million in 1955, and $70 million in 1956. Receipts from sale of scrap were $17 million in 1954, $40 million in 1955, and $57 million in 1956. Acquisition cost of items scrapped is not reported. Mr. C u r t i s . I a m curious to know if the Bureau of the Budget has at all followed the progress in the Military Establishment on their unification of some of their services in the field of what might be termed common-use items. To illustrate, the unification of medical supply of procurement and distribution. Have you followed that at all? Mr. B r u n d a g e . Yes. It is going a lot slower than we would like to see it. However, I think it is making some progress. Mr. C u r t i s . Sometimes it is difficult to see the progress. Mr. B r u n d a g e . Yes. Mr. C u r t i s . D o you know whether the Military Establishment h a s carried over the example in medical supplies to other areas where 66 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT there could be the same formula of unification in procurement and distribution ? Has the Bureau taken any interest in that ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . Unification has not been carried nearly far enough. I would like to see it go further. Mr. C u k t i s . The Congress very specifically wrote laws, the O ’Mahoney amendment in particular, requiring that to be done. There are some of us, and I might say I am among them, who feel that the Military Establishment has not been complying with that law. There are various areas of savings where we could actually get better defense as a result if they would go through these processes. To illustrate, I do not believe anything has been done in the Chap lains Corps in the way of procurement and supply. It is a little thing, but it is an example. The main questions which I am directing to you is whether the Bureau of the Budget in reviewing these requests of the Military Establishment for additional appropriations has asked them these questions and gone into the matter to see what progress they are making. Mr. B r u n d a g e . Yes, we have. It is under study, but it is awfully hard to get it out of the study stage into the action stage. Mr. C u r t i s . I agree with you on that. I have a general question prepared that I would like an answer to. There is a widespread concern about the size of the Federal budget for fiscal year 1958, particularly with respect to its implications fo r : (1) the extent of the Government’s participation in total economic activity; and (2) the possible inflationary consequences of expending budget expenditures; and (3) the prospects for tax reduction. One or more of these aspects has been referred to in the statements made by the President, Secretary Humphrey, and by you, since the presentation of the budget. The Congress has been invited by all three of you to reduce proposed expenditures. A t the same time, the Con gress must assume that the executive branch has done the best job it could in keeping proposed budget expenditures to a minimum. In view of that assumption, what specific, as well as general, stand ards would you recommend the Congress use in acting upon the budget expenditure recommendations, and m what respect do these standards differ from those employed by the executive branch in preparing the budget? Mr. B r u n d a g e . That is quite a big question. I will say that the Secretary and I have been pursuing this prob lem of economy very aggressively and persistently, not only this last year, but ever since we have been down here. The problems which have met us are the demands of the people and the Congress for a number of good programs. There is no question about the pro grams. We all recognize the needs of defense. As you see here, the big increase this year is in the protection cate gory. We are expanding our defense partly because of world con ditions and partly because of the cost of replacing the older weapons, and while the newer weapons are so much more effective they are so much more expensive. The B-29 bombers, for instance, cost on the average of a little over $600,000 and the B-36 cost an average of $4 million, and the B-52, $8 million. That is just an example. There is a tremendous amount of research and development. We are spending over $5 billion in the military in the whole area of re- ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 67 search and development, including procurement of weapons that are used for experimental purposes besides those added to stock, and for all personnel in development and testing. Then, atomic energy, as you see, is going up from $1.9 billion to $2.3 billion in expenditures and from $2 billion to $2:5 billion in new obligational authority—that is practically all either research and de velopment, or in the general defensive area. We have a program, as you know, for peacetime uses of atomic energy. There is a lot of research and development going into re-! actors, but the actual amount of fissionable material which is being handed out is still pretty small. Miv C u r t i s . Could I say this in the light of your answer to my previous questions regarding some of these problems on military pro curement and supply: When you said you were still conducting studies in that area to see what could be done, would I be right in saying that in these areas where you still are studying but have not reached conclusions, that might be the areas that the Congress could possibly pick up an<i’ carry the studies further to try to reach some conclusions ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . Well, I will welcome any cuts that you can mak«£ without sacrificing our protection or the needed services. You may remember in our budget message that we called atten tion to the fact that we had these terrific competitions and pressures and inflationary pressures, and we were asking all of the departments' and agencies to limit their construction expenditures particularly, and also their personnel increases, even though they are provided for in the budget. This budget does not start to be spent for another 6 months, and then it will not be finished for 18 months, and we firmly believe that reductions and savings can be made. Mr. C u r t i s . Mr. Brundage, the question I would like to ask that refers to this basic point I am presenting is this: Do you believe that the Government participation in our total economic activity for the size of $68.9 billion in 1957, and 1958 is $71.8 billion—Do you believe that that participation is going to create sucli inflationary forces that probably we will not be able to control them ? While that is my tentative conviction now, I would like to have you comment on a positive statement. I f we spend $68.9 billion in our present economic development, it seems to me whether the budget is balanced or not we are going to create such inflationary forces that we will be hard put to controlling it. Mr. B r u n d a g e . I think any increase in spending is an added infla tionary force. You cannot deny that. However, as long as you have a budget surplus, and some retirement of debt, it seems to me that it U not too serious. After all, if we had a tax reduction, which was all used by the iridir yiduals to increase their consumption of consumer goods, and increase their purchases of consumer goods, you would have just as much of an inflationary aspect, only in a different area. ! Mr, C u r t i s . I agree with you, but suppose the tax reduction were in suc^i a way that the money, instead of going into consumer credit, went into investment. You would have the opposite, would you not ? Mi*. B r u n d a g e . That would be savings; yes. Mr. O ufcTis. Actually, is not that where the pinch seems to be, in t ^ investments dollar right now, rather than in the consumer dollar? 68 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Mr. B r u n d a g e . Well, there is a tremendous shortage of investment funds, there is no question about that. Mr. C u r t i s . Which usually means that there is more consumer de mand than there is ability to produce to satisfy it. That means usually that there is not enough investment in plant and facilities to produce to meet the consumer demand. Mr. B r u n d a g e . We are helping that by our retirement of public debt this year, of $2.2 billion. That will go to retire debt and make that much more available for other investments. Mr. C u r t i s . Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. M i l l s . Senator O ’Mahoney will inquire. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I was involved with another matter and so I have been delayed in getting here, and I am sorry I did not have an opportunity to listen to your opening statement, Mr. Brundage. I have hastily glanced over it and it immediately suggests some, I think, important questions. I would like to call your attention to page 5 of your statement. There in the second paragraph from the end, the second sentence says: Many of these recommendations, such as improvements in antitrust and merger legislation, improvements in labor standards legislation, and broadening of un employment compensation coverage— That aroused my completely sympathetic interest. I know the anti trust and merger legislation which has been pending before the Judi ciary Committee, of which I am a member, and of which last year I was the acting chairman of the Subcommittee on Antitrust and Monopoly. The Department is in full agreement with the enactment of legis lation, and I am happy to have the President endorse this. But I know that the Department of Justice does not begin to have the jmoney that will enable them to carry out the President’s program when and if we pass this law. As a matter of fact, they do not have money enough now to review the cases which are presented. All you have to do is look at the business section of the newspapers for the past year to read about merger after merger which are concentrating our national economic system and making it impossible for people in the States, and businessmen in the States and in the local communi ties to carry on as they should. That is one of the reasons the Presi dent wants the antimerger bill passed. It is a prenotification bill, to call upon corporations which are planning to merge, to notify the Federal Trade Commission and the Department of Justice in advance so that those two Commissions could determine whether or not the mergers were in violation of law, and in the public interest. In the conversation I had with the Department last year, I learned they wanted and needed at least 100 more lawyers to do the research. I can cite to you the research which your Bureau requires as an illus tration of the necessity for supplying the Department of Justice with sufficient staff to look into these most complex matters. Your budget does grant an increase to the Federal Trade Commis sion, but you ask less for the Antitrust Division this year than you gave them last year. That is less than Congress gave them last year. This I suggest is not in harmony with the President’s message. Mr. B rundage . We gave them all they asked for, Senator O’Mahoney. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 69 Senator O ’M a h o n e y . Would you look into that again, please? Mr. B r u n d a g e . There is a new man, and they had been preparing some further estimates which I believe they would like to have sub mitted as a supplemental. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . Let me say a word in support of the supple mental estimates because I think it is in the public interest. Mr. B r u n d a g e . The appropriations of Antitrust Division, accord ing to the table on page 806 of the budget, went up from $3,464,000 in 1956, to $3,569,000 in 1957, and $3,785,000 in 1958, and I think that they have some further requests under consideration. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I do not know from what you are reading, but I read the release that you gave out. I do not have it with me at this time. When the budget was coming up, and the appropriation for the Antitrust Division was mentioned, the request was less for 1958 than the appropriation was for 1957. Mr. B r u n d a g e . That is not correct. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I f I am mistaken in that, I will check it up and see that the record is corrected. Mr. B r u n d a g e . The figure is on page 806 of the budget document for 1957. The new authorization for 1956 was $3,464,000, and for 1957 it was $3,569,000. For 1958 it is $3,785,000, and the expenditure for 1956 was $3,545,000, and for 1957, $3,625,000, and for 1958, $3,774,000. As I say, I think that they have some further requests to make. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . They have supplemental requests ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . Yes; that is right. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . Of course, we all know that Congress itself is struggling with the problem of the increased payment for retire ment. We have to pay 6y2 percent now for the staffs of the various committees, whereas it was much less than that a year ago. I suspect that some of the increase of which you speak there has to do not with the number of persons on the staff but with the increased costs of administration. Mr. B rundage . That has been distributed among all of the branches and agencies of the departments. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . Would you be good enough to check up on that personnel item ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . I will be glad to. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . And particularly with respect to increasing the supplemental. Mr. B r u n d a g e . We did not cut their request, however, Senator. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I am glad to have you make that a part o f the record and I will accept that statement as coming from an authori tative source. But I want to point out this further fact, that the Antitrust Division in the past when diligently and effectively adminisered has been a source of revenue to the Government. The Antitrust Division under Thurman Arnold, and I mention him because he comes from my State, earned for the Government in fines and costs from violators of the antitrust law more than the appropria tion for the Division usually amounted to. That is right if my recol lection is correct. A ll of these questions that I am asking now arise from my knowledge that some expenditures are productive of revenue. Some expendi tures are completely lost. The money that is spent on shooting instru 70 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT m ents produce no revenue at all. They win victories and eventually the peace, we hope. For years we have had a very uncertain peace, but in the domestic field we have many projects which would produce revenue for the Government and for the people and improve their living standards. Some of these are included in the discussion on page 6 of your state ment. That is : Carrying out previous commitments will also lead to an increase in expendi tures by the Corps of Engineers and the Bureau of Reclamation. Together, their expenditures are estimated to be $91 million more than in 1957, of which $10 million is for the 1958 outlays on new projects to be started. The President has just completed an airplane tour over the droughtstricken States so that he and all the country knows the great damage that was done by the drought and is being done. It is cutting off revenue and the earnings of the people in those areas. For many years we have struggled, we who live in the upper Colo rado River Basin, to secure the authorization of improvements in that system and in the construction of dams to store the water and to pre vent floods. Finally, last year, Congress passed the bill which the President signed, authorizing the improvement of this upper Colorado River Basin at an estimated cost of about $753 million. The President opened that project by pushing a button sometime last October. He was sitting in Washington and a blast was set off in Utah, I believe. It was very helpful and it gave notice that the project was going to begin. But the appropriation which you allowed is so small that it will take 32 years to complete that project. In the meantime, the water which rises in the upper basin States will be flowing past the doors of the people up there and down into the lower basin and ulti mately into the sea. I wrote a letter to the Secretary of the Interior at the time of this opening and urged the Secretary of the Interior to see if it would not be possible to have a statement made at the ceremonial opening that the Bureau of the Budget would not be permitted to place a ceiling upon the development of the Colorado River Basin. The ceiling, how ever, is here. I think the total appropriation is so small that in my State on several of the projects which are very essential for the people living there, the planning will not be finished until 1960 or 1962. Mr. B r u n d a g e . For the first years expenditures, they are always small, Senator, you know because of the planning. Assistant Director Merriam here has this under his direct surveillance. Can you comment on that, Mr. Merriam ? Senator O ’M ah on ey . I know that. W hat I am saying to you is this: The more haste you can put into this thing the sooner you will be improving the conditions of the people who live in that basin and the sooner you will be increasing their capacity to pay income taxes on which you depend for the balancing of the budget, M r . "M e r r t a m . As you know, of course, the President has from the start pushed very vigorously for this project and certainly the admin istration is in complete agreement with what you have said. Are you talking about the participating projects now, or the actual dams? Senator O ’M ahoney. Some of them are participating projects. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 71 Mr. M e r r i a m . As you unquestionably know, as far as the participat ing projects are concerned, the President did ask the Department of Agriculture in conjunction with the Department of the Interior to take a relook at exactly how those projects were being developed. There has been, quite correctly as you have stated, some delay in the participating projects, but not in the dams themselves which are going ahead at what we and the Department think is an economic rate. There is no ceiling. I think that ought to be clear. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I want to get your sympathy for this thing and I am not criticizing. M r. M e r r ia m . Y ou h a v e it. Y o u d o n o t h a v e t o g e t it . Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I am asking you to take note of the fact that you say in this paragraph that I have just read, that these expendi tures for the Corps of Engineers to stop floods which clearly destroy the property and the income of the people and the Bureau of Recla mation which build new homes and new farms will be increased. You say it is increased by $91 million. But four paragraphs down in your statement you say, “With respect to the interest on the national debt, these expenditures are estimated to be $100 million more in 1958 than in 1957.” In other words, your presentation to us relates the sad fact that we have to increase the amount expended for interest on the national debt by $9 million more than you are increasing expenditures to prevent disaster here at home and to build constructive waterways for the benefit of the people of the United States. I think you must bear in mind that statement in your further con sideration of supplemental estimates. Mr. B r u n d a g e . I would like to say that we are spending something over $1 billion on these projects altogether including flood control and development. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . Let us see where you show them on the charts. Here is chart No. 2, “ Protection”—that is a good name to give that column—is $45.3 billion. “ Civil benefits” is $16.9 billion. Interest, and that is interest on the national debt, is $7.4 billion. “ Civil opera tions” is $1.8 billion. Now, I seriously believe that if the Bureau of the Budget will give some attention to increasing expenditures on civil operations whereby we will develop our natural resources more rapidly than they are being developed and increase the capacity of the people to produce, you will be doing more toward balancing the budget than by follow ing the policy which pays more for interest on the national debt and more for foreign aid. There is now $200 million that is now proposed to be expended without a single standard in the Middle East. You can produce a good deal more in the United States. You can produce oil in the United States. Mr. B r u n d a g e . The civil operations to which you refer is confined to administrative and maintenance operations of the Government. Many of the expenditures for conservation projects are included with the civil benefit programs. “ Special analysis ( L ) ” on pages 1149 and 1150 shows that the programs for conservation and development of land and water resources will be $1,070 million, in 1958, as against $940 million in 1957 and $803 million in 1956. 72 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Senator O ’M a h o n e y . Where is this ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . This is on page 1150 in the back of the book, the very last page. That is under “ Natural resources.” Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I have the document before me. That is the conservation and development of land and water resources. That has been estimated for 1958 at $1,070 million. That is what you stated? Mr. B r u n d a g e . Yes, sir. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . But that does not change at all the comparison which you made in your statement. The interest on the national debt is increasing by $9 million more than the increase on the Corps of Engineers and the Bureau of Reclamation expenditures. There is not any doubt about that for you wrote it. Mr. B r u n d a g e . That is not taking all of it. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . D o you wish to correct the statement? Mr. B r u n d a g e . N o ; there are other programs besides the Corps of Engineers and the Bureau of Reclamation. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . O f course, that is true. But can you give me the total for those ? Where are they broken down in your statement? Mr. B r u n d a g e . They are all shown in the budget. I will be glad to give you a table on it. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . Would you please put it in the record here at this point? M r . B r u n d a g e . I w i l l b e g l a d to . (The information is as follows:) Expenditures for land and water resources included in natural resources function of the budget [Fiscal years; in millions of dollars] Agency 1956 actual Corps of Engineers, civil functions............................. ................ Department of the Interior: Bonneville Power Administration........... ........... ................ Southeastern Power Administration.................................... Southwestern Power Administration..................... ............ Bureau of Indian Affairs....................................................... Bureau oi Land Management................................. ............ Office of Saline Water........ .................................................. St. Lawrence Seaway Development Cooperation----------- -----Tennessee Valley Authority------ ------ - ............................- ........ Department of State (international boundary commissions)— Federal Power Commission......................................................... Total.................................................................................... 1957 estimate 1958 estimate $534 $600 $660 161 35 174 32 204 35 7 40 19 45 25 7 49 28 3 5 39 3 7 5 46 27 5 803 940 1,070 1 1 9 -10 2 8 1 2 1 6 N ote .— D etail m ay not add precisely to totals because of rounding. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . Y ou show a surplus on chart No. 1. That is, a surplus for 1956, 1957, and 1958. You discuss this on page 2 of your statement. The recommended budget for 1958 is balanced. This will be the third succes sive budget with a surplus. The actual surplus for the fiscal year 1956, which ended last June 30, was $1.6 billion. The current estimate for the fiscal year 1957, which is now at its midpoint, is that the surplus will be slightly higher, $1.7 billion. The estimates for 1958 show a surplus of $1.8 billion, based on the continuation of current tax rates. Is it not a fact that during this period the debt has been increasing? Mr. B r u n d a g e . N o . Senator O ’M a h o n e y . What is the national debt now? ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 73 Mr. B rundage . It is down. The details are shown in the budget. That is on page M-10, right in the beginning. The public debt at the start of the year 1956 was $274.4 billion. At the end of 1956 it was $272.8 billion. At the end of 1957 it is estimated to be $270.6 billion. At the end of 1958 it is estimated to be $269.2 billion. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I have in my hands the Economic Indicators for January of 1957. It was prepared for this committee by the Council of Economic Advisers. Mr. B rundage . I have it here. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . On page 31 on the last column you will find the heading “ Public Debt, End of Period.” Mr. B rundage . That is the end of the first 5 months. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I beg your pardon. We begin at the top, under “ Public Debt, End of Period.” That is fiscal year 1944, it was $202.6 billion. In 1947, $258.4 billion. Fiscal 1948, $252.4 billion, a reduction. In 1949 it was 252.8. In 1950,257.4. 1951,255.3. In 1952, 259.2. In 1953,266.1. 1954,271.3. In 1955,274.4. During this period, which includes, I think, part of the period for which you are claiming a surplus, the debt was increasing. In 1956 it went down to 271.5. In October of 1955 it was estimated to have risen to 279.9. Now, this was about the time that Congress began to pass resolutions allowing special increases in the hope that the collections might be sufficient to increase the receipts and thereby balance the budget. Mr. B rundage . That is right. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . N ow it appears that the fiscal condition of the Government is such that we are constantly increasing the rate of interest upon the debt. That is right, is it not ? Mr. B rundage . The interest has been going up because money rates have been going up. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . The New York Times for yesterday morning in its business section published, as it always does on Monday, the total of Treasury securities which must be met within the ensuing calendar year. This morning, as I recall the figures, it was about $77.6 billion and that was greater than it was a year ago and greater than it was a week ago. On these securities which are being brought out, we are paying constantly higher rates of interest. The Federal Reserve Board, testifying from exactly the position in which you are sitting before this committee, in December acknowl edged that foreign countries are buying the securities of the United States, even the short-term securities on which we are paying these rates of interest. These are the very foreign countries to whom we are granting more and ,more aid out of our deficits who are buying these bonds. Mr. B rundage . I doubt if it is the same foreign countries. They are probably other fereign countries. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . N ow , that is an expression of doubt on your part. I suggest that you look up the facts. Mr. B rundage . Most of our economic aid is not going to countries which have any substantial foreign balances. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . Would you be kind enough to look it up and put it in the record, please. 87624— 57------ 6 74 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Mr. B r u n d a g e . I will be glad to do that; yes. (The material referred to follows:) As shown in the table below, the countries which have increased their holdings o f United States Government bonds and notes in the year from September 1955 to September 1956 are Belgium, Germany, Norway, and Switzerland, none of whom receive economic assistance. Estimated holdings of U. S. Government bonds and notes by foreign countries [Position at end of period in millions of dollars] Area and country September 1955 September 1956 (pre liminary) Continental Western Europe: Belgium-Luxembourg (and Belgian Congo)__________________________ Federal Republic of Germany_______________________________________ France (and dependencies)_________________________________________ Netherlands (and Netherlands West Indies and Surinam)_____________ Norw ay.. ________________________________________________________ Switzerland_______________ ________________________________________ Other countries (including Bank for International Settlements)________ 10 5 161 41 53 44 31 12 13 7 23 83 126 40 Total_______ ______ ________ _____________________________________ 345 304 Sterling area: United Kingdom___________________________________________________ Other countries____ ____________ __________________________________ 286 16 265 Total____________________________________________________________ 302 277 12 Canada_______________________________________________________________ 397 357 Latin America: Cuba_____________________________________________________________ Other countries____________________________________________________ 169 25 167 24 191 Total_________________ __________________________________________ 194 Other areas: Indonesia________________________ !________________________________ Other countries____________________________________________________ 15 21 Total____________________________________________________________ 36 25 Total foreign countries________ :___________________________________ 1,274 1,154 0) 25 i Less than one-half million dollars. Source: P. 63 of Treasury Bulletin, December 1956. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I am pointing out to you, sir, the reasons which compel me to think that the objective of the Bureau of the Budget should be to increase expenditures here at home where we can increase the revenue of the people who pay the taxes to meet the risi ng interest on the rising national debt. Representative M i l l s . I have a very few questions, Mr. Brundage. You said in your statement on page 2 in the second full paragraph: The assumptions with respect to economic conditions which underlie this budget are that the Nation will continue to have a high rate o f business activity with increasing national income and with prices relatively stable at about current levels. Secretary Humphrey in a letter to the committee dated January 16, which was included in the record of yesterday, made the statement that— We do not assume any change in prices for the present with respect to the estimates. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 75 Now, does that denote a difference in the thinking between the Department of the Treasury and the Bureau of the Budget with respect to those estimates of revenue % Mr. B r u n d a g e . N o , in d eed . Representative M i l l s . Y o u mean the same thing ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . It is on the same basis; yes. Representative M i l l s . N o w , if prices are to remain at present levels, I take it to mean that there is relative stability in the price picture. Mr. B r u n d a g e . W ell, some are estimated to increase a bit on the basis of information we have at this time. For example, I believe in the Defense Department they are estimating a few price increases in procurement o f special lines, particularly electronics, but it is rela tively stable. That is what we mean. Representative M i l l s . The point that both you and the Secretary o f the Treasury were endeavoring to make with respect to the budget and the estimates of revenue in connection with the budget is that you do not predicate additional revenues in the fiscal year 1958 as a result of further inflationary trends and conditions. Mr. B r u n d a g e . That is correct. The big increases in our revenue during the past 3 years have occurred during a period of relatively stable prices. Representative M i l l s . Y o u referred to the estimate of personal income rising to $340 billion in calendar year 1957 compared to $325.5 billion in calendar year 1956. Mr. B r u n d a g e . That was 1957 and 1958,1 think. Representative M i l l s . It has to do with the calendar year rather than the fiscal year ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . Y es; that is right. Representative M i l l s . That represents an increase, you say, of ap proximately 5 percent in personal income. Mr. B r u n d a g e . Yes. Representative M i l l s . That then, is a reflection of an increase, an anticipated increase, in calendar year 1957 over 1956 in the gross national product; is it not ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . It is a big increase, but the big increase that we had in the national income and in our receipts came in fiscal 1956. Representative M i l l s . W e were told yesterday that that increase in personal income would result from an anticipated increase of 3 or Sy2 percent in gross national product in calendar year 1957 over calendar year 1956. I do not know whether you have a different figure in mind. Mr. B r u n d a g e . One is the gross national product and the other is national income. Representative M i l l s . I f you have a 5 percent increase in personal income as predicted for purposes of the budget, then you would have an increase of 3 or 3 ^ percent in gross national product which, I take it, is the factual situation with respect to the estimates in the budget. Mr. B r u n d a g e . I believe so, yes. The Treasury made those esti mates, but we incorporated them in our budget and in our compu tations. Representative M i l l s . That would mean then, that we would have to have as much or more increase in gross national product in 1957 76 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT over 1956 as we had in 1956 over 1955 in order to have a balanced: budget if the Congress appropriates the funds suggested in this proposed budget, and we do not have inflation. Mr. Brundage. O f course, the income is partly held over. W e are only partly on a pay-as-you-go basis. The income of fiscal 1956 affects our budget in 1957. Eepresentative M ills. The point I am getting at, Mr. Brundage, is this: In order for us to have a balanced budget and $1.8 billion surplus in fiscal year 1958, it would be necessary for us at least for 6 months of that fiscal year, to enjoy the predicted increase in gross national product that I have referred to of 3 or 3y 2 percent. I f we are going to have relatively stable prices, that would be true. Mr. Brundage. I would think so, yes. Eepresentative M ills. That would mean, would it not, that our budget estimates are predicated upon as much or more growth eco nomically in this country in calendar year 1957 over 1956 as occurred in 1956 over 1955 ? Mr. Brundage. I would think approximately so, sir. Eepresentative M ills. That means that the Congress has a respon sibility to delve into the future with respect to a determination of economic conditions if it appropriates what is contained in this budget with reasonable expectation that those appropriations will not create deficit financing. I am always very dubious, myself, of making concrete appropri ations which necessitate increases in revenue predicated upon a growth in gross national product of that dimension in order to have a balanced budget. I would much prefer and I feel more secure, and I am sure you would as a businessman and as a former certified public accountant,, with a budget which on its face shows that it will be in balance i f economic conditions are not better or not worse than those in the pre vious calendar year. Mr. Brundage. I think George Humphrey and I both agree on that. Eepresentative M ills. Now I wanted to talk to the Secretary of the Treasury when he came here about the point that is reflected in the Economic Indicators of January 1957 which you have before you. On page 8 there is a reflection of decreases in corporate profits for the calendar year 1956. This budget surplus is predicated, in part at least, on an increase of $1 billion in corporate profits in 1957 over 1956. I think that we are on somewhat precarious ground there, as well as, perhaps, with respect to the increase predicted in personal income,, although I am not and I do not propose to be a prophet in the field o f economic activity. I am sure that none of us would want to take on that mantle. To go back to my point, however, I am very much concerned about the possibility of what we do to our economy, not only in the long run but in the short run, through the appropriation of this staggering amount that is involved in this budget. There are too many “ifs” in the way for us, I think, to tell the country now that we can appropriate this much money and assure a continuation of a balanced budget at the end of the fiscal year 1958, which would be June 30,1958. That is looking quite a bit ahead of today and making estimates o f revenue predicated upon what I would consider to be the most favor ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 77 able economic conditions that we could expect to enjoy during that period of time. \ The budget itself is predicated upon no downturn in business activity any time during the calendar year 1957. That would have to follow if we enjoyed 3 or Sy2 percent increase in our gross national product. I am much concerned as to whether or not we are safe in appro priating on the basis of those estimates of economic activity and contending as we appropriate that we will end up with a balanced budget. I think that you are eminently right. I think the President is right and I think the Secretary of the Treasury is right and I am crediting to all of you the highest degree of sincerity when you sug gest to the Congress that this budge should be whittled by the Con gress if it can be whittled. I am sure that each of the three of you, however, are not suggesting that the Congress use the broad-ax approach to the reduction of this budget. Mr. B r u n d a g e . W e would like to see it selective. I would also like to say, Mr. Mills, that these assumptions are in broad harmony with views of the experts in the Council of Economic Advisors and the Treasury, as well as the Bureau of the Budget. It is their considered judgment as to the most reasonable assump tions to use. As you say, I think that we all would like to have more o f a surplus and a little more leeway. Representative M i l l s . O f course, what we are doing actually in our Government expenditures, is to increase our expenditures either for defense or nondefense, whatever it might be, at about as rapid a rate as our revenues are increasing as a result ox this increased economic activity. This is reflected in your contemplated surpluses which are, appar ently, to remain relatively stable, whereas your receipts are going up much faster and your expenditures following your receipts are going up at a relatively even keel. So we are faced, I think, with the absolute necessity of trying to 'bring this budget down to a more reasonable level, at least in the opinion of the people that I have talked to and heard from. They think it has reached too high a level in peacetime. They have been sold on the idea that we are at peace and it is a little hard for them to understand a wartime budget or a budget of wartime levels in what they have been told is a peaceful era. O f course, you and I know it is not as peaceful as we sometimes say it is in political campaigns. However, I am interested in trying to find from you, if it is possible, and even though this is not primarily the function of this committee, whether or not you feel that you are in a position to completely defend this budget on the basis of the stand ards which are utilized in the Bureau of the Budget for purposes, first of all, of determining whether an item will be included in a budget and then as to what the amount will be for that particular item. Mr. B r u n d a g e . It is a compromise, Mr. Chairman, as all budgets are. The agencies almost uniformly came in with substantially higher requests. Aside from the military, the protection item, I think the cuts we made were something over $3 billion. 78 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT Now we could have cut more, there is no question about it. But the question was, Would that prejudice some of the good programs like those to which Senator O’Mahoney referred? The conclusion we reached was that this is a compromise, but it is a fair compromise and it is a reasonable provision for the protection of this country and for the conduct of the operations which our people seem to demand. I think that you can make more economies. But I think if you make any very substantial reduction, I think you have to cut out some of these programs. Representative M ills. Now you are not saying to us, Mr. Brundage,. in your statement, I am sure, that the Bureau of the Budget comromised the standards which the Bureau of the Budget uses for etermiiiing whether or not an item should be included in the budget and at what level it should be included. You did not compromise the standards which you used for determ ining expenditures, did you? That is not what you mean. Mr. B r u n d a g e . That is not what I mean. It is a compromise be tween opinions as to how fast and how far you should go and when. Representative M ills. Those standards that you used for deter mining expediture recommendations to the Congress are, in your opin ion, the best possible standards that could be developed within the Bureau, are they not ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . I believe so. Representative M ills. The best you have been able to develop ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . That is right. Representative M ills. I am sure they are as good as any standards anybody else has developed because I have a very high regard for your ability, frankly, and the ability of those that work with you. Now, if you have utilized the very best standards that you could con ceive in determining expenditures and recommendations, does not the statement which you make and which the President makes either as sume that the Congress will use a broadax approach to economy, or that the Congress can develop better standards than the administra tion can develop for determining expenditures for the fiscal year 1958 ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . I would hope that the Congress, which has the responsibility just like we do, would reexamine as you always do the policy decisions that have been reached. W e are going to try to cut expenditures within the budget, as has already been brought out, in reducing our contraction and limiting our personnel increases and so on. W e have already started to work on those things. The other decisions, I think, will have to be policy decisions for which the Con gress is equally responsible. A lot of these things that we are doing have been instigated, or encouraged at least, by the Congress. You take these health programs. W e estimate over $600 million of expenditure on our health programs for this next year. Now, maybe you may decide that that is going too far too fast. That amount pro vides for what you legislated last year. Maybe you will decide that we do not neied to go so far so fast, and that we can depend upon private charity or local and State authorities for things like hospitals and all of these other programs. Senator O’Mahoney. Will you yield for a moment? I noticed a S rather amusing cartoon in one of the papers the other day that repre ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 79 sented the presentation to the Congress of the budget accompanied by a pair of scissors, implying that what was being done in presenting the budget here was a presentation with the fond hope that we would take the responsibility of making the cuts. W hat I am interested in funding out is whether there is any sub stantial agreement between the Bureau of the Budget and the Secre tary of the Treasury as to where the cuts should be made. I know the chairman is interested in that subject, too. Representative M i l l s . I had in mind propounding that question and trying to obtain from you, because you are in a better position than any of us to know, just what areas exist within the budget which hold out the greatest hope, upon further consideration by the Con gress, of some reduction. Mr. B r u n d a g e . W e are hoping that we will not have to send up supplemental, that there will not be increases in pay and that you will give us the increase in the postal rates that we are asking for. Those kinds of things would be particularly helpful, and then on the broad programs you know as well as I do where the money is going and I think that you have to evaluate it just as we are doing. W e have tried to study it and we have tried to balance the desires of people for projects with their real needs and with what our fiscal re sources are. I think we have come up with a pretty good balance, myself, between the programs and between the different needs and desires and our fiscal resources. I would like to have you take a look at it and a careful look, and I hope thq,t you will be able to come up with reductions. Representative M i l l s . W e have talked entirely with respect to the budget for 1958. You have alluded to the future. In connection with that, you have pointed out that some of these expenditures that we now are making must, of necessity, remain high until we can reach some agreement with respect to limitations of armaments and inspec tion involved in that problem. Let us assume for purposes of my question that you are correct and that these expenditures for national defense for the next few years ahead will not be reducible because of our failure to reach agreements upon which we can rely for disarmament. Let us assume that our interest on the Federal debt does not increase beyond what it is today. Let us assume we do enact this budget and the programs which are recommended in the economic message and other messages. Do you see any prospect in the succeeding fiscal year, under those circumstances, that our budget estimates of expenditure and actual expenditures will be less than the $71.8 billion which is projected in this budget? Mr. B r u n d a g e . I doubt it. I am going to try, but we are already starting on our 1959 projections and I would hope that we would be able to hold to the present levels, but I doubt if we could cut it very much. Representative M i l l s . W ell, that causes us in this committee even greater concern, I think, with respect to the economic effect of what we are doing now in the expenditure of funds. Now, as I pointed out, it has been developed that in order for us to have a balanced budget and appropriate what is contained in this request, there must occur a growth in ourrgross national product of 80 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT some 3 or 3% percent. In order for us to have a balanced budget, that rate of growth will have to continue evjen beyond the calendar year 1957 and through the calendar year 1958 and on into 1959. That is true or else we will be involved again in deficit financing with these amounts of expenditures. Now, you know and I know that the projection of these expenditures over that period of time on the very tenuous basis that economic growth will sustain a balanced budget is a dubious projection and a dubious position for us to be in, is it not? Mr. B r u n d a g e . W ell, I think if we are able to hold our expenditures within the $70 million to $72 million level, our economic growth will enable a substantial surplus and, I would hope, consideration of tax reductions in 1958, in the spring of calendar year 1958 for fiscal 1959. Eepresentative M i l l s . I f we could hold our expenditures at this level? Mr. B r u n d a g e . That is what I say. That is what I am hoping to do in 1959. Eepresentative M i l l s . And if we enjoy a rate of growth of 6 or 7 percent in the 2-year period, perhaps that growth would permit reduc tions in taxes. But I would not want to promise the American people that we could reduce taxes and have a balanced budget on that basis. Mr. B r u n d a g e . I would not either. Eepresentative M i l l s . I am sure you would not. M r. B r u n d a g e . N o. Eepresentative M i l l s . S o that we are faced with a very serious prob lem with respect to the economic effects that we create in this action this year in the Congress. I had some further questions but I will not delay the committee. Senator F la n d e r s . Unfortunately, I have only just been able to get here. I had both the Mideastern hearing and then a problem with the Engineer Corps on a condemnation proceedings in my hometown and I could not dodge that one. I am sorry I was not here earlier. There is one point just raised by Mr. Mills about which I wish to say a word. It is the general assumption that defense expenditures cannot be reduced. In spite of all of the turmoil and uncertainty and all of the negative results of approaches to disarmament, I do not at the present time feel that a reduction in armaments is impossible. I am not going to make a speech. I am just going to make the suggestion. I feel it is possible to find an arrangement in the selfinterest of both the Soviet Government and of the Western Powers which can result in a considerable decrease in our commitments in return for a better sense of military security and a withdrawal of Eussia in return for that from some of the occupied territory. I shall bring these points out in greater detail later. I do not wish at this time to write off as an impossibility the idea o f somewhat reducing our military commitments. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . M r . Chairman, before Senator Flanders ar rived this morning at this hearing, Congressman Curtis raised some •questions about the consolidation of the purchasing operations of the Defense Department. Senator F la n d e r s . Those are very pertinent questions to raise. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . It was in 1952 that I sponsored an amendment to the Defense Appropriations Act requiring the purchasing agencies o f the Department of the Army, the Department of the Navy and the Department of the A ir Force to get together as soon as they could. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 81 Mr. Hoover, in the reorganization of the Government also recom mended that consolidation. The hearings which the Appropriations Committee held over many years whlie I was a member of it showed there was constant duplication among the three branches. I have no doubt that considerable gain could be made if the Depart ment of Defense would only carry out that law. I think probably you would save more money than you expect to gain by increasing the postal rates. Eepresentative C u r t is . W ill the gentleman yield for a further com ment ? This is in the area of common-use items which does not involve tanks and guided missiles and things that the military regard as sacrosanct. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . It is in the area of items which are used in every war that this Nation has ever fought and has resulted in the accumulation of vast reserves of unusuea materials that were never of any use to anyone, except those which could be sold as surplus property. Too much is bought consistently. Senator F la n d e r s . A s a member of the Armed Services Committee, I want to give assent to that statement. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I think that you can really get somewhere if you go at it, and put as much pressure on the Department of Defense as the Secretary of the Treasury is putting upon you. Mr. B r u n d a g e . W e are working at that, I assure you, and any help you can give will be greatly appreciated. There is a terrific resist ance to this, as you know. ^ Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I know what you are up against all of the time. Mr. Chairman, may I ask Mr. Brundage a question? Representative M i l l s . Had you concluded? Senator F la n d e r s . Yes. Representative M i l l s . Senator Flanders, my assumption followed the statement which Mr. Brundage had made to us in connection with his prepared statement that expenditures for defense purposes would have to remain high until we could reach some agreement on disarma ment that we could rely upon. I was going along with an assumption predicated upon his state ment rather than any thought in my own mind that there could not be some reduction. Senator F la n d e r s . May I say that in any given fiscal year, we should proceed on no other assumption. Representative M i l l s . That is right. Mr. B r u n d a g e . I personally feel that there is some hope for the idea which Senator Flanders has announced. It seems to me that the Soviet must be having all of the troubles that we are having and a lot more. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I have just one question. May I call your attention, Mr. Brundage, to this chart No. 1 in your statement. This is the chart which shows the surplus of which you have spoken by a graph which indicates that the receipts will during 1957 and 1958 be above the expenditures. The figures upon which that chart is drawn for 1957 and 1958 are labeled “estimates.” Mr. B r u n d a g e . That is right. 82 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Senator O ’Mahoney. Where do I find the breakdown of the ex pected receipts? Mr. B r u n d a g e . It is right in the budget. Senator O’Mahoney. I know there was a table but it escaped my attention. Mr. B r u n d a g e . Y es; here it is on page 1069. Senator O’Mahoney. I think it would be well, Mr. Chairman, to have that table inserted in the record at this point. The C h a ir m a n . Without objection, the table requested by Senator O’Mahoney will be included in the record. (The table referred to follows:) Budget receipts {by source) [In millions] Source 1957 estimate 1958 estimate Increase (+ ) or de crease (—), 1958 over 1957 Individual income ta x e s__ _______________________________ Corporation income taxes.________ ____ ___________ _______ Excise taxes. _____________________________________ _____ Employment taxes____ __________________________________ Estate and sift taxes___________________ ____ ______________ Taxes not otherwise classified..................................................... Customs _ . _____________ "__________ ____ ________ Miscellaneous receipts____________________________________ Deduct— Transfer to Federal old-age and survivors insurance trust fund.................................................................................... Transfer to Federal disability insurance trust fund............ Transfer to railroad retirement account............................... Transfer to highway trust fund........................................... Refunds of receipts __________________________ ________ $38,500 21,400 10.691 7,750 1,380 5 775 2,986 6,445 335 660 1,539 3,880 6,609 826 665 2,173 4,156 +164 +491 +5 +634 +276 Net budget receipts________ ________________________ 70,628 73,620 +2,992 $41,000 +$2,500 +600 22,000 +380 11,071 8,420 +670 1,475 +95 5 800 ............... +25 +292 3,278 Mr. B r u n d a g e . There is an accompanying analysis beginning on page 1068. It gives more details. Senator O ’M a h o n e y . I think the reference merely to this page would be sufficient for our record. W e do not need to republish it. Representative C u r t is . I wanted to comment on an implication that I was afraid might be left from Mr. Mills’ line of inquiry. I am pretty sure he did not intend the implication but I just wanted to be sure that the Congress has no source of information or wisdom apart from, the Executive that it can apply to this big problem of our ex penditures. In my judgment, I feel that Congress has many techniques and sources of information which are not available to the Bureau of the Budget or the executive department. The Government Accounting Office, as many people fail to remember, is an arm of the Congress. W e have a vast quantity of information that we can acquire on ex penditures and what we might say were extravagances in the past. Furthermore, we have the means of providing our citizens with a forum whereby they can give information that is within their knowl edge on the expenditures of Federal funds. I think that to imply, and I do not believe the implication was in tended, that the Congress did not have a tremendous responsibility in this field would not be correct. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 83 The Executive has commented upon that responsibility of its sister branch of the Government. There should not be such an implication. The Congress is limited to what the executive branch brings before us. I feel we have available tremendous tools and knowledge and that we can perform a real service within this area. Mr. Brundage, as I view your approach, and that of Mr. Hum phrey and the President, it is calling upon this sister branch of the Government to use its information and knowledge. Is that a fair interpretation ? Mr. B r u n d a g e . That is quite correct. Representative C u r t is . I thank you, because I did not want to leave those overtones remaining. I, as a Congressman, feel quite jealous of the prerogatives of the Congress and of its independence of the executive department and our need to do a job in this area. Reperesentative M i l l s . I have the same jealous regard for the Congress that my colleague from Missouri has and I did not desire to leave any implication. I wanted to call attention to the fact that the responsibility given Congress this time to cut a budget is one that is staggering in its im portance and it does imply that the Congress can utilize better stand ards, if it is not to use the meat-ax approach, than the Bureau of the Budget has yet been able to develop. Perhaps, the Congress can develop those better standards. Representative C u r t is . Evidently, there is an area of disagree ment. I think the standards that the Bureau of the Budget has ap plied in handling this budget have been excellent. I am suggesting that the Congress, because of its different nature can apply different techniques which the Bureau of the Budget by its nature and the executive department by its nature cannot apply. It is not that our standards are better, it is the fact that we can use a different approach and do some things that they cannot do. Now, I think if I would be critical, I would be more critical of the Congress for not having applied standards that they could have ap plied and in my judgment should, even to this day, apply in approach ing the budgets that are presented to us. It is our standards that in my judgment have been weak more than the executive department stantards. Senator F la n d e r s . I desire to state that the Senate likewise has strongly maintained the coordinating powers of the Congress. I f there is any doubt about that matter, I would like to repeat it. Representative M i l l s . There is no doubt in my mind, Senator, that we both exercise independence as evidenced by our record of generally appropriating more money than the budget has requested for the past several years. That is regardless of who happened to be in control of the Congress. So that we are independent and we do exercise our independent judg ment. I fear that we will do it this time but in the direction opposite to what I hope will occur. Mr. B r u n d a g e . I know your capabilities and you can join the Budget Bureau any time you want to. Representative M i l l s . I may come to you some day. 84 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Representative C u r t is . Could I ask one specific question that was suggested by another line of questions ? I notice that the customs receipts are listed as expected to rise by about 10 percent, reflecting a higher level of business activity. That is on page 1069 of the budget. Yet the estimate of growth on corpora tion taxes is much smaller, about half a percent, which incidentally I believe was about the lowest in 4 years. Now, does this mean that there will be little growth of domestic activity and a great increase of foreign activity or is this based upon different facts or predictions. This relates to Mr. M ills’ observation that this is all predicated on an increase in gross national product of about 3 to 3.5 percent. Yet,, the corporate tax return is only up about half a percent, if my figures are correct. Mr. B r u n d a g e . W e expect increasing foreign trade, but somewhat narrower margins of profit. I think the total volume is expected to go up. This, as I said, is primarily a Treasury estimate but we worked it out jointly with the Counsel of Economic Advisers. Representative C u r t is . In other words, the apparent inconsist ency lies in the fact that the corporations although increasing the amount of their activity, will not be having as much profit. Then the increased income from taxes will be derived from personal income,, wages, and salaries, and so on. Mr. B ru ndage. That is right. Representative C u r t is . I get the picture. Thank you. Representative M ills. I f there are no further questions, the com mittee will stand adjourned until 10 o’clock in the morning and we appreciate, Mr. Brundage, your presence and the presence of the members of your staff and the information you have given. In the morning our discussion will be directed at the economic out look for the coming year, which is very appropriately scheduled. (Whereupon, at 12:10 p. m., the committee was recessed, to recon vene at 10 a. m. Wednesday, January 30,1957.) JANUARY 1957 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT W E D N E S D A Y , J A N U A R Y 30, 1957 C ongress of t h e U n it e d S ta te s , J o in t E co n o m ic C o m m it t e e , Washington, D. C. The committee met at 10 a. m., pursuant to recess, in room P -36 o f the Capitol, Hon. W right Patman (chairman of the joint com mittee) presiding. Present: Representatives Patman (presiding), Mills, Talle, Curtis, and Kilburn. Present also: Dr. Grover W . Ensley, executive director of the joint committee, and John W . Lehman, clerk of the joint committe. Chairman P a t m a n . The committee will please come to order. The President’s Economic Report contains much information on economic developments of recent years and particularly of 1956. It was cautious, however, in discussing what is likely to happen during the coming year to the labor force, Government, business, and consumer demand, and agriculture. I might say that the executive session on Monday with the Council of Economic Advisers provides considerable elaboration of the Coun cil’s views on the outlook for 1957. This testimony will be released as soon as it can be edited and printed. Today the committee has 5 experts from Government and from re search organizations to discuss m considerable detail the outlook for the next 12 months and beyond. W e have asked these witnesses to present facts and survey results and to provide us their personal judg ments. The policy implications derived from this discussion, and the appropriate action for the Federal Government, will be discussed at later sessions of the committee. In order to expendite the discussion this morning, the Chair will recognize each of the 5 panel members for purposes of making an opening statement of 8 minutes, summarizing the facts and in the area to each individual witness. W e will proceed without interrup tion through the opening statements, following which there will De a general discussion by members of the committee and the panel. I understand that this procedure is agreeable to the panel and that they have requested that the committee staff notify each when his 8 minutes has expired. As chairman of the committee I would like to indicate at this time the plan for questioning which I propose to govern this set of hear ings. Each committee member will be recognized for 10 minutes for purposes of questioning the witnesses. This will apply during first go around in order that each member of the committee may have time to participate in the questioning. 85 86 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT I will ask the staff to notify each member when his 10 minutes has expired. The first topic this morning is labor force, hours, productivity, and potential output. This area will be discussed by Mr. Ewan Clague, Commissioner of Labor Statistics of the Department of Labor. STATEMENT 0E EWAN CLAGUE, COMMISSIONER OP LABOR STA TISTICS, UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR Mr. C la g u e . Mr. Chairman, you have asked me to discuss recent developments in some of the fields which fall within the scope of the data-collecting responsibilities of the United States Department of Labor’s Bureau of Labor Statistics, and to give you some appraisal of the significant factors which are now influencing, or are likely to influence, economic trends in 1957. I have with me, for insertion in the record, a presentation on the subjects which you assigned to me— labor force, hours of work, pro ductivity, wages, and prices. I might say that the statement that I resent contains three segments. It contains my short statement which am reading here today, a complete report, and lastly, a set of the charts. I hope that this more detailed material will be useful to you in your deliberations. In my brief statement here today, I shall at tempt to summarize some of the more notable highlights, using some of the charts which are attached. ? LABOR FORCE Out of the many facts which we know about the labor force, the one which I find most significant at the moment is that its growth in any one year cannot be predicted with any certainty. As chart No. 1 shows, there was no year from 1950 to 1956 during which actual labor force changes were the same as the amounts that might have been expected. However, as the second chart shows, over a span of years the actual additions to the working force have in fact matched the amounts expected by the technicians. This, I believe, highlights one of the conclusions which can be drawn from the data for 1956: growth in the economy does not occur on a straight-line year-after-the-year basis. A s you will note from chart 2, we have carried forward the 1950-55 projections to 1960. W e are starting this year well above the trend line, mostly because there has been a much greater than expected rise in employment of youngsters and of women 35 to 64 years of age. You will see that in chart 1. W e could get another such rise this year— the reservoir of housewives and students is far from exhausted— or we could get a return toward the trend line. About the most that we can say now, in response to the request of the committee and its staff, is that if the labor force expands to the total now being projected for 1960, there would, be an increase of about 800,000 in 1957, O f this, almost 700,000 would be due to the increase in the population of working age. Another important highlight in recent employment trends is that the increases in employment have been primarily in nonmanufacturing industries, and even the gain in manufacturing has been mainly among nonproduction workers. See chart 3. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 87 Using Bureau of Labor Statistics data seasonally adjusted, we have made a comparison of the changes in employment from the peak of mid-1953 up to the end of 1956. Total employment in the goodsproducing industries— manufacturing, mining, and construction— was approximately the same at the beginning and at the end of the period. By contrast, total employment in the remainder of the nonfarm estab lishments (including trade, transportation, Government, and the other service industries) was over 7 percent higher at the end of 1956 than it had been at the end of the Korean hostilities. HOU RS OF W O R K Trends in the size of the workweek are much less clean-cut, even over a span of years, than are trends in the labor force and employ ment. W e know that in agriculture and in a large number of the non manufacturing industries there has been a long-term downward trend which is still continuing. This downtrend has been muddied to some extent by the recent sharp rise in the number of part-time workers. Nearly half of the 1956 increase in employment consisted of part-time workers. In manufacturing, on the other hand, there does not seem to have been any clear trend in recent years. Within the past few days I have received the first tabulations of a new set of figures prepared by the Bureau; that is, seasonally adjusted hours of work. A quick glance at these summary figures— which we have plotted on chart 4— furnishes some clues which indicate that changes in the factory work week tend to precede changes in employment. In other words, em ployers tend to use the workweek— overtime dr short time, as the case may be— as the first method of adjusting for changes in demand. In making future projections the continued downtrend in the work week in nonmanufactunng industries justifies assuming some further decline in the average workweek for the economy as a whole; but, as far as manufacturing is concerned, it is better not to predict the work week without first making some assumptions about the trend of output. The size of the workweek is only one of the factors which determine total man-hours worked per year. Also important is the uptrend in the number of paid holidays and weeks of vacation. PR O D U C TIV ITY When we come to the subject of productivity we discover that what I said about labor force, that almost anything can happen in a single year, is even more true. It is chartcteristic of productivity trends that they do not move uniformly from year to year. A year of rapid expansion may be followed by one of leveling on. A s this committee knows, we have prepared estimates on produc tivity trends over the years through 1953. For the 3 most recent years the data are still so skimpy that it is impossible to do anything but make very preliminary estimates which have a rather low degree of reliability. A s nearly as we can tell from the data which are now available, the increase in manufacturing productivity in 1954 and 1955 was substantially higher than the previous postwar average, but the increase in 1956 was small. 88 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT As indicated in the more detailed presentation, output per man-hour of production workers in manufacuring increased 3 to 3.6 percent a year from 1947 to 1953, about 4% percent a year from 1953 to 1955, and from 1 to 2y 2 percent in 1956, depending on which of various production estimates are used. I f the estimates are based on the hours of work of all factory em ployees, rather than production workers alone, the average increases would be reduced by at least one-half a percentage point for the period up to 1953, and about 1 percentage point for the last 3 years. I f we take into account the whole private nonagricultural economy, we find an average annual gain of about S y2 percent from 1947 to 1953, 3 percent annually in 1954-55, and practically no increase in 1956. This is based on hours of all persons at work. ^ Figures are still so crude and so lacking in detail that it is very difficult to account specifically for the 1956 decline in the rate of pro ductivity growth. Some possible factors include the moderate gain in output m 1956, utilization of marginal resources, production ad justments to new equipment, and the large increase in the labor force. I must repeat: Productivity does not move in a straight line. The decline in the rate of productivity growth in 1956 followed 2 years of higher than average increases, at least in manufacturing, and is not necessarily an indicator of a new trend. WAGES Some aspects of the wage situation are fairly clear. Wage-rate in creases negotiated in 1956 tended to be higher than those agreed to in 1955. About 3 out of 4 of the workers covered by major settlements concluded during 1956 received increases in rates of pay averaging at least 10 cents an hour. Hourly earnings rose significantly in a number of nonmanufacturing industries as well as in manufacturing (see charts 5A, 5B, and 5C ). There are now at least 5 million workers who can expect wage in creases during this coming year on the basis of contracts concluded in 1955 and 1956. These workers are found in almost every industry, but are concentrated in metalworking, construction, transportation, food, and mining. About half of them will receive pay adjustments of between 6 ana 8 cents an hour. In addition, cost-of-living escala tor clauses may affect the incomes of nearly 4 million workers. The 1957 deferred increases in these long-term contracts are gen erally lower than the raises which became effective at the beginning of those contracts in 1955 or 1956. These deferred increases will undoubtedly have some effect on 1957 negotiations in other industries, but nevertheless there can be no cer tainty as to the size of the wage increases which will be negotiated this year. Among the important industries in which contracts are due to expire or are subject to reopening on wages tins year are petroleum, rubber, lumber, chemicals, textiles, coal mining, paper, telephone and other utilities, trade, and construction. The major influence in these negotiations will be the general economic climate modified by the outlook in each individual industry. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 89 PRICES When we come to the last of the subjects assigned to me, prices, we move into an area in which there is no agreement at all as to the ^normal” trend. W e are now in the midst of the third period of price increases during the past 10 years. The first (1947-48) was due to heavy demand arising out 01 war-created shortages of goods. The second (1950-51) was due primarily to the outbreak in Korea* Un like the two earlier ones, the present price rise, which began in mid1955, is due entirely to strong forces of domestic origin in both consumer and producer markets. The charts show that there are several distinctly different factors at work in the current price situation, in addition to the continuing strong demands resulting from our rising standards of living and increasing population. One of these has been the extremely strong business demand for new plant and equipment (see chart 9 ). A second factor in price movements in 1956 was the firming up of the farm situation after several years of steady decline. From the peak in early 1951 to the end of 1955, farm prices fell about 30 percent, but there was a substantial recovery in 1956. A third factor, which is particularly important in consumer prices, is the steady rise in rents and services, which shows no sign of abating (see chart 1 1 ); and, of course, there has been the special impact of the Suez situation on a few commodities. So far as the immediate future is concerned, if the demand factors which gave rise to the price increases show no further strengthening— in other words, if investment demand flattens out and if consumer buying follows the income curve and consumer credit is expanded only moderately— there may well be more stability in the price picture. A s of this time, signs of upward price pressures are still evident in those sectors of the economy where demand continues to burgeon; signs of price weakness are appearing only in those fields where demand is less urgent than it formerly was. In addition, there is no indication of any halting of the long-run uptrend in the cost of serv ices ; the demand for personal and professional services is continually rising. A t the same time, price declines in the agricultural sector are no longer offsetting increases elsewhere. (The material referred to is as follows:) MATERIAL SUBMITTED BY EWAN CLAGUE, COMMISSIONER OF LABOR STATISTICS, UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR, BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS, TO JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE I. L abor F orce T rends The total labor force averaged 70.4 million in 1956, an increase over 1955 of 1% million—about twice the amount of growth expected on the basis o f popula tion increase and long-term trends in rates o f labor force participation. The occurrence such a large increase following the substantial gain o f 1.1 million in the preceding year illustrates the difficulty o f determining how much labor force growth there is likely to be in a given year. The annual increases since 1950 are shown in chart 1. In this period they ranged from a low o f 400,000 in 1952-53 to the 1955-56 high of 1% million. Our experience since W orld War II indicates that it is possible to make pro jections o f labor force over longer periods o f time which come fairly close to actual developments. For example, in early 1951, the Bureau o f Labor Statistics 87&24S7 ------ 7 90 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT projected labor force growth through 1955.1 The projections included growth resulting from increased population and assumed a continuation of 1920-50 trends in rates of labor force participation for each age-sex group with an adjustment in the rates of adult women to take account o f accelerated increases observed in 1947-50. For the 5-year period the estimated expansion of 3.7 million workers almost exactly matched the actual growth. As can be seen in the upper half o f chart 2, however, the year-to-year increases did not follow the trend line. In some years the labor force expansion was far greater and in other years much less than the average expected growth o f 750,000 and in some years the expansion was much less. The deviations of actual labor force from trend during the years 1951-54 (table 1 and chart 1) appear to be related to the general expansion of military and economic activity following the Korean hostilities and to the recession which followed. Between 1950 and 1951 the labor force increased by 1*4, almost onehalf million more than was anticipated. The expanded size o f the Armed Forces brought a large increase in the labor force activity o f men under 25. At the same time, the number of women entering the labor force exceeded the long-run expec tation. In the following year the labor force was still above the projected trend level but the amount o f excess had shrunk. There appeared a deficit among women under 25, probably related to the increase in marriages following the Korean outbreak and the subsequent rise in the number of births. Women over 25 continued to be added to the labor force in excess o f the numbers expected. 1 Harold Wool, Long-Term Projections of Labor Force, Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. XVI, National Bureau of Economic Research. The original projections have been revised to take account of revised population data. T a b le 1 .— Deviation of actual from trend 1 labor force , by age and sex, annual average 1951-56 [In thousands] 1950 Age and sex 1951 1953 1952 Actual labor Actual labor Trend labor Deviation of Actual labor Trend labor Deviation of Actual labor Trend labor Deviation of actual from. force force2 actual from force2 actual from force force force 2 force trend trend trend 66,401 65,942 459 66,977 66,706 271 67,362 67,417 -5 5 47,072 46,828 244 47,391 47,186 205 47,692 47,528 164 to 24.............................................. to 64................................... and over............................. 8,474 35,348 2,595 8,586 35,878 2,608 8,419 35,771 2,638 167 107 —30 8,510 36,342 2,539 8,383 36,124 2,679 127 218 -1 4 0 8,423 36,729 2,544 8,342 36,454 2,732 81 275 -1 8 8 Female, 14 and over...................... 18,718 215 19,586 19,329 19,520 19,668 19,889 -2 2 1 to 24.............................................. to 64............................. - .............. and over............................. 4,675 13,427 616 4,683 14,064 582 4,622 13,843 649 61 221 -6 7 4,513 14,453 620 4,583 14,255 682 4,399 14,571 693 4,546 14,619 724 -1 4 7 -4 8 -3 1 14 25 65 14 25 65 OF 1954 1956 1955 Actual labor Trend labor Deviation of Actual labor Trend labor Deviation of Actual labor Trend labor Deviation of of actual force force of actual force force of actual force force from trend from trend from trend 67,818 68,144 -326 68,896 68,854 +42 70,387 79,750 47,847 47,832 +15 48,054 48,108 -54 48,579 48,389 190 14 to 24........................................................................... 25 to 6 4 . . . . ........... , ...................................... ................ 65 and over...... .................... .......................... 8,257 37,065 2,525 8,303 36,778 2,751 -46 +287 -226 8,229 37,299 2,525 8,261 37,052 2,795 -32 +247 -270 8,424 37,552 2,603 8,278 37,587 2,524 146 -35 79 Female, 14 and over............................................. 19,971 20,312 -341 20,842 20,746 +96 21,808 21,361 447 to 24........................................................................... to 6 4 .------- ;......... ...................................... ............... and over............................................... ....... 4,380 4,530 15,028 754 -150 -103 -88 4,445 15,617 779 4,541 15,410 795 -96 +207 -16 4,648 16,338 821 4,500 16,053 808 285 13 14 25 65 14,925 666 1Trend labor forces for 1951-55, made in 1951, are based on 1950 and assume continua tion of 1920-50 trends in age-sex labor force participation rates with an adjustment in the rates for adult women to take account of accelerated increases observed in 1947-50; the 1956 trend labor force, made in 1956, is based on 1955 data and assumes continuation of 19*7-55 trends in age-sex labor force participation rates. 637 PRESIDENT Total, 14 and over................................................. Male, 14 and over....................................... *....... THE Age and sex 19,114 66 —70 198 -6 2 REPOBT 65,135 46,417 ECONOMIC Total, 14 and over....... ....... Male, 14 and over......................... 148 2 The actual labor force estimates for 1950, 1951, and 1952 are based on revised popula tion estimates and therefore differ from published census figures for the same dates* N ote.—Figures may not add to totals because of rounding. Source: U. S. Bureau of the Census and Bureau of Labor Statistics. co 92 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT With the slowing down o f defense activity in 1953, the labor force showed only a small increase. The inflow o f additional women workers was sharply reduced and the participation o f men over 65 continued to drop, erasing the ex cess o f the actual labor force over the trend projection. Between 1953 and 1954, with increased unemployment and curtailed activity in many sections o f the economy, labor-force growth was again less than ex pected and the actual was 300,000 below trend line. The recovery in 1955 brought a substantial amount o f labor force growth and the 1955 average labor force was Ijack to the long-term trend level o f 68.9 million. The labor force increase o f 1% million workers between 1955 and 1956 con sisted o f about 600,000 additions resulting from population growth, about 200,000 from continuation o f long-term trends in labor-force participation rates, and about 650,000 from a greater-than-expected increase in worker rates for women 35 to 64 years of age and for youngsters o f school age. These increases for adult women and young workers appear to be related to the high level o f economic activity and provide evidence that these groups enter the labor market in greater numbers when job opportunities are plentiful. Many o f these women and youngsters are in part-time jobs. Between 1955 and 1956 there was an unusually large increase of 850,000 in the number o f persons employed less than 35 hours a week. The lower half o f chart 2 shows the projected trend labor force to 1960, and the actual 1955 and 1956 labor forces. The extrapolation of trends in laborforce rates to 1960 was revised in 1956 to take account o f additional data through 1955. By 1960, the labor force can be expected to number almost 73% million on the basis o f trend, an increase o f about 4% million over 1955, or an average o f about 900,000 each year between 1955 and 1960. However, the 1956 actual labor force increased by about 600,000 more than expected. Therefore the expected increase between 1956 and 1960 is reduced to about 3 million or 800,000 a year for the next 4 years. Even if the projection to 1960 proves to be correct, we do not expect the growth to occur in equal annual increments. Nonfarm employm ent in 1956 The number o f workers on nonfarm payrolls continued at record levels for each month o f 1956, mainly as a result o f persistently greater-than-seasonal gains in the nonmanufacturing sector. For the year as a whole, employment in nonagricultural establishments averaged 51.5 million, more than 1.5 million higher than the average for 1955. Employment in nonmanufacturing industries accounted for 1.2 million o f this job increase, a 3.6 percent gain from 1955. Every major nonmanufacturing division reported an employment increase. Manufacturing employment, at 16.9 million, rose only 330,000, or 2 percent from 1955 levels as large gains in a few industries were offset by scattered losses or only modest gains in other industries. Large gains, resulting in record job levels, were made in retail and wholesale trade, contract construction, State and local governments, and the service in dustries. In manufacturing, substantial over-the-year increases in employment were reported in the machinery and electrical machinery industries, as well as in primary metals, chemicals, printing, and paper. A 12 percent drop in auto mobile employment in 1956 outweighed substantial over-the-year gains in air craft and shipyard employment, resulting in a large decline in jobs in tile trans portation equipment industry. Over-the-year job losses were also registered in lumber, textiles, tobacco, leather, and ordnance. While nonmanufacturing employment moved steadily upward during all o f 1956 (allowing for seasonal variation), manufacturing employment was relatively stable during the first three quarters o f the year, beginning to move upward in October when large-scale job expansions occurred in industries producing auto mobiles and their component parts. The steel strike in July had only a temporary effect on job totals. One o f the more interesting developments in manufacturing employment in 1956 was the relatively large increase in the number o f nonproduction workers. While the average number o f production workers increased by less than 1 per cent during the year, the number of nonproduction workers increased by more than 6 percent. Two-thirds o f the over-the-year gain o f 330,000 in total manu facturing employment was made up o f nonproductiofa workers. Most o f the increase in nonproduction workers occurred in aircraft, machinery, and electrical equipment plants, where personnel requirements for research and development have been increasing sharply in the past year. 93 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT II. T ren ds in t h e W ork w eek H ou rsof work in 1956 The average workweek in the entire economy in 1956, as measured by the Bureau of the Census, was 39.5 hours, two-tenths of an hour below the level o f the previous year. The decline was somewhat less than had been projected for 1956 on the basis o f an assumed long-term downtrend in the length o f the workweek.2 The workweek in manufacturing, as measured by the Bureau o f Labor Statis tics, averaged 40.5 hours in 1956, down two-tenths hour from 1955. The length o f the factory workweek started an abrupt decline in the early part of 1956, after more than a year and a half of almost continuous rise (allowing fo r seasonal fluctuations). A leveling off or turnabout in this upward trend o f hours was characteristic of most manufacturing industries, but was especially evident in the automobile and its supplier industries (notably rubber), and in industries connected with home construction (lumber and furniture). In June, the general decline had been halted and an upturn commenced. By the last quarter of the year, hours o f work in manufacturing had recovered much of the loss suffered since the end o f 1955 and were about at, or slightly above, the postwar average. j p ostwar trends in the w orkw eek The most significant factor in the average workweek in past decades has been a long-term downtrend in both agricultural and nonagricultural industries!. This secular decline in hours of work, temporarily reversed by W orld War II, apparently again has been resumed in the postwar period. The workweek in agriculture, as measured by the Bureau of the Census, declined from 48.8 hours in 1947 to 45.4 in 1956. Hours o f work in nonagricultural industries have also shown a marked decline since 1947 according to Census Bureau statistics, dropping from 40.4 hours in 1947 to 38.8 in 1956. ( See table 2 .) 1 T a b le 2.— W eekly hours o f wage and salary w orkers in agriculture and in nonagricultural industries [Annual averages 1947-56] Total weekly hours Year 1947.............. 1948 . 1949.............. 1950.............. 1951__- ........ I 41.6 40.8 40.3 39.9 40.4 Agricul ture 48.8 48.5 48.1 47.2 47.8 Nonagri cultural industries 40.4 39.6 39.0 38.8 39.4 Total weekly hours Year 1952.............. 1953___ ____ 1954........... 1955.............. 1956.............. 40.4 40.1 38.9 39.7 39.5 Agricul ture 47.4 48.0 47.0 46.3 45.4 Nonagri cultural industries 39.6 39.1 37.9 38.9 38.8 1Averages indude workers reporting no hours of work. Source: U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. . The decline is especially evident in nonmanufacturing and has been the result o f several factors. A growing proportion o f workers have had their scheduled workweeks reduced to 40 hours or below. This is indicated by the smaller proportion of nonagricultural employees working 41 hours or more. T a b le 3.—H ours worked in nonagricultural industries Percentage of employees working— 1 to 34 hours May 1947................................................................................... May 1956__________ ________________ ____ ____ 12.6 17.0 35 to 40 hours 48.0 49.4 41 hours or more 39.4 33.6 Source: U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. a A reduction o f ‘ ‘slightly less than 1 percent” — or about 0.4 hour was projected in the report of the Joint Committee on the Economic Report on the January 1956 report of thePresident, 84th Cong., 2d sess., March 1956, p. 86. 94 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT This pattern is true o f all major groups in nonagricultural industries from May 1947 to May 1956. Census data show the following declines during this period in the proportion working 41 hours or m ore: in construction, from 35.1 to 26.7 percent; in transportation, communication, and other public utilities, from 55.3 to 25.6 percent; in wholesale and retail trade, from 55.7 to 43.3 per cent ; and in service industries, from 39.7 to 31.4 percent. The decline in manur factoring was the smallest o f the major groups—from 28.2 to 24.1 percent— primarily because the overwhelming proportion o f manufacturing industries already were on a regularly scheduled 40-hour week. An increase in part-time workers is another major factor affecting the average workweek. The increase of 1.8 million in civilian employment between 1955 and 1956 was made up about equally o f men and women. To a large extent the increases were part-time workers. Nearly half of the 1956 employment increase o f 1.8 million consisted of people who were working less than 35 hours a week. As compared with 1955, there were about 450,000 more women and 400,000 more men working less than full time, the great majority in nonagri cultural industries. In agriculture, the decline in the workweek has also been influenced by the decrease in the proportion o f self-employed farmers and unpaid family workers— who usually work long hours— and the corresponding growth in the proportion of hired farmworkers. Although a long-term downtrend in hours o f work was also evident in manu facturing industries before the war, short-term economic influences have appar ently been o f more importance in determining the factory workweek in the postW orld War II period. Bureau of Labor statistics figures on annual average weekly hours in manufacturing have ranged, in the period since 1947, from a high of 40.7 hours to a low of 39.2 hours, with no clear evidence o f an overall downtrend. There have been sharply divergent trends in the workweeks o f individual industries. Durable-goods industries showed an increase in weekly hours, while nondurable-goods industries failed to show a gain. (See chart 4.) Hours of work tend to be a factor in equating supply and demand for labor in the short run. When changes in demand require changes in labor input, the first response appears to be changes in hours o f work. There are a number o f advantages to a firm in this approach. First, if the firm is not certain that the new conditions of demand will persist, increasing or decreasing hours of work are methods o f adjusting labor inputs which, on the downswing, minimize the loss o f trained work force and creation of morale problems. In a period o f rising demand, increasing the hours o f work avoids the expense and difficulties o f recruiting and training good workers. In addition, in a tight labor market, overtime and premium pay may be an inducement in recruiting and longer hours may be the only alternative to hiring less desirable, untrained workers. How ever, since overtime work typically is costly because of premium wage rates, and has other disadvantages as well, the firm will generally employ additional labor or make other adjustments within a relatively short time. These facts are evident on chart 4, which presents seasonally adjusted monthly data on production worker employment together with preliminary data which I have just received on seasonally adjusted average weekly hours for 1947-56. I have had these new estimates charted, and they indicate that changes in the workweek tend to precede changes in employment for both durable and nondur able groups. The seasonally adjusted data on hours of work presented in this chart will be available in complete tabular form in about a month. I exipect that this series will provide valuable insight on the relationship between employment and hours. Supplementing the seasonally adjusted employment series, these forthcoming data on seasonally adjusted factory hours in manufacturing will make possible adjusted man-hours data which will provide another useful tool for current economic analysis. Overtim e hour The Bureau o f Labor Statistics has recently inaugurated another series, de signed to give precise information on overtime hours worked by factory produc tion workers for premium pay. The period o f 1 year for which these data have been collected is as yet too short to realize the full potential of this measure, particularly the application of overtime hours as a lead indicator of changes in the factory workweek, and possibly o f employment as well. To analyze the economic relationship of overtime hours to total hours and to employment, it will s ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT 95 be necessary to have several years o f data in order to determ ine seasonal patterns in overtime work. The overtime series have, nevertheless, already yielded useful, information on the differential patterns o f overtime in various manufacturing industries, on the relationship o f overtime to economic activity and the relationship o f over time work to earnings. For example, o f the average o f 40.5 hours a week o f factory production workers in 1956, we know that 2.8 hours have been overtime hours at premium pay. Based on time and a half for the overtime work, factory workers received on the average $8 per week for this work, or 10 percent o f their average gross weekly earnings of $80. III. R e c e n t T r e n d s i n P r o d u c t i v i t y Long-run and postwar trends M anufacturing.—During the course o f the hearings held in October 1955 by the Subcommittee on Economic Stabilization o f the Joint Economic Committee on Automation and Technological Change, the findings of BLS Report..100, Trends in Output Per Man-Hour and Man-Hours Per Unit o f Output, Manufacturing, 1939-53, were discussed and the report itself was included in the record o f the hearings. The report indicated that the long-run' average annual increase in output per production worker man-hour o f manufacturing industries, prior to 1939, was about 3.3 percent. The wartime dislocations and subsequent problems o f reconversion resulted in a much smaller rate o f increase, about 1 percent, be tween 1939 and 1947, followed by a return to the long-run average o f 3 to 3.6 per cent during the postwar years 1947-53. Other measures may be computed to take account o f the employment in manu facturing o f nonproduction workers, although a major problem is the absence o f data on weekly hours o f nonproduction workers. Estimates have been pre pared, using the alternative assumptions that nonproduction workers work the same hours as production workers, or that they work a standard 40-hour week. For the postwar period as a whole, either assumption yields about the same result. Since the proportion o f nonproduction workers to total employees has been increasing during the postwar period, productivity in manufacturing based on hours o f all employees would show less o f an increase than a measure based on production-worker-hours only. For the 1947-53 period, output per total employee-hour would show an aver age annual increase o f about 2% to 3 percent, that is, about one-half o f 1 percent less than that based on production-worker-hours only. Total nonagriculture.—In its report, Potential Economic Growth o f the United States, the Joint Economic Committee published a table providing estimates o f output per man-hour for the total private economy, with separate estimates for the farm and nonfarm sectors. The estimates covered the years 1910 through 1953. In this statement we will be primarily concerned with the trend for the nonfarm sector. Estimates o f the average annual increase in output per man-hour for total nonagricultural industries, based on the JEC report, were published as part o f the BLS Report 100 on manufacturing productivity. These estimates indicated an average annual increase o f about 2 percent fo r the 1910-53 period, but a much larger increase o f about 3.4 percent for the postwar period. Trends since 1958 M anufacturing, 1953-56.—The detailed quantity, value, and price data o f the type used in BLS Report 100 for computing output per man-hour o f manufac turing industries are not yet available for the years after 1953, and extension o f the estimates will have to wait for the publication o f the detailed figures o f the 1954 census o f manufactures and subsequent surveys. In the meantime, because o f the great interest in recent productivity trends, the Bureau o f Labor Statistics has attempted to develop interim measures. These estimates, based on cruder data and methods, should be considered as preliminary interim indicators and have a lower degree o f reliability than the careful and detailed work done for the earlier period. The Federal Reserve Board index o f production has been used, rather fre quently to derive current estimates o f changes in output per man-hour. This method has some serious limitations, from the viewpoint o f productivity meas urement, because the production estimates for recent years already embody a productivity assumption; that is, production indexes for'industries covering 96 ECONOMIC BEPOBT OF TH E PRESIDENT about half o f manufacturing are based on man-hour trends adjusted for extrap olated changes in productivity. The BLSj has experimented with other interim measures. One is based on selected FRB industry indexes, excluding those derived from man-hours adjusted for productivity trends. The other is based on Department o f Commerce, Office o f Business Economics, data on shipments, adjusted fo r change in inventories o f finished goods and goods in process, and deflated to eliminate the influence o f changes in price. The interim measures developed by the BLS are far from satisfactory and suffer from limitations o f their own, but they do not embody any productivity assumptions. An analysis and technical description o f these measures was presented in a paper given by members o f the Bureau o f Labor Statistics at the December 1955 annual meeting o f the American Statistical Association. Using the published FRB indexes and the measures developed by BLS, latest available data indicate that the increase in output per hour o f production workers was about 4% percent per year between 1953 and 1955—substantially higher than the postwar average o f about 3 to 3.6 percent* These estimates also indicate a considerable slackening o f the irate o f in* crease in 1956, although there is a substantial variation depending on which measure is used. An estimate based on the published total FRB production index shows an increase o f about 2% percent in output per man-hour o f produc tion workers in 1956; measures based on deflated OBE data show increases o f about 1 percent* I f estimates are based on hours o f all employees, rather than production workers alone, the 1953-55 average is lowered to something close to 3% percent In 1956, the change in output per man-hour would drop to a range o f about zero to m percent increase. Total nonagriculture, 1958-56.—Estimates fo r the years 1954 and 1955 were published by the Joint Economic Committee in their 1956 Joint Economic Re port. However, these estimates are not based on the same data for man-hours used in previous estimates and may, therefore, not be entirely consistent with them. The estimates up to 1953 were based on detailed industry employment and hours data, which were aggregated for major sectors. The most recent esti mates are based primarily on census labor force data on employment and hours. Taking into account revisions to the basic data fo r both output and manhours, the estimates as revised indicate an increase o f about 6 percent in output per man-hour, o f all persons employed, between 1953 and 1955, or about 3 percent per year. This is higher than the long-run average but slightly below the postwar average. As in the case o f manufacturing, more than half the increase took place In 1955. Preliminary data for 1956 indicate almost no change in output per man-hour in the total nonagricultural sector. The data used to derive preliminary esti mates o f output per hour fo r 1956 are the same as those used in the 1956 Joint Economic Report to develop estimates for 1954 and 1955. Factors which may have affected productivity in 1956.— In evaluating the decline in the rate o f increase in output per hour during 1956, one should bear in mind that these estimates refer to broad aggregates such as total nonfarm and total manufacturing. Based on past experience it is quite probable that within these aggregates there may have been substantial variations, with some industries continuing to show substantial gains while others may have actually experienced declines in productivity. Another general observation which relates to the evaluation o f productivity for any one year is that while there is rarely an overall decline in productivity, there is little uniformity in the year-to-year rates o f change. A year o f rapid expansion may be followed by one o f leveling off, or vice versa. In fact, according to the preliminary indicators, the low rate o f increase in 1956 was preceded by a year o f more than average gain. Moreover, the high capital investment o f 1956 and prior years, including investment in automation and oilier forms o f advanced tech* nology, could pay off in 1957 in the form o f significantly higher productivity. * Measures derived from selected FBB industry indexes (i. e., excluding those based on man-hours) show a higher increase fo r the years 1054 and 195(5, and a smaller increase fo r 1956. Since these are a sleeted group o f industries ,they are not necessarily) representative o f total manufacturing. ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT 97 In the present economy o f full employment and high levels o f output, it is possible that utilization o f marginal resources and strained capacity in many plants may have affected the productivity potential. Continued high investment in new equipment in many plants and industries may have required extensive production adjustments before fu ll efficiency could be realized. In addition, there were undoubtedly weak spots in a few industries where production was curtailed, and these volume declines may have been accompanied by a decline in the rate o f productivity increase, i f not an actual decline in the level o f produ o tivity. It should be noted in this connection that volume o f output did not expand at a high rate in 1956, and it is not unusual for the rate o f productivity growth to slacken off during periods o f moderate production gains. It is possible that the much larger than usual increase in employment during 1956 may have; required adjustments in some plants and industries, particularly in view o f the' large increase in employment which occurred in 1955, foUowing the recession o f 1954. As a final word o f caution, and to repeat the warnings made earlier in the state ment, these estimates o f recent productivity trends are based on preliminary production and man-hour data, all o f which are subject to revision. IV . W age D evelo pm en ts, 1956 a n d 1957 The past year Wage-rate increases negotiated in 1956 tended to be higher than those agreed to in 1955 and, as in 1955, were generally accompanied by changes in one or more supplementary benefits. There was some reduction in the number o f major agreements concluded during the year as compared with 1955; this decline was due to the fact that fewer large agreements were subject to negotiation in 1956. (Most o f the long-term contracts—notably those in the automobile, farm equip ment, and trucking industries—that had been in existence prior to 1955 were renegotiated in that year and were not subject to reopening in 1956.) Workers covered by most major agreements not reopened in 1956 received wage rate in creases which had been agreed to earlier. Negotiated wage rate increases.— A summary o f a group o f major collective bargaining settlements concluded during 1956 indicates that about 3 out o f 4 o f the workers covered by these settlements received increases in rates o f pay averaging at least 10 cents an hour. Settlements providing average increases of 10, but less than 11, cents appUed to about 4 out o f 10 employees.4 D eferred and cost-of-living increases effective in 1956.— In addition to the workers affected by contracts agreed to in 1956, about 2% million workers received deferred wage increases specified by contracts negotiated in 1955 or earlier years. Many o f these workers also obtained further increases in money wage rates as a result of cost-of-living escalator clauses. The most common wage rate increases resulting from deferred and cost-of-living increases together amounted to about 12 cents an hour. Thus, the automobUe workers received an annual improvement factor increase o f sUghtly more than 6 cents plus escalator adjustments o f 6 cents. H ourly and w eekly earnings.—Hourly earnings, reflecting negotiated wage rate increases as weU as deferred and cost-of-living wage changes and other factors,5 also rose substantiaUy during 1956. In December o f that year hourly earnings o f factory production workers were about 12 cents, or 6.2 percent higher than in December 1955. Weekly earnings advanced by about 5.4 percent on the average. Earnings in most nonmanufacturing industries also rose significantly. For example, between November 1955 and November 1956, hourly earnings o f em ployees in retail trade rose 6 cents (3.9 p ercen t); in gas and electric utilities * This summary covers collective bargaining settlements involving 1,000 or more workers reported in the Bureau of Labor Statistics* Monthly Report on Current Wage Developments. These settlements accounted for a total o f over 5.5 miuion workers. The summary covers all major industry groups except construction, the service trades, finance, and govern ment : information on union scale changes in the construction trades is presented separately on table 5. Information on deferred increases for both 1956 and 1957 as presented later in the text includes construction, but because data are less complete for this industry than for the others included in this summary it is excluded from the table showing deferred increases. Data included for the final 3 months o f 1956 are preliminary. All increases are presented as averages for all workers affected by a settlement. Actually, many settlements provide for varying the cents-per-hour increase among occupations so that not all workers receive the average. 6 Including the effect o f the $1 minimum wage under the Fair Labor Standards Act, increases fo r workers not covered by collective agreements, merit or length o f service pay raises, changes in the composition o f the labor force, and changes in incentive earnings. 98 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT the increase amounted to 12 cents, or 5.6 percent over the yea r; and in bituminous coal mining hourly earnings rose about 29 cents, or 10.9 percent. (See table 4 and charts 5A, B, and O.) , , 4 . —Average hourly earnings o f production w orkers or nonsupervisory em ployees in selected industries annual averages, 1955 and 1956 and Novem ber 1955 and 1956 T a b le 1956 Industry Novem Annual Novem ber 1 average1 ber I I§ | So Mining: Metal.................................................................. $2.34 Anthracite. , „ 2.71 Bituminous CO&l.. „ 2.95 Contract construction_________________________ _ 2.81 Nonhnllding construction 2.55 2.87 Building construction Generafcontractors________________________ 2.70 Special trade contractors____________________ 2.99 Manufacturing________________________________ 2.03 Durable goods_____________________________ 2.16 •Nondurable goods__________________________ 1.85 Ordnance and accessories_____________ ______ 2.25 . Food and kindred products__________ _______ 1.91 Tobacco manufactures______________________ 1.44 Textile mill products__________ ____________ 1.50 Apparel and other finished textile products........ 1.47 Lumber and wood products_________________ 1.76 Furniture and fixtures______________________ 1.71 Paper and allied products___________________ 1.98 Printing__________________________________ 2.45 Chemicals and allied products_______________ 2.13 Products of petroleum and coal______________ 2.57 Rubber products___________________________ 2.19 Leather and leather products________________ 1.52 Stone, clay, and glass products_______________ 1.99 Primary metal industries____________ _______ 2.44 Fabricated metal products__________________ 2.13 Machinery (except electrical)________________ 2.25 Electrical machinery_______________________ 2.04 Transportation equipment__________________ 2.39 Instruments and related products____________ 2.04 Miscellaneous manufacturing industries_______ 1.78 Class I railroads..................... .................................. (*) Local railways_______________________________ ; 1.98 Communication: Telephone____________ ____________________ 1.88 Telegraph_________________________________ 2.02 Other public utilities: Gas and electric utilities........ 2.27 Wholesale and retail trade: Wholesale trade____________________________ 2.04 Retail trade_______________________________ 1.58 Service and miscellaneous: Laundries 1.06 1.28 9! 1955 Annual average Percent change average 1955 to average 1956 $2.31 2.61 2.81 2.74 2.49 2.80 2.64 2.92 1.98 2.10 1.81 2.19 1.85 1.44 1.45 1.44 1.76 1.69 1.94 2.42 2.10 2.54 2.17 1.50 1.95 2.37 2.07 2.21 1.98 2.31 2.01 1.75 <’> A 1.96 $2.27 2.55 2.66 2.65 2.40 2.71 2.58 2.80 1.93 2.05 1.74 2.10 1.80 1.33 1.42 1.36 1.69 1.65 1.87 2.36 2.04 2.41 2.17 1.44 1.90 2.31 2.03 2.15 1.91 2.30 1.94 1.69 1.98 1.90 $2.19 2.53 2.56 2.60 2.36 2.66 2.52 2.77 1.88 2.01 1.71 2.05 1.75 1.33 1.39 1.35 1.69 1.62 1.83 2.35 1.99 2.36 2.10 1.41 1.85 2.24 1.98 2.09 1.88 2.23 1.91 1.66 1.95 1.87 +5.5 +3.2 +9.8 +5.4 +5.5 +5.3 +4.8 +5.4 +5.3 +4.5 +5.8 +6.8 +5.7 +813 +4.3 +6.7 +4.1 +4.3 +6.0 +3.0 +5,5 +7.6 +3.3 +6.4 +5.4 +5.8 +4.5 +5.7 +5.3 +3.6 +5.2 +5.4 1.86 1.97 2.22 1.88 1.87 2.15 1.82 1.87 2.10 +2.2 +5.3 +5.7 2.02 1.57 1.94 1.52 1.91 1.50 +5.8 +4.7 1.05 1.26 1.02 1.20 1.01 1.20 +4.0 +5.0 1Preliminary. * Not available. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, U . S. Department of Labor. Union wage scales in construction During 1956 union scales in the construction trades in major cities in the United States rose approximately 14 cents an hour as compared with 10 cents in 1955. As table 5 indicates, over 4 out o f 10 o f these scales were increased at least 15 cents an hour during 1956 as compared with 1 out o f 5 in 1955. The most common single increase in 1956 was 15 cents an hour, the change in aboijt 1 out o f 5 union scales; in 1955 the single most frequent increase amounted to 10 cents an hour. 99 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT T a b le 5 .—Percentage distribution o f changes in union wage scales in 7 construc tion trades in m ajor cities,11955 and 1956 Cents-per-hour increases Percentage of scales In— 1956 All scales............... All Increases.......... Under 5.0.............. 5.0 and under 10.0.. 5.0— .............. 7. 5 10.0 and under 15.0. 10.0.................. 12. 5 15.0 and under 20.0. 15. 0 20.0 and under 25.0. 20. 0 25.0 and over......... 25.0................. No change............. *100 77 2 18 8 7 38 23 11 12 9 4 3 4 3 21 87 1 12 5 5 30 17 9 24 19 9 7 11 8 13 i The 7 trades studied were bricklayers, carpenters, electricians, painters, plasterers, plumbers, and build ing laborers. The information relates to changes effective during the year regardless of when they were 2Because of rounding, sums of individual items do not necessarily equal the totals. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, U. S. Department of Labor. Unlike most years, 1956 evidenced a change in almost a fifth o f the scales in the fourth quarter o f the year. The increase in average hourly rates during the fourth quarter o f 1956 amounted to 2.8 cents, approximately double that registered in the corresponding quarter o f 1955. Supplementary benefits.—About 3 out o f 4 o f the major agreements concluded in 1956 liberalized or added one or more supplementary benefits in addition to increasing wage rates. Health and welfare benefits were most frequently affected. Changes in provisions for paid vacations, paid holidays, and pensions also were frequent. Supplemental unemployment benefit plans were adopted in a number o f major industries, notably steel, aluminum, and rubber. Spread o f long-term agreem ents.— A notable feature o f bargaining in 1956, as in 1955, was the spread o f long-term agreements specifying wage-rate increases for a period o f 2,3, or even 5 years. Settlements covering about half the workers affected by all major agreements concluded during 1956 were negotiated for a period o f more than a year and specified increases to go into effect in subsequent contract years. Among the industries in which such contracts were negotiated in 1956 were basic steel, aluminum, meat packing, railroads, and nonferrous metals. In addition, many o f these agreements incorporated cost-of-living esca lator clauses and thus made provision for the protection o f the real value o f the wage rates o f the workers covered by the contracts. The resurgence o f interest in cost-of-living escalation that accompanied the growth o f long-term agree ments brought the total coverage o f escalator clauses to a level equaling or slightly exceeding their previous peak (in 1952) of about 3.8 million workers. The wage outlook D eferred increases.— Since many o f the contracts concluded in 1955 and 1956 specified wage increases to go into effect in future years, the magnitude o f the 1957 wage movement can be in part anticipated with reasonable accuracy. As pointed out above, however, many o f these long-term contracts also contain costof-living escalator clauses; hence, the exact change in money wage rates for most o f the workers affected will depend on changes in the level o f retail prices. Another area o f uncertainty regarding the precise magnitude o f the 1957 wage movement arises from the fact that a substantial number o f major collective bargaining agreements are due to expire or are subject to reopening on wages during the year. Among the industries in which important union contracts per mit wage negotiations during 1957 are petroleum, rubber, lumber, chemicals, textiles, coal mining,6 paper, telephone and other utilities, trade, and construc «In this industry workers will receive an increase in April 1957 as a result of 1956 negotiations, but the agreements are subject to renegotiation on or after September 30, 1957, upon 60-day notice. 100 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT tion. The extent to which wage increases will be negotiated in these situations will clearly be affected by the general economic climate and business conditions in each o f these industries. Existing provisions for deferred increases in other industries will probably have some indirect effect on these negotiations. Within the framework o f these limitations, a summary o f the increases al ready specified for 1957 may provide some clue as to the nature o f the changes in money wages that may occur more generally during the year. By the beginning o f 1957 there were at least 550 major bargaining situations covering at least 5 million workers on which agreement had already been reached regarding specific wage increases to go into effect during the year. Some deferred increases will go into effect in almost every industry group, but the bulk o f the workers affected are concentrated in metalworking, construction, transportation, food, and mining. Roughly half o f the workers scheduled to receive deferred increases are employed in the automobile, farm equipment, electrical equipment, aircraft, primary metals (steel, aluminum, and other nonferrous metals), and other metalworking industries. More than a fifth are in transportation, notably railroads and trucking. Generally, deferred increases are somewhat lower on the average than those scheduled to go into effect during the first year o f a long-term contract These differences in magnitude are due to two factors: In some cases (e. g., in the automobile and farm-equipment contracts negotiated in 1955) skilled workers received greater increases in the initial than in subsequent contract years; in others (e. g., basic steel, aluminum, railroads, and some construction agreements), the general wage increase fo r all workers was higher in the first than in subse quent contract years. Nonwage items, notably various supplementary benefits, typically became applicable at the time o f contract negotiations, thus further enhancing the value o f the initial “ package” settlement. Pay increases already specified fo r 1957 will generally amount to 5 but less than 11 cents an hour; increases o f this magnitude are provided by contracts covering 9 out o f 10 workers who are to receive deferred pay advances. About 2.5 million workers (h alf the workers scheduled to benefit from deferred increases in 1957) will be covered by pay advances o f 6 but less than 8 cents an hour. Rate increases amounting to 9 but less than 10 cents are scheduled to go into effect for approximately three-fourths o f a million workers. The deferred increases due in 1957 are summarized in tables 6a and 6b. T a b l e 6 - A .— -Deferred wage increases scheduled to go into effect in 1957 in situations affecting 1,000 or more workers in manufacturing and selected nonmanufacturing industries Approximate number of workers affected (in thousands) i 534 210 95 358 1,165 486 76 722 74 7 67 7 107 3 22 11 4 9 1 1 6 11 1 Because of rounding, sums of individual items do not necessarily equal totals. 2 Does not include construction industry settlements. 3 Includes a few settlements in the following industry groups for which separate data are not provided: 19,000workers in textiles, 28,000 in apparel, 10,000 in lumber and furniture, 5.000 in rubber, 11,000 in leather and leather products, 44,000 in stone, clay, and glass, and 2.000 workers in miscellaneous manufacturing. 44 25 1,492 55 56 245 1,121 355 42 675 59 10 50 49 35 794 203 38 220 2 230 200 Warehous- Trans Public Situa- Work utili tions2 ers aftion ties J & - porta sale and retail trade 92 1,106 65 100 100 42 14 7 770 197 6 16 22 6 73 * Data for nonferrous mining included with metalworking. « Less than % of 1 percent. Sourco: Bureau of Labor Statistics, U. S. Department of Labor. 27 28 6 17 7 (5) 1 1 PRESIDENT 3,020 145 407 1,199 1,280 279 759 294 24 33 10 82 Min ing * THE 14 4,512 Total Paper Print Chem nonand ing and icals Metal- manupub work facturallied and ing ing prod lishing allied studied ucts prod ucts OF 71 147 103 35 87 27 5 Food and kin dred prod ucts REPORT Total............. ....... Under 5 cents____ _____ 5 but less than 6 cents... 6 but less than 7 cents... 7 but less than 8 cents. _. 8 but less than 9 cents... 9 but less than 10 cents.. 10 but less than 11 cents. 11 but less than 12 cents. 12 but less than 13 cents. 13 cents and over.......... . Amount not specified- _. Num ber of situa All Total tions2 indus manu tries 2 factur ing 3 ECONOMIC Amount of average wage increase Percentage o f- O 102 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Number of workers who will be affected by deferred increases in selected union wage scales in the construction industry due in 1957 T a b l e 6 - b .— Increase in scales Number of workers Total............................................ 362.000 Under 5 cents per hour.......................... 5 and under 7 cents per hour-------------7 and under 9 cents per hour...... .......... 9 and under 11 cents per hour............... 8,000 50.000 26.000 115.000 Increase in scales Number of workers 11 and under 13 cents per hour_______ 13 and under 15 cents per hour_______ 15 and under 17 cents per hour_______ 17 cents per hour and over___ ____ Not specified.......................................... 10,000 22,000 70,000 14.500 46.500 Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, U. S. Department of Labor. Cost-of-living escalator clauses.—As previously noted, the precise changes in money rates of pay for most workers covered by deferred increases will depend on changes in the level of retail prices, since a substantial majority of the work ers who will receive deferred increases are also covered by cost-of-living escalator clauses. By the beginning of 1957, as previously pointed out, the real rates o f pay o f at least 3.8 million workers were protected by clauses providing for periodic adjustments in wage rates geared to changes in the Bureau o f Labor Statistics Consumer Price Index (table 7.). Almost all of the agreements with cost-of-living escalator clauses provide for adjusting wage rates with price changes on a quarterly or semiannual basis. Most o f the contracts specify that all workers (from skilled to unskilled) shall receive the same cents-an-hour adjustment in rates o f pay. The agreements affecting the vast majority o f workers under cost-of-living escalators provide for a 1-cent change in wage rates for a change of 0.4 to 0.5 o f a point in the price index. This means that these escalator provisions call generally for a change in rates of pay o f roughly 1 percent for a 1-percent change in the Consumer Price Index. T able 7.—Estimated number of workers covered by cost-of-living escalator clauses, Jan. 1,19571 Industry All industries____________________ Industries in which major groups of these workers are concentrated: Automobiles and parts............... Railroads..................................... Steel (basic steel and steel fabri cating). ^Electrical machinery.................. Trucking and transit.................. Aircraft and parts....................... Agricultural machinery.............. Meatpacking............................... Aluminum................................... Iron ore mining........................... Estimated number of workers covered by escalator clauses * (total) Most common types of escalator adjustments Frequency Amount of adjustment *3,840,000 1 cent for 0.5-point change in B LSCPI. Semiannual. __ 1 cent for each 0.5-point change. 850.000 640.000 ....... do.............. 2 cents for each 0.9-ppint change (1 cent for alternate 0.4- and 0.5-point increase. Decreases to occur only if index declines at least 0.9-point). Formulas vary. 390.000 Quarterly 270.000 Semiannual... 1 cent for each 0.55-point change. 1 cent for each 0.5-point change. 200.000 Quarterly. 115.000 ____do............. 1 cent for 0.5-point change. 100.000 Semiannual. __ 1 cent for 0.5-point: increase; de creases computed differently. 60,000 ....... do.............. Same as steel. Do. 30,000 ....... do.............. 910.000 Quarterly....... i Based on situations affecting 1,000 or more workers as reported in the Bureau of Labor Statistics Monthly Report on Current Wage Developments. * Includes over 3.5 million workers covered by collective agreements and about 300,000 workers not covered by such agreements. 8 Includes workers in some industries not shown separately. 103 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT V. F a c t o r s A f f e c t in g P r ic e s in 1956 After several years of relative stability, the major price indexes moved upward in 1956. We are now in the third period of general price rises since the end of World War II (see chart 8). The first, the immediate postwar period, was one where the increases reflected the influence of postwar civilian shortages plus the end o f price controls. The second period o f general price increase was the direct result of the Korean conflict as a result of both hoarding and the diversion o f resources towards military activity. In the current period the general rise appears to be mainly the result of strictly civilian forces with no direct military overtones. A host o f factors can be pointed to as playing a role in the recent price rise, but behind the great bulk of them lies the fact that strong and rising demand, especially for capital goods, has placed such great strains upon our plant and manpower capacity as to foster an accumulation of cost increases. These cost increases— some actual and some anticipated—have been pyramided as they were passed on through the business structure. Wholesale price index.— The upward movement o f primary prices began in mid-1955. In the following 18 months, this index lias risen more than 5 percent, and the group o f commodities exclusive o f farm and foods was up about 8 percent. Seven of the 13 nonagricultural commodity groups o f the wholesale price index reached new post-World War II highs in the last quarter o f 1956 (see table 8). The significant increases were mainly but not exclusively among the durable goods, particularly the producers’ goods, such as machinery and equipment, and the important metal materials. T able 8 . —Primary market price indexes for major commodity groups, highs and lows, 1954-56 High point Low point Group Index All commodities....................... ................. ...... Farm products________ ____________ ______ Processed foods___________ __ ____________ All but farm and foods__ _________________ Textile products and apparel-........._- ......... . Hides, skins, leather and products........... ...... Fuel, power, and lighting materials............... Chemicals and allied products............. ......... Rubber and rubber products................. ......... Lumber and products.......... ........................... Pulp, paper, and products_________________ Metals and metal products............................ . Machinery and motive products..................... Furniture and other household durables........ Nonmetallic minerals, structural.................... Tobacco manufacturers and bottled beverages. Miscellaneous products__________________ Date Index Date 116.5 117.6 112.9 124.6 115.9 127.7 113.1 112.6 153.0 128.5 128.1 152.4 143.5 121.4 131. 5 123.6 February 1951.......... March 1951............... February 1951.......... December 19561____ March 1951............... February 1951.......... December 19561....... February 1951.......... January 1951............ April 1956................. October 1956............ December 19561....... December 19561....... December 1956 i....... October 1956....... .... December 1956 * 92.3 82.9 94.0 91.8 92.8 91.8 82.7 92.0 94.1 84.9 95.7 87.9 89.7 93.8 90.9 96.8 January 1947. December 1955. January 1950. January 1947. May 1950. December 1954. January 1947. March 1950. July 1947. January 1947. August 1949. January 1947. January 1947. January 1947. January 1947. January 1947. 120.0 January 1948______ 87.7 February 1947. * Preliminary. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, U. S. Department of Labor. Two important commodity groups— chemicals and textiles, including apparel— held fairly stable over the year. To a considerable extent, this reflected diverg ent trends within the groups: for instance, industrial chemicals rose while fertilizer prices fell, and wool products increased substantially in price in mid1956, but cotton products and synthetic textiles price declined. And two groups— rubber and lumber— were lower at year end than a year earlier, reflect ing changes in the demand.for those particular commodities. Actually, as a study o f the chart on wholesale prices shows (chart 8 ), the upward pressure on industrial prices was at work well before the overall index started moving up in mid-1955. But these pressures had been offset in the grand total by the weakness o f farm products and foods. Prices of farm prod ucts fell steeply to a low in December 1955, then recovered somewhat in 1956. Processed-food prices, which had drifted downward at a slower pace, also made gains in 1956. Thus, the strengthening of the agricultural sectors of the index, 104 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT reflecting Government programs and export demand which helped to cut down supplies, came at the same time as the industrial price rise was accelerating. Analysis of wholesale-price movements by degree o f fabrication, after elim ination o f the food and feedstuffs, indicates that the remaining crude materials, which account for less than 5 percent of the total wholesale price index, were the first to turn upward after the post-Korea adjustment. The intermediate and finished durable goods have been the major influences in the upswing since mid-1955 (see chart 9 ). The producers-finished goods, with a weight o f about 10 percent, have made by far the sharpest rises in the past year and a half. At the other extreme, the finished consumer nondurables, constituting about 15 percent of the total, have held fairly steady. Consumer price index.— The average of all consumer prices began moving upward in the spring of 1956, after 4 years o f exceptional overall stability (charts 10 and 11). During this 4-year period, services and rents had been rising steadily, but declines in commodity prices had offset their advance. This past spring, however, the declining trend in commodity prices was reversed. The most important shift was in foods, with meats recovering from an abnormally low level, and fruits and vegetables also going up substantially. The appearance in the autumn of the new 1957 automobiles, at substantially higher prices, caused a rise in the transportation index. In December, new cars were priced 6.5 per cent above the comparable models of a year earlier. Commodities as a group rose 3 percent from April to December; this was their first significant increase since 1951. Services (medical care, personal care, transportation, laundry, cleaning, etc.) rose nearly 2 percent over this same 8-month period— about the same rate of rise as during 1955. Despite the recent rise, commodities were costing the consumer less than they did 4 years earlier; only apparel (mainly shoes) had a higher average price than in December 1952, although still below the postwar peak. Services, on the other hand, were up about 12 percent, in these past 4 years and rent about 11 percent. Thus, the 1956 rise in consumer prices was due in part to a return o f commodity prices to earlier levels, but also in part to the steady rise in the costs of the various services. In this latter connection, chart 11 shows that the costs o f services and rents still have increased less since the pre-World W ar II period than have commodities. Forces currently at work.—There are, of course, numerous demand and supply forces at the individual commodity and group levels which have not been discussed systematically in this review. The behavior of the overall indexes, however, makes certain factors abundantly clear. One of these is the especially strong demand for investment goods, which has raised the whole cost structure o f the industries producing metal goods and nonmetallic structural minerals. Another is that the straining o f capacity in some industries and areas tends to result in cost increases which then fan out into other industries and areas. Still another is that, when wages rise because o f a variety o f factors not connected with direct productivity gains, they are added into prices as businesses seek to protect their profit margin. In addition, there has been the special Impact of the Suez situation upon a few commodities. Underlying all o f these factors has been the continuing strong demands arising from our rising standard o f living, our increasing population, and our expanding labor force. So far as the immediate future is concerned, if the demand factors which gave rise to the price increases show no further strengthening—in other words, if investment demand flattens out and if consumer buying follows the income curve and consumer credit is expanded only moderately— there may well be more stability in the price situation. As o f this time, signs o f upward price pressures are still evident in those sectors of the economy where demand con tinues to burgeon; signs of price weakness are appearing only in those fields where demand is less urgent than it formerly was. In addition, there is no indication o f any reversal o f the long-run uptrend in the cost of services; the demand for personal and professional services is continually rising. At the same time, price declines in the agricultural sector are no longer offsetting increases elsewhere. 105 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT A n n u a l C h a n g e s in T o t a l L a b o r F o r c e , b y Sex A C T U A L COMPARED WITH PRO JECTED AN N U AL AVERAG E » 9 5 0 'I 9 5 6 MALES ImNL H i;;;i l'/A XL %'/A tz\ W/A W/A M l Source: m U. & Bureou of the Census-, Bureau of Labor Statistics 106 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT C o m p a r is o n o f A c t u a l a n o P r o j e c t e o To t a l L a b o r Fo r c e U N ITEO ST ATES DEPAR TM EN T OF LABOR S U R E A U O F L A S O ft S T A T I S T I C S Sourct: U.S. Burtou of th« Census* Bursou of Labor Statistic* ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT EMPLOYEES IN NONAGRICULTURAL ESTABLISHMENTS BY MAJOR INDUSTRY DIVISION «*m&sumMfAniKKior utot LATEST DATAi 0C0CM8CR I 9 9 « 107 108 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT E m p l o y m e n t a n d A v e r a g e W e e k l y H o u r s o f P r o d u c t io n W o r k e r s in D u r a b l e a n d N o n d u r a b l e G o o d s M a n u f a c t u r in g BY MONTHS, 1 9 4 7 - 5 6 (Adjusted for Seasonal Variation) UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR •UREAU O f LABOR S TA T IS T IC S DATA FOR NOVEMBER AND OECEMSER ISSS: PR ELIM IN ARY N OTE: SEASON AL A D JU S T M E N TS FOR AVERAGE W EEKLY HOURS ARE PRELIMINARY. Souroe: Bureau of Labor Statlctlci ECONOMIC REPORT OF T H E PRESIDENT 109 A v e r a g e H o u r l y E a r n in g s in S e l e c t e d I n d u s t r i e s 1952-54 Annually: 1955-56 Monthly 'Dollars UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR t U A tA U O f LABOR S T A T IS T IC * Dollars LATEST OATA: MANUFACTURE# - DECEMBER 1*36 NONMANU?ACTUA4Ma - NOVEMBES I9SS ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 110 S A v e r a g e H o u r l y E a r n i n g s in D u r a b l e G o o d s In d u s t r ie s elected 1 9 5 2 -5 4 Annually, 1 9 5 5 -5 6 Monthly Dollars Electrical Machinery ‘52 '53 ‘54. 1955 U N IT E D STATES DEPARTM ENT OF LABOR BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS 1956 LATEST DATA: DECEMBER 194ft 111 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT S A v e r a g e Hourly elec t ed Nondurable E a r n i n g s in G o o d s In d u s t r i e s 1952-54 Annually-, 1 9 5 5 -5 6 M onthly DO LL AR S ' 5 2 ' 53'54 1955 1956 '52 *53'54 1955 1956 L A T E S T D A TA : 0CCCM 6CR <956 112 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Fa c t o r y W e e k l y E a r n in g s , G r o s s a n d N e t S p e n d a b l e * COMPARED WITH REAL NET SPENDABLE EARNINGS EXPRESSED IN 1947*49 DOLLARS Dollars Production Worker With Three Dependents LA TES T UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR BUREAU OF LABOR S TA TISTIC S OATAt OECEMSER |»SS *Earnings after deduction of Federal Income and Social Security taxes Dollars 11& ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT AVERAGE WEEKLY EARNINGS AND "REAL"WEEKLY EARNINGS IN MANUFACTURING I9M 1920 1925 1930 I93S 1940 1945 1950 1955 1957 LATEST DATA: I9M Preliminary # MONEY EARNINGS ADJUSTED FOR CHANGES IN COST 0 ¥ LIVING 1947-49=100 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE P R E S ID E N T WHOLESALE PRICES 1926 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955 1957 holesale P rice In d e x ECONOMIC SECTOR INOEXES SE L E C T E D GROUPS IN DEX I » 4 7 ~4 » « I 0 0 IN D E X ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE P R E S ID E N T W UNITEO STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR BUREAU O F L A IO R S T A T IS T IC S L A T t S T DATA! DRCCMSER l » S « 1 1 47 49 40 9 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CONSUMER PRICE INDEX FOR WAGE-EARNER AND CLERICAL-WORKER FAMILIES IN U.S. CITIES I- * t t * T ftJW U M O tW M * 117 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CONSUMER PRICE INDEX SPECIAL GROUPINGS INOEX 240 220 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 1939 *40 '41 ’42 ’43 *44 ’45 *46 *47 *48 '49 '50 ’51 '52 *53 ’54 *55 1956 w nep m j n p m m iiin of u i o i t A T I ST OAT'*' DECEMBER IS 118 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT The C h a ir m a n . Without objection, we will ask each one of our witnesses to proceed with his 8-minute statement, and in that way we will make sure that no one is slighted. I f we were to stop now I am apprehensive that we would possibly take up too much of the time with one witness. Mr. T a l l e . M ot I make an explanatory statement? I must appear before the Rules Committee at 10:30. I f that committee does not de tain me long I will return before this morning’s hearing is completed. Chairman P a t m a n . W e understand your situation, and thank you, Dr. Talle. Mr. Paradiso. STATEMENT OF LOUIS J. PARADISO, ASSISTANT DIRECTOR, AND CHIEF STATISTICIAN, OFFICE OF BUSINESS ECONOMICS, DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE Mr. P a r a d is o . I am Louis J. Paradiso, Assistant Director, of the Office of Business Economics of the Department of Commerce. I have been asked to present a translation of the Government budgets into national income and product account basis. I want to discuss first the Federal budget expenditures and their translation into the national income and product account. In 1956 the total governments, Federal, State, and local, purchased goods and services which amounted to about one-fifth of the total pro duction of all goods and services in the Nation. The Federal Gov ernment alone purchased goods and services amounting to about 11 percent. In order to get some idea as to what the Government take is likely to be of the total output of this country in 1957, it is necessary to trans late the Government budgets into the national income and product account. Therefore it is this kind of a statement which I will try to present so that we may be able to get an idea as to what the Gov ernment’s total take would be of the output of the Nation. First, I will deal with the Federal Government, and it will be in connection with the purchases of goods and services. These pur chases are derived by a rearrangement of the items given in the budg et, eleminating expenditures which do not represent purchases of goods and services. These excluded items involving such major types of expenditures as transfer payments, grants-in-aid, and interest pay ments, are not part of our estimates of purchases of goods and services. In the calendar year 1956, Federal purchases of goods and serv ices amounted to $47 billion. The rate of purchasing increased after the middle of the year to reach an annual rate of $48.3 billion in the fourth quarter. The budget implies that in calendar year 1957 Gov ernment purchases of goods and services would be $49.5 billion or $2.5 billion more than the total of calendar year 1956 and $1 billion above the fourth quarter rate. Thus it is clear that the implication of the budget on Government purchases of goods and services is for a very modest increase from the fourth quarter 1956 rate. Practically the entire 1957 rise in purchases of goods and services is in the items encompassed in the national security expenditures. In calendar 1956 these expenditures totaled $41.6 billion and in the ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 119 fourth quarter of that year the rate was $43 billion. The budget pro grams call for an estimate of national-security purchases of over $44 billion in calendar year 1957. Other purchases are expected to show relatively small changes. Now, with respect to the total Federal expenditures, here again I am talking about these expenditures in relation to the national income and product accounts. I f we add the other type of expenditures to purchases of goods and services, the result represents the total exr penditures of the Federal Government on the basis of these accounts. These expenditures by the way closely approximate those in the cash budget except for certain conceptional adjustments involving mainly capital transactions and all loans except those related to CCC operations. Total Federal expenditures on the income and product account in the fiscal year 1956 were $70 billion. In fiscal year 1957, they are estimated at nearly $75 billion. In fiscal year 1958, the estimate is close to $80 billion. These compare for the respective fiscal years with cash budget expenditures of $72.5 billion in fiscal year 1956, and $78 billion in fiscal 1957, and nearly $83 billion in fiscal year 1958. Now let us move over to the Federal receipts, and here again we go through a translation of these receipts into the national income and product basis. These are estimated on the basis of the budget pres entation which implied a personal income of $340 billion in calendar year 1957 compared with an estimated total of $325 billion in calendar year 1956 and a rate of $333 billion in the fourth quarter of 1956. Also implied in these receipts is the fact that corporate profits before taxes were assumed at $44 billion in calendar 1957, compared with about $43 billion in calendar 1956. On the income and product basis, Federal receipts amounted to $75.5 billion in fiscal year 1956. They are estimated at a little over $80 billion in fiscal 1957, and $84 billion in fiscal year 1958. These re ceipts also approximate those on a cash budget basis. The main difference between the two sets of accounts is that on the income and product account, corporate taxes are included on a liability basis rather than on a colection basis as is done in estimating cash receipts. The major source of increase in the receipts in the current and next fiscal years is expected to arise from personal taxes. Smaller advances are expected in indirect business taxes and in con tributions for social insurance. Thus to summarize, on an income and product account, a surplus of $5.5 billion is estimated for fiscal year 1957 and nearly $4.5 billion in fiscal year 1958. These may be compared with a surplus of almost $5.5 billion in the past fiscal year, namely 1956. These surpluses are somewhat higher than the cor responding surpluses on a cash basis and substantially above those on the administrative budget basis. Now, let me turn to the State and local governments and just a word on the expectations of these bodies. For State and local governments we had data developed through fiscal year 1957. Basing the estimates for calendar year 1957 on the data for the fiscal year and the recent trends, we have the following results: . (1) Purchases of goods and services by all State and local govern ments have been rising at a fairly constant rate in the past few years. 120 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT In calendar 1956 they amounted to $32.8 billion and we estimate that in o-n-lftTnfar 1957 they will total about $35.5 billion, namely about $2.7 billion more than last year. The increase will be about equally divided between expenditures for construction activity and for employee compensation. (2) For other expenditures, such as transfer payments and net interest paid, not much change is expected from current rates. In calendar 1956 total expenditures on an income and product basis amounted to $35.8 billion. W e are estimating that in calendar 1957, these will amount to $38 billion. (3) The receipts of State and local governments on an income and product basis amounted to $33.6 billion in calendar year 1956. As with the Federal receipts, the major adjustment from the cash receipts is placing corporate profit taxes on an accrual basis instead of a col lections basis. In calendar 1957, the total receipts of State and local governments are estimated at about $36 billion. These estimates imply a deficit in calendar 1957 for State and local governments on income and product account of slightly more than the deficit in calendar 1956, which was about $1.5 billion. Finally, I want to make a few comments with respect to the recent trend of prices. A record output of goods and services in 1956 lifted the value of the gross national product to $412 billion, more than $21 billion, or 5% percent above 1955. In the last half of 1956, the rise in business activity accelerated, resulting in an increase in the gross national product to a seasonably adjusted rate of $424 billion in the fourth quarter. About half of the 1956 increase in the gross national product reflected higher prices so that the gain in real output amounted to slightly more than 2y 2 percent. The composite of gross national product prices reflects price move ments in relative proportion to the gross national product expendi ture groups and therefore is heavily weighted by consumer price changes. Following 3 years of relative stability, this composite price increased nearly 3 percent last year. Consumer prices which have been stable since early 1953 increased beginning in April of last year and by December of 1956 had risen nearly 3 percent above a year •earlier. A ll major components contributed to this advance. The rise in consumer prices in the latter part of 1956 was moderated to a ■degree by relative stability in the prices of food products. Whole sale prices in December of last year were 4 percent above a year earlier, following a fairly steady rise throughout 1956. There was substan tial variation, however, in the relative pressure on different com ponents during the year. Wholesale farm and food prices rose rather sharply in the first 6 months of 1956, and thereafter either stabilized or tended downward. Industrial prices tended to rise somewhat faster in the latter part of 1956. An important factor in these increases was the general strong demand for goods which persisted throughout the year, and advances in the cost of production. Thank you. (Letter from Department of Commerce, Office of Business Eco nomics, dated January 18, 1957, to chairman, Joint Economic Com mittee, follow s:) 121 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT D e p a r t m e n t of C o m m erce , O f f i c e o f B u s in e s s E con o m ics, Washington, D.C., January 18,1957. Hon. P a u l H. D o u g la s , Chairman, Joint Economic Committee, United States Senate, Washington,, D. O. D e a r M r. C h a ir m a n : The enclosed table showing Federal Government re ceipts and expenditures is furnished in accordance with the letter of January 16 by the Secretary o f Commerce in reply to your letter of January 7. The table shows three measures o f the budget. The top two are the adminis trative and cash budgets, taken directly from the budget o f the United States Government for the Fiscal Year ending June 30, 1958. The last measure repre sents a translation o f receipts and expenditures given in the budget to the na tional income and product account basis. In accordance with your request for State and local government receipts and expenditures, the Governments Division o f the Bureau o f the Census has provided data which indicate the following on a national income and product basis: for fiscal year 1956, receipts o f $32.5 billion and expenditures of $33.7 billion; for fiscal year 1957, receipts of $35.2 billion and expenditures of $36.3 billion. The amount o f detail furnished has been worked out in consultation by tech nicians o f our staff with Mr. Knowles. I f we can be o f further help to you, please let us know. Sincerely yours, M . J o sep h M e e h a n , Director. Federal Government receipts and expenditures: Administrative budget, cash budget j and national income and product account: 1956-58 [Billions of dollars] Fiscal years Actual 1956 Estimated 1957 Administrative budget: Receipts____________ ________________ __________________ Expenditures__________ — . _____ ____________________ _ 1958 68.1 66.5 70.6 68.9 73.6 71.8 1.6 1.7 1.8 Cash budget: Receipts _______________________ ____________ ________ Expenditures_______ . . . . . ___ ——__—_- _- _____ - ___ - ___ 77.1 72.6 81.7 78.2 85.9 82.9 SlirplnS-.. t __ „^rr . t* , , Surplus___________ —— ______ — _______ - __ — _— _ 4.5 3.5 3.0 National income and product account: Receipts_______________________ ______ _______ _________ Expenditures_________________________ ____________ __________ 75.4 70.0 80.3 74.8 84.0 79.7 Surplus_________ —___ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . _— ________ — 5.4 5.5 4.3 Source: Administrative and cash budgets from the Budget of the United States Government for the Fiscal Year Ending June 30,1958; national income and product account data from the U. S. Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics, statistics for 1957 and 1958 based on estimates in the budget. U. S. Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics, Jan. 18, 1957. Chairman P a t m a n . Thank y o u , sir. Next we have Mr. Martin Gainsbrugh, chief economist of the National Industrial Conference Board. STATEMENT OF MARTIN It. GAINSBRITGH, CHIEF ECONOMIST OF THE NATIONAL INDUSTRIAL CONFERENCE BOARD Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I am Martin Gainsbrugh, chief economist of the National Industrial Conference Board, and I am honored to be back with you again for, I believe, the eighth time. 87624—57------9 122 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT I have a long statement, but I would like to concentrate my oral comments on possibly the most controversial aspect of the outlook for 1957; namely, the trend for private business investment. I have some additional comments on residential construction, inventories, and net foreign investment in my full statement which is submitted for the record. To give you my conclusions first—particularly in the light of the uncertainties of the opening weeks of 1957—the outlook for business spending for plant and equipment for 1957 is good. A t least this is how all three existing barometers of private capital formation now read in early 1957. These three barometers are the Department of Commerce and the SEC survey of expected capital expenditures for the first quarter of 1957, the McGraw-Hill survey of expected capital expenditures for the full year of 1957, and the latest innovation touched off by the research of your own task forces several years ago, the newly initiated National Industrial Conference Board’s quarterly survey of capital appropriations for the 1,000 largest manufacturing companies. A ll three surveys point in one direction: A good year for plant and equipment. In the current quarter, private industry expects to spend some $38 billion for plant and equipment, a new high. This is indicated on page 10 of your Economic Indicators if you would like to look at that series. In view of the rapid advance in such spending during 1956, we are already at a higher level than the average of last year, which was only $35 billion. The first quarter rate this year is $38 billion. The current quarterly average for all industry is 8 percent above the 1956 rate. In manufacturing, the current quarter is 9 percent above last year’s average; in public utilities 13 percent, and in railroads, 23 percent. Almost all along the line American business is now spending record amounts in adding to, replacing, and modernizing their plant and equipment. The McGraw-Hill survey furthermore suggests that these dollar amounts may be exceeded— though modestly— later during the year. A s compared with the 8-percent gain over 1956, already experienced in the first quarter, business plans to increase its spending for the year as a whole by some 11 percent. It is important to see this in perspective. In 1956, however, capital outlays rose by 22 percent above the 1955 rate. Thus, even the 11-percent figure Signifies a tendency toward a levelling out of capital expenditures, at a record rate. An immediate area of concern in early 1957— and that may be too strong a word since I do not mean to be too alarming about the year as a whole— relates to capital expenditures by durables manufacturing companies. These expenditures in the current quarter are expected to be below the fourth-quarter rate, the first such decline in the past 2 years. Each of the three surveys on capital spending serves a distinct and significant purpose. First, the Commerce-SEC survey obtains the initial estimate of business programs from 5 to 6 weeks before the quarter actually begins. These are -the figures I was quoting above, in discussing the first quarter of 1957. A t this stage of business plan ning, most of the decisions have been made, so that the expenditures can reasonably be expected to be met. I believe they will be. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 123 Secondly, the McGraw-Hill survey, which provides the earliest available annual expectations data, is a compilation of business plans*. Some of these may already have been formalized in annual capital budgets; some may be close to such formularization; and some may be; of a more speculative nature. The conference board’s new quarterly series on capital appropria tions represents a translation of these annual capital budgets. Each specific project has to be approved by top management before the com pany can place the order and start to spend. Our survey sponsored by Newsweek magazine covers only manufacturing companies, by the way. It indicated a broad upsurge in capital appropriation approvals in the first half of 1956, portending a rise in capital outlays tins year. Backlogs of approved appropriations also rose. However, in the third quarter, the durables manufacturing companies indicated a decline in new appropriation approvals; the soft-goods sector continued to post gains. That is the first such decline in our series, which spans 2 years. It was this decline that raised some question in our mind several months ago, whether during the second half of 1957 capital spending by the durables group might not be facing a reversal in trend. Since then, the first signs of this reversal, very faint to be sure and subject to revision, have already shown up in the governmental estimates of first quarter spending rate. A t the present time, we are engaged in processing our returns for the fourth quarter. Based on replies from only a handful, and of these mostly the smaller and medium sized companies in our group, there has been a rise in new appropriation approvals from the third to the fourth quarter^ but probably of no more than seasonal dimen sions. There usually is an increase in appropriations from the third to fourth quarter. From all indications it would appear that the fourthquarter data will support the barometric readings of the third: a plateau or decline in the appropriations process viewed seasonally. The conference board’s survey thus ties in by and large with the other surveys. Capital outlays by manufacturing industry may level off at a high rate later this year. But that is only 43 percent of all capital outlays. Such nonmanufacturing sectors as public utilities and communications are still planning significant hikes in capital outlay. Translating these surveys of business plans for 1957 into the gross national product account, it would appear that for the year as a whole producers’ durable equipment and nonresidential construction outlay in 1957 would be somewhat above ($1 billion to $2 billion) the fourth* quarter rate. Generally overlooked in the discussion of rising prices during the past year has been the advance of plant and equipment prices. This is no surprise in the face of the surging demands by business for plant and equipment. Apparently, it is a fact of life for businessmen too. They report in the McGraw-Hill survey that they expect to pay 6 per cent higher prices this year than last. Since the fourth-quarter aver age of capital goods prices is already considerably above the annual average, it would appear that business expects these prices to continue to rise, but at a much slower rate. As the Economic Report indicates on page 32, the prices of producers equipment in December of 1956 were already 13 percent above mid-1955. 124 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT On balance, it would appear that very little if any of the modest rise expected in 1957 for capital outlays above the present rates will repre sent a gain in volume. For purposes of appraising 1957 as a whole, I believe the most practical assumption for tne capital goods sector is a continuation of the current level of physical activity. On the basis of the available foreshadowing statistics, little or no improvement in residential home construction can be expected in 1957. Housing starts, F H A applications, VA-appraisal requests, mortgage recordings, and contract awards were weaker in the second half of 1956 than in the first, and this slippage will apparently be reflected in new residential spending at least until June of this year. Housing starts were running at about a 1,135,000 annual rate— seasonally adjusted— in the first 6 months of 1956. In the last 6 months starts were down to a 1,060,000 rate. The number of mort gage recordings of $20,000 or less was 7 percent behind 1955 in the first 6 months of last year. In the 5 months through November, the decline was 9 percent. Contract awards for new residential construction for 37 States east of the Rockies, as reported by F . W . Dodge, show an even sharper drop. Dollar award figures for the last 6 months of 1956 were 13 percent behind the volume recorded in the same months of 1955. The annual joint Bureau of Labor Statistics-Department of Com merce forecast of construction activity calls for 5 percent less dollar spending in home building in 1957 than in 1956, but assumes about 9 percent fewer homes will be built. Dollar spending has fallen less than the number of starts since 1955 because more houses built to sell for over $10,000 are going up. The average proposed selling price of a 1-family house rose about $800 in 1956. This trend is expected to carry over into 1957. A ll of this suggests about 1 million homes in 1957. Some private forecasters would put the figure higher— something over 1.1 million. Some home builders, however, are talking of a figure as low as 850,000 for 1957. It is the consensus in the building trade that the precise level of housing starts in 1957 will depend substantially on conditions in the mortgage market. There are no serious material shortages in sight. Home builders wer$ able to erect 1.3 million units as recently as 1955. Despite the 12 million new housing units erected since 1945, builders feel me need and desire for new housing is far from satiated. The essence is that the outlook is for a lower level of housing starts for 1957 from 1956. In the fourth quarter of 1956, the physical volume of business in ventories rose, for the eighth successive quarter. Net additions to inventory in 1956 amounted to about $3.5 billion— significantly above a rate that could be considered normal secular growth. Because of rising prices, the book value of business inventories evidently rose between $6 billion and $7 billion. Operating rates and sales volume in most industries have also risen, relative to a year ago, and it is apparently agreed by most .analysts that the current level of inventory-sales ratios, while ample, is not excessive. Inventory growth in 1956 was substantial, but it was well proportioned to need: a large part of the total additions to inventory book values occurred in those industries where orders and backlogs were rising sharply. ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT 125 The condition of inventory statistics at the end of 1956 was certainly not alarming. However, there appears to be good reason to think that the present rate of accumulation— which amounts to perhaps over $4 billion on a gross national product basis, and about $8 billion in terms of book value— is likely to dwindle by midyear. And there remains the somewhat less pleasant possibility that if accumulation continues at its present rate for the next two quarters a certain amount o f liquidation may occur late in 1957* The reasons for expecting at least some decline in the present rate of inventory accumulation are— (1) Considerably lower liquidity on the part of corporations, and relatively high borrowing costs, both of which are dissuading business from substantial further net investment in inventory; (2) The fact that in capital goods industries, where a substantial part of recent accumulation has occurred, the rate of ordering is evi dently slowing down, reducing the requirements for forward inventory coverage; and (3) Growing capacity in most industries is progressively eliminating the supply uncertainties which provided some of the incentive for accumulation in late 1955 and 1956. Surveys of expectations with respect to inventory policy contain a rather wide margin o f error, for the obvious reason that inventory policy itself is volatile. However, a survey of over 200 industrial companies conducted by the conference board in late 1956 found that while in 1956 about 70 percent of the companies increased dollar inven tories, and about 15 percent reduced their dollar inventories, only 40 percent expect to continue to increase inventories in the first half of 1957, while 30 percent expect a reduction. Granting the difficulties of expectations data in this area, I believe these percentages correctly reflect a declining interest, on the part of business, in further inventory investment. The inventory outlook for all of 1957 seems to point to a moderately higher book value at the end of the year, but no appreciable change in physical level, and hence something approaching zero in the gross national product inventory component. A continuation of the increase in net foreign investment is likely in 1957. The past year saw net foreign investment reach $1.1 billion (this excludes economic and military aid shipments, which do not give rise to foreign investment as usually defined in our national accounts) , the first time since 1951 that the net foreign investment of the United States has been positive. Probably developments in 1957 make it 'appear unlikely that a like increase will take place in this year, but it does seem likely that foreign investment will continue to increase substantially. The National Foreign Trade Council balance of payments grdup (consisting of a large and representative number of individuals serv ing generally in the role of economists with manufacturers, exporters, importers, banks, transportation companies, and other concerns di rectly engaged in international trade and investment) expects that net foreign investment will come to about $2.2 billion in 1957, about double the 1956 rate, but the increase is still below that which took place in 1956. Their expectation is for commercial merchandise exports, the largest component of the current account, to be $18 billion in 1957 against 126 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT $17 billion last year. The latter figure represents nearly a 20-percent increase over 1955. Imports, according to the N FTC, will approximate $13 billion, up only $300 million from 1956. The rise in imports has evidently slowed down, since the increase from 1955 to 1956 was $1.2 billion. ‘ Among the factors that are expected to lead to this situation are the following: First, there is the general broad expectation that business activity within the United States will continue on a high plane. The closeness of high business activity and high imports has been established and will continue. Second, the unsettled situation in the Middle East will tend to make Europe turn to the Western Hemisphere for its supply o f fuel. Coal exports are already high and can be expected to remain high or actually increase as a result of Europe’s needs. Europe will have to turn to the United States and Venezuela to meet its petroleum needs as long as operations and transportation from the Middle East are disrupted. Third, there may be a need for increased imports of other goods, particularly consumer goods, from the United States. Some slowdown of industrial activity in Western Europe is already reported. A t present, the letdown has been mainly in private investment, but should the crisis continue, a twofold impact may be felt in the consumer-goods field. The shortage of fuel may operate directly to cut consumer-goods output immediately. Should private investment be curtailed for any substantial period of time, an indirect effect may emerge in the in ability of industry to meet the growth in consumer demand. Fourth, the large gold and dollar balances of foreign countries, particularly continental European countries, puts them in a position to increase their purchases from the United States immediately with out having to export immediately in order to pay for the imports. Continental OEEC countries have more than doubled their gold and dollar holdings since 1950. The United Kingdom has not experienced a similar growth, but it has recently arranged with the International Monetary Fund to draw on its full quota of $1.3 billion if needed. A fifth consideration is the extent to which price increases will affect the value of our imports and consequently necessitate our spending more to meet our needs. Some price increases are already evident, and more can be expected. A related question is the extent to which internal prices will rise in the United States and consequently con tribute to our attractiveness as a market for imports. United States exports and imports o f goods and services and net foreign investments, 1952-57 [Billions of dollars] 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 (estimate) Export surplus of goods and services1___ Total unilateral transfers, except military. 2.4 2.5 0.4 2.5 1.8 2.3 2.0 2.5 3.4 2.3 4.7 2.5 Net foreign investment..................... -.1 -2 .0 -.4 -.5 1.1 2.2 1 Excluding transfers under military aid program. Sources: Council of Economic Advisers; National Foreign Trade Council. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 127 My final comments are devoted to financial aspects which underlie the picture for private business investment. Turning next to financial aspects of these investment possibilities, the basic issue here is the level of liquidity. In 1956 the record outlays for plant and equipment and the largest boost to inventory book values experienced during the past 5 years combined to bring consid erable pressure on business financing. As a partial offset to these pressures depreciation allowances increased sizably, continuing the ostwar trend; lending increased, as did the volume of security issues, detained earnings were down somewhat significantly. The biggest change, however, was the decline in cash and United States Govern ments. In other words, the pressure was relieved by a decline in corporate liquidity. This provided a safety valve for business invest ments in 1956. Retained earnings were down significantly. That is the key point. There was a decline of some $5 billion in cash and United States Government holdings. The figures are in the Eco nomic Report. A s already indicated, the presently available surveys suggest that 1957 plant and equipment outlays will be up considerably less this year than in 1956. The rise in inventories, too, should be somewhat less than it was last year. The demand for funds in 1957, therefore, should not rise as much as in 1956. In fact, it is conceivable that the use of funds for capital and inventory purposes combined may be no higher in 1957 than in 1956. On the other hand, depreciation allowances will undoubtedly in crease as much, if not more than, in the previous year, while corporate profits available for internal use may be about the same as in 1956. The leveling of capital outlays, together with a diminution in the rate of inventory buildup, could make financing problems less acute in 1957 than in 1956. This may even serve to bring to a halt the decline in corporate liquidity. It is worth emphasizing, however, that the attainment of the 1956 rate of capital outlay was largely possible as a consequence of this lessened liquidity. In fact, the current leveling off of plant and equipment and the liquidity decline may well be associated. Finally a word about profit margins. They are now narrowing. This may mean that even after assuming a higher average level of activity m 1957, corporate profit totals may well be around 1956 aver age level. They have been steadily narrowing throughout 1956. Profits were not responsible for the bulge in prices in 1956. I f this narrowing of profit margins is continued, it could have a significant impact on future plant and equipment outlays. It is in this area that we find the key problem of 1957: the direction of trend in business investment in the closing half of this year. In summary, I view business investment as a strong sustaining force throughout the year, mildly expansionary in the opening months, but not the explosive force in 1957 that it was in 1956. Chairman P a t m a n . Thank you very kindly, sir. Now, Mr. George Katona, program director of the survey research center of the University of Michigan. S 128 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT STATEMENT OP GEORGE KATONA, DIRECTOR OF ECONOMIC PRO GRAM, SURVEY RESEARCH CENTER, AND PROFESSOR OP ECONOMICS AND OP PSYCHOLOGY, UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Mr. K a t o n a . I am George Katona, from the University of Mich igan. Large consumer purchases will help make 1957 a good year. It appears probable that in 1957 consumers will devote a slightly higher proportion of their income than in 1956 to discretionary expendi tures, especially to purchases of durable goods. Yet the consumer outlook is not without some soft spots. Those who expect that con sumers will provide a substantial new impetus to the economy are likely to be disappointed. For the past 10 years the survey research center of the University of Michigan has been conducting nationwide sample interview sur veys in which particular attention has been given to the study of the psychological factors influencing consumer spending and saving. Consumer spending depends both on ability to buy and on willingness to buy. Little need be said at present about consumers’ ability to buy: incomes and liquid reserves are growing at a slow rate and consumer debt, for most people, is not unduly burdensome. Therefore, I shall turn to an analysis of consumer sentiment which greatly influences the short-range prospects. My remarks are based on the results of a survey completed in December 1956. The American consumer is satisfied with his financial situation and confident regarding the future. A slight deterioration in consumer sentiment which occurred early in 1956 has now been halted. People’s satisfaction wTith their financial welfare is maintained close to peak levels, and favorable expectations about personal finances continue to far outweigh pessimistic expectations. Confidence that good times lie ahead for the Nation’s economy during the next year, as well as during the next several years, is as widespread today as at any time during the postwar period. Signs that consumer inclinations to buy are improving may be found primarily in expressed buying intentions. Plans to buy new cars are substantially more frequent than they have been earlier in 1956, before the introduction of the new models. However, they remain well below the very high level attained in the fall of 1954. In tentions to buy used cars are at a peak for the 1954-56 period. That probably is an effect of price increases. Intentions to buy homes have increased in frequency m recent months. They now compare favor ably with house-buying plans expressed at other times during the past 2 years. However, there are indications that some people who exressed house-buying plans this November and December may have een unaware of the present credit stringency and may be forced to postpone their plans. Plans to make home improvement or repairs are unchanged from a year ago. Plans to buy major household goods give little or no indication of recovery from their earlier decline. Yet consumer attitudes and buying plans are not as buoyant as in late 1954 and in 1955. A t that time optimism was growing rapidly. Since then people’s expectations about their own welfare and national business conditions have been stable at a high level of satisfaction. The stimulus of growth in optimism has been lacking. During the last few months there was a further leveling off. The proportion of S ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 129 families who said that their financial situation was the same as a year earlier and who expected no change was somewhat higher in December 1956 than it had been earlier in 1956 or in 1955. Similarly regarding people’s general economic outlook, no signifi cant improvement has occurred during the last few months. The crisis in the Near East caused only a very slight increase in uncertainty. The results of the presidential election were most commonly viewed as having no effect on business conditions. Another major reason for the lack of buoyancy in inclinations to spend lies in the price situation. Most people are aware of rising costs of living and consider price increases an unfavorable development. The feeling that good buys are available is much less common than 2 years ago. The belief that prices have risen and will rise in the future began to spread in the spring of 1955 and was still growing in summer 1956. Yet between August and December 1956, no further increase has occurred in the proportion of consumers who see an upward trend in the price level. A s of now, concern with prices and fear of infla tion have not reached the point at which they would either reduce discretionary spending substantially or impair people’s desire and willingness to save. People on the whole are intent on improving their standard of liv ing. Needs as well as demand have been upgraded over the last 10 years. Even though today the American people own more and newer houses, automobiles, and other durable goods than ever before, they are not saturated and desire more and newer and better goods. A t the same time, however, people are also anxious to accumulate liquid reserves, that is, to save. Despite the popularity of installment buy ing, the will to save and the importance attributed to saving have not declined. Many people feel that their reserve funds or savings are not large enough. In 1956 liquid saving by consumers increased. (The present tight money is due primarily to demand rather than to supply factors.) The supply has grown but not proportionately to the increase in demand for money. According to current indications we may expect that the rate of liquid saving will remain at least as high in 1957 as in 1956, while at the same time borrowing (installment buying) may increase. W e expect a better automobile year in the next 9 months than we had a year ago, and we expect that installment buying will likewise increase. A s you know, in the Federal savings statistics, borrowing is con sidered a negative saving, and therefore the prospects for total savings as published in the Federal statistics is for lesser savings. But we must separate the accumulation of liquid reserves, for instance in savings and loan shares which are now the most popular form of liquid savings in this country, from borrowing which has other functions. I f I may summarize my remarks, 1957 promises to be a good year for the consumer sector. But in contrast to 1954 and 1955, the con sumer is not likely to lead. In 1955, the explosive factor was the con sumer. In 1956, as Mr. Gainsbrugh just indicated, it was the capital expenditures of business. # 1957,1 believe, neither will provide a new stimulus. Thus we are in a leveling off situation, and consumers cannot be relied upon to swim contrary to trends. 130 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT In other words,^ should in some other sectors recession or a small decline originate, it is unlikely that the consumers would step in and change the direction in which the economy is moving. Chairman P a t m a n . Thank you very much. W e will now hear from Mr. W ells, Administrator of the Agricul tural Marketing Service of the United States Department of Agri culture. STATEMENT OP ORIS V. WELLS, ADMINISTRATOR OP THE AGRICUL TURAL MARKETING SERVICE, DEPARTMENT OP AGRICULTURE Mr. W e l l s . Mr. Chairman, I am Oris V . W ells, Administrator of the Agricultural Marketing Service of the Department of Agricul ture. The first question on which I have been asked to concentrate is the outlook for farm production, prices, and income in 1957. A t our annual outlook conference held about 2 months ago, we con cluded that prices received by farmers in 1957 should average some higher than in 1956, and that this would also be true of net income realized by farm operators. W e expect that domestic demand for farm products will continue strong, that exports will hold at a high level, and that there will be some cut in farm marketings as a result of smaller hog production and the soil bank. Developments during the last 2 months have generally reinforced the appraisal made last fall. W e expect some further increase in economic activity and con sumer incomes during 1957. Under these conditions, expenditures for food probably will increase at about the same rate as disposable con sumer income. However, with the rising demand for services along with continuing increases in marketing costs, only part of the rise in food expenditures will be passed through to farm markets. Currently, farmers are receiving only about 40 cents out of the average dollar spent for food at retail. The value of farm exports for 1955-56 fiscal year rose about 11 per cent over the preceding year, even though cotton exports dropped to only 2.2 million bales. Meanwhile, exports have been moving out very rapidly since last June, with tne total value for the last half of 1956 now estimated at about 3’9 percent above the last half of 1955. Wheat exports are up sharply, while sales of cotton by the Commodity Credit Corporation for export during the current marketing year total 6.3 million bales through January 8. W e may have both a record volume and record value of farm exports in fiscal 1956-57. The soil-bank program will be in full operation in 1957. Announced goals call for 20 to 25 million acres from basic crops to be placed in the acreage reserve, and about 20 million acres of cropland in the con servation reserve. This should reduce total crop production this year unless yields are unusually high. The reduction in last fall’s pig crop, together with the small cut in prospect for this spring are expected to hold hog slaughter below a year earlier through most of 1957. The combined effects of the soil-bank program and the decline in hog numbers should mean some reduction in total farm output in 1957. However, the reduction in total farm marketings is not likely to be large. Crop rotation in 1956, part of which will be marketed ECONOMIC REPORT OF TELE PRESIDENT 131 this year, was at a record level, and the production of poultry, eggs, and dairy is likely to increase further. In addition, record stocks of corn, wheat, cotton, and rice were on hand at the beginning of the 1956-57 marketing year. Increased exports are reducing stocks of wheat, cotton, and rice, but corn stocks are increasing as a result o f last year’s big crop. In summary, some increase in average prices for 1957, together with payments under the soil-bank program, are likely to raise farm in comes above 1956, even though the volume of marketings may decline somewhat. W e do not look for an increase in total expenses of farm production. Consequently, we expect the realized net income of farm operators to increase, perhaps about 5 percent. The 5-percent gain from 1955 to 1956 was the first since 1951. The second question which I have been asked to concentrate on is the effect of farmers’ spending in 1957 on new construction and farm machinery. W e do not have data which will permit a very precise answer to this question, but I will try to summarize what we know. The decline in farm income in recent years has had an impact on farm purchases from nonfarm industries. Nevertheless, farmers have attempted to maintain purchases of machinery, equipment, and other industrial goods. To some extent, this appears to have been accom plished by going further into debt. Total farm indebtedness, ex cluding CCC loans, increased by $2’% billion in 1955 and 1956, to reach a total of about $18 billion at the beginning of this year. How ever, this is not large compared to total farm assets estimated at $176 billion as of January 1,1957. Farm production expenses reached a peak of almost $22.5 billion in 1952. Although they have eased off slightly since then, the de cline has been small compared with the drop m gross income. Largely in response to declining incomes, farm purchases of machinery and equipment in 1956 are estimated to be around 15 percent smaller than in 1955, and more than one-fourth below the heavy purchases in 1951. Farm construction outlays for 1956 were down about 3 percent from 1955, about one-sixth lower than in 1951. The farm market for construction and new equipment represented around 13 to 15 percent of total business spending for new plant and equipment in 1950-52, but declined to something less than one-tenth in 1956. Farm expenditures for new equipment and construction are expected to increase slightly this year due primarily to the effects of higher farm income in both 1956 and 1957. Purchases of some other production items may be reduced as more acreage moves under the soil bank. Mr. Chairman, I have supplied Mr. Ensley with a supplementary table on capital expenditures by farmers, which indicates a rough estimate of $3,815,000 for 1956, and if I had to set down a specific figure for 1957,1 would put it about $4 billion. In addition to these direct answers to the 2 questions, let me say that I always hesitate, even though I am a statistician, to simply cut a slice of 12 months of calendar time out of the farm business and say, “This is the farm outlook.” So I would, if you will allow me, like to say a few words about some medium-run trends which have to be kept in mind looking at the farm picture. They affected farm income last year, they will affect farm income in 1957 and they will still be operating in 1958 and, I suspect, until about 1960. 132 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT (The chart referred to is as follows:) Farm capital expenditures, 19S9 and 1946-56 [Millions of dollars] Gross capital expenditures on: Buildings i Year 1939.______ . . . . 1946.................... 1947.................... 1948.................__ 1949.................... 1950.............. . 1951-.,............... 1952.................... 1953.— . . ........... 1954.................... 1955.................... 1 9 5 6 * ...-......... Farm oper ators’ dwell ings 110 409 560 712 695 750 863 885 841 769 749 Motor vehicles Service build ings and other struc tures* Total Tractors 103 621 768 885 793 857 983 1,006 957 876 852 213 1,030 1,328 1,597 1,488 1,607 1,846 1,891 1,798 1,645 1,601 1,560 151 241 449 661 766 715 861 718 738 621 676 515 Trucks 73 216 463 535 540 542 508 472 431 463 484 500 Automo biles * Total 122 104 194 307 484 432 414 263 540 393 467 380 346 561 1,106 1,503 1,790 1,689 1,783 1,453 1,709 1,477 1,627 1,395 Other machin ery and equip ment * 215 444 795 1,159 1,256 1,242 1,409 1,315 1,152 1,172 1,113 860 All items 774 2,035 3,229 4,259 4,534 4,538 5,038 4,659 4,659 4,294 4,341 3,815 * Includes new construction, additions, and major improvements. * Includes fences, windmills, wells, and dwellings not occupied by the farm operator. * For farm business use (40 percent of total farm purchases of automobiles, 50 percent in 1942-45). , * Excludes harness and saddlery and other minor types of equipment charged to current expense. * Preliminary estimates based on incomplete information. Source: The Farm Income Situation, July 1956. M r, W ells. Following the Korean inflation, prices received by farmers entered a period of decline which extended to the latter part of 1955. Since then a gradual improvement has taken place, with the result that the index of prices received by farmers during the last 3 months of 1956 averaged 235 percent of the 1910-14 base, compared with 225 in the last 3 months of 1955. Meanwhile, prices and cost rates paid by farmers have continued to increase as evi denced by a parity ratio averaging 82 in the last quarter of 1956, compared with 81 a year earlier. In other words, prices paid by farmers have been going up at almost the same rate as prices received by farmers. Underlying trends in domestic demand have been favorable. Our population of about 168 million persons in 1956 was 15 percent higher than in 1947-49. This increase m the number of consumers has been augmented by continued increases in consumer incomes to new record levels, Although these increases in income have been accompanied by only relatively small increases in per capita purchases of farm fooa products, the rise of 4 percent in the index of average per capita food consumption from 1947-49 to 1956 has been a significant factor in the expansion of total domestic demand. When combined with the increase in the number of consumers, the result has been an increase of about one-fifth in total United States food consumption since 1947-49. Recent trends in the exports of farm commodities have been favor able. After reaching a record level of $4.1 billion in 1951-52, they dropped about one-third in the next fiscal year. Since then, total farm exports have increased steadily. The expansion in exports in ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 133 the current marketing year has been especially important for wheat, cotton, rice, and fats ana oils. However, it needs to be emphasized that the recent expansion has been largely the result of Government pro grams, particularly those carried out under title I of Public Liaw 480. There is in the President’s Economic Report a most interesting chart which breaks total farm exports down into those financed by normal transactions and those financed by foreign currency and other trans actions where the dollar currency really rises within our own Government. W e also need to bear in mind that the underlying trend in farm production is up, and that carryover stocks of many important farm commodities are still very large. Farm output in 1956 is currently estimated at 114 percent of the 1947-49 average, which is about equal to the population increase. It is comprised of a 6-percent increase in crops and a 23-percent increase in livestock and livestock products. Although the soil-bank program should help to check uneconomic ex pansion, advances in farm technology and increased mechanization also mean that farm-production expenditures will continue at a relatively high level. I have a summary and three illustrated charts that I hope can also be included in the record. Chairman P a t m a n . Without objection, they may be included. (The material referred to follows:) 134 , , Selected data relating to agriculture United States 1939 and 1946-56 Farm output Prices received by farmers Parity index Parity ratio Index numbers, 1910-14=100 Percent 77 113 115 110 100 101 107 100 92 89 84 83 81 81 85 83 82 80 98 95 104 101 100 103 107 108 108 113 114 85 101 100 97 103 106 111 112 114 117 121 123 82 98 93 106 101 97 99 103 103 101 106 106 94 104 102 99 99 100 98 100 102 101 103 104 Millions $7,872 24,770 29,664 30,253 27,864 28,405 32,909 32,538 31,169 29,714 29,264 29,800 28,900 29,600 29.700 29.700 30,200 Millions $6,162 14,324 16,831 18,643 17,909 19,248 22,258 22,476 21,246 21,442 21,599 21,900 21.300 21,600 21,800 21,800 22.300 Millions $4,394 15,000 17,191 15,943 13,673 12,857 14,802 14,256 13,880 12,021 11,340 11,900 11,200 11,600 11,600 11,900 12,500 Millions $4,489 14,923 15,458 17,695 12,866 13,716 16,111 15,120 13,263 12,487 11,680 11,700 11.400 11,500 11,300 11,600 12.400 PRESIDENT 123 208 240 260 251 256 282 287 279 281 281 286 279 281 285 287 288 Total, including change in net inven tories » THE Millions $655 3,173 3,957 3,472 3,578 2,873 4,040 3,431 2,847 3,054 3,195 2 3,620 894 829 1,031 978 Realized i Index numbers, 1947-49=* 100 1 Quarterly data are seasonally adjusted annual rates. 2 1st 11 months. Produc tion expenses 1 OF iQett:__ifti smarter iQKfi_icf miartpr 2d quarter 3d Quarter 4th Quarter 95 236 276 287 250 258 302 288 258 249 236 236 225 227 241 239 235 Crops ODerators Agricul tural exports REPORT 1939 ...................................... 1946 ...................................... 1947 .................................. .................................. 1948 1949......................................... 1950......................................... 1951 ........................... ........................... 1952 1953 ............................ 1954 ........................... .................................. 1955 .......................... 1956 Total Net income of farm Cash receipts from farm market ings i ECONOMIC Year Livestock and products Food con sumption per capita ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE ) L -i.i, » . I . i .1 i . q ,1 l i * M O N T H L Y DA T A * INCLUDES 1910 1920 ...................................................L - i - i - i — 1930 I NTE RES T, TAXES, A N D 1940 WAGE RATES. BY Q U A R T E R S . 1924 - 3 6 , B Y M O N T H S , U. S. D EP A R T M E N T OF AGRICULTURE ANNUAL , i - ± > I .1 A— 1., - I- J.. .1- 1950 AV. D A T A , 1 91 0 - 2 3 ; 1937 TO D A T E N EG. 98 - 57 ( 1 ) A G R IC U L T U R A L M A R K E T IN G S E R V IC E PRESIDENT F A R ME R S ’ P R I C E S o FARM OUTPUT A N D POPULATION * ECONOMIC EEPOKT OF THE PRESIDENT CO * U .S. D EP AR TM EN T OF AGRICULTU RE 3-YEAR m o v i n g a v e r a g e s NEG. 19 1 2 -5 7 (1 ) A G RICULTU RA L M A RKETIN G SE R V IC E FACTORS IN FARM PRODUCTION Per Unit o f Farm Output % OF 1935-39 200 100 0 1935 1940 U. S. D EPARTM ENT OF A G RICULTURE 1945 1950 NEG. 222A- 57 ( 1) 1955 1960 A G RICULTU RAL M A RK ET IN G SE RVICE 138 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Chairman P a t m a n . I would like to ask a few questions, and I will ask the staff director to make sure I am advised when the 10 minutes have expired. Mr. Clague, in preparing the cost of living index, do you include the cost of interest? Mr. C l a g u e . Yes, we do. In the case of homeownership which is included in our index, we count the rate of interest as one of the costs. Chairman P a t m a n . H o w significant is it? Mr. C l a g u e . It would not be a very large item in the homeowner ship picture* The first item is, of course, the price of the house itself. We also include maintenance and repair costs to keep the house up, and then interest would be another cost. I cannot give you the exact weight o f that interest, or how much influence it has on the index, but I could supply that if you would like to have it. Chairman P a t m a n . Since it is divided over a long period of years, it would probably be insignificant or at least not large for 1 year, I assume. Mr. C l a g u e . That is right; it is cumulative, of course. It lasts a long time, and it will stay at that rate until and unless the owner can refinance the house at a more favorable time later. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Paradiso, do you in your interesting state ment assume the tight money situation as continuing during 1957 ? Mr. P a r a d is o . I did not make that statement, Mr. Chairman. Chairman P a t m a n . I know you did not make the statement, but you did say something along that line. Did you consider the money situation for 1957 ? Mr. P a r a d is o . Yes, I did. I considered that situation to be pretty much a continuation of what we are now going through. I did not envisage an alteration from the present situation. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Gainsbrugh, you discussed the retained earnings, and the fact that capital expenditures for plant and equip ment are expected to be up for 1957. Last year I believe 67 percent of the capital expenditures came from retained earnings and deprecia tion. How will that figure compare with 1957, assuming that the 67 percent is approximately correct? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . That sounds a little low to me. Chairman P a t m a n . Is it about 70 percent? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . It is about that. In 1956, retained profits and depreciation allowances accounted for more than 80 percent of plant and equipment outlays by nonfinancial corporations. I would expect the flow of cash funds from depreciation to be higher in 1957 than in 1956 because the asset base is larger again as we enter 1957 than it was in 1956. I f the profits figures are about the same in 1957 as they were in 1956, and that was implied in Mr. Paradiso’s statement, among others, I think there will be a recognition by industry of the need for funds for internal purposes to a greater extent this year than there was last year. Last year dividends went up by 8 percent. I would think that in the light of requirements in 1957, dividends might hold about where they are, which would mean that retained earnings plus depreciation would give a higher cash throwoff in 1957 than in 1956. So there should be more internal funds for investment purposes in 1957 than in 1956. Chairman P a t m a n . In your statement, did you also assume that the money situation would remain about the same as it is now, which, I ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 139 believe is generally considered tight ? Did you consider it would ease or get tighter ? .• Mr. G a in s b r t j g h . I am hopeful that if the tapering off process that is envisioned by our capital appropriations does transpire toward the middle of 1957 or thereafter, there will be some easing off in the tight-credit policy. For purposes of warranted economic growth, we would need more of an expansion in our monetary supply than we have had in the past 12 or 18 months. But that is only if the taper ing off does occur. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Katona, how do you consider that the in creased interest that the consumer must pay will affect his savings? Mr. K a t o n a . I do not believe that the increased interest affects consumer savings. Most consumers save in order to have reserve funds and not for the sake of interest return. Chairman P atm an . You do not think it affects consumer savings? Mr. K a t o n a . I do not believe so. Chairman P a t m a n . That is, the consumer is not interested so much in the actual interest he receives on his investment as the security o f the investment and the capital? The interest rate itself, whether it is 2 1/2 percent or Sy2 percent is not so important as the safety of the security, is that right? Mr. K a t o n a . We are pretty sure, Mr. Chairman, that for the great majority of American savers, interest rate or changes of interest rate by 1 or iy 2 percent do not amount to much. I f I may say one more sentence. For some very rich people whose savings may be substan tial, it may amount to something. Even in installment buying, con sumers are not concerned, perhaps it is their fault, with the charges. In mortgages and in buying houses, they are concerned, and so in residential building I do expect an effect. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Wells, suppose that the farm prices had gone up in 1956 the same percentage as industrial prices went up. How would that have affected the cost of living? Mr. W e l l s . Well, that is a little difficult for me to answer. Farm prices in 1956 actually averaged the same level as 1955. How much did industrial prices go up ? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . They went up as much as industrial prices, and they were 7 percent higher at the year end. Mr. W e l l s . From December of 1955 to December of 1956, farm prices did go up 7 percent. Chairman P a t m a n . I am looking back over a period of years and wondering how the price index could remain about the same without somebody giving up something when we know that industrial prices have gone up considerably, that is, steel, automobiles, and many things like that. Was it not a lot of it as a result of the losses the farmers took, Mr. Wells? Mr. W e l l s . There was a period of 59 months, from February of 1951 to December of 1955, in which farm prices fell by 30 percent. There is no question but what this fall in farm prices did result in masking the effect of what was happening quite a bit o f the time to the rest of the economy and give us a stable phice level made up of the falling farm sector and the rising prices of other products. Chairman P a t m a n . The stable prices, in other words, were at the cost of the farmer ? 140 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Mr. W e l l s ; Certainly, if we had not falling farm prices, the price level would not have been stable. Chairman P a t m a n . During that 59 months^ suppose that farm prices had gone up in the same percentage as industrial prices, the index would probably have been considerably different? Mr. W e l l s . I think so, yes. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Curtis, do you wish to inquire? Mr. C u r t i s . I will pick up with Mr. Wells. I am first interested in knowing the percentage of Government support in relation to the total farm income* I think our total farm income was $11.9 billion in 1956. I have some figures on this and I understand that about 10 percent of net farm income in recent years is due to Government pay ments plus Government loans. But I notice our budget includes about $5 billion of farm supports. How is that reconciled ? It would look to me that probably that is pretty much an annual figure and I am interested m knowing whether it is 10 percent o f the farm income derived from Federal supports or as much as about 40 percent. Mr. W e l l s . This is a difficult question for me to give a short answer to, but let me call your attention to several things: First, the budget for agriculture for this year, and I think I should say last year, and probably for next year, tends to cumulate the cost of agricultural price supports over a number of years because we are disposing of stocks of agricultural commodities that have been built up since we came out of the Korean inflation period. That is first. , Second, I question comparing the size of the fiscal 1958 agricul tural budget, about $4y 2 billion excluding loan advances which I do riot think belong in this discussion, with the net realized income of farm operators, of about $11 billion. The cash sales of farm prod ucts runs about $30 billion and the cash expenses of farm production ran $21 billion or $22 billion. I would suggest that these budget expenditures support not the net realized farm income, but rather cash receipts from the sale of farm commodities, a large block of which goes back—twenty-odd million dollars—back into the pur chase of farm production goods. So I think the comparison should be against either cash sales or gross value of farm production. Cash sales would have been sub stantially lower without supports. Farmer purchases of both pro duction and farm family living goods would have been substantially loweir without the support-price program. Mr. C u r t i s . I appreciate your comments. In trying to evaluate our farm economy on whether it is 10 percent or 40 percent or what, such a big factor is involved that it becomes important. Now you state that you are rather optimistic that we will be able to continue the export rate and in fact improve the export of our farm products. Yet, from a little experience I had in talking with a few people in Western Europe, and also listening to some of the gripes at the Geneva Conference of the GATT countries, there was a lot of talk about the fact that the United States was dumping farm products, and there seems to be a growing resistance on their part perhaps to disposing of our farm products in that fashion. ^ Did you take that possible factor into consideration in estimating an increase of disposing of our surpluses ? ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 141 Mr. W e l l s . Yes, sir. You will remember that I have addressed myself here in this first section to precisely the 12 months’ slice of time, the calendar year 1957. I think we do have commitments already underway and prospects which indicate to me that calendar 1957 is going to tie a very high year. Mr. C u r tis . I f this psychology did exist, it would be a factor at a later time. Mr. W e l l s . I suppose I am probably also assuming that the Con gress will agree with the President in extending Public Law 480 for an additional 12 months and by an additional $1 billion. I think the kind of questions you are raising have to do with the longer run outlook for farm exports, and there we must take into account not only this feeling you mention but also the increase in production of agricultural commodities as against the increase in population over the world and the desire of many countries to get a low-priced commodity wherever they can buy it. Mr. C u r t i s . Mr. Clague, in your discussion of part-time work, I was wondering if you had included in that the farm economy? I have been quite interested in the figures over a period of years of the percentage of farm income that comes from nonagricultural work, which is largely in this area of part-time industrial work or nonfarm work. Was that calculated in your studies ? Mr. C l a g u e . Yes, Mr. Congressman, it was. These are census figures which I was quoting and they are derived from the census, the monthly census of population and labor force which the census takes* I called attention to the lrge increase in 1956 in the number of these part-time workers. Undoubtedly some of them were on the farm. I am sorry to say I do not have before me the extent to which that is true. I might also add that I am sure a good many of them were also in industry and trade to some extent, too, as shown by the large numbers of women who seem to be coming into the labor force on a part-time basis. Mr. C u r t i s . O f course, in the farm economy, a lot of that is the farmer’s wife or daughter. You did not have a breakdown of that? Mr. C l a g u e . N o , but I think I could supply that to you. I do not have it with me but I could put it in the record, if you like. Mr. C u r t i s . Yes. (The information is as follows:) P art -T im e E m p l o y m e n t The extent o f part-time work has increased in recent years in both farm and nonfarm employment. In 1956, 18 percent of all persons at work were em ployed less than 35 hours a week, compared with 14 percent in 1947. Part-time employment in nonagricultural industries has increased sharply for both men and women. The number on part-time work has jumped from about 6 million in 1947 to almost 9% million average in 1956. Part-time workers comprised 17 percent o f nonfarm employment in 1956, as compared with 13 percent in 1947. While the proportion on the part-time work has also increased for agriculture— from less than 24 percent in 1947 to over 28 percent in 1956—the number of part-time farmworkers has not actuaUy increased, because there has been a decline over the period in the total number o f farmworkers. 142 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Full-time and part-time workers in nonagricultural industries and in agriculture by sex, annual average 1956 1955 and 1947 , , , Number (in thousands) Sex, industry, and hours worked during survey week Both sexes: Total at work1__________________________ 35 hours or more_____________________ 1 to 34 hours. ______________________ Nonagricultural industries________________ 35 hours or more_____________________ 1 to 34 hours.__________ ________ _____ Agriculture.____________________________ 35 hours or more_____________________ 1 to 34 hours. _______________________ Males: Total at work 1__________________________ 35 hours or more...................................... 1 to 34 hours.________ _______________ Nonagricultural industries________________ 35 hours or more............ .......................... 1 to 34 hours__________ __________ ___ Agriculture............... ........... .......................... 35 hours or more_____________________ 1 to 34 hours___________________ _____ Females: Total at work 1____________ _____________ 35 hours or more....................... ............... 1 to 34 hours.________ ______________ _ Nonagricultural industries............................. 35 hours or more_____________________ 1 to 34 hours............ ................................ Agriculture...................................................... 35 hours or more......... ............................. 1 to 34 hours............................................. , Percent distribution 1956 1955 1947 1956 1955 1947 61,818 50,640 11,178 55,425 46,062 9.363 6,393 4,577 1,815 60.261 49,933 10,329 53,728 45.046 8,683 6,534 4,887 1,646 55,554 47,635 7,919 47,573 41,538 6,034 7,981 6,097 1,885 100.0 81.9 18.1 100.0 83.1 16.9 100.0 71.6 28.4 100.0 82.9 17.1 100.0 83.8 16.2 100.0 74.8 25.2 100.0 85.7 14.3 100.0 87.3 12.7 100.0 76.4 23.6 42,166 36,529 5,637 37,060 32,536 4,523 5,107 3,993 1,114 41,432 36,196 5,234 36,122 31,897 4.224 5,310 4,298 1,010 39,983 35,781 4,201 33,276 30.239 3,037 6,707 5,542 1,164 100.0 86.6 13.4 100.0 87.8 12.2 100.0 78.2 21.8 100.0 87.4 12.6 100.0 88.3 11.7 100.0 80.9 19.0 100.0 89.5 10.5 100.0 90.9 9.1 100.0 82.6 17.4 19,652 14,111 5,541 18,366 13,526 4,840 1,286 585 702 18,831 13,736 5,093 17,606 13,147 4,458 1.224 589 636 15,570 11,853 3,716 14,296 11,299 2,997 1,274 554 719 100.0 71.8 28.2 100.0 73.6 26.4 100.0 45.5 54.6 100.0 72.9 27.0 100.0 74.7 25.3 100.0 48.1 52.0 100.0 76.1 23.9 100.0 79.0 21.0 100.0 43.5 56.4 * Excludes persons with a job but not at work. N o t e . —Figures may not add to totals because of rounding. Source: U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. Prepared by U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Division of Manpower and Employ ment Statistics, Feb. 1, 1957. Mr. C u r t i s . H o w much do your figures reflect the possibility of double jobs, where with this shortage of hours there seems to be a number of people at any rate that hold two jobs. How much of that data do you have ? Mr. C l a g u e . That is entirely eliminated in the figures I supplied you, which come from the census, because they get these data from the homes of people. They call on the family, and there the fact that a erson held 1, 2, or 3 jobs would not make any difference. In our >ureau of Labor Statistics reports which come from employers, this double jobholding does exist or would be included. We would find a man on two different payrolls and he would be counted twice. The census has made some reports on that subject from time to time. I have the impression, if you will let me correct it later, that there are about 3y2 million persons in this country who hold more than one job at one time. (Mr. Clague later submitted the following:) g E m p l o y e d P e r s o n s W i t h T w o or M ore J o bs Preliminary estimates1 of the number of persons holding two or more jobs are available from a special survey conducted by the Bureau of the Census in July 1956. These figures show that, o f the 66.7 million persons employed during the 1 Detailed data not yet completely prepared for publication. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 143 week ending July 14,1956, 3.7 million had more than 1 job or business. The 3.7 million included 2.8 million persons whose primary jo b s 2 were in nonagricultural industries and 900,000 whose primary jobs were in agriculture. Among agricultural workers with additional jobs, 300,000 were wage and salary workers (hired farmhands) and 600,000 were self-employed or unpaid family workers. The secondary jobs o f most of the wage and salary farmworkers were also in agriculture but almost 350,000 of the 600,000 farm self-employed or unpaid family workers held additional jobs in nonagricultural industries. This sug gests that many of the latter were owners o f small farms near urban areas where industrial jobs are available. Many of this group spend most o f their time on farmwork during busy seasons like planting and harvesting and are therefore classified by census as agricultural workers. During the rest of the year they spend most of their working time on their industrial jobs and are classified as nonagricultural workers. Mr. C u r t i s . Thank y o u . Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Mills. Mr. Mili s. Mr. Chairman, as I understand the President’s economic message and his budget message, the view is expressed that the objec tives of the Employment Act will be carried out and accomplished in the calendar year 1957. In other words, there will occur on the basis of fixed or relatively stable prices an increase in gross national product of 3 or 3% percent which is the figure that we normally say represents the growth from year to year necessary to carry out the objectives of the Employment Act. Am I right in concluding from the statements that each and all of you have made this morning that there is some serious doubt that gross national product will increase by 3 or 3y 2 percent in 1957 over 1956 on the basis of fixed or relatively stable prices ? I have raised the question because I have been concerned over the statements, particularly those that have been made with respect to the increase in the labor force that will be employed, and increase in investments and plant expansion, and inventory accumulations, consumer demand, and prices of farm products and income received by farmers. You have said that the investment in plant and equipment, Mr. Gainsbrugh, and inventory accumulations, will not supply the im petus which apparently is needed for that degree of growth in gross national product. You have said that the consumers will not react in 1957 as they did in 1955 to supply the lead. That is the expansion that occurred at that time and it was apparently needed at that time to bring about the increase in gross national product. As I understand, Mr. Wells, even though the situation with respect to farmers may be more favorable in 1957 than 1956 it will not be so favorable as to supply the leadership in attaining a 3- to 3 % -p e r c e n t increase in gross national product. As I understand from your statement with respect to Federal, State, and local expenditures, perhaps that situation is more favorable than any of the others discussed by these gentlemen. In all probability, then, Mr. Paradiso, I must conclude that if a gross national product increase of 3 or Sy2 percent will occur in 1957 over 1956, the expansion generating that increase must come from Federal and State and local expenditures. Now, am I justified in that conclusion? 2 Primary job classification is based on the greatest number of hours worked during the survey week. 144 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Mr. P a r a d i s o . Congressman, I think that you have to keep in mind the developments since the middle of the year. When you talk about comparing 1957 with 1956, we have already exceeded the gross national product for the average of 1956 by something like 3 percent roughly, although in terms of real gain, that is, eliminating the price rise in the fourth quarter of last year compared with the year as a whole, we are up 1y2 percent. So let us start with that. This means that we have to consider, from indications as developed here at this table, how much more gross national product we can expect to result in a 3- or 3%-percent increase for 1957 as a whole com pared with 1956. All the statements around this table seem to indicate modest in creases, small increases from the fourth-quarter rate. The Federal Government purchases, as I have indicated, would show a small rise from the fourth-quarter rate. That is $1 billion in 1957, compared with the fourth-quarter annual rate. The consumer purchase statement seems to indicate a small rise. Business-investment programs do not level off in the fourth-quarter rate but indicate a small rise. You do not need too many of these small rises to yield a total for 1957 which would be close to a 3-percent rise over 1956, particularly in view of the fact that we have already gone a good way toward approaching the 3-percent increase. Mr. M i l l s . I s it your thought then that we are reasonably safe in expecting a 3- or 3^-percent increase in gross national product in 1957 over 1956? Mr. P a r a d i s o . Reasonably safe, viewing the trend as we see it now. M r . M i l l s . We very shortly will begin to consider a budget request that in order to be financed on the basis of existing tax rates will re quire increases in personal income and corporate income that we have translated into a 3- or 3^-percent increase in gross national product. It becomes very important, as I view the situation, for us to be as certain as we can as we look at the future, and always there are uncer tainties, but as certain as we can as to what our revenues may be under existing rates, in making these enormous expenditures for the Federal Government. Just a slight error in our projection of increase in gross national product could cause us to end the fiscal year 1958 in the red rather than in the black. All of us know what that might do at this particular time or under conditions similar to these today to economic stability here at home. Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I would like to offer one comment if I may on your general question. I agree thoroughly with the statement that Mr. Paradiso has made that it is the summation of small gains in all sectors of the economy that may v e r y well give us a higher level of national economic activity in 1957 than in 1956. In a sense we do not want a repetition of the explosive forces in 1956 because those explosive forces in 1956 gen erated inflationary pressures, as Mr. Clague has indicated. However, there was implicit m the line of analysis that was presented, a thesis that possibly we needed increased Government spending to maintain a high level of activity. I wanted to depart from that point of view. I think we have built up a case here this morning which indicates a continuation of high-level activity or the probability of a continuation of high-level activity throughout the year. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 145 I do not believe that greater governmental spending is needed at this particular moment to buttress the economy. And there is always the alternative of fiscal and monetary policies other than governmental spending that can be stimulative in character. We can ease the tight ness in the credit stream, if that is required. We can bring more activity into being in the home-building field than we have permitted difring the past year. That sector has been affected by monetary policy. There is also the possibility that if corporate taxes, for example, are oppressive or excessive or inimical to further capital investment, tax reductions can be just as stimulative to the economy as increased gov ernmental spending. I did want to make that reservation of mine clear. M r . M i l l s . I am merely asking a question for information. Are you saying in part that it is not necessary for the Congress to appro priate more money for fiscal year 1958 than we appropriated in fiscal year 1957 to buttress the economy ? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I f that is the sole purpose of the appropriations, yes, I would say that I am arguing against an expansion of budgetary expenditures for purposes of strengthening or holding up the economy with the thought that there might be tapering off or slowdown in economic activity. Mr. K a t o n a . I would like to agree with your initial statement. I believe that from December of 1956 to December of 1957 there is little chance for a 3 percent real increase in gross national product if Fed eral expenditures do not increase. Mr. C l a g u e . It is not appropriate for me to talk about Federal expenditures, but I would like to call your attention to one area which I did cover in my statement. That is wages and salaries. You will notice that deferred wage increases are already written into contracts of 5 million workers. Half of these range from 6 to 8 cents an hour, which is about 3 to 4 percent. In construction, the largest number of increases range about 9 to 11 cents per hour, which would also be about 3 or 4 percent. It is hard to imagine that the new contracts that will be negotiated in 1957 by unions and management will be any less than that when they come up for renewal this year. Now, I do recognize, in making this statement, that wages are a cost to the employer, and they may be shaving profits as Mr. Gains brugh indicated. But if you start out with the assumption that there will be a businessman’s demand that will keep these people at work, I would foresee a consumer demand arising out of this which would be at least sustained along previous levels. Consequently, if these con sumers spend, and Mr. Katona indicates they may, they will certainly create a demand of a private character, and nongovernmental char acter, which will be very important. This is not a forecast, but this is just an indication of one segment of expansion of demand that is likely to occur. Mr. M i l l s . Your statement generally raised the thought in my mind that you were expecting that we would have some inflationary increases in prices in 1957, as a result of the wage increases. Of course, if we have sufficient inflation in 1957, we can expect that in crease in receipts of Government, perhaps, that are needed to finance 146 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT these expenditures that are contained in this budget. I had hoped we would be able to do it without the necessity of further inflation. That is all, Mr. Chairman. Representative K i l b u r n . As a new member of this committee I stand in awe of so many eminent economists and I am somewhat hesitant in proposing questions to you. As I understand the President’s state of the union message, he suggested that increases in wages and prices only follow increased productivity. I presume that means not only the individual worker’s productivity but the general increases resulting from improvements m plant and equipment. Do you see any hopes of halting inflation by that method ? Mr. C l a g u e . Would you like me to try that, Mr. Congressman? Representative K i l b u r n . Yes, please. Mr. C l a g u e . The President’s statement did indicate that for the economy as a whole, productivity is the one way in which you raise the standard of living. That is to say, if you pay higher wages, or raise prices to the consumer, and that is the sole method of increase in the gross national product, or if there is no productivity to match the wage increases, then obviously wages and raw material costs convert into prices and prices go up. Now, on the other hand, productivity can mean a cut in the costs because the employer is using less labor to produce the same amount of product. Consequently, we could get a rise in the standard of living due to this productivity. That is a truism. Now, how this will work out in any one year is not very certain. Our figures on productivity for the most recent years are not very good, as I explained so fully in my statement. They do indicate that 1956 was not a very good year from that point of view. On the other hand, 1954 and 1955 were. What the outlook is for 1957, I am not sure. But it is clear that unless we get a moderately good increase in productivity, answering Mr. Kilburn and Mr. Mills, men of course it might take the form of price increases which would give you the esti mated gross national product but not in real terms. Did I answer your question, Mr. Kilburn? Representative K i l b u r n . I am impressed by these figures and the way in which all of you follow these matters so very closely. I am wondering whether any of you think that the recommendations of the President to stop inflation have any chance of really prevailing. Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I have a different view about the basic causes of the inflationary pressures of the past 12 to 18 months from some of my other colleagues here, apparently. They place their primary em phasis upon the cause of the bulge in prices as being demand. I am inclined to agree that part of it did stem from the demand side. I am of the opinion, however, that the inflationary pressures of the past 12 to 18 months are essentially different from the inflationary pressures o f the first postwar decade. Those stem now largely from the pressures of an expanded money supply upon the price structure. The inflation of the past 12 months came in a period of a balanced budget and of tight money. The pressures came primarily from the cost side in my opinion rather than from the demand side. The basic cause of that cost pressure was wage increases in excess o f the gains in output per man-hour. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 147 To come back to your basic question, I think it is a question that concerns the whole Western World and not just the United States alone. Until such time as we do get a recognition that wage increases in excess of productivity are harmful to the national interest, we will not have met the question of sustained inflation arising from the cost rather than from the demand side. The President has singled out the question of the wage-cost push, or wage inflation if you like, as being a question of dominant concern in 1957. There is one further corollary to this, if I may develop it. That is that wage inflation may not be long sustained in character. The infla tion stemming from the huge deficits of World War I I ran a long course. But wage inflation can push huge sectors of our population out of the market place rather quickly. In so doing, the price we pay for wage inflation would not be sustained inflation over a prolonged period of time but increasing unemployment. I do not foresee that as the picture for 1957. I am looking at this over a longer period of time. Representative K i l b u r n . I think that is a very clear statement and a. very instructive one to me. It seems to me that the big unions and the big labor leaders are in exactly the same position as the big corporations in that they are competing with each other. Just as soon as one union gets a wage increase, then the next union or the head of the next union wants to make as good a showing, and so he goes after an equal or greater increase. That same thing is true of course of big corporations. They want to make just as good a showing in earnings. It is difficult to see where to stop it. Mr. K a t o n a . May I say it is not only the unions. According to consumer surveys, the great majority of the Ajnerican workers are convinced that they have a right to expect year by year or every 2 years some wage increase. This is today’s psychology which contributed to the prosperous times in the last 10 years. I think it will be very difficult to change this very strong demand from the rank and file. Therefore, I personally expect further wage increases and some further price increases. Representative K i l b u r n . Most of the union members expect an increase every year and presumably, then, they want to increase inflation every year. Mr. K a t o n a . People are not quite as consistent, Congressman, and they do not realize that. Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I did not want my comments to be misinterpreted in that respect. I was speaking of the relationship between wage against productivity. I f this economy continues to grow more efficient year after year and that seems to be the record, then it is possible, as Mr. Katona has indicated, for wages to rise and living standards to rise. But they must be commensurate in the main, and not in any given year, but in the main with the increased efficiency of the economy. Where we get wages outstripping the gains in productivity, then we begin to get imbalances in the economy which can be harmful to the national interest. Representative K i l b u r n . They should get wage increases under those conditions. 148 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Gainsbrugh, did you indicate a while ago that you would favor a reduction in taxes this year to stimulate the economy ? „7'. Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I did not. I said, however, that in the eyent stimulation of the economy did become necessary there were various mechanisms that were open to us over and above an increase in gov ernmental, spending. One such mechanism might be a review of our whole tax system against this particular framework, if I may develop it. Chairman P a t m a n . Did you notice in the Wall Street Journal this morning that United States Steel declared a quarterly dividend of 75 cents? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . No; I have not read that. Chairman P a t m a n . I wanted to invite your attention to it for this reason: It has been suggested here that employment cost or wages were such an important factor in inflation. This statement in the Wall Street Journal discloses that for the fourth quarter employment costs aggregated $434,188,236, and the products and services sold dur ing that same quarter of 1955 was $1,093,747,000. The employment cost amounted to 40 cents on the dollar. In the fourth quarter of 1956, a comparable period, the employment cost was $471,795,000, and the products and services sold was $1,194,587,925, or still about 40 cents out of the dollar. How do you reconcile that with the statement that the employment cost was the cause of inflation insofar as United States Steel was concerned? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . My comments were directed to the ^national pic-, ture rather than to any individual instance. 1 think at all times, and in every stage of the cycle, you will find some companies that are benefiting and that are above the average, and others that are below the average. But if you will look at the data that you have in your Economic In dicators you will find that corporate profits in the aggregate in 1956 were if anything, a little bit below where they were in 1955. Chairman P a t m a n . That does not apply to United States Steel. Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I do not believe it did, from the figures that you have read. I am, however, dealing with the corporate economy as a whole. Chairman P a t m a n . I understand that. I just invited your a t tention to this one particular case. Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . Y o u will find that national income went up rela tively and that wages went up relatively, but that profits after taxes were declining rather than rising in their share of the national income. Again, in the Economic Report, you will find that the rate o f return for the corporate entity both on sales and on equities was lower in 1956 than in 1955. Chairman P a t m a n . I think Mr. Katona made a very important statement a while ago when he said that the small savers were not induced to save by reason of the interest return. As they become larger they may become more interested. In other words, I assume, however Mr. Katona, that the average saver, being a small saver, is not influenced too much by the interest rate. Is that a fair assumption from what you stated? Mr. K a t o n a . I would say so; yes, sir. ECONOMIC REPORT OP THE PRESIDENT 149 Chairman P a t m a n . Do you agree with that, Mr. Gainsbrugh ? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I would have to, on the basis of Mr. Katona’s research. _ I do think, however, that there can be a shift in the charac ter of savings as a result of the change in interest rates. That is, in the composition of savings and movement from one type to the other. Chairman P a t m a n . Let me ask you this question. Suppose interest rates go up to 4 or 5 percent? Will the savers accept that and say, “ That is enough for me and I do not want to look around for an op portunity to invest my money and make more out of it” ? Would it be against the national interest to have an interest rate such that the saver would be satisfied with the return he received and thereby have no inducement to look around and try to invest in private enterprise and become a part of the private-enterprise system? What do you think about that, Mr. Katona ? Mr. K a t o n a . That is hard to say. I personally would not consider it bad if more medium savers would invest in common stocks. You can provide impetus to our economy by investing in common stocks by savers who had invested in savings and loan shares. Such shifts may occur. On the whole I would say that even with 4- or 5-percent interest rates, savers would not be induced to have much more, except a few people, and the bad effects of such an increase, especially on mortgage financing, would outweigh the advantages obtained from increased saving. Chairman P a t m a n . Y o u think the increases are detrimental to the economy rather than helpful? Mr. K a t o n a . An increase of interest rates on savings to 5 percent would definitely, in my opinion, be detrimental; yes. Chairman P a t m a n . What about 4 percent? Mr. K a t o n a . I believe that we should have low interest rates and I personally think, though I cannot base it on scientific findings, that a 4-percent savings rate is likewise higher than I would like to see it. , Chairman P a t m a n . It is higher than you would like to see it? Mr. K a t o n a . That is right. Chairman P a t m a n . This is consistent with your belief that the average saver, who, of course, is a small saver, is not attracted by the interest rate? Mr. K a t o n a . He is not sufficiently attracted to save more because saving has primarily other purposes, namely, to put away money into safe reserve funds for future spending or for emergencies and not to provide him with additional income. Representative K il b t t r n . When you say savings, d o you mean interest on savings accounts? Chairman P a t m a n . Yes; I do. Mr, K a t o n a . That is what I meant, too. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Paradiso, do you agree with these gentle men on what they said about savings and interest rates on savings? Mr. P a r a d i s o . Well, I do not have any other evidence than some o f the information developed by Mr. Katona in his own surveys. On the basis of that, and froija my own personal observation, it does ap pear that the consumer is not unduly affected by changes in interest rates. There are certain groups that are. I will agree, generally, with the foregoing statements. Chairman P a t m a n . What about you, Mr. Clague? Do you agree with Mr. Katona and Mr. Gainsbrugh? 150 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Mr. C l a g u e . This question does not grow out of any of my present work, but I do recognize the way in which interest payments enter into the average consumer’s budget; for example, when he buys a house he commits himself to pay an interest rate in borrowing the money. Now, a certain amount of the saving that occurs in the country is a kind of compulsory saving. I am saving compulsorily every month, when I have to pay back a certain amount of money which includes the interest I am paying on a loan from the mortgage company. In that sense, I think economists have long recognized that the small saver is generally a person who saves partly because he wants a house or he wants a car or other specific things, and some of his savings consist in committing himself for those purchases. Then he pays back money which becomes reloanable later on. Now, I think in that sense Mr. Katona is right. The small saver does not quit buying a house because the interest rates change. He would like to get the house and he will try to get it if any money, becomes available to him. Chairman P a t m a n . I am afraid we do not have our definitions straight. You are talking about the saver whom I would consider more or less of a captive saver. He is compelled to save. Mr. C l a g u e . That is right. It is compulsory. Chairman P a t m a n . We are talking about the person who volun tarily saves. The question is: Will the voluntary saver be induced to save more by reason of a little higher interest rate, or does the, interest rate enter into the question a great deal ? Mr. C l a g u e . I think I agree with Mr. Katona on that. I f he did not borrow the money to buy a house he would set it aside to buy a house. I f he has the objective of buying a house, the answer is that the rate of interest does not influence him too much in that decision. I think most economists agree with that. Chairman P a t m a n . Would you like to comment on that, Mr. Wells ? Mr. W e l l s . I really should not, because you people have simplified this too much for me. You are talking here mostly about the ordinary American who feels he does well to make a living and put aside a certain minimum amount for security. There, I agree with everything that has been said about the fact that small changes in interest rates are of secondary importance. However, I also feel, without being a savings statistician, that the amount of savings in the United States that accrue from this source are very small relative to the amount that accrues from other sources. I f you are talking about the average saver in terms of numbers, which we are now talking about, that is one thing. I f you are talking about those individuals and institutions who account for the larger amount of dollars actually saved, I would suggest that profit and interest rates are extremely important, Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Curtis, would you like to ask a question ? Eepresentative C u r t i s . I did not intend to enter this savings argu ment, but I must make this comment. I know, as I serve as a director in a savings and loan company and have done so for many years, that we have had to increase our interest rates in order to get the money in. I also suggest that one reason savings and loan associations have become such a repository for the small man’s savings in place of the ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 151 savings bank has been to a large degree the interest rate. So in that respect, at any rate, looking at it from the institutional standpoint, we are pretty much convinced that the interest rate does make a difference. I have one other comment on that too. I think you would agree that the worst thing that can happen to a small saver is inflation. I wanted to pick up a question that was posed to Mr. Gainsbrugh and 1 know he wanted to make a further answer. I want to anticipate what the answer might be so that he can comment on that. In this business of tax reduction, if I get to the point that you were making, if the actual funds would be free from tax reduction and went into investment capital as opposed to consumer spending, then it would be deflationary or it would resist the inflationary trends. Is that about right or am I wrong? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . The point I was on the verge of developing was that we are shifting from the highly stimulative economy of the first postwar decade to the highly competitive economy of the second post war decade. I felt it was relatively easy for all forms of business, small business and large, to obtain funds for expansion during the first postwar de cade. In part it was because the banks were largely depositaries for Government bonds and welcomed all borrowers; partly because they had built up reserves during World War II, and in part because excess-profits taxes were eliminated and that eased their problem somewhat. But this is completely different environment now. The banks are loaned up and credit is difficult rather than easy to secure. It may very well be that corporations in the years ahead will have to look far more to internal sources for expansion purposes and to the traditional sources of long-term capital, the equity markets, than they did in the first postwar decade. That leads me to the basic point that I wanted to stress. Cor porate taxes, high as they were, may not have been oppressive in the stimulative environment of the first postwar decade, but at some future period of time they may be. They may be the chief restraining factor in that there is not sufficient funds available for plow-back purposes within the corporate entities. Eepresentative C u r t i s . I happen to share your views on that and I would like to make this other comment: You said “ for expansion.” I would pose this situation; that it is to a large extent to maintain our present position due to the fact that our depreciation accounts do not have enough in them at the inflated cost to even replace the capital outlays of plant and machinery. As I see it, we have been in a period when these companies have had to do a lot of replacing. They find that their reserve funds are just not adequate under inflationary costs. So they have to get addi tional capital somewhere else. Would you say that is a fair statement ? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . That point is well taken and again I think, to fur ther elaborate on it, through recourse to certificates of necessity, some of the inadequacies of the treatment of the depreciation were corrected. Now, we are getting less and less of the accelerated amortization through the certificates of necessity. We have had some changes in tax law that are favorable to a more realistic treatment of depreciation. But I still think that it remains true for the small- and medium-sized firm with a heavy fixed investment per dollar of sales. 152 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT That is particularly so because of the large price rises of the past 12 or 18 months in equipment and construction costs. They find their depreciation reserve inadequate when it comes to replacement time. Representative C u r t i s . I personally dislike the use of the certificates of necessity because of the inequities that exist there and also the Government actually can direct the course of where the investment capital will go. Although, as you say, it has eased it. It has done it, in my judgment at any rate, in a very inequitable way, particularly with relation to small- and medium-sized businesses. Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . That was not meant to be an endorsement of cer tificates of necessity. It was rather a review of the factors at work. One of those was accelerated amortization under certificates of neces sity which did ease the problem of inadequacies of depreciation for the steel industry, among others. Representative C u r t i s . I have one other comment. It seems to me that the President’s Economic Report and the comments of the panel emphasize that the shortage in credit is not in the consumer dollar as much as it is in the investment dollar. I would say that is so. This is the thing I wanted to pose in the home-building field. Although we see a consumer dollar tightening, it has been tightened because of the shortage of building materials and glass and cement and steel and so forth, which are short, in turn, be cause there has not been enough investment capital for the expansion of production for those basic materials. Would anyone care to com ment on that, either agree or disagree ? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I do not think it was the shortage of materials that held back the home-building industry iji past months. I think it was primarily the deterioration m their competitive position so far as available funds were concerned. The housing starts figures suggest the weaknesses are in the FH A and GI area rather than in the conventional mortgage area where we did have a free interest rate at work. Representative C u r t i s . I know that the Government actually did put a clamp on home financing. But I am suggesting that one reason they did that, and one of the few reasons I could go along with it although I worried about it, was the fact that there seemed to be the shortage in these basic materials. I f they had allowed that credit to continue, the prices of these basic materials would have gone up beyond the point they did go up. That is the syllogism I was trying to pose. Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I accept that. I think the picture is quite dif ferent now from the picture of 12 to 18 months ago. I am hopeful that in the light of what has been said this morning about some of the forces that will be tapering off as 1957 moves along, that housing can become a sustaining if not expansionary force in terms of timing. It would be most desirable in terms of timing if that curve turned upward in the closing half of 1957. Representative C u r t i s . Certainly the demand is there, as Mr. Katona pointed out. Thank you. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Ensley, would you like to ask any ques tions? Mr. E n s l e y . I have a couple of questions on which I would like to see if I can get some clarification. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 153 Mr. Clague, with respect to the various indexes that you publish, particularly the Consumer Price Index and the wholesale index, do you believe that they are accurate measures of price movements? To put it another way, are they a good measure of inflation ? Mr. C l a g u e . We make these figures, both the wholesale prices which are business prices and the Consumer Price Index which is consumer prices at retail; and we try in every way possible to make those in dexes accurate. I have published a number of statements this year calling attention to the steps we take to do that. Now, I would have to add that there are certain kinds of changes in value which we have a hard time taking into account. However, we do price automobiles for the constimer at the discount that the consumer gets and not at the list price. Mr. E n s l e y . Y o u are pricing what is actually paid, rather than some list prices? Mr. C l a g u e . That is right. We get from the automobile dealers a report on what they are actually selling the cars for. We try to take into account special sales also if they extend over a reasonable period. We do not capture all of the spectacular discounts that are available to consumers through special discount shops and stores of that sort, but generally we pick those discounts up a little later because the department stores compete. We are now finding that for household appliances we are getting plenty of discounts from list prices right in our department stores. We include specialty stores, radio, television shops, and other spe cialty appliance stores in our sample in order to find places where discounts are taking place. I would say in general that we get a very close approximation of actual price changes. I f you will allow a few months to go by while the competitive situation takes care of it, I would say that we catch UP - Mr. E n s l e y . T o what extent do you believe the recent price in creases are the result of pent-up inflationary pressures that were built up during World War II and Korea which are only now finding their way into the indexes for one reason or another ? Mr. C l a g u e . I say to a small extent that would be true. Our rent index comprises about 5 or 6 percent of our Consumer Price Index. Homeownership is a bigger item because roughly half of the wage earners and salaried earners own their homes. But taking rent, for example, there is still rent control in New York City and there are still a few places in which rent is held down. Rent is still trying to catch tip. As controls are relaxed, that small segment of our index would reflect that rise. Now, look in our chart No. 11—the last chart I presented to you— which sketches these. The services have a definite lag also. That is partly streetcar fares and public-utility prices which are regulated by Government. On the other hand, I would say that in 1956 the major change in the index and the reason we moved away from stability was that food prices no longer helped us. For 4 years food prices declined and that offset the rises in these rents and services and other factors on the industrial side. Then, in 87624— 57--- 11 154 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 1956, food prices turned around and joined the others, and so our index went up. Mr, E n s l e y . Could I, Mr. Chairman, see if I can get the consensus o f the five men on the panel here with respect to the outlook for 1957 ? I f I understand your testimony correctly, I believe you would all agree that 1957 in real terms would probably be better, without being too precise as to precentages, than calendar year 1956. Would anyone dissent from that? Apparently there is no dissent from that. The second question is this: Would you not all agree, from your testimony and the testimony presented, that we coula anticipate a moderate price increase in calendar 1957 over calendar 1.956? I gather that is agreed. What would you anticipate the price in crease would be from the present levels and over the calendar year 1956 as a whole? Are we safe in saying that you would anticipate some further price increase from present levels as well as from the calendar year 1956 ? Would anyone dissent from that generalization ? Mr. C l a q u e . Let me say a word about our Consumer Price Index. It is very much influenced by what happens to farm prices because foods make up 30 percent of the weight of the average family budget. So what Mr. Wells says about agriculture and agricultural prices will have a great bearing on what will happen to our index. I am quite sure that we will have continued rises m rents and services, but what will happen to commodities is the question. That, of course, includes all kinds of commodities, including cloth ing and things of that sort. But the one that will have the most influence on our index in 1957 is probably food prices. I f they remain stable we will not do at all badly. Mr. E n s l e y . In the light o f this prediction or forecast I want now to refer to the President’s report where he said that of particular importance in the maintenance of a prosperous economy is the re sponsibility of leaders of business and labor to reach agreements on wages and other labor benefits that are consistent with productivity prospects and with the maintenance of a stable dollar. My question is, How can we develop a mechanism by which leaders of business and labor assume this responsibility? I wonder if Mr. Gainsbrugh would like to comment on that? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . Let me go back to your first question while I think about the second one. I think we have backed up price pres sures already in the hopper as we enter 1957 that will be at work upon the price structure in 1957. There are increases at the wholesale price level that have not yet materialized in the retail price index which will show up a 2-, 3-, or 4-month time lag. I think again, the basic reason for the price pressures over and above those that Mr. Clague has cited, is the fact that wages went up faster than did productivity and, as a result, unit labor costs rose. Over a long period of time, we find a very tight correlation between the rise in unit labor cost of manufactured products and the subse quent prices of those manufactured products. There is one further comment: We have already been told about the emerging wage pattern for 1957. These are almost always given ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 155 in terms of major contracts that call for further increases in wages in 1957. I have forgotten the figures that Mr. Clague gave us but let us say they center around 8 cents more or less. Mr. C l a g u e . 6 t o 8 cen ts. Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I f that is the pattern just these wage increases alone are again on the verge above the probable gain in productivity, if not at that particular point. Let us assume a 2 to 3 percent in crease in national productivity and no new breakthrough in the wage pattern for 1957. We already have banked up wage increases that will be about equal to the gains in productivity in 1957 unless the gains in productivity are exceptional. I do not think we have found an answer yet to how you deal with this particular problem anywhere in the Western World. That is, the problem of rendering our full-employment goals compatible with price stability. I am perfectly willing to concede that hortatory measures may be no more successful in the future than they have been in the past. The course of the economy reflects these pressures in the face of the desires of the employer to hold down prices or of the employee to keep wage increases consistent with productivity. At least this has been the pattern so far. I f I were asked to single out one approach that might be productive, I would suspect it would have to be the educational process, singling out this particular phenomenon for national attention, holding hear ings as you are now doing in connection with the cost patterns, the wage patterns, and the price patterns of our major industries, and perhaps through that mechanism, exercising some degree of restraint. The other approach that is hinted at in the President’s message is through direct controls of one type or another—and these are not specified or developed—as compared with the voluntary mechanism. I am hopeful that through the educational process we can restore a better balance between wages, costs, and prices than we now have. Mr. E n s l e y . It is one of the most difficult problems currently facing us. Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . Yes, sir. Mr. E n s l e y . Would it be permissible to insert at the end of Mr. Paradiso’s statement some correspondence with the Secretary of Com merce with respect to data underlying the President’s Economic Re port? Chairman P a t m a n . Without objection, that is so ordered. The bankers use an expression, “ moral suasion.” Do you go that far or do you just say “ education” ? Mr. G a i n s b r u g h . I would use both. Representative C u r t i s . Mr. Ensley’s line of questioning, particu larly about these pent-up forces, raises some question in my own mind on that agricultural picture. I have not thought it out but I will be interested in your reply, Mr. Wells, in regard to the relationship of Government subsidies in our agricultural economy. It was pointed out that we are experiencing what amounts to pent-up forces that are now coming out in our na tional expenditures. Realizing that the price of agricultural goods does make up 30 per cent of the budget, would you think that that is a type of pent-up 156 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT force that is exhibiting itself as having inflationary effects now? I have not thought it through and I am wondering if it has any bearing. Mr. W e l l s . There are several observations I would like to make partly to your question and partly to Mr. Clague’s comments. I did try to make the point that the agricultural budget last year, this year, and next year is partly paying the cost of pressures which were built up during 5 years of decline in prices, that is, averaging it out. Representative C u r t i s . That is what I am directing my question to. Mr. W e l l s . It is a fact that over those years, for about 59 months, prices were falling and they did give stability to the cost-of-living index. Mr. Clague suggests that perhaps what happens to the cost-oiliving index during this year is more closely tied with farm prices than with anything else. I, of course, would have to differ with Mr. Clague. In the first place, although about 30 percent of his budget is food, about 60 per cent of that is not farm prices. The farmer gets about 40 percent of the food dollar and that means that 18 percent of the consumer price index is goods and services beyond the farm level that are associated with food. Representative C u r t i s . I have just a word of caution. I, of course, have heard that presentation but I have also noticed that a great deal of the processing of foods is now being done on the farm, more particu larly in our large mechanized farms, or right nearby. This actually gets directly into the farm economy itself. But essentially your point is well taken. Mr. W e l l s . I personally think that the rise in the price of the farmfood commodities from the level that was prevailing in December will be quite modest indeed. I think we have had most of our rise in farm prices during the last 12 months. I would place more emphasis than Mr. Clague does on this auto matic round of wage increases plus the negotiated wage increases which will accompany it as an inflationary factor during the coming year. I am also more interested, I think, than our discussion here has so far led us, in the kind of consumer and business psychology that is going to prevail at the end of this year than I am with the actual level of averages for the year. I do not know whether I make myself clear or not. We live through time and what I am interested in is, How are we going into 1958? I think there a great deal depends on Mr. Katona’s consumer. Now, I happen to believe that Mr. Clague’s index is an excellent index, but there is one type of inflationary pressure that Mr. Clague’s index does not measure and that is the desire of the American con sumer to upgrade his standard of living. I f American consumers all decide they want pushbutton, two-tone automobiles with tubeless tires instead of secondhand cars, and if half of them decide to buy deep freezes or color televisions, the increase in buying pressures which flow from such optimistic consumer and business attitudes is, I think, one of the chief factors in such situations as developed in 1955 and 1956. Now, in 1954, for the first time American business spent more money advertising in a year of falling consumer demand than they had spent the previous year. They conditioned the American consumer to want more, or so my advertising friends claim. These questions as to what ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 157 influences consumer psychology interest me just as much as what influ ences the businessman’s expectations and capital expenditures. What kind of a frame of mine are the American consumer and the American businessmen going to have going out of 1957 into 1958 ? Representative C u r t is . Thank you. Mr. C la g u e . I have just two points. Mr. Wells and I are not in basic disagreement at all. I would like to clarify what I meant when I said food was important in our index. Food happens to move seasonally and it swings up and down during the year. We will have rising food prices until we get the summer markets and then those prices fall. In the meantime, however, food may be the one factor that will make our index move more in the short run, that is, in the spring of 1957* I have assumed all along that the other factors, rents ana the services and perhaps certain other commodities, will increase slowly as they have been doing. But he did not give me that assurance. I have one last point. I want to make sure that I get it clear to the committee. Mr. Wells said it correctly but I want to emphasize it so there will be no misunder standing. Our index does not put into the price of an automobile the rising standard of living that Mr. Wells was talking about. He said it correctly; we factor that out. A rising standard of living means more purchasing power by consumers, but our index does not show what that is. We have not designed it to do that. We designed it to show the rising costs of the same kind of market basket and, as far as possible, the same quality of goods. Mr. K a t o n a . Mr. Chairman, may I make a short remark on interest rates? Mr. Curtis has correctly pointed out that the savings and loan associations have profited substantially from the fact that they paid higher interest rates than other savings mediums. Now, that is a differential effect and does not change the fact that the average saver does not save more if interest rates go up. We have at the present time a rather unfavorable differential effect. For most Americans the most popular and most favored savings medium is still United States Government savings bonds. United States savings bonds, which had a relatively favorable interest rate over 10 years, are now in an unfavorable position as compared to other savings mediums. Secondly, what is missing there is “upgrading.” People want some thing new and something added, and savings bonds have not changed over the past few years. I personally believe that some people save less because their favorite medium is less attractive than, differentially speaking, it had been 5 years ago. One question for the Congress of the United States, I believe, is whether that should continue or whether some changes in the interest structure or tax privileges of United States Government savings bonds should not be introduced. Chairman P a t m a n . I just want to ask you, Mr. Wells, to place in your testimony, if you please, the month-by-month figures for farm prices during the 59 months that you mentioned farm prices went down, from February of 1951. 158 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Mr. W e l l s . I w ou ld be g la d to d o that. (The material referred to follows:) , , , Prices received by farmers prices paid or parity index and parity ratio, United States by months February 1951—January 1957 , [1910-14*100] Date Prices received index1 Parity index 2 Parity ratio a 277 281 284 284 113 311 312 285 285 288 290 289 290 290 288 287 288 100 1951—February., March____ April.......... M ay.......... June.......... July........... August___ September. October___ November. December _ 1952—January. __ February. _ March....... April......... M ay_____ June______ July........... August___ September. October__ November. Dccenrber1953—January February.. March....... April......... M ay.......... June_____ July........... August___ September. October___ November. December. 294 291 292 297 303 306 299 293 291 292 291 290 292 294 275 269 267 260 263 257 258 255 256 255 282 281 284 281 282 280 280 277 278 279 277 276 277 278 111 110 108 106 104 103 103 105 107 104 101 101 101 100 101 102 102 101 Date 1954—January - .. February.. March....... April......... M ay.......... June......... July.......... August___ September October.... November. December . 1955—January. ... February.. March...... April_____ M ay.......... June.......... July.......... August___ September. October.... November. December1956—January ..... February.. March...... A pril.____ May.......... June.......... July.......... August.... September. October.... November. December _ 1957—January. Prices received index1 258 255 257 255 247 246 248 246 214 242 246 242 241 235 229 226 227 228 235 242 247 244 237 236 234 234 237 Parity Parity index2 ratio3 284 91 91 90 91 90 281 280 279 279 279 87 87 86 284 284 85 S7 282 282 281 280 279 280 279 278 281 280 282 284 286 286 287 288 287 287 289 290 292 86 86 86 85 84 83 84 82 80 80 80 8! 81 83 S5 86 85 82 82 82 81 82 82 1 Index of prices received by farmers. * Index of prices paid by farmers for commodities used in farm production and farm family living, includ ing allowances for wage rates paid hired farm labor and interest and taxes per acre of farm real estate. 3 Ratio of index of prices received to index of prices and cost rates paid by farmers. Source: Agricultural Marketing Service. Chairman P a t m a n . Would it be asking too much of you or should I ask Mr. Clague to do this: To take the information that you have and ascertain what the cost of living index would have been!had farm prices gone up during that period of time as industrial prices went up. (Seep. 598.) ! Mr. W e l l s . I think Mr. Clague and I could come to an agreement on that. That is on the assumption, Mr. Chairman, that nothing else would have changed. Chairman P a tm a n . Without objection, the committee will stand in recess until tomorrow morning at 10 o’clock in this room. (Whereupon, at 12:20 p. m., the hearing in the above-entitled matter was recessed to reconvene at 10 a. m. Thursday, January 31, 1957.) JANUARY 1957 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT THURSDAY, JA N U A R Y 31, 1957 C ongress of t h e J o in t E U n it e d co n o m ic S tates, C o m m it t e e , W ashington,) D . 0 . The committee met at 10 a. m., pursuant to recess, in room P-63 of the Capitol, Hon. Wright Patman (chairman of the joint com mittee) presiding. Present: Representatives Patman, Bolling, Mills, Talle, Curtis, and Kilburn; Senators Sparkman, O’Mahoney, and Watkins. Present also: Dr. Grover W. Ensley, executive director of the joint committee, and John W. Lehman, clerk of the joint committee. Chairman P a t m a n . The meeting will come to order. We are all aware of the upward trend in prices. A panel of dis tinguished economists told this committee yesterday that prices are likely to continue upward during the coming year. The Economic Eeport expresses concern about this situation. The President indicated the limitations of Federal monetary and fiscal policy in maintaining economic stability under present circumstances. Much of the President’s report is in the form of exhortation to leaders of business and labor to exhibit statesmanship in their wage negotia tions and pricing policies. Today we have assembled a panel of economists to discuss price changes and policy implications. We have submitted to them ques tions as to the amount and nature of recent price changes, factors in price changes, and implications for policy. Every attempt has been made to secure a well-balanced group of witnesses. In order to expedite the discussion the Chair will recognize each of the 8 panel members for purposes of making an opening statement of 8 minutes, summarizing the views of the witness. We will proceed without interruption through the opening statements, following which there will be general discussion by members of the committee and the panel. The committee staff will notify each speaker when his 8 min utes has expired. Our first witness this morning is Mr. Leon H. Keyserling, economic consultant, and former Chairman of the President’s Council of Eco nomic Advisers. Mr. Keyserling, you are recognized for 8 minutes. STATEMENT OF LEON H. KEYSERLING, CONSULTING ECONOMIST Mr. K e y s e r lin g . Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, we should all be concerned about price rises which, during the past 12 months, have been more than 4 percent for industrial prices, about 3 159 160 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT percent for consumer prices, and in the case of such items as steel more than twice as much. At the same time, we should not confuse this situation with the wartime overall inflationary situation; and be cause the two situations are being confused, we are doing the wrong things in the wrong places in our national economic policies. We are inflating the parts of the economy that are inflated, deflating the parts that are deflated, sacrificing our great national objectives which we must achieve for world security, and neglecting to fight inflation in reasonable ways. In an overall economic inflation such as during World War I I there were shortages of everything. The economy was growing at more than a normal rate. Because there were shortages of everything, all prices were going up. The proper approach in those times was to use the classic anti-inflationary weapons all along the line. The situation today is entirely different. There are some shortages, but there are lots of surpluses. Some prices and incomes are going up too fast, other prices and incomes are going down much too fast. We have mixed inflationary and deflationary forces operating at the same time. To illustrate, the rate of our economic growth is slowing down, and, as underscored by the Symington report of 2 days ago on airpower and by the statement in the New York Times today that the Russians in recent years have expanded their industrial output by 10 to 11 percent, the slowdown of our rate o f economic growth is real and serious. We grew by more than 41/£ percent annually in real terms during the first few years after World War II. We slowed down to 2.6 percent an nually during the last 4 years. During the past 12 months we have grown only by 2.5 percent. The consensus or unanimity of witnesses yesterday was that our real rate of growth would be even slower in the next 12 months. Therefore, we are faced with this dilemma: I f we apply to the economy the repressive measures which are desirable in an overall inflationary situation, we are saying that we can afford and should try to grow only one-fifth or one-fourth as fast as the Russians. Second, the selective inflationary trends of today represent distor tions, rather than overall inflation. I have on page 6 of my statement the details of this. I don’t have the time to give all the tacts in my opening statement. In summary, the essence of the recent situation has been an expansion of an investment boom in plant and equipment at more than a sustain able rate relative to the growth of consumption. This has been under pinned during the last 4 years by an increase in certain types of in comes, big business profits, dividend income, interest income, at a more than sustainable rate, and a progressive falling behind in the under pinning of consumption which rests primarily in wage payments and farm income. We cannot cure these distortions by pouring oil on the flames of inflation where it exists and water on the embers of de flationary sectors. Yet current national economic policies are directed toward these purposes. For example, first of all there is the hard money policy. The hard money policy has practically no effect whatsoever upon the relatively excessive rate of growth o f investment, or the relatively excessive growth o f prices and incomes in some parts of the economy. The very large companies which have been contributing to the investment boom, ECONOMIC REPORT OP THE PRESIDENT 161 which has been relatively too fast, are not affected by the hard money policy. They finance out of their own resources, out of depreciation re serves, and out of the price structure. They finance in advance out of the consumer before they build their plants, and after they build their plants they use the increased productivity to be paid again for the same plants, and then they use the fact that wage increases come along at that time as a justification for still further price increases. In contrast, the hard money policy is pouring water on the embers. It is deflating farm income further by making the financing of crops harder. It is forcing out the marginal small-business man. It is decreasing the ability of consumers to buy durable goods. As a matter of fact, during the past 12 months, consumer buying has increased only by 2 percent m real terms, or even less than the extremely low 2% percent rate of growth in the overall economy. This has not been due to excessive saving. It has been due to inadequate consumer income, as I can elaborate when I have more time. Third, the budgetary policies of the Federal Government have also poured water on the fuels of inflation and failed to deal with the bottle necks and shortages which are inflationary in the short run, and de flationary in the long run. We hear that the new budget is the biggest budget m peacetime. Realistically measured, it is the smallest. Since 1953, the budget of the Federal Government has shrunk from 20 percent to 16 percent of the size of the national economy represented by gross national product. I f we could afford this so-called economy now, in terms of our international needs and our domestic deficiencies, I would be for it. But it certainly throws a lot of doubt on the tradi tional classical palaverings about the causes of inflation to have the kind of price inflation we have now when we have been running a nice budgetary surplus, and when Federal budgetary outlays have decreased by 20 percent relative to the size of the economy. Actually, the Federal budgetary outlays are not directing them selves to the specific bottleneck situations, such as the inadequacy of resource development. This is inflationary. And infinitely more important, they are not directing themselves to the world situation. Let us remember that even during World War II, when we had an infinitely more inflationary situation, we did not throw out the baby with the bath. Even then, we did not, as the theoretical economists would have had us do, collect in taxes all that we spent. Because while theoretically that would have been anti-inflationary, we also had to remember that it was even more important not to disrupt our pro ductive system. Nor did we during World War I I decide that, be cause we were fighting inflation, we should fight Hitler at half speed. We put first things first, and that is the purpose of a Federal budget. I do not mean that we should run a Federal deficit now. But we could spend more to meet basic needs, stimulate a more adequate rate of growth, and still run a budget surplus. The Federal budget of today is defective from the viewpoint of fighting inflation, defective from the viewpoint of our national needs, and the hard money policy is even more upside down. Now, the current inflation is not caused by an overall excess of demand. You certainly do not have an overall excess of demand, when your economy is slowing down more and more below its normal rate of growth. But some people say that the current inflation is 162 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT being caused by cost pressures operating against the price structure, namely and specifically by wages. This is erroneous. Let us take the steel industry as an example. Is our business man agement so lacking in judgment that they will pay out more and more m dividends every year when they do not have ample funds for plant expansion? The answer is obviously no. Why are dividends rising more and more month by month and year by year if profits, the func tion of which are to finance expansion, are inadequate? As I have said before, they have had ample funds to finance expansion, and yet they have been financing largely out of the consumer, out of the price structure, out of the retained earnings, and out of tax favors from the Government. There has not been the kind of pressure upon costs which could justify these kinds of price increases. In fact, we are faced with a situation which national economic policy has not come abreast of. It is not an overall inflationary situation. It is not an overall deflationary situation. It is a mixed situation. In a mixed situation, we have to solve this conundrum: How can we maintain a high enough level of economic activity to use our resources effec tively and to meet the world threat confronting us, and do justice to the underserved portions of our population, and at the same time avoid a price inflation which in the current situation is not resulting from general overstrain, is not resulting from general shortages, but instead is resulting from the tendency of an administered price system to get what it can while it can? So long as we have our kind of economic system, and I believe we are going to have this kind of system, and I am for this kind of system, then we must find ways to combat this par ticular kind of selective and administered price inflation. May I say what kind of selective inflation is now combined with selective deflation? It is in part the cause of the inadequate rate of economic growth, because the same restrictionary policies which are contributing to the price inflation are not expanding capacity enough. It is in part the result of an inadequate rate of economic growth. It is causing deflationary tendencies in other parts of the economy. We now have not a problem of general inflation, but a problem of bad balance. We have to adjust our national economic policies to restore a better balance, and I recommend the following policies. My 8 minutes are up. My prepared statement covers the subject in detail, and includes my recommendations. Thank you very much. (The statement follows:) S u m m a ry o f F u l l S ta te m e n t o f Mb. K e y s e k l i n g There is proper concern about combating the inflationary price trends in various parts of the economy. But current national economic policies and programs are seriously tending to fight the wrong enemies in the wrong battles at the wrong time and in the wrong places. This is because these policies and programs are utilizing, though to a lesser degree, some o f the broadside weapons which were appropriate to the type o f overall inflationary situation characteristic o f wartime, when the total resources o f the economy were over strained, when total demand far exceeded total supply, when the overaU growth rate o f the economy was abnormally high, and when commodity shortages almost everywhere were pushing up prices almost everywhere. The situation today is entirely different, and calls for highly selective treatment. The economy as a whole is not overstrained; the rate o f economic growth has fallen to seriously low levels; shortages in a few selective areas are accompanied by surpluses or ample supplies in most areas; and excessive price, income, and investment trends in some parts o f the economy are accompanied by excessively low price, income, and production trends in other parts o f the economy. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 163 We are now in a mixed situation, where there is not general inflation caused by an overstrained general economy, but rather a selective and distorted inflation, and a selective deflation, which are in part the result o f and in part the cause of our economy’s lagging far behind an optimum rate of economic activity and real growth. Yet the Federal budgetary policy is in the overall on the repressive rather than the expansionary side. It is designed to short-change the national security which we need most for our national survival, and to short-change the development of natural and human resources which we need for adequate economic growth. Yet it is not designed in detail to break some o f the specific bottlenecks or remove some specific shortages which are contributing to the immediate inflationary pressures. The credit and monetary policies, including the hard money policy, are repressing the rate of overall economic growth, and adding to the distortions in the economy by pouring oil on the flames o f selective inflation and water on the embers o f selective deflation. A Federal budget which has been reduced from 20.8 percent o f our total national production in fiscal 1953 to about 16 percent now is cramping the things that we need most as a Nation. A hard money policy which is making it harder to build schools is having the same effect. An exhortation to labor to be more restrained with respect to wages fundamentally misreads the current economic situation, which is characterized in the overall by a nonsustainable investment boom getting more out of line with inadequate consumption. Price increases which largely represent the administered judgments o f business, with out basic economic justification, are attributed to the wrong causes and as sailed with paper swords. The problem o f building our world strength, and the problem of combating vigorously the first lurking signs o f deflationary forces, are being relegated to the sidelines, while attention is being concentrated upon inveighing against an overall inflationary situation that does not exist while ignoring or neglecting both the selective inflationary dangers and the selective deflationary dangers which do exist and interact upon each other. Instead o f this, we need a more vigorous effort to expand production, and to elevate our rate o f overall economic growth to attainable and desirable levels. To meet our full needs, we must have maximum production. We need a Federal budgetary policy which carries forward the things we need most, and if this should in fact cause inflationary pressures, we should be prepared to restrain the superfluous ra ther than the essential. W e need specific programs or incentives to break some o f the bottlenecks— such as steel capacity—which are cramping the whole economy, instead o f trying to force the economy into the bottle through the narrow neck. We need a comprehensive congressional investigation, from top to bottom, o f why some prices are rising so much when the economy as a whole is lagging, and when there is no intrinsic justification for many o f these price rises. We need a reversal o f the hard money policy, which hits the economy where it is most vulnerable, and aids those who need no stimulus. We need, from the Council of Economic Advisers through the Economic Report o f the President, a far more alert responsiveness to the mandates o f the Employment Act o f 1946. Currently, the Council is not setting forth needed levels of employment, produc tion, and purchasing power, and thus it is providing no concrete guides to economic adjustments, programs or policies. F u l l S t a t e m e n t of M r . K e y s e r l i n g Mr. Chairman and members o f the committee, your inquiry into the many signs of price inflation is vital and urgent. It is my hope that your general examination o f this subject may shed light upon and be followed shortly by a detailed investigation o f the whole price situation by the appropriate committees o f the Congress. During the past 12 months, the consumer price index has risen about 3 percent, the wholesale price index for all commodities has risen about 4 percent, and some prices in critical areas have risen far more. It would be dangerous i f these inflationary trends were ignored or neglected. But the far greater actual danger today is that, substituting excitement for clear analysis, we are applying some national economic policies and programs which intensify rather than reduce the current inflationary dangers; misread the nature o f the economic situation and therefore contain ultimate threat of a deflationary spiral; and, above all, throw out the baby with the bath by neglecting national security and domestic needs which are more imperative than absolute price stability, although the more adequate servicing o f these needs would also contribute to 164 ECONOMIC REPORT OP THE PRESIDENT price stability. Due to the lag in economic thinking and its practical application, we are in process o f fighting the wrong enemies, in the wrong battles, at the wrong time, and in the wrong places. The economic problems o f depression and wartime inflation created approaches which were not completely effective when used, and which in any event now lead to gross oversimplification and misdirection o f effort when applied to the current situation. An examination o f some history is essential to an understanding o f the current situation. During the great depression, we suffered from tremendous underutilization o f our total resources, accompanied by a negative rate o f economic growth from year to year. This was reflected in surpluses o f goods or o f productive capaci ties almost all along the line, accompanied by sharply falling prices almost all along the line. To reverse these trends, the formula was developed that Gov ernment spending and deficit financing should be greatly increased, and that credit should be made very abundant and very cheap. There is now common acceptance that this approach was correct. But it nonetheless was an over simplification, because it did not sufficiently stress that the causes and cures o f our economic difficulties are complex and manifold. Not enough attention was paid, for example, to the quasi-independent factor o f business investment Not enough attention was paid to the fact that Government spending and deficit financing could not be increased rapidly enough, nor credit availability expanded enough, to do the whole job. To have attempted the whole job through these devices would have involved the Government in a range and scope o f activities far beyond the very nature o f our economic system in peacetime. Consequently, full prosperity was not restored until World War II, which is another way of saying that the lifting o f the economy from unusual depths through prime reUance upon the spending power o f government involved operations of a size tolerable only in wartime. There is common acceptance today o f the proposition that there was much inadequacy and oversimplification in the idea that severe deflation could be fought successfully by enlarged government spending, deficit financing, and easy credit. Yet, today, we are applying this oversimplification in reverse. W e are running into the serious error o f trying to fight so-called inflationary dangers by excessive reliance on a tight control of government spending, budgetary sur pluses, tight credit, and hard money. This would be too narrow an approach, even if we were confronted with general and overall inflationary pressures o f the wartime type. But it is a doubly dangerous approach today, when the socalled inflationary pressures are of an entirely different type, indicative o f en tirely different fundamental economic conditions, and fraught with entirely different types o f perils. To illustrate this, we must compare the wartime inflationary situation with the enormously contrasting conditions o f today. In the early stages o f World W ar II, for example, the total private and public demand for goods and services far exceeded the Nation’s total productive power, even when the economy was operating at top levels and expanding at an unusually fast rate o f real economic growth. There were shortages all along the line, for farm products as well as for industrial products. These conditions generated sharply upward price movements all along the line. To prevent price inflation from rationing goods in the wrong direction under such conditions, there was need for the classic anti-inflationary weapons: very high taxes, drastic restraints o f credit, and even price and wage controls. There was need also to defer civilian housing, school and hospital construction, road building, and a wide range o f consumer goods including automobiles. But even during W orld War II, we did not let the theoretical economists run away with us and substitute theory for sound policy. Despite the need to fight inflation, we did not lift taxes enough to achieve a budgetary surplus, because to do so would have distorted the whole process o f productive expansion through the use o f our enterprise system. Nor did we, through preoccupation with the fight against inflation, decide to fight Hitler at half speed. We redoubled our efforts with respect to the things we needed most, and put aside the superfluous instead o f foregoing the essential. Above all, although it created some additional inflationary strains, we concen trated upon the expansion o f total production at far above the normal rate, so as to get closer to a situation where we could enjoy without inflationary strains some o f the thi ngs we needed less. In the Korean war situation, we faced the same types o f problems in smaUer size. There were some who wanted to fight inflation solely by cutbacks o f ci vilian production, and by freezing all prices, profits, and wages. Believing that this would be a highly undesirable approach, I took the contrary view that we should combine appropriate anti-inflationary measures with vast efforts to ex- ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 164a LABOR AND FARM INCOMES, l953-'56 GREW TOO SLOWLY RELATIVE TO OTHER INCOMES TO SUSTAIN FULL PROSPERITY Averoge Annual Rotes of Change in 1955 Oollars + 7 .0 % THE BALANCE WAS BETTER IN 1947-53 (Farm Income Did Decline, but Less Than in 1953-'56) Average Annual R ates of Change in 1955 Oollars + 5 .7 % Oatai 1947*1955, Dept of Commerce; 1956 estimated by Conference on Economic Progress on basis of first half year ond Outlook. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 165 panti production, and particularly the industrial base o f production, as the most fundamental solution to many foreseeable years of high national security efforts in a critical world situation. This broader approach was successful, to the degree that by the middle of 1951 and for several years thereafter we enjoyed relative price stability because we had brought our productive genius to bear upon the problems confronting us. I f we had not done this, we not only would have failed to put first things first, but we would also have had more inflation— first suppressed and then overt—for a longer period of time. These experiences have some bearing upon the economic situation today, and some implications for current policy which I shall come to shortly. But first o f all, we must grasp firmly the supremely important fact that the so-called infla tionary pressures of today are entirely different in all respects from those during World War II or during the early stages of the Korean war. The inflationary trends of today are occurring, not when the economy as a whole is overtaxed or growing at an excessively fast rate, but rather when the total private and public demand for goods and services is far short of the Nation’s productive po tential, and when the overall rates of economic activity and expansion have for some time been much too low. The so-called inflation of today is not general but highly selective, and reflects increasing distortions in the whole economic structure. While some prices and incomes and lines o f activity have been ad vancing too fast in absolute or relative terms, other types o f prices or incomes or lines o f activity have been advancing too slowly in absolute or relative terms, or standing still, or falling dangerously backward. Under such circumstances, inflationary and deflationary forces are commingled; and the inflationary trends, instead of reflecting an excessive overall rate of economic activity or growth, are in fact the types o f distortions which are holding overall economic activity and growth far below normal or desirable levels and are threatening the emer gence of a deflationary spiral. Meanwhile, Government policies and programs have tended to slow down the things we need more of, stimulate some of the things we need less of, and add both to the inflationary and deflationary dangers by accentuating the distortions. Let us now examine the facts supporting these propositions. (1) The overall growth rate of the economy has been slowing down dangerously. During the seven-year period 1947-53, the total economy expanded at an aver age annual rate of about 4.7 percent, measured in uniform 1955 dollars; during 1953-56, the rate fell to about 2.6 percent; and from fourth quarter 1955 to fourth quarter 1956, the expansion was only about 2.5 percent. The average annual rate of our real growth during the past 40 years has been about 3 percent, and since World War II much higher. Thus, it is clear that recent developments have swung far below the rates of growth consistent with full and efficient use without inflation o f a growing labor force and a rapidly advancing technology. The majority judgment o f business analysts today is that, at best, the economy will continue to exhibit only about this excessively low rate of real growth in the coming year. This unsatisfactory outlook is due primarily to the inability of the investment boom in plant and equipment to continue to expand so much more rapidly than general consump tion, and due correspondingly to the inadequate expansion o f consumer demand for residential construction, other durables, and some soft goods. On the do mestic front, this means that the central economic problem of today is to enlarge the overall rate of economic growth, lest the insufficient absorption o f a rapidly growing labor force and a rapidly growing technology result in the emergence of powerful deflationary forces. However, the world situation is the overwhelm ingly urgent reason why we need greatly to accelerate our rate of economic growth. The Soviets are now expanding four to five times as fast as we are in real terms, and allocating a much larger part of their total production to the military and economic aspects of the world struggle. Our own long-range experience makes it preposterous to assert that we cannot grow much faster than 2.5 percent a year without general inflationary pressures. And the world situation makes it imperative that we grow faster, even if this generated some selective inflationary pressures, which should then be counter acted by effective measures. In fact, the low rate of economic growth itself con tributes to current inflationary pressures. It discourages adequate expansion of productive facilities, and thus creates bottlenecks. It encourages the tendency to substitute higher prices for bigger sales. It reflects shortages in some resource areas, which we say we cannot afford to overcome because the economy is not growing rapidly enough to support the needed programs, while in fact these shortages are cramping the rate o f growth and thus will be highly inflationary in the long run. 166 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT And as already indicated, the excessively low rate o f economic growth is the product of existing inflationary distortions, even while the low rate o f growth contributes to further distortions. (2) The selective inflationary trends of today reflect and create serious im balances and distortions within the general economy, which do not result from an excessive overall rate of economic activity and growth, but instead stunt overall economic growth and threaten economic stability. During the 1953-56 period as a whole, farm income from all sources has dropped 8.3 percent, in constant dollars, while national income has increased 11*5 percent; and farm prices have dropped 8.5 percent while industrial prices have risen 7.2 percent, consumer prices 1.6 percent, and retail food prices dropped only 1.0 percent. During the same period as a whole, personal interest income has been advancing about 65 percent faster than wages, and dividend income has been advancing about 75 percent faster than wages. Corporate profits have been advancing about 29 percent faster than the personal income o f the people as a whole, even while the ratio o f small business profits after taxes to big business profits after taxes has declined from about 70 percent in 1952 to about 50 percent in 1955; some improvement appeared in this ratio in 1956. These disparate trends have been both cause and effect o f the growth in our productive facilities at a much more rapid rate than the growth in con sumption, which in the long term view has deflationary rather than inflationary implications. From fourth quarter 1955 to fourth quarter 1956, while investment in plant and equipment grew about 10 percent in real terms, consumption grew only about 2 percent. And because disposable personal income in real terms has grown even more slowly than consumption, even this inadequate growth in con sumption has needed support from a nonsustainable credit boom. Under these circumstances, it is a complete misreading o f the situation to complain that wages have been advancing too fast, or to assert that this is the central cause of price inflation. While there is a real problem of unevenness in the wage structure, and of lifting low-income families relatively faster than others, con sumer incomes, of which wages are the major portion, have been advancing much too slowly to maintain balance between investment and consumption at a satisfactory rate o f economic growth. Nor in the main have the wage increases as a cost factor necessitated the price increases; the excessive relative rate o f investment, and the constant lifting o f dividend payments to new heights, indi cate that profits in the overall have been more than adequate to support their investment and income functions. (3) Most of the specific price increases, under these circumstances, have not been due generally to an inflationary strain on resources. Consumer prices and even food prices have been advancing. But this has not been due to an undersupply o f clothing or o f food ; both o f these areas are in surplus. Some o f the price advances have been due to the power o f an adminis tered price system, under semi-monopolistic conditions, to advance prices even when productive capacities are by no means strained. Some have been caused by the predilection of an administered price system to utilize legitimate wage increases as an excuse for pyramided price increases and excessive profit margins* Of these tendencies, the steel industry is a good example. The industry raised its prices even during the economic recessions of 1949 and 1953-54, when oper ating far below capacity. The industry sought to justify its large price increases in 1956, which were several times the computed cost of the wage increases, on the ground that it needed more money to finance plant expansion. But plant expansion should be paid for out of the improved productivity and efficiency which results from the new plants; when it is paid for by the consumer before the new plants are built, there is an extra and unjustifiable payment. The steel industry has kept its capacity too low, so that it is now operating at more than 100 percent o f capacity, and has operated too close to capacity in all fully prosperous years. Today, there is a steel shortage which operates as a bottle neck on the whole economy. Compared with 1953 as a whole, wholesale industrial prices by the fourth quarter of 1956 had risen only about 9 percent, while steel prices had risen more than 22 percent. Comparing fourth quarter 1956 with 1955 as a whole, industrial prices rose only 6 percent while steel prices rose about 12 percent. The disparities in fact are greater, because the index o f industrial prices includes steel prices. We are now confronted with a situation, where most o f the price rises are due, not to genuine inflationary pressures but ECONOMIC REPOBT OF THE PRESIDENT 167 rather to concentrated economic power unwisely exercised. This threatens deflation more than it threatens inflation, and this is the problem with which we need predominantly to deal. (4) The budgetary policies of the Government have not been responsible for these selective inflationary trends; they have been responsible for the in adequate rate of overall economic growth and for some of the distortions in the structure Federal budgetary outlays for national security have declined from 14.1 percent o f our total national production in fiscal 1953 to an estimated 9.6 per cent in the current fiscal year 1957. Thus, the proportion o f our total annual production being channeled into this priority purpose has decreased by 32 percent within 4 years. Federal budgetary outlays for all purposes other than national security have declined from an annual average o f 8.3 percent of total national production during the fiscal years 1947-53 to only an estimated 6.6 percent in the current fiscal year. The total Federal Budget, which represented a ratio o f 20.8 percent to our total national production in the fiscal year 1953, has fallen to a ratio o f about 16.2 percent in the current fiscal year 1957. These trends may also be shown in terms o f outlays for goods and services, which relate more closely to gross national product. The President’s new Budget, which is mistakenly called “ the biggest ever in peacetime,” would represent only an estimated 16.1 percent of estimated total national production in the fiscal year 1958. These downward trends in the relationship between the Federal Budget and the national economy, ac companied by nice-looking budgetary surpluses in the most recent years, demon strate conclusively the error o f the notion that inflationary or anti-inflationary price trends can be correlated with the Federal Budget alone. We have recently been following, and seem committed to continue to follow, a Federal budgetary policy which has not grappled properly with the inflationary problem, but instead has succeeded only in giving lowest priority to the things we need most—national defense, international economic exertions, and domestic expan sion of such important foundations for economic stability and growth as re source development and schools. Actually, by stunting the rate o f economic growth, these Federal budgetary trends are inflationary in the short run and deflationary in the long run. They are not compatible with stable economic growth, and therefore are not compatible with stability in the price structure. (5) The credit and monetary policies of the Government, including the so-called “hard money policy ” have even more clearly been based upon a misreading of the overall economic situation; they have contributed to the distortions which mean selective inflation on the one hand and selective deflation on the other hand As an aggregative device, the hard money policy has once again demonstrated, as I have insisted on many early occasions, that it cannot stop selective price inflation without being pushed to the point that would threaten a general deflation and rapidly rising unemployment. More specifically, the hard money policy is operating directly conversely to correcting the distortions in the economic structure. It has exercised almost no effective restraint against the parts o f the economy which have been booming relatively too rapidly, such as investment in plant and equipment. The very large companies which are responsible for most o f this investment boom finance themselves by methods which leave them relatively unaffected by such restraints. But the hard money policy is operating severely against the very parts o f the economy which are relatively depressed and underutilized—the small businessman, the farmer, the homebuilder, and the low-income consumer purchaser o f durables. In addition, the hard money policy is holding back the most needed public improvements at the State and local level, and increasing by one-half to three-fourths of a billion dollars a year the cost to the Federal Government of doing the very things that we are not doing enough of. The hard money policy, in short, by handling out income bonanzas and incentives to some who do not need them, and reducing the in comes and activities o f others who are in real trouble, is pouring fuel on the fires o f inflation in some parts o f the economy and water on the embers in other parts o f the economy. 87624—57------12 168 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT BECOMMENDED PROGRAMS The lines of approach which we need to deal with the current economic situa tion and outlook, in the context of a world situation which we are told is becoming more perilous, are in sumjnary these: (1) First and foremost, we need to maximize production and economic growth. We cannot do enough of anything—and we need to do more of many things— if we keep half-hidden the productive genius which is the great non-secret weapon of the American economy. The Economic Report of the President and his budget message, instead of overemphasizing the things that we must do without, should elevate to central importance the things that we must do. Of course, we cannot do everything at once, but we must achieve the necessary before we enjoy the superfluous; and the full production we can have, in a situation short of total war, can provide both the necessary and the superfluous. (2) We need to utilize the Federal budget to provide the American people with an adequate level of national security, plus a level of basic domestic programs, with respect to our material and human resources, sufficient to reduce inflationary pressures by breaking bottlenecks and by overcoming shortages, and sufficient also to underpin an optimum rate of economic production and growth from year to year. The strongest Federal budget is that which helps to make the national economy strongest. (3) We need, through private and public economic policies combined, to correct the current distortions in the price, income, and production structure, which are increasing inflationary pressures in some areas, increasing deflationary dangers in other areas, and thus threatening us ultimately with a deflationary spiral. On the public side, this means a Federal budget which helps those first who need help most, instead of stimulating those who are out of line on the high side. To prevent the incomes of the people and the necessary outlays of Govern ment from being taxed by selective price inflation, we need a detailed congres sional investigation of the whole price situation from top to bottom. A large proportion of the recent price increases have been due, not to economic necessity, but rather to economic misbehavior. Direct controls of prices are undesirable in these times, but the watchful eye of an informed Congress and an informed public is highly desirable. (4) We need to abandon the so-called hard-money policy, which in the interest of special groups is rationing incomes and goods in the wrong direction, and holding the overall rate of economic growth to dangerously low levels. In place of this hard-money policy, we may need some more specific and selective re straints which fight selective inflationary dangers instead of injuring the econ omy and the people. (5) We cannot intelligently nor effectively apply segmental aspects of eco nomic policy, unless we have the whole perspective of the economy in operation and what we are seeking to do. The most recent material prepared by the Council of Economic Advisers, for transmission by the President in his Economic Report to the Congress, has completely disregarded the statutory requirement to state needed levels of employment, production, and purchasing power. Without these targets as benchmarks, there is no way of appraising the validity of pro posed economic policies and programs, and this explains the vacuity of the attempts by the Council to set forth or discuss forward-looking policies or programs. Mr. K e y s e r l i n g . Additional charts bearing on the matters dis cussed in this statement were presented in my testimony before the Senate Subcommittee on Disarmament on January 17, 1957, and are available in the printed hearings of that subcommittee. Chairman P a t m a n . Professor Backman, professor of the school of commerce, New York University. STATEMENT OF DR. JULES BACKMAN, PROFESSOR OF ECONOMICS, NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Mr. B a c k m a n . Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I have a more complete statement which I would like to file with the re porter, and would just like to summarize the highlights. Chairman P a tm a n . That is agreeable. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 169 Mr. B a c k m a x . The outlook is for a price rise of several percent in 1957. However, we do not face an explosive inflation spiral. The rise in prices has reflected the cost push exerted by increases in labor costs in excess of gains in productivity in a business boom which has made it relatively easy to pass these cost increases on to the buyer. There is an understandable concern with the problem of inflation. However, we are not in a period of classic inflation reflecting either Federal Government budgetary deficits or large expansions in money supply. So long as the Federal budget remains in the black and monetary policy prevents a sharp expansion in money supply, there is little likelihood of a runaway price inflation. Unless the wageprice spiral is fed by an expanding money supply, it is more likely to lead to unemployment of resources as they are* “priced out of the market” than to a major price inflation. To the extent that monetary and fiscal policy are used to blunt the boom, one of the major factors contributing to "price advances will be modified or eliminated. But there will still remain the problem of excessive increases in labor costs. Little can be done in the wage area in 1957 because “ key wage bargains” already have been reached. But we must look to the future if we are to prevent a repetition of the current situation. President Eisenhower has pointed squarely to the proper goal in this area in his statement that: Negotiated wage increases and benefits should be consistent with productivity prospects.and wtih the maintenance of a stable dollar (p. 3 ). But this objective will only be achieved if management in major industries firmly refuses to agree to labor cost increases in excess of national productivity gains and if the public is educated to under stand the dangers which arise wrlien labor cost increases exceed these amounts. What factors explain the creeping price rise which has been taking place during the past year and a half ? It is important to keep in mind that this price does not result from large Government budgetary deficits with an accompanying expansion in bank credit or from a large increase in money supply, including deposits and currency. The rise does reflect a combination of the business boom and increases in labor costs in excess of the gains in productivity. During the fiscal years 1955-56 and 1956-57, the Federal budget is estimated to be in the black. The cash surplus is in excess of $3 billion in each year. During this period the Federal debt is being reduced by modest amounts. This is clearly a picture of a Federal budget which is deflationary, not inflationary. This is a budgetary situation which is in sharp contrast to the huge deficits and accompanying tremendous rise in public debt which characterized World War II and the first postwar year with the accompanying large inflation in prices. The total money supply was increased by only about 1 percent in 1956. Under conditions'of capacity operations in key sectors of the economy, a larger rise in currency and demand deposits could only have meant further pressures on the price level. The period since mid:1955 has been marked by a further rise in labor costs of substantial proportions. Total hourly labor payments including fringes have increased by more than 10 percent on the average and in many industries by considerably more. Since mid- 170 ECONOMIC REPORT OP THE PRESIDENT 1955, it appears that increases in labor costs have far outstripped the gains in productivity in manufacturing industries. The result appears to have been a rise in unit labor costs in excess of 5 percent. The largest increases in prices were recorded for metal and metal products (14.9 percent) and machinery and motive products (12.9 percent). It is interesting to note that within the machinery group, the rise for agricultural machinery which deals with a lagging sector of the economy was 7.7 percent while the increases in prices of con struction machinery and electrical machinery, both areas of dynamic expansion, approximated 15 percent. The overall rise for fuel, power and lighting materials was only 5.9 per cent. However, one compo nent, coal prices, rose 22.8 percent under the combined influence of sharply expanding demand and large increases in wage rates. Pe troleum products rose 8.4 percent reflecting in part the Middle East situation. At the other extreme, small net declines were shown for processed foods, lumber and wood products, and farm products. The areas with the major increases in prices have been largely those in which the pressures of the boom have been greatest while the iareas in which prices have lagged have been the areas in which economic activity has not been stimulated significantly. These data also suggest that a slowing down of the boom will be the most potent force to stop the price rise. It is interesting to note that sensitive prices like copper scrap, lead scrap, and rubber have actually declined during the past year despite the general rise in the price level. This is not the behavior one would expect under conditions of general price inflation. These declines are explainable, however, in terms of the reduced level of activity which characterized the automobile industry and residential building in 1955. It is the pattern of behavior that would be expected during a boom which has an uneven impact on the economy. It is important to keep in mind that a price rise attributable to these factors will not have the same spiraling effect of an inflation flowing from monetary and fiscal factors. This is not the background for an explosive inflation. It is the background for a further modest price rise so long as the boom persists. There can be little quarrel with the President’s objective of volun tary restraint. However, we must recognize that many key sectors in the economy are not free to apply this proposed standard in 1957. For many important industries, including automobile, steel, electrical equipment, railroads, meat packing, agricultural implements, and coal, wage increases for 1957 and in some cases for 1958 have already been incorporated in contracts. In many of these industries, the negotiated wage increases are scheduled to be 6 or 7 cents an hour. In addition, provision usually is made for further adjustment in wages if the cost of living should rise. I f the rise in the consumers’ price index should be two points, it will mean a wage increase of an additional 4 cents an hour in most of the industries listed. In light of these contract provisions, we already seem assured of an increase in wage rates of 4 percent to 5 percent in 1957. Past ex perience indicates that the wage#adjustments in these^ key areas will be a very potent force in determining wage increases in other sectors ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 171 o f the economy where contracts still remain to be negotiated. Under these conditions, it is impossible for industry and labor to exercise the restraint called for by the President unless they were to reopen the existing agreements and negotiate smaller wage increases. Since the probability of such an action is completely nonexistent, it is clear that there is not much that can be done through voluntary restraint insofar as wages and other labor costs are concerned during 1957. The President warns that the failure of voluntary restraints could lead to wage-fixing and price-fixing by Government. I would like to state categorically that I am completely opposed to any such program to limit price rises in peacetime. Such a program is foredoomed to failure and can only result in disruptions to production, impairment o f incentives, and an ever-widening area of controls which will create worse evils than the control program would be designed to overcome. The effort to limit price and wage increases by exhortation has never succeeded in the past and will be no more successful under current con ditions. I believe that better results can be obtained through monetary and fiscal policy. Any restraint exercised through monetary or fiscal policy, however modest, will inevitably hurt some groups. This is unavoidable regardless of what policies are adopted. But to state the problem in these terms is to give only a partial picture. What hap pens if these restraints are not imposed and prices are permitted to spiral? Then the burden falls on the large groups who live on fixed incomes and on those whose incomes do not and cannot keep pace with an inflationary price rise. Unfortunately, there is no best policy in the sense that no one will feel its effects. There is only a “ least worst” policy in the sense that its adverse effects will be kept to a minimum. In these terms, the alternative to hurting some groups who do not contribute to the inflation is to hurt still larger groups who do not contribute to the inflationary pressures. Do we seriously believe that we are making every effort to combat inflation on the monetary front when mortgage credit, consumer credit, and bank credit continue to expand at near record rates? And is mortgage credit excessively restrictive with the present low down pay ments and 30-year maturities for mortgages? The Federal Reserve Board “ has leaned against the wind,” to use Mr. Martin’s descriptive phrase, but it certainly has not leaned far enough to be in danger of falling over. I f stronger fiscal and monetary restraints are required to halt an inflation they should be imposed. The evils attending inflation are more serious than those attending strong anti-inflation policies. Thank you. (Mr. Backman’s prepared statement follows:) S t a t e m e n t op D e . J u l e s B a c k m a n P rofessob of E c o n o m ic s , N e w Y ork U n iv e b s it y THE ANATOMY OF THE PRICE RISE Since June 1955, the wholesale price index has risen by 5.3 percent However, there has been a wide variation in the behavior o f individual prices and groups o f prices. It is instructive to determine the areas o f the economy which have experienced the greatest price rises as a background against which to evaluate the causal forces and the adequacy o f proposed policies. I have prepared sev 172 ECONOMIC REPOET OP THE PRESIDENT eral tables which show the changes in wholesale prices since June 1955 and since December 1955. Because of the seasonal price movement for many food and farm products, comparisons between June and December inevitably involve some distortion when allowance is not made for seasonal factors. When comparisons are made between the same months o f successive years, this problem o f seasonal price movements is overcome. Table 1 shows the changes in wholesale prices by major industry groups from June 1955 to December 1956. The changes are arrayed in order o f magnitude. The overall rise was 5.3 percent in the wholesale price index and 7.8 percent in the index for commodities other than farm products and foods during this period. The largest increases were recorded for metal and metal products (14.9 percent) and machinery and motive products (12.9 percent). It is interesting to note that within the machinery group, the rise for agricultural machinery, which deals with a lagging sector o f the economy, was 7.7 percent while the increases in prices of construction machinery and electrical machinery, both areas of dynamic expansion, approximated 15 percent. The overall rise for fuel power and lighting materials was only 5.9 percent. This smaller than average rise resulted from the fact that one component, elec tricity, showed a small decline and another component, gas, was about un changed. In contrast, coal prices rose 22.8 percent under the combined influence o f sharply expanding demand and large increases in wage rates. Petroleum products rose 8.4 percent, reflecting in part the Middle East situation. At the other extreme, small net declines were shown for processed foods, lumber and wood products, and farm products. An examination of table 1 indicates that the major increases have taken place in those sectors of the economy which have been most stimulated by the boom or in industries in which labor costs are of greatest relative importance. On the other hand, in industries which have not done too well during the past year and a half, price rises have been nominal or nonexistent. These include tobacco manu factures, textile products and apparel, and the three areas of declining prices previously noted. This table underlines the importance of expanding demand and boom time conditions in the overall price rise which has taken place. A similar picture is shown in table 2 which arrays the changes in major groups of wholesale prices between December 1955 and December 1956. W e find the major increases in machinery and motive products, metals and metal products, and structural nonmetallic minerals. Also included among the larger increases in 1956 were farm products and processed foods, which advanced from the depressed levels o f December 1955. Lumber and wood products (which were adversely affected by the decline of nonresidential building), rubber and rubber products (which were adversely affected by the large decline in automobile sales), and textile products and apparel (which have experienced lagging markets) reported no change or declining prices in 1956. Another area with relatively small in creases in prices was tobacco manufactures, which has been affected by the lagging sales of cigarettes partly as a result o f the cancer scare. This is also an area of relatively low labor costs. Chemicals and allied products also involve relatively low labor costs. By economic sector.—Table 3 shows the breakdown o f the wholesale price index by economic sectors. Between June 1955 and December 1956, the overall index for crude materials showed no change. However, when the important com ponents o f that index are examined, it is found that foodstuffs and feedstuffs de clined 5% percent in contrast to the rise o f 7.2 percent for nonfood materials except fuel and a 13.9 percent rise in fuel. This latter increase reflected primarily the sharp rise which has taken place in coal prices. The overall index for intermediate materials supplies and components rose by 7.3 percent in the past year and a half. The table shows that there was practi cally no change for food manufactures and that materials for nondurable goods manufactures rose only 2% percent. The major rises in prices occurred in ma terials used in durable goods manufactures (10.1 percent) and for components for manufacturing (15.4 percent). Intermediate materials used for construction rose 7.1 percent. The pattern for the finished goods was similar. There has been little change for foods and a rise o f only 3.1 percent for other nondurable goods; in contrast, finished durable goods prices rose 6.4 percent and prices o f producers finished goods rose 13.2 percent. This tabulation again indicates the relatively small price changes for the nondurable consumers goods in contrast to the sharp rises ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 173 which have taken place in producers goods and for consumers durable goods. As the President has noted, “ Prices o f investment goods and semimanufactured materials and components rose quite rapidly, reflecting heavy pressure o f de mand relative to supply” (pp. 30, 32). A little later in the report, reference is made to the continued rise in prices o f producer finished equipment, “ the demand for which was especially insistent” (p. 32). It seems clear that the areas which have been most stimulated by the boom show the largest price rises in contrast to the relatively modest price changes in other sectors of the economy. It must be recognized that economic data o f this type rarely yield a picture o f perfect relationships. Nevertheless, it appears to me to be significant that the areas with the major increases in prices have been largely those in which the pressures o f the boom have been greatest while the areas in which prices have lagged have been the areas in which economic activity has not been stimulated significantly. These data also suggest that a slowing down o f the boom will be the most potent force to stop the price rise. To the extent that fiscal and mone tary policies act to blunt the rate o f advance in the boom areas, the overall rise in prices can be slowed down and then brought to a halt. Sensitive price index.— Table 4 shows the changes in the Bureau o f Labor Statistics spot primary index for three selected dates. The changes for each of the specific commodities is also shown. Such prices usually reflect inflationary pressures in our economy very promptly. At the slightest hint of inflation, they move upward sharply. Past experience has shown that the general wholesale price index and the consumer price index generally follow the movements of the sensitive wholesale price index, though not as sharply. From 1939 through August 1945, the sensitive price index almost doubled as compared with increases of about one-third in the general level of wholesale prices and in retail prices. By 1948, the sensitive price index had increased to a level 204 percent above prewar as compared with an increase of 112 percent in the wholesale price level and 76 percent in retail prices. From June 1950 to February 1951, the sensitive price index rose more than 50 percent as compared with an increase of only 16 percent in the general whole sale price index and 8 percent in retail prices. When the substantial inflation ary pressures anticipated as a result o f the Korean war failed to take place, sensitive prices began to reverse their rise. In fact, currently, the index is only moderately higher than in 1950. What has happened to these prices in the past year and a half? Since May 31, 1955, the overall index has risen only 3.5 percent. In the past year, the rise has been 2.6 percent. Table 4 shows the wide diversity in price changes for the individual products. Of the 24 products shown in the tabulation, nine were lower in January 1957 than in May 1955 and one was unchanged in price: 14 commodities had increased in price. The largest increase was for steel scrap which advanced 90.6 percent; it has since declined a little. At the other ex treme, cocoa beans recorded a decline of 35.3 percent. Half of the commodities showed changes within a range of plus and minus 6 percent. A similar pattern o f diversity o f price behavior is shown for the past year. From January 10, 1956, to January 10, 1957, 10 commodities declined and one was unchanged in price. The extreme changes were a price increase of 50.6 percent for hogs and a price decline o f 28.2 percent for copper scrap. It is interesting to note that sensitive prices like copper scrap, lead scrap, and rubber have actually declined during the past year despite the general rise in the price level. This is not the behavior one would expect under conditions of general price inflation. These declines are explainable, however, in terms o f the reduced level o f activity which characterized the automobile industry and residential building in 1956. It is the pattern o f behavior that would be expected during a boom which has an uneven impact upon the economy. FACTORS CONTRIBUTING TO PRICE RISES What factors explain the creeping price rise which has been taking place during the past year and a half? Is this a rise which is due to the same type o f factors which resulted in the explosive rise of World War II and the early post war years? How does it differ from that earlier rise and do these differences have any significance in the outlook for prices? It is important to keep in mind that this price rise does not result from large Government budgetary deficits with an accompanying expansion in bank credit or from a large increase in money supply, including deposits and currency. The rise does reflect a combination o f 174 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT the business boom and increases in labor costs in excess of the gains in productivity. I should like to review each o f these factors briefly. It is important to under stand the nature of the price rise and the basic pressures which are operating, if we are to formulate proper public policy. The Federal budget During the fiscal years 1955-56 and 1956-57, the Federal budget is estimated to be in the black. The regular budget will show a surplus of a little less than $2 billion for each year. The cash surplus is in excess of $3 billion in each year. During this period the Federal debt is being reduced by modest amounts. This is clearly a picture of a Federal buget which is deflationary, not inflationary. This is a budgetary situation which is in sharp contrast to the huge deficits and accompanying tremendous rise in public debt which characterized World W ar II and the first postwar year with the accompanying large inflation in prices. The President has properly pointed out that the budgetary surplus “prevented addi tional strains on the economy” (p. 40). Money supply The total money supply was increased by only about 1 percent in 1956. Total demand deposits showed little change despite an $8 billion increase in com mercial bank loans because this was offset in part by a liquidation o f investments, particularly Government securities, and because of the rise in time deposits. Under conditions of capacity operations in key sectors of the economy, a larger rise in currency and demand deposits could only have meant further pressures on the price level. The report emphasizes the heart o f the problem when it concludes: “ A large overall expansion of bank credit would not have resulted in a significantly higher national output, but would instead have led to a greater rise in prices” (p. 40). Again we have a sharp contrast with the World War II situation. From the end of 1940 to the end of 1945, total demand deposits and currency outside the banks rose by 141.8 percent (from $42.3 billion to $102.3 billion). This tre mendous increase in money supply was a potent factor in the large war and postwar rise in prices. It is encouraging that we are not experiencing any significant rise in money supply in the current situation. This is due in large measure to tighter monetary policy which the Federal Reserve Board has appropriately instituted. Money has been passing from hand to hand at a faster rate. According to data compiled for demand deposit turnover by the Federal Reserve Board, there was an increase of 6.6 percent in New York City, 5.7 percent in 6 other large cities, and 6.8 percent in 337 other reporting centers in 1956 as compared with 1955. Since the New York City totals are influenced by the volume o f security trading, the totals outside New York City are usually considered a better guide to turnover related to general business activity. This greater turnover of bank deposits has reflected first, the growth of bank loans which usually create very active deposits and second, the business boom with the accompanying spirit of confidence. While the total supply o f demand deposits has shown little change, that total has been used more intensively. The business boom One characteristic o f a boom is the shortages which develop in some sectors of the economy. The 1956 boom in plant and equipment expenditures created pres sure on many of the durable-goods industries. One evidence o f this pressure is the large backlog of unfilled orders which accumulated in the durable-goods indus tries as the affected industries operating at capacity could not fill all orders promptly. Unfilled orders in the durable-goods industries increased from $52 billion at the end o f 1955 to about $59 billion at the end o f 1956 despite the rising volume o f deliveries during the year. In the latter part o f the year, the steel industry operated at capacity and could not meet all demands. As I noted earlier, these areas o f shortage experienced the largest price rises during the past year and a half. In fact, the price rise reflects largely the pressures generated by a business boom. Increases in labor costs greater than the gains in productivity Increases in average hourly earnings and various fringe benefits have been o f major magnitude during the war and postwar years. The increases in labor costs have exceeded by a wide margin the gains in output per manhour. The result has been a sharp rise in unit labor costs throughout the economy during ECONOMIC REPORT OP THE PRESIDENT 175 the war and postwar years. The period since mid-1955 has been marked by a further rise in hourly earnings o f substantial proportions. In the 18 months following June 1955, average hourly earnings in all manufac turing industries rose by 9.6 percent; the increases for durable- and nondurablegoods industries were about the same. Average hourly earnings June 1955 All manufacturing_________________________________________ Durable goods_____________________________________________ Nondurable goods__________________________________________ $1.87 1.99 1.70 Decem ber 1956 $2.05 2.18 1.86 Percent change— June 1955-December 1956 + 9.6 + 9.5 + 9.4 The increase o f 18 cents an hour in earnings does not measure the entire rise in labor costs. In addition, there has been a considerable increase in the so-called fringes during this period. Overall estimates of the magnitude of these higher fringe costs are not available. Illustrations include supplementary unemployment benefit plans which cost 3 to 5 cents an hour and liberalization of pension and welfare provisions. Clearly, total hourly labor payments includ ing fringes have increased by more than 10 percent— and in many industries by considerably more— during this year and a half of price rises. During the past 12 months, average hourly earnings have risen by 6.2 percent in manufacturing industries and total labor costs per hour by an even larger proportion because of the increase in fringe benefits. Average hourly earnings December December 1955 1956 All manufacturing________________ _________________________ Durable goods.____ ________________ _______ _______ _________ Nondurable goods________________ . ________________________ $1.93 2.06 1.74 $2.05 2.18 1.86 Percent change— December 1955December 1956 + 6.2 + 5.8 + 6.9 To the extent that output per man-hour has risen, the unit labor costs o f a company or industry have risen less than indicated when attention is devoted to labor payments alone. How much has productivity risen during this period o f a year and a half? Although precise estimates are not yet available, a rough approximation may be made on the basis o f available data for production and man-hours. In manufacturing, a man-hours in 1956 appear to have increased fractionally for production workers and a little more for nonproduction workers. During the same period, the Federal Reserve Board index o f production o f manufactures increased by 2.8 percent. These data suggest a rise in productivity in manu facturing industries o f no more than 2 percent in 1956. Average hourly earnings were 5.3 percent higher in 1956 than in 1955 ($1.98 compared with $1.88). In addition, fringe costs rose. Labor Commissioner Ewan Clague reported at a National Industrial Conference Board meeting last year that “ Insofar as later quarters in 1955 were concerned, there was some indication of leveling out [in productivity] in the latter part o f the year.” Thus, since mid-1955, it appears that increases in labor costs, including wages and fringes, have far outstripped the gain in productivity in manufacturing industries. The result appears to have been a ripe in unit labor costs in excess o f 5 percent. Gross national product rose from $387.4 billion at annual rates in the second quarter o f 1955 to $413.8 billion in the third quarter o f 1956, an increase o f 6.8 percent. In real terms, the rise was about 3 percent During the same period, total employment increased by about 2 percent Thus, for the entire economy, the rise in productivity appears to have been less than the long term annual rate o f gain o f 2 percent. On the basis o f these data, it appears that during the past year and a half o f creeping price advance, wage increases plus fringe benefits outstripped signifi cantly the gains in productivity. The President emphasizes this point on page 176 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 34 o f the Report where he concludes that for 1956, “ only a very small gain in overall productivity is indicated * * * the smallness of the 1956 gain contributed to the rise in unit labor costs and, in turn, to the increase in prices/* There is virtually unanimous agreement among economists that labor cost in creases in excess of gains in productivity will result in pressure for higher prices as the President has pointed out. This brief review o f the forces affecting prices during the past year or more indicates that the President is on sound ground in his conclusion th a t: “ The combination o f heavy demands from the investment goods sector o f the economy, rising labor costs, and renewed advances in prices o f many raw mate rials resulted in price increases for a broad range of semimanufactured mate rials, components, and supplies. And these price increases became cost increases to producers of finished goods, many o f whom were also experiencing rising labor costs” (p. 32). It is important to keep in mind that a price rise attributable to these factors will not have the same spiraling effect as an inflation flowing from monetary and fiscal factors. This is not the background for an explosive inflation. It is the background for a further modest price rise so long as the boom persists. POLICIES PROPOSED TO LIMIT FURTHER INFLATION To limit further inflation, the President emphasizes three areas o f attack. 1. Voluntary limitation o f wage and price increases by labor and business leaders. 2. Monetary policy. 3. Fiscal policy. 1. Voluntary limitation of wage and price increases In his Report, the President suggests that, “ Specifically, business and labor leadership have the responsibility to reach agreements on wages and other labor benefits that are fair to the rest o f the community as well as to those persons immediately involved. Negotiated wage increases and benefits should be consistent with productivity prospects and with the maintenance of a stable dollar.” There can be little quarrel with this objective. Wage increases in excess o f gains in productivity result in higher unit labor costs, which create pressure for price rises. Nevertheless, we must recognize that many key sectors in the economy are not free to apply this proposed standard in 1957. For many important industries, including automobile, steel, electrical equipment, railroads, meat packing, agri cultural implements, and coal, wage increases for 1957 and in some cases for 1958 have already been incorporated in contracts. BLS reports that 5 million workers are covered by long term contracts which were negotiated in 1955 or 1956. While this is but a small proportion o f the labor force, it does cover most of the “ key wage bargains.” In many of these industries, the negotiated wage increases are scheduled to be 6 or 7 cents an hour. In addition, provision usually is made for further adjustment in wages if the cost o f living should rise. The cost o f living adjustments are made quarterly in some industries, such as automobiles, and semiannually in other industries like iron and steel. In most instances, the contracts provide for an increase o f one cent an hour fo r every half point increase in the consumers’ price index. Further advances in the consumers’ price index seem probable in 1957. I f the rise in the index should be two points, it will mean a wage increase o f four cents an hour in most o f the in dustries I have listed. I f the increases in living costs are larger, the wage increases will be correspondingly greater. In addition to these contract pro visions for wage changes, some contracts provide for additional fringe benefits to become effective in 1957. In light o f these contract provisions, we already seem assured o f an increase in wage rates o f 4 percent to 5 percent in 1957. Past experience indicates that the wage adjustments in these key areas will be a very potent force in deter mining wage increases in other sectors o f the economy where contracts still remain to be negotiated. Under these conditions, it is impossible for industry and labor to exercise the restraint called for by the President unless they were to reopen the existing agreements and negotiate smaller wage increases. Since the probability o f such an action is completely nonexistent, it is clear that not much can be done through voluntary restraint insofar as wages and other labor costs are concerned during 1957. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 177 The Report also emphasizes that “businesses must recognize the broad public interest in the prices set on their products and services.,, (p. 3) The ability o f industry to hold down its prices is not unrelated to what happens to labor costs. With an average wage increase of 4 or 5 percent likely in 1957 and the probability that productivity will increase by a much smaller percentage, many industries will be subject to a further rise in unit labor costs this year. Under these ; conditions, I question whether the President’s appeal for voluntary restraint to hold down prices can be attended by much success. I suspect that we will experience a further price rise o f several percent in 1957 largely as a result o f the rise in labor costs and a continuation o f boom time conditions. I f the boom subsides later in the year, as some anticipate, then the pressure on prices should also subside. The President warns that “ * * * failure to accept the responsibilities inherent in a free economy could lead to demands that they be assumed by Government, with the increasing intervention and loss o f freedom that such an approach in evitably entails” (p. 3 ). In other words, the failure o f voluntary restraints could lead to wage fixing and price fixing by Government. I would like to state cate gorically that I am completely opposed to any such program to limit price and wage rises in peacetime. Such a program is foredoomed to failure and can only Tesult in disruptions to production, impairment o f incentives, and an ever widen ing area of controls which will create worse evils than the control program is designed to overcome. The effort to limit price and wage increases by exhortation has never suc ceeded in the past and will be no more successful under current conditions. I believe that better results can be obtained through monetary and fiscal policy. 2, Monetary policy and fiscal policy Although the President gives considerable emphasis to monetary and fiscal policy he states th at: “ To depend exclusively on monetary and fiscal restraints as a means o f con taining the upward movement o f prices would raise serious obstacles to the main tenance o f economic growth and stability. In the face of a continuous upward pressure on costs and prices, moderate restraints would not be sufficient; yet stronger restraints would bear with undue severity on sectors of the economy having little if any responsibility for the movement toward a higher cost-price level and would court the risk of being excessively restrictive for the economy generally” (p. 44). Any restraint exercised through monetary or fiscal policy, however modest, will inevitably hurt some groups who will be quick to react as we have seen in the past year. This is unavoidable regardless o f what policies are adopted. And it is also possible that some groups who have little responsibility for the spiral will be adversely affected by such restraints. But to state the problem in these terms is to give only a partial picture. What happens if these restraints are not imposed and prices are permitted to spiral? Then the burden falls on the large groups who live on fixed incomes (pensioners, dependents o f those in the Armed Forces, widows, and similar groups) and on those whose incomes do not and cannot keep pace with an inflationary price rise (Government employees, teach ers, ministers, and many white-collar groups). Unfortunately, there is no best policy in the sense that no one will feel its effects. There is only a “least worst” policy in the sense that its adverse effects will be kept to a minimum. In these terms, the alternative to hurting some groups who do not or may not contribute to the inflation is to hurt still larger groups who do not contribute to the inflationary pressures. Do we seriously believe that we are really making every effort to combat infla tion on the fiscal front when Government spending continues to rise and new programs of spending are being initiated? It is true that it is expected that the Federal budget will be in balance even with the enlarged spending, but isn’t this the time when even larger budgetary surpluses should be built up as a com pensation for the boom in the private economy ? Do we seriously believe that we are making every effort to combat inflation on the monetary front when mortgage credit, consumer credit, and bank credit continue to expand at near record rates? And is mortgage credit excessively restrictive with the present low downpayments and 30-year maturities for mortgages? The Federal Reserve Board “has leaned against the wind,” to use H r. Martin’s descriptive phrase, but it certainly hasn’t leaned far enough to be in •danger o f falling over. 178 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT I f stronger fiscal and monetary restraints are required to halt an inflation they should be imposed* The evils attending inflation are more serious than those attending strong anti-inflation policies. CONCLUSION The rise in prices has reflected the cost push exerted by increases in labor costs in excess o f gains in productivity in a business boom which has made it relatively easy to pass these cost increases on to the buyer. There is an under standable concern with the problem of inflation. However, we are not in a period o f classic inflation reflecting either Federal Government budgetary deficits or large expansions in money supply. So long as the Federal budget remains in the black and monetary policy prevents a sharp expansion in money supply, there is little likelihood o f a runaway price inflation. Unless the wage-price spiral is fed by an expanding money supply, it is more likely to lead to unem ployment of resources as they are “priced out o f the market” than to a major price inflation. To the extent that monetary and fiscal policy are used to blunt the boom, one of the major factors contributing to price advances will be modified or eliminated. But there will still remain the problem o f excessive increases in labor costs. Little can be done in the wage area in 1957 because “key wage bargains” already have been reached. But we must look to the future if we are to prevent a repetition o f the current situation. President Eisenhower has pointed squarely to the proper goal in this area in his statement that: “Negotiated wage increases and benefits should be coexistent with productivity prospects and with the maintenance o f a stable dollar” (p. 3 ). But this objective will only be achieved if management in major industries firmly refuses to agree to labor cost increases in excess o f national productivity gains and if the public is educated to understand the dangers which arise when labor cost increases exceed these amounts. T a b l e 1.— Changes in the major groups of the wholesale price indew, June 1955- December 1956 [1947-49=100] June 1955 December 1956 Metals and metal products________ ________________________ Machinery and motive products___________________________ Pulp, paper, and allied products___________________________ Commodities other than farm products and foods___________ Hides, sirins, and leather products____ _____________________ Nonmetallic minerals, structural__________________________ Fuel, power, and lighting materials________________________ Furniture, other household durables_______________________ Rubber and products___________ ________________________ All commodities._________________________________________ Miscellaneous____________________________________________ Tobacco manufactures and bottled beverages_________ _____ Chemicals and allied products_____________________ —_____ Tflitite products apd apparel ____ . ______ r Foods, processed_________________________________________ Lumber and wood products_____________________________ _ Farm products..^....... .............. ................................_........ „ _ Source: XJ. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 132.6 127.1 118.3 115.6 92.9 123.7 106.8 115.2 140.3 110.3 89.1 121.6 106.8 95.2 103.9 123.7 152.4 143.5 127.9 1216 99.4 131.3 113.1 121.4 147.9 116.2 91.6 123.6 108.3 95.6 103.1 120.9 91.8 88.6 Percent Change -f-14.fr -t-12.fr + 8 .1 + 7 .8 + 7 .0 + 6 .1 + 5 .9 + 5 .4 + 5 .4 + 5 .3 + 2 .8 + 1 .6 + 1 .4 + 0 .4 — 0.8 — 2.3 -3 .5 179 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Taklet 2.— Changes in the major groups of the wholesale price index, December 1955-December 1956 [1947-49=100] December 1955 Machinery and motive products____ . _. . . _________________ Farm products___________________________________________ Metals and metal products__ ________. _____ . _____________ Foods, processed___________________ - _____________________ Nonmetallic minerals, structural_________________ . ____ ___ All commodities_________________________________________ Commodities other than farm products and foods___________ Fuel, power, and lighting materials__ ___ __________________ Furniture, other household durables-.-.___________________ Pulp, paper, and allied products— ________ _______ Miscellaneous____________________________________________ Hides, skins,' and leather products_____ . ___________________ Chemicals and allied products_____________________________ Tobacco manufactures and bottled beverages..__ ___________ Textile products and apparel___. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . __ ——___ ___ Rubber and products_____ . . . . . . . . . . . . . ____________________ Lumber and wood products____________ . . . . ____ ______ _ 133.0 82.9 143.9 98.2 125.4 111.3 119.8 109.3 117.3 123.6 88.8 96.7 106.6 121.7 95.6 151.0 125.1 December 1956 143.5 88.6 152.4 103.1 131.3 116.2 124.6 113.1 121.4 127.9 91.6 99.4 108.3 123.6 95.6 147.9 120.9 Percent change 4-7.9 + 6.9 + 5.9 +5.0 +4.7 + 4.4 +4.0 + 3.5 +3.5 +3.5 + 3.2 +2.8 + 1.6 + 1.6 0 -2 .1 -3 .4 Source: U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Tabus 3.— Wholesale price indexes by economic sector June 1955, December 1955, and December 1956 [1947-49*100] June 1955 Decem ber 1955 All commodities............................................... Crude materials, total..................................... Foodstuffs and feedstuffs.......................... Nonfood materials except fuel.................. Fuels.......................................................... Intermediate materials, supplies, and com* ponents, total................................................ Total materials and components for man ufacturing.............................................. Materials for food manufacturing— Materials for non-durable-goods manufacturing................................. Materials for durable-goods manufac turing ............................................... Components for manufacturing......... Materials and components for construc tion......................................................... Finished goods, total....................................... Total consumer.......... ..................... ......... Foods................................................... Other nondurables.............................. Durables.............................................. Pr«4acer.................................................... Source: XT. S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Decem ber 1956 December-1956 from— June 1955 December 1955 110.3 96.2 89.7 107.7 102.9 111.3 89.9 75.8 114.9 110.1 116.2 96.2 84.5 115.5 117.2 + 5.3 0 -5 .5 +7.2 +13.9 115.7 119.4 124.2 +7.3 +4.0 117.1 100.0 120.9 94.8 125.9 100.0 ft? + 4.1 + 5.6 102.4 103.7 105.0 + 2.5 + 1.3 137.2 128.2 144.7 137.5 151.1 147.9 +10.1 +15.4 + 4.4 +7.6 124.2 110.6 106.5 102.1 107.4 115.1 127.1 129.0 111.5 106.1 98.3 108.7 118.1 132.9 133.0 116.0 109.2 101.8 110.7 122.5 143.9 + 7.1 + 4.9 + 2.5 -0 .3 + 3.1 + 6.4 +13.2 +3.1 +4.0 + 2.9 + 3 .6 + 1.8 + 3.7 + 8.3 + 4.4 + 7.0 +11.9 + 0.5 + 6.4 180 T a b l e 4 . —Daily ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT index numbers and spot primary market commodity pricest May 81,1955, Jan. 10,1956, and Jan. 10,1957 [1947-49=s 100] May 31, 1955 Jan. 10, 1956 Jan. 10, 1957 Percent change to Jan. 10, 1957, from— M ay 31, 1955 Jan. 10,1956 Groups: All commodities........................................ Foodstuffs...................................... . Raw industrials............ .................. . Livestock and products..................... Metals......... ............................. ......... Textiles and fibers.............................. Fats and oils....................................... Commodities: Burlap............................................ yard.. Butter.......................................... pound.. Oocoa beans.................................... do___ Copper scrap........... .......... .......... do___ Corn............................................bushel. _ Cotton, 14-market average......... pound.. Cottonseed oil................................do___ Hides............................................... do___ Hogs..................................... 100 pounds. . Lard............................................. pound.. Lead scrap.............................. . . . . . d o ___ Print cloth: Spot and nearby...................... yard__ Most distant contract_______ do ... _ Rosin....................................100 pounds. _ Rubber........................................ pound.. Steel scrap.........................................ton.. Steers........................... ........ 100 pounds.. Sucrar............................................... d o___ Tallow..........................................pound.. T in.................................................. do___ Wheat: Kansas C ity..........................bushel. _ Minneapolis............................. d o___ Wool tops.................................... pound.. Zinc................ ................................ do___ 89.0 86.2 90.8 62.9 105.4 84.2 65.3 89.8 74.8 101.8 92.1 83.3 98.6 66.7 58.5 129.3 80.8 62.9 122.2 $0.106 .574 .310 .415 1.248 .339 .119 .155 11.750 .108 .092 $0,116 .594 .236 .298 1.345 .334 .144 .140 17.700 .153 .085 .062 .915 .206 .195 9.600 .422 51.000 21.375 5.850 .072 1.064 .186 .188 9.700 .344 61.000 22.375 6.400 .069 2.462 2.471 1.815 .125 2.150 2.325 1.555 .140 $0,115 .571 .365 .350 1.461 . 336 .141 .132 18.750 .122 .082 .187 .188 9.200 .318 32.000 23.000 6.000 85.3 71.8 + 3.5 -3 .4 +8.6 +6.0 +15.9 +1.3 10.0 + +.9 + 4.0 -3 5.3 -1 4.9 -7 .9 -.6 +2.1 +6.1 -5 .6 +25.4 +3.7 -.5 0 + 2.6 +11.4 -3 .1 +14.0 - 5 .5 +5.6 +14.1 +9.4 +3.5 -2 3 .9 -28. 2 + 7.8 -1 .5 +21.0 -9 .7 +50.6 +41.7 - 7 .0 - 9 .7 - 3 .6 +1.0 1.012 +5.4 +8.2 +90.6 -2 .7 +6.7 +11.3 +10.6 -1 8.5 +19. 6 + 4.7 +9.4 -4 .2 -4 .9 2.330 2.335 1.950 .140 -5 .4 -5 .5 +7.4 412.0 + 8.4 +• 4 +25.4 0 Source: U. S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Brubaker, research director, United Steel workers o f America. STATEMENT OF OTIS BRUBAKER, RESEARCH DIRECTOR, UNITED STEELWORKERS OF AMERICA Mr. B r u b a k e r . Mr. Patman, members o f the committee ladies and gentlemen, the Steelworkers Union is delighted to accept the invitation o f the Joint Economic Committee to participate in this panel discus sion o f the question of the so-called wage-price inflation spiral men tioned prominently in two recent Presidential statements. This panel discussion can be, and we hope it will be, the beginning o f a serious investigation by the Joint Economic Committee o f the causes o f infla tion and what can be done about them. Certainly our union, the United Steelworkers o f America, does not now, and never has, favored inflation. The members o f our union and the retired former members suffer as much as do other members of the public when pay checks and pension cheeks buy less and less because o f inflation, i. e., higher prices o f food, clothing, shelter, and the other necessities of life, is constantly nibbling away at the real buying power o f their incomes. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 181 Unfortunately, however, there is much misinformation about infla tion and its causes. There is a deliberate, widespread, and systematic attempt in our country by such groups as the National Association of Manufacturers, the chamber of commerce, many newspapers, and other large employers to lay the blame for inflation on the efforts of wage earners and their unions to secure wage and fringe improvements in order to raise the standard of living of the American worker. Congress can do much in this regard if it will search out the facts concerning wages, prices, and profits, their roles in our economic system, and assess the blame on those who cause and those who profit from inflation. In fact, if the spotlight of congressional publicity is kept focused on those who would like to raise prices and constantly increase profit margins, it may have a salutary effect in curbing price increases. Our union has prepared some fairly elaborate studies, with the assist ance of Mr. Robert Nathan’s office, which we are presenting to the com mittee. We would like to ask that they, along with this shorter state ment, be made a part of the record of the hearing. Chairman P a t m a n . The committee will consider it. There is no question about putting in your statement. We do have a problem in printing^ with respect to those documents, particularly the charts and illustrations. Mr. B r u b a k e r . Standing alone this briefer statement is not an adequate statement. We have made many references to these more elaborate studies. Chairman P a t m a n . Without objection they will be inserted in the record. (The documents follow:) U n ite d S t e e lw o r k e r s o f A m e r ic a Pittsburgh 22, Pa. D e a r Si r : Since midnight o f June 30 the basic steel industry has been idle because of the decision o f the companies to shut down operations when labor contracts with the United Steelworkers of America terminated. Instead o f engaging in good faith bargaining with the union prior to June 30 to work out new contracts which would meet the needs of the employees and provide them with an adequate share in the tremendous prosperity of the in dustry, the companies forced 650,000 o f their employees and thousands in other industries into unemployment with consequent harm to the economy. We o f the United Steelworkers did not want this shutdown to happen. We did everything in our power to prevent it. W e made reasonable proposals for an honorable settlement which would be fair to the employees, the stockholders, and the public. However, we were confronted by a totally inadequate take-itor-leave-it proposition from the industry. We are not indulging in wild charges, but stating our sober conviction, when we say that the leaders of the steel industry forced the shutdown— for ulterior reasons which they must be better able to explain than anyone else. You will recall that the Steelwokers Union, just before contract talks with the industry spokesmen were broken off, made a forthright offer to extend our agreements for 15 days with customary retroactivity to provide more time for negotiations. The industry showed its true purpose o f forcing a shutdown when it flatly rejected this offer. Thus we stand at the present impasse—with time ticking away, with a needless great loss in production, in wages, in purchasing power to keep the wheels of our economic machine turning. I realize that you, as a public-spirited citizen, would like to know more o f the facts on this situation than can be found in the newspapers. Ours is a responsible union. We believe that you—and the public in general— have a right to know the facts because all of us have a stake in the outcome. It is in recog 182 ECONOMIC EEPORT OF THE PRESIDENT nition o f your right to know that the United Steelworkers of America has prepared two well-documented studies of the facts and real issues involved in our present dispute with the steel industry. For it is only through a study o f the clear facts that the issues can be reasonably appraised and intelligent negotiations carried on. Unfortunately the spokesmen for the industry have not been willing to engage in genuine negotiations based on the irrefutable facts contained in these two studies. Rather, they have substituted press releases, press conferences, and newspaper advertisements for genuine negotiations. Because their inadequate proposals, which they well knew the union could not accept, were handed down with a take-it-or-leave-it attitude which cannot be defended, they have obscured or misrepresented the facts. So I commend, then, for your judgment, the facts in our two studies here summarized. In the one entitled “ Steel and the National Economy 1956,” there is a thorough analysis o f the current state o f the economy and the over-all effect o f the steel industry on the national economy, with special emphasis on the ques tion of inflation. In the other study entitled “ Facts on Steel: Profits, Pro ductivity, Prices and Wages, 1956,” there is a detailed examination o f the finan cial position of the industry, with significant comparisons of the relationship o f profits, productivity, prices, and wages. You recall that steel industry spokesmen have sought to justify their failure to offer a reasonable wage increase by invoking the word “inflation.” They said that “ no increase in employment costs at this time would be in the Nation’s best interests * * *” since it would set off “ another ruinous round o f inflation.” Now, there are very few people indeed who want inflation, but we sharply dis agree with the industry’s contention that inflation is caused by wage increases— for to say this is tantamount to saying that it is impossible for the living stand ards o f the working population to improve at all. Indeed, any inflationary tendencies that may exist in our economy stem not from wage and salary in creases, which are vitally needed, but from pricing policies o f industry generally and particularly the steel industry. Let us see what our studies have to say on this and related subjects. STEEL A N D THE N A T IO N A L ECONOM Y The volume which addresses itself to the problem of inflation and the present state o f our economy contains the following facts and essential policies: Concern is expressed by the union as to the need to safeguard and improve the health of our economy as a whole. Note is taken o f the fact that there have been some serious soft spots in the fabric o f the economy, which has been on a plateau for some 9 months. Despite precarious inventory accumulations and higher consumer debt, the full employment levels o f 1952 and 1953 have not been matched. Prosperity in the last decade has been sustained by wage and salary increases and labor’s rising share o f the total income. (Though in steel labor’s total-income share has fallen in this decade.) But labor’s share in the economy, as well as in steel, has fallen in the last year and consumer purchases are lagging. Unless corrected, this could spell trouble. With confidence in the fundamental strength o f our economic system, and with faith in its potential growth, we also in this study take into account the possibilities and challenges o f the years ahead. A growing labor force and ris ing productivity make possible a doubling o f our production and our standard of living within the next 20 years. These can be achieved only if there is an active market for the goods and services we can produce. Consumers buy $5 of every $6 worth o f goods and services purchased pri vately. Since consumer purchasing power arises largely from wages and sal aries, wages and salaries must increase if economic expansion is to be resumed and a market provided for this doubled production. Our study refutes any alleged relation between wage increases and inflation and states: “ Experience has proved that wage incrases have not caused infla tion, that wages can be increased without prices being raised, and that rising real wages give us stable prosperity and growth.” Wage increases, says our report, lagged behind price increases in the im mediate post-war and Korean inflations and obviously could not have caused inflation. The pattern o f inflation is rising prices, rising real profits and lag ging real wages. In the stable period since mid-1951, on the other hand, wage rates in manufacturing have risen 23 percent, living costs less than 4 percent and industrial prices 4 percent. Yet total profits before taxes reached record levels in 1955. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 183 Rising real wages, stable prices and sustained high profits, made possible by constantly increasing productivity, are thus the keys to economic stability and perpetuation of prosperity for all segments of our economy. Our study points o u t: “ Productivity * * * has been increasing more than 3 percent per year. In manufacturing industries, the annual rate has been exceeding 4 percent. Auto mation will increase the pace. * * * Real hourly earnings in manufacturing fell behind the rise in productivity at the time of the Korean War and have not caught up yet. This disparity must be corrected through rising real wages.” With steel a conspicuous exception, the union’s report says, rising volume of business in industry generally has tended to be associated with lower profit margins per unit of production in periods of stability. This policy has yielded prosperity and high total profits. The spurt of industrial prices ahead of wages and the sharp rise in profit margins in 1955, after 4 years of moderate decline, spell danger and must be reversed. Our study reveals a disturbing irresponsibility in the pricing and profit margin policies of the steel industry. Our study states: “ The contrast between the pricing policies of the steel industry and o f all manufacturing industries as a whole is rather startling. Steel prices have in creased proportionately with wage rates since 1947 ignoring rapidly rising pro ductivity in its pricing policies. For all manufacturing, industrial prices in creased considerably less than half as much as wage rates from 1947 to 1955. “The steel industry does not follow the principle of higher volume and lower margins. I f there is any single industry that has followed inflationary pricing practices; that has shown a disregard for the economic welfare of the country, especially relative to its key role in the economy; that has truly practiced infla tion ; that has the least right to hide behind the cloak of favoring a sound dollar and to contend that wage increases are inflationary; it is the steel industry/’ Before the union commenced negotiations with the industry, several steel company spokesmen had issued public statements calling for higher prices for their products. They based this mainly on the plea that price increases were required to finance expansion. Our study says of th is: “Contentions by leaders of the steel industry and other industries that prices . must be increased so that there will be more profits with which to finance expan sion are astounding. Raising prices to secure funds for new plant and equip ment in effect forces the consumer to put up the money for new plants for th e' benefit of existing stockholders. The consumer gets nothing for his forced ‘investment.’ The opportunity for American citizens to participate in the growth of American industry is denied when expansion is financed entirely through exorbitant profits rather than security flotations.” F A C T S O N ST E E L : P R O F IT S , P R O D U C T IV IT Y , P R IC E S A N D W A G E S Now let me refer you to the second o f our two economic studies, which deals with the financial position o f the steel industry in relation to industry as a whole and in relation to profits, wages, prices and— of special significance— productivity in relation to all o f these factors. Our study emphasizes productivity as the key to the entire question o f wages, prices, profits and the health of the overall economy. “ It is now commonly accepted that, over long periods, wage gains and rising living standards must come largely from increased productivity, i. e., rising output per man-hour,” states our report. “ With this concept the union has no quarrel as long as one prior condition is met—namely, that the income shares as between management and investors on the one hand and labor on the other * * * are fair and equitable. There is no such equitable sharing in the steel industry today.” Here is what our analysis of the productivity record o f steel reveals: Taking note of the great, continuing rise in productivity for many years, we observe especially “ the sharp acceleration in the productivity rate in the most recent years.” For example, productivity in the steel industry currently has been running at a rate 4.7 percent higher than in 1955. And the rate in 1955 was a phenomenal 11.2 percent above 1954. In short, steelworkers are producing more and more steel per man-hour. Increased productivity in steel has run well in excess of the increase in the economy as a whole and in manufacturing industries. Yet what does a comparison show us? Taking the years 1939-1956 (more than 16 years), we find the “real” productivity increase in the steel industry to be 68.8 87624 0— 57------ 13 184 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT percent. For the same period, the “ real” straight time average hourly earnings of the steelworker rose only 47.1 percent. It is evident that increasing productivity is the key to providing higher wages, higher standards of living, broader and more stable prosperity— and all without the need to boost prices beyond reason and without harm to the rightful profits of the industry and its investors. For if the millions of workers in industry do not receive a fair share of these benefits o f increased productivity, then our free enterprise economy cannot continue to function. And it is in this area that the leaders of the steel industry have, so far, been far too backward and shortsighted. Our study of the industry contains interesting revelations as to steel profits. Far from being in dire straits, profit-wise, the steel corporations under examina tion have been showing a 1956 profit rate o f 15.3 percent higher than last year and, believe it or not, 107.4 percent higher than in 1954! These are profits before taxes, and it should be remembered that wage increases are offset from profits before, not after, taxes. As to profits after taxes, you will find that these com panies have been reaping, at the 1956 rate, net profits 13.1 percent higher than in 1955 and 95.6 percent higher than in 1954. That is not all of the story, however, for any such gain in profits has to be compared to profits in other lines of manufacturing to make real sense out of the comparison. You will find in our study that such a comparison shows that the steel industry has done very well indeed. Take a look at this, if you will, from the point o f view of profits as a share of the “ sales dollar,” which is a favorite approach o f many companies. What we discover is th is: While net profits as a share of the sales dollar in the steel industry went up from 6.2 cents in 1947 to 7.9 cents in 1956, the record shows that net profits for all manufacturing companies went down from 5.7 cents in 1947 to 4.3 cents in 1956. And these figures, by the way, do not at all mean that companies in other manufacturing lines are in bad condition, profit-wise, or are ill-managed. Rather, it means simply that with increased productivity and higher volume of business these companies are taking less profit per dollar of sales. In contrast to this, the steel industry has been siphoning off more and more profit from each and # every sales dollar, instead o f passing on more o f the benefits of increased produc# tivity and high-level sales to their employees and their customers. You will find, too, a striking contrast in the rising size o f dividend payments by the steel companies, whose dividends more than tripled between 1947 and 1956 while the dividends from all corporations were not quite doubled. This study discloses, as does our other study, that the pricing policies of the steel industry have shown little concern for the welfare of the public. Tradition ally the industry has sought to justify price increases as being necessitated by wage increases, increased materials costs, alleged “ too low” profits margins, and more recently, the “ need” to finance expansion out of profits. We have already seen from our studies that profit margins certainly are not “ too low” and that the concept of financing expansion out of profits is untenable and in contradiction to the traditional system o f obtaining expansion capital through flotation of se curities. The facts in our study likewise contradict the industry’s assertions that in creased wages and materials costs have necessitated price increases. The indus try has increased prices out of all proportion to increased costs. For each $1.00 increase in labor costs since 1945, exorbitant price increases have yielded $3.19 in additional revenues. The figures on materials costs are equally startling. Materials costs since 1947 have risen about 28 percent, but steel prices in the same period have risen 78.2 percent— an excess of price increases over cost in creases o f nearly 3 to 1. A central and overriding fact relative to the current dispute which emerges from our study o f the steel industry is the ability o f the industry to absorb a truly substantial wage increase without a price increase. This is due to the relatively small portion of total costs represented by wage costs, about one-third only, and to the great profitability o f the industry. Within the framework o f its 1956 operations, the steel industry could absorb for a full year a wage “cost” increase which would meet the needs of its em ployees, forego a price increase, and end up with net profits comparable to the huge profits of prior years. The return on net worth would still be nearly dou ble the fair and reasonable rate of 6 percent, and the return on sales would be well above the 4.3 cents for all manufacturing corporations in 1956. The picture becomes even more overwhelming when we realize that the fore ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 185 going figures are based on an assumption o f no increase in productivity. Clearly, even a modest productivity increase o f 4 or 5 percent will facilitate the industry’s ability to absorb wage increases without increasing prices and still end up with enormous profits. What does all of this prove? Certainly not that the industry should not make good profits, nor that the stockholders should not receive good dividends. Rather, what it demonstrates is that the steel companies can well afford, beyond the shadow o f a doubt, to meet the Steelworkers* proposals for a substantial wage increase and the other benefits we ask for our members and that they can do so without raising prices. The Steelworkers Union presented reasonable, practical and justifiable pro posals to the steel industry. We asked for a substantial wage increase which is vitally needed to permit steelworkers to improve their living standards, to share in the industry’s record prosperity and productivity which they have greatly helped to fashion, and to provide them with the increased purchasing power needed for a prosperous and expanding economy. We asked for Sunday premium pay at double time and Saturday premium pay at time and one-half in line with the predominant practice in American industry. We asked for improvements in “fringe” benefits such as holidays, vacations, shift differentials, and insurance. These provisions of our contracts have fallen far behind practices now preva lent in American industry as indicated by the following table taken from our report: American industry practices Pay for Sunday work _ __________________ Pay for Saturday work.................................. Paid holidays......... ........................................ Premium above holiday: Pay for work on holidays ____________ Vacations for: 3 years of service - ________________ 10 years of service __________________ Over 15 years of service............................ Shift differentials: Evening ___________________________ Night............................................ ............ Double time............ ............ Time and one*half................ 7............................................. Steel industry practices Single time. Single time. 6. One-half time or better......... None. 2 weeks................................ 1 week. 3 weeks.................................. 2 weeks. 3 or 4 weeks..... ..................... 3 weeks. 10 cents.................................. 6 cents. 15 cents____ ____ _____ ____ 9 cents. We asked for a supplemental unemployment benefits plan to protect steel workers against the ravages o f unemployment which occasionally occurs in this industry. We asked for improvements in other contract provisions which need moderniza tion. Our study points out that the steel industry has refused to make a wage offer or an offer on the other contract items which even begins to meet the needs here noted. Customarily, the industry and the union have signed 2-year contracts with provision for wage reopening after 1 year. Now the industry has de manded a closed-term, 5-year contract, the provisions of which are decidedly substandard. The industry has flatly refused to make any wage or contract proposals for the customary 2-year term. The industry has advertised far and wide that the take-it-or-leave-it package which they have offered us, over the 5-year term, would cost 65 cents an hour. This industry figure, as our study proves, is propaganda rather than fact. Giving the companies the benefit of any doubt, the ultimate value o f the industry’s offer, when they all finally go into effect in 1961, would be 45.3 cents per hour. Moreover, the average benefit over the 5-year term amounts only to 28.5 cents per hour since many o f the offered benefits would not become effective for several years. This is much less than we have received on the average during the past 10 years under 1- and 2-year contracts. The industry has alleged that any substantial meeting o f the union’s demands would (1) represent a cost too great for the industry to bear, (2) force a large hike in steel prices, (3) be highly inflationary in steel and in the economy. These allegations are, as our studies have shown, wholly unsupported by the facts. They are a deliberate attempt to mislead the public. It is plainly not true that increases in employment costs in steel would set off another round o f inflation. Inflation is an increase in prices— and it is the companies’ price 186 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT policies which have an inflationary effect, not its wage policies. As has been shown above, the steel industry—unlike almost every other American industry— has refused to absorb wage increases in the past and has instead passed on to the consumer three times the cost of each wage increase. The steel industry— unlike almost every other American industry—has increased its profit on each dollar o f sales, instead o f lowering it, as volume increased. The steel industry— unlike almost every other American industry—has refused to recognize that wages should increase without a price increase when workers produce more steel for each hour they work. In short, the steel industry can afford to meet the union’s proposals without increasing prices, and without setting off any inflationary effect whatsoever. Not only can they afford it, but they have a responsibility to do so— in order that the benefits of increased productivity and profits shall be shared by their employees and thus keep purchasing power in balance with output to insure a healthy economic situation. For you will find in our study of the industry that the steel industry’s share of the sales dollar in gross profit has risen from 10.9 cents in 1947 to a rate o f 10.2 cents in 1956. But in shocking contrast to this, an analysis of the 11 com panies on which proper information was available reveals that wages and salaries, as a share o f the sales dollar, have been reduced from 40.5 cents in 1939 to 35.5 cents in 1955. In other words, as we state in our report, “the wage earner’s portion of the sales dollar has grown smaller and smaller.” The facts reveal, for example, that despite the hourly wage increases (plus pension and insurance improvements) in 1954 and 1955, the actual labor cost per ton o f steel produced is less in 1956 than it was in 1954. All this is, indeed, a far cry from the impression created by steel-industry propaganda, with its complaints of rising wage costs and too-small profits. And, o f course, the factual record of their pricing policies do not jibe with their piously expressed concern over inflation. The facts, as our two studies prove, are that the industry’s profit position has been steadily improving while its wage and salary costs have been substantially reduced. Obviously, if such a trend as this were prevalent throughout all industry, there would spread such a gap between the output of mass production and the buying power o f the consumers as to create a serious danger to the economy. There must be a balanced sharing of the benefits derived from increased pro ductivity to keep the economy going forward. The steel-industry leaders should face the plain economic facts which are presented in our two studies and which I have outlined to you here. Adm. Ben Moreell, of Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp., speaking in behalf of the steel industry over -a nation-wide television network on June 28, -said that agree ment could be reached between men of good will. We in the steelworkers con curred in that, and we still concur. Added to good will must, o f course, be reason. And reason must operate within the framework of the economic facts. The union has been willing throughout, and is willing now, to negotiate a fair and honorable settlement based on our proposals, which our studies prove are reasonable, practical, and entirely justifiable. It is the plain duty of the industry, now that it has succeeded in forcing a steel shut-down, to begin—for the first time— the process of give-and-take negotiation which alone can end the present crisis. Sincerely yours, D a v id J. M c D o n a l d , President. FACTS ON STEEL: PROFITS, PRODUCTIVITY, PRICES AND WAGES 1956 UNITED STEELWORKERS OF AMERICA 1500 COMMONWEALTH BUILDING PITTSBURGH 2 2 , PENNSYLVANIA Printed In U.S.A. JULY, 1956 188 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Introduction The Steelworkers Union has presented to the Steel Industry a set of reasonable, practical and justi fiable collective bargaining proposals in 1956. The Union has asked for: 1. A wage increase. 2. Improvements in the out-dated “ fringe” benefit provisions of the agreements covering such “fringes” as holidays, vacations, shift differentials, and insurance. 3. Premium pay for Saturday and Sunday work, for the first time. 4. Institution of a Supplemental Unemployment Benefits plan. 5. Modernization of many of the non-monetary clauses of the agreements such as union security, seniority, hours of work, safety and health, and others. These collective bargaining proposals are modest in scope. The justification for the proposals is clear and unequivocal. In fact, the Steel Industry during the negotiations with the Union has pretended that it agreed with the bases on which most of the Union’s proposals rest. The bases for the proposals are: 1. A wage increase is obviously necessary in order to accomplish at least four goals: (a) To permit Steelworkers to improve their living standards along with millions of other Amer icans who likewise are enjoying wage and salary increases in 1956— increases which are aver aging at least 10^ per hour and are ranging as high as 25^ in some of the more prosperous industries. (b) To permit Steelworkers to share in the prosperity of the Steel Industry which they have greatly helped to fashion. (c) To permit Steelworkers to receive a fair share of the fruits of the large increases in productiv ity—output per man and per manhour— to which they have so importantly contributed. (d) To provide Steelworkers with that part of the increased purchasing power and income needed among wage and salary workers if our Economy is to prosper and expand. 2. The “ fringe” benefit provisions of the contracts with Steel Companies have fallen far behind the practices now prevalent in the vast majority of the collective bargaining agreements in American Industry. They must be greatly improved just to “catch up” with the benefits already provided by most other industries and major companies. The Steel Industry’s current proposals—some of which would not be effective until July 1,1960 — still fall most significantly short, on nearly every item, of meeting the presently prevailing prac tices in American Industry. 3. A Supplemental Unemployment Benefits plan to help Steelworkers during the serious layoffs and losses of pay which occasionally occur in this Industry is badly needed. The Industry has conceded this principle, though it has proposed a wholly unacceptable plan. Sunday Premium Pay at double time and Saturday Premium Pay at time and one-half are also the predominant practice in American Industry. The Steel Companies, however, still refuse to meet this practice. Instead they propose a minor premium for Sunday (1/25 time) and none for Saturday. Even this insignificant Sunday premium would begin only three years hence. 4. Many of the other contract provisions are also subnormal. Steel is one of the very few major in dustries which still adamantly refuses to grant a union shop. It still insists on seniority provisions which result in discriminatory layoffs for senior employees. It still refuses to make proper ar- ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 189 rangements with the Union to safeguard the safety and health of Its employees. It still insists on split work weeks and schedules which disrupt eaeh employee’s life each week by rotation from day shift to evening shift to night shift and which force nearly all Steelworkers to work fre quently on Sundays and Saturdays, when most of the work could just as readily be scheduled on other days. The Steel Industry has refused to make a wage offer or an offer on the other contract items which even begins to meet the needs here noted. Customarily, the Industry and the Union have signed 2-year contracts with provision for wage reopening after one year. Now the Industry has demanded a closedterm, 5-year contract, the provisions of which are decidedly substandard. The actual offer, taken to gether with the conditions made a part thereof, bears little resemblance to the publicized proposal. The Industry has flatly refused to make any wage or contract proposals for the customary 2-year term. It has alleged that any substantial meeting of the Union’s demands would: (1) represent a cost too great for the Industry to bear, (2) force a large hike in Steel Prices, (3) be highly inflationary in Steel and in the Economy. These allegations are, in the Union’s opinion, wholly unsupported by the facts. They are a delib erate attempt to mislead the public. It is important and appropriate to check these claims against the facts and data which are available. This the Union has attempted to do in this presentation. In the financial analysis which follows the Union has examined the facts and figures available in the Annual Reports to the stockholders of each of these Companies and in the statistics published by the Government and by various private organizations. This analysis of the Steel Industry examines the data of 25 major Steel Companies and treats these Companies, which account for over 90 percent of all steelmaking capacity in the United States, as being representative of the whole Industry. These 25 Companies include all firms with annual ingot capacity of 500,000 tons or more as of Janu ary 1, 1956, except for Ford Motor Company, International Harvester Co., Timken Roller Bearing Co., and Merritt-Chapman & Scott Corp. (parent of Newport Steel Corp. and Milton Steel Div.) which are primarily engaged in business other than Steel production; and Reeves Steel and Mfg. Co. (parent of Empire Steel Corp.) for which no financial data are published. These 25 Companies are listed in each of the Tables in descending order of ingot capacity. The Companies and their ingot capacities are shown in TABLE 1 and graphically in CHART 1. Table 1 THE STEEL INDUSTRY (25 Companies) Annual Capacity la Tons U.S. Steel............................................ 39,215,000 Bethlehem............................................ 20,000,000 Republic............................................... 10,262,000 Jones & Laughlin................................. 6,166,500 National............................................... 6,000,000 Youngstown S and T .......................... 5,750,000 Inland.................................................. 5,200,000 Armco.................................................. 5,150,000 Colorado F and 1................................. 2,514,500 Wheeling.............................................. 2,130,000 Sharon................................................. 1,763,000 Kaiser................................................... 1,536,000 Crucible............................................... 1,423,400 McLouth............................................... Pittsburgh............................................. Detroit.................................................. Granite City.......................................... Barium.................................................. Allegheny Ludlum................................. Northwestern S & W ............................ Lukens................................................... Alan Wood............................................ Copperweld........................................... Lone Star.............................................. Laclede.................................................. 1,380,000 1,320,000 1,290,000 1,080,000 898,600 864,200 825,000 750,000 625,000 618,380 550,000 500,000 TOTAL (25 COMPANIES) 117,811,580 This 117,811,580 tons of capacity of these 25 Companies is 91.8% ot the total capacity (128,363,090 tons) of the Industry as of January 1, 1956. SOURCE.—American Iron and Steel Institute. 190 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CHART 1 Steel Ingot Capacity as of January 1,1956 128,363,090 tons The Big 3 Steel Companies have 54.1 % of the Industry's Capacity 90 U *c i> American iron and Steel Institute 191 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Summary Statement The Union’s proposals for improvements in the current agreements with the Steel Industry (25 Companies) are fully justified on the basis of the facts. These are fully documented in the detailed analysis which follows. Some of the highlights of that documentation are: 1. Profits of the Steel Industry (25 Companies) are at a record high level: The 1956 annual rate of Profits Before Taxes is $2,350.7 million. This is: 15.3% 107.4% 238.3% 1,390.6% higher than in 1955 ($2,038.5 million) higher than in 1954 ($1,133.6 million) higher than in 1947 ($ 694.9 million) higher than in 1939 ($ 157.7 million) The 1956 annual rate of Net Profits is $1,153.4 million. This is: 13.1% 95.6% 192.5% 812.5% higher higher higher higher than than than than in in in in 1955 1954 1947 1939 ($1,019.4 ($ 589.8 ($ 394.3 ($ 126.4 million) million) million) million) 2. Profit margins for the Steel Industry (22-25 Companies) have widened. For All Manufactur ing Corporations profit margins have narrowed. In Steel Net Profits as a share of the Sales Dollar rose from 6.2^ in 1947 to 7.9^ in 1956. In All Manufacturing Net Profits as a share of the Sales Dollar declined from 5.7^ in 1947 to 4.3^ in 1956. In Steel Net Profits as a rate of Return on Net Worth rose from 10.5% in 1947 to 13.8% in 1955. In All Manufacturing Net Profits as a rate of Return on Net Worth declined from 15.1% in 1947 to 12.3% in 1955. 3. The Steel Industry (25 Companies) has handsomely rewarded its stockholders. Dividend payments in 1956 are at an annual rate of $412.9 million, a record high. This is an increase of 223.1% since 1947. All Corporations showed an increase during this period of only 80.0%. 4. The Steelworker has increased his produc tivity—output per manhour—sharply. By 4.7% in the 1st quarter of 1956 By 11.2% in 1955 (a record high for a year) By 68.8% since 1939 For his efforts the entire Steel Industry wants to reward him with a decreasing rate of wage in crease: 11.3^ actual average wage settlement in last four years 7.3^ offered average wage increase for next five years 5. The entire Steel Industry has reaped a bo nanza from Steel Price increases out of all pro portion to increased costs. Since 1945 there have been 8 rounds of wage increases (plus pensions and insurance during another year) and 18 rounds of price increases. The cumulative impact of the Price and wage increases measured on 1955 operations meant to the entire Steel Industry. Additional Revenues.............. $5,697.2 million Additional Labor C ost...........$1,783.2 million Total G a in ......................$3,914.0 million For each $1.00 increase in labor costs the Steel Industry has generated $3.19 in additional rev enues by their unjustifiably big Price increases. 6. Since 1947 (through March, 1956) Prices of Steel Sold (1st quar ter, 1956, average is 77.7%) +78.2% Prices of Materials Purchased +26.7% 7. An examination of major “fringe” practices in Industry which can readily be compared shows the serious lag of the Steel Industry. Pay fo r Sunday W ork P ay fo r Saturday W ork Paid Holidays ................ Premium above Holiday Pay for W ork on Holidays ...................... Double time Tim e and onehalf 7 Single time Single time One-half time o r better Vacations for: 3 years o f service— 10 years o f service.— O ver 15 years o f s e r v ic e -----------------Shift Differentials: E v e n in g -------------------Night ----------------------- 2 weeks 3 weeks 1 week 2 weeks 3 weeks 1<* 15* 64 9* 192 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT A. THE FINANCIAL POSITION OF THE STEEL INDUSTRY The facts on the Steel Industry tell a most re markable story. Never in the history of the Steel Industry has its financial position been as strong and as sound as it is today. Mea sured by any standard and measured against any year, the Profits of the Industry are at a fabulous and exorbitantly high level. This applies to the Industry as a whole and to the individual Steel Companies comprising the Industry. With in the framework of its current Profit structure the Industry can grant the workers substantial wage increases and other benefits, absorb them, and still maintain Profits at record or near record levels. The steady and almost uninterrupted in crease in the Profits of the Industry are readily apparent from even a cursory inspection of its own financial reports. TABLE 2 is a summary showing pertinent fi nancial data since 1939 for the Steel Industry: Table 2 COMPARATIVE FINANCIAL DATA* (dollars in millions) STEEL INDUSTRY (25 Companies) Common Stock Cash Dividends Net Profits as a Rate oj Return on Net Worth (; Sales Profits Before Taxes Net Profits $14,576.2 $2,350.7 $1,153.4 $412.9 1955 12,993.9 2,038.5 1,019.4 353.9 7,390.4 13.8% 1954 1953 1952 1951 1950 1949 1948 1947 1946 1939 9,855.1 12,165.1 9,966.3 11,053.3 9,064.3 7,179.3 7,867.5 6,421.6 4,514.9 2,368.1 1,133.6 1,600.7 929.6 1,884.0 1,530.7 933.3 985.9 694.9 368.3 157.7 589.8 679.4 492.5 633.5 728.5 521.8 534.9 394.3 249.9 126.4 269.0 248.7 238.8 240.3 246.0 167.9 150.2 127.8 95.6 16.4 6,681.0 6,303.0 5,890.8 5,668.4 5,177.1 4,714.0 4,395.3 3,754.1 3,527.3 3,025.7 8.8% 10.8% 8.4% 11.2% 14.1% 11.1% 12.2% 10.5% 7.1% 4.2% 1956** Net Worth (a) 15.6% * Indudes 25 Companies. Two of the smaller Companies were not operating in 1939. Exclusion of the figures for these two Companies for later years to make the number of Companies entirely uniform throughout would have only a negligible effect on the above comparisons. ** Annual rate projected from 1st quarter 1956 figures (except for Kaiser for which 6 months ending 12/31/55 was used). (a ) Net Worth is as of the end of year. Computation of the rate of Return on Net Worth was based on Net Worth as of the end of the year except for 1956 for which beginning Net Worth was used. SOURCE.— Based on other Tables. As can be seen from these figures, Sales, Prof its Before and After Taxes, and Common Stock Cash Dividends all were at record peaks in the year 1955. The 1st quarter 1956 reports of the Industry indicate that the results for the year 1956 will even surpass those new records estab lished in 1955. What is most significant is not only that the dollar amounts of Profits are at a record high level, but that profit margins themselves are ex- 193 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Table 3 PRO FIT S B E F O R E T A X E S * (dollars in m illions) ST E E L IN D U ST R Y (25 Com panies) U. S. S teel.................. Bethlehem .................. R ep u blic...................... Jones & Laughlin •. . N ational...................... Youngstown S and T. Inland.......................... A rm co .......................... Colorado F and I b. . W heeling..................... Sharon......................... Kaiserb ........................ Crucible...................... M c L o u th .................... Pittsburgh0................. D etroitd...................... Granite C ity. ............ Barium ........................ Allegheny L u d lu m ... Northwestern S&W* L ukens'....................... Alan W o o d ................. Copperw eld................ Lone S ta r................... L aclede........................ TO TA LS 1956** 1955 $844.8 3 57.2 208.8 106.8 117.2 8 2.8 117.2 160.0 3 2 .0 4 5 .6 18.0 15.0 3 3 .2 2 0.4 2 1.2 1 8.4 3 1.3 1 4.0 3 8.8 14.4 1 2.0 5 .2 8 .4 1 8.8 9 .2 $736.1 361.2 170.3 96.6 96.6 8 3.8 105.5 131.0 2 1 .6 3 5 .8 1 5.8 1 0.5 2 8 .8 1 5.5 1 4.8 13.0 2 6.3 1 .7 3 1.5 8 .7 5 .7 4 .2 5 .4 9 .4 8 .7 $ 2,350.7 $ 2,0 38 .5 Increase in 1956 over other years1.............................. 1 5 .3 % Increase in 1955 over other years*.................................................... 1954 1953 1952 1951 1950 1947 $545.1 294.9 157.2 5 8.9 118.5 5 8.9 7 3.2 84.7 2 2 .6 2 6 .5 1 3.9 2 0 .3 1 2.0 1 6.8 10.0 1 1.8 13.4 6 .2 1 9.5 1 .1 13.3 5 .7 6 .0 2 .5 7 .7 $282.3 156.9 86.9 14.7 79.6 4 0 .2 3 6.9 7 4.4 1 4.2 18.4 7 .9 2 1 .8 1 1.0 1 3.8 9 .6 8 .9 7 .5 9 .3 8 .8 2 .8 6 .2 4 .7 4 .7 3 .2 4 .9 $622.7 268.5 175.4 85.3 145.3 6 9.6 8 7.9 104.1 2 9.3 5 1.1 2 7 .3 1 5.7 2 6.5 1 6.5 2 2.5 32.3 13.1 12.8 2 9.0 8.1 12.7 6 .5 8 .3 5 .6 7 .9 $485.0 245.0 154.3 73.6 124.4 7 4.5 7 9.2 9 5 .2 7 .1 3 5.7 1 8.9 2 1.6 1 4.5 11.2 12.5 1 7.2 11.1 3 .6 20.1 4 .4 3 .7 4 .3 4 .4 2 .6 6 .6 $244.4 8 2.1 58.3 31.6 4 9.6 4 2 .9 4 8.4 4 1 .5 7 .8 1 9.4 10.9 X 3 .1 2 .9 6 .9 12.9 2 .6 2 .9 10.1 3 .4 4 .7 3 .2 2 .7 0 .2 2 .4 $1,1 33 .6 $ 1,600.7 $929.6 $ 1,8 84 .0 $ 1,530.7 $694.9 1 0 7 .4 % 4 6 .9 % 1 5 2 .9 % 2 4 .8 % 5 3 .6 % 2 3 8 .3 % 1 ,3 9 0 .6 % 7 9 .8 % 2 7 .4 % 1 1 9 .3 % 8 .2 % 3 3 .2 % 1 9 3 .4 % 1 ,1 9 2 .6 % $385.4 2 51.8 102.8 4 7.6 58.1 3 2 .4 7 9.2 8 3.6 1 3.2 18.1 5 .0 1 5.2 8 .1 -0 .4 t 3 .1 0 .8 8 .4 —2 .2 f 8 .7 2 .1 4 .8 1 .5 1 .3 -l.O f 6 .0 1939 $54.1 3 0 .8 13.1 3 .7 1 4.2 5 .9 1 3.5 4 .8 0 .2 6 .6 0 .5 N.O. 3 .4 0 .4 0 .7 0 .7 0 .4 -0 .2 t 2 .5 0 .1 0 .1 0 .8 1 .2 N.O. 0 .2 $157.7 * The figures cover each Company’s fiscal years ending in the years indicated. The figures are Profits Before Federal Taxes on Income. Where the Companies’ Annual Reports have shown such a figure separately, it has been used. Where no such figure was reported, it was derived by adding Federal Income Taxes to the Stated Net Profits. (In a few cases it was necessary to add an Income Tax figure which included State and/or Cana dian Income Taxes because they could not be segregated.) In the few instances in which there was a Net Loss reported for a year, the Loss figure was used as a minus Profit Before Taxes figure unless a Loss Before Taxes figure was shown separately. The only adjustments made in the Stated Profits Before Taxes figures were for those few Companies which have used Accelerated Depreciation Charges. Since these amounts were, and are, not allowable for income Tax purposes, they were added to the Profits Before Taxes figures shown in the Annual Reports in order to correct for the understatement of Profits Before Taxes resulting from the use of this accounting device. The Companies, years and amounts (in millions) involved were 1954 U .S . Steel............................................................ Republic............................................................... National................................................................ Kaiser................................................................... Lukens..........! ...................................... $ 0.7 1953 .... .... .... $ 1.5 0.3 1952 »21.6 .... .... 1.5 0.2 1951 $40.4 3.0 5.0 1.5 0.3 1950 $35.5 11.3 5.5 1.6 0.3 1949 $22.0 3.0 11.9 1.7 0.3 1948 $55.3 7.0 10.5 1.5 0.3 1947 $26.3 4.0 3.5 1.8 ** Annual rate projected on a straight-line basis from 1st calendar quarter of 1956 for all Companies except Lukens (12 weeks ended 3/24/56), Northwestern Steel & Wire (3 months ended 4/30/56), and Kaiser (6 months ended 12/31/55). X — Less than $50,000. N.O.— Not Operating. » For 1939 the figure was computed by adding the revised Net Profits figure to the revised combined Income Tax figure. From this total was subtracted the Income Taxes other than Federal as originally reported by the Corporation. b Fiscal years ended June 30th. • For certain of the earlier years the figures were computed by adding revised Net Profits and Income Taxes, from a prospectus, and subtract ing State Income Taxes as shown in Moody’s Industrials and the Company’s Annual Reports. d Includes reported Net Profits of Portsmouth (acquired at end of 1949) for 1947 (also for 6 months of 1946 and for 1948 and 1949 not here shown). • Fiscal years ended July 31st. 1 Fifty weeks ended 12/31/55. Prior fiscal years are 52 week periods ending at various dates in October. « If Kaiser and Lone Star were excluded from the later years’ ngures, the percentage increases would be very slightly affected. Only the per centage comparisons with 1939 are affected slightly as here shown. SOURCE.—Annual Re-ports of the Companies; Moody’s Industrials. Calculations ours. 194 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CHART 2 Profits Before Taxes 35Q Index (1947=100) * 25 major companies accounting for 91.8 of total steel capacity, of the same corporations * * SO U RCE: U.S.Department of Commerce source : Annual ond quarterly reports ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT traordinarily high. Profits Before Taxes in 1955, as a rate of Return on Net Worth were 27.6% —a rate exceeded only twice (1950 and 1951) in the Industry’s recent financial history. In 1956 the rate has jumped to 31.8% which surpasses all recent years (except 1951). Since it is from Prof its Before Taxes that wage “cost” increases would, come if the “ costs” were absorbed, this measure of profitability is most significant. Net Profits (After Taxes) as a rate of Return on Net Worth for 1955 were 13.8%, which is con siderably higher than the rate for any year in the last quarter of a century (except for 1950) and more than double the 6% rate which normally and traditionally has been considered to be a fair and reasonable rate of return on stockholder in vestment. The rate of return for 1956 is 15.6%, which is more than 13% higher than the near record rate achieved last year. Profits Before Taxes in 1955 represented 15.8$* out of each Sales Dollar. This margin has further widened to 16.2^ in 1956. These exorbitant mar gins reflect the degree by which the Industry has overpriced its products. The 1955 rate has been surpassed only twice in recent years (1950 and 1951). They are too high by any standard. Net Profits (After Taxes) as a share of the Sales 1— Profits Before Taxes Profits Before Taxes (Federal Corporate Income Taxes) of the Industry (25 Companies) reached a record high level in 1955—and even this record high level is being far surpassed in 1956. The an nual rate of Profits Before Taxes for 1956 is $2,350.7 million. This is 15.3% higher them Profits Before Taxes in 1955. It is more than double the level in 1954 and 1952 and more than double that for any year preceding 1950. In fact, it is almost 15 times as much as was earned in 1939. It is most significant to note that the rate of growth of Profits Before Taxes in Steel between 1947 and 1956 has been more than twice as rapid as in All Corporations and in All Manufacturing Corpo rations. These data appear in TABLE 3 and CHART 2 (also TABLE 22). 2— Net Profits (After Taxes) In 1955 the Industry (25 Companies) reported Net Profits (After Taxes) of over a button dollars ($1,019,400,000) for the first time in its history. This was 72.8% higher than Net Profits in 1954, 195 Dollar were 7.9^ in 1955 and have held at this rate so far in 1956. This is a high rate of return on Sales for this Industry—and one which has only been equalled once in the last 15 years. It comes at a time when the Industry can readily cut profit margins per Sales Dollar and still make a fair Profit because of its high operating rate and peak Sales volume. The record high Profits result in part from in creased productivity and in part from higher Steel Prices charged by the Steel Companies for their products. As pointed out elsewhere in this anal ysis, the Industry has not shared equitably with its employees the huge gains resulting from in creased productivity. The public has received no share whatsoever of these gains. At the same time the Industry has increased its Prices far more than was necessary to compensate for increased “costs” . This is true even if one accepts the In dustry’s faulty and mistaken premise that it must raise Prices every time the “cost” of materials or labor increases. Actually, those presumed “costs” have already been absorbed by productivity gains and by high level operations. A more detailed examination of these financial facts about the Steel Industry follows: It is within the framework of its Profits Before Taxes that a Company’s or an Industry’s ability to absorb a “ cost” increase is measured, whether the increase be wage “ cost” or any other “cost” . These 25 Companies in 1955 employed an average of approximately 775,000 persons. If this same employment is assumed for 1956 and if a 2,000 hour man-year is assumed for each employee, total annual manhours would be about 1,550 mil lion. This means that for each manhour worked in 1956 the Industry is making an average Profit of $1.52—a rather substantial Profit on each hour of labor—one which is more than 60% of the total amount actually paid for each hour of work. It certainly leaves an adequate margin within which substantial labor “cost” increases can be absorbed. 39.9% higher than Net Profits in 1950, the prior record year, and more than 8 times as much as Net Profits in 1939. This is a record of Profit growth which should have been eminently satisfactory. But in 1956 it ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 196 TaMe 4 NET PROFITS — REPORTED* (dollars in millions) STEEL INDUSTRY (25 Companies) U .S. Steel................. Bethlehem................. Republic.................... Jones &Laughlin.... National.................... Youngstown S and T. Inland........................ Armco........................ Colorado Fand I*... Wheeling................... Sharon....................... Kaiser*...................... Crucible.................... McLouth................... Pittsburgh................. Detroit1*..................... Granite City............. Barium........ ............. Allegheny Ludlum... Northwestern S&W*. Lukens*..................... Alan Wood................ Copperweld............... Lone Star.................. Laclede...................... 1956** 1955 1954 $416.8 180.0 100.0 54.4 56.4 40.8 56.0 78.8 16.0 21.4 9.2 7.8 14.8 9.6 10.0 8.8 15.8 6.0 18.4 6.8 5.6 2.8 4.0 8.8 4.4 $370.1 180.2 86.3 50.1 48.3 41.7 52.5 64.4 10.9 17.3 8.0 5.7 13.2 8.1 7.5 6.3 12.6 0.7 15.0 4.1 2.6 2.6 2.4 4 .8 4.0 $195.4 132.8 52.9 25.0 30.3 20.2 41.3 41.1 7.1 9.6 3.1 7.9 3.7 1.7 2.2 0.9 4.0 -0 .4 t 4.2 1.0 2.0 1.2 0.7 -l.O f 2.9 TOTALS....... $1,153.4 $1,019.4 $589.8 1953 1952 1951 1950 1947 1939 $222.1 133.9 56.7 31.0 49.2 30.8 33.9 33.9 8.0 12.5 6.7 9.1 5.1 5.2 4.6 5.2 6.5 2.3 7.8 0.4 3.6 3.2 2.9 2.1 2.7 $143.7 90.9 44.3 19.5 37.6 22.9 23.8 31.3 5.8 11.0 5.1 10.4 5.4 4.2 5.2 4.3 5.0 2.7 5.9 2.0 2.3 2.3 2.3 2.5 2.1 $184.4 106.5 54.9 31.0 45.3 30.6 34.4 35.0 10.0 17.4 8.9 7.5 8.4 5.2 7.3 10.5 5.1 4.2 8.8 3.1 3.5 2.9 2.7 3.1 2 .8 $215.5 123.0 63.8 39.7 57.8 40.6 38.0 47.0 4.4 18.3 9.3 11.9 6.3 5.8 6.4 8.9 5.7 1.5 9.8 2.7 1.9 2.8 2.6 1.6 3.2 $127.1 51.1 31.0 20.1 26.8 26.3 29.9. 25.0 5.2 11.7 6.7 -1 .8 f 2.1 1.8 4.0 8.0 1.7 1.7 6.0 2.0 2.8 2.0 1.5 0.2 1.4 $41.1 24.6 10.7 3.1 12.6 5.0 10.9 4.0 0.1 5.6 0.4 N.O. 2.8 0.3 0.6 0.5 0.3 - 0 .2 f 2.0 0.1 0.1 0.7 0.9 N.O. 0.2 $679.4 $492.5 $633.5 $394.3 $126.4 $728.5 Increase in 1956 oyer other years*............................ 13.1% 95.6% 69.8% 134.2% 82.1% 58.3% 192.5% 812.5% Increase in 1955 over other years*............................................... 72.8% 50.0% 107.0% 60.9% 39.9% 158.5% 706.5% *—The figures cover each Company’s fiscal yean ending in the yean indicated. The figures shown are Stated Net Profits without any adjust ment, except for revisions made by the Companies themselves in subsequent Annual Reports. Where such revisions have been made by the Com panies, they have been used in every case where they were available. **—Annual rate projected on a straight-line basis from1st calendarquarter of 1956 for all Companies except Lukens (12 weeks ended 3/24/56), Northwestern Steel & Wire (3 months ended 4/30/56), and Kaiser (6 months ended 12/31/55). t—Loss. N.O.—Not Operating. • —Fiscal years ended June 30th. b —Includes reported Net Profits of Portsmouth (acquired at end of 1949) for 1947 (also for 6 months of 1946 and for 1948 and 1949 not here shown). • —Fiscal yean ended July 31st. <*—Fifty weeks aided 12/31/55. Prior fiscal years are 52-week periods ending at various dates in October. • —If Kaiser and Lone Star were excluded from the later yean’ figures, the percentage increases would be very slightly affected. Only the percentage comparisons with 1939 are affected slightly as here shown. General Note: A number of these Companies reported their Net Profits and Profits Before Taxes on a different basis than the other Steel Companies. These Companies in their reports to stockholders showed regular Depredation on expanded or new facilities rather than Rapid Amortization as permitted by the tax laws under certain circumstances. However, they took credit for Rapid Amortization for tax purposes and showed the tax saving as a Reserve for Future Taxes. This method resulted in an overstatement (comparatively speaking) of Net Profits. These overstatements were not great enough, however, to alter seriously the comparisons shown and the conclusions reached in this analysis. McLouth, Pittsburgh,. Granite City, Northwestern Steel & Wire and Lone Star used this method beginning in 1953. Jones & Laughlin, Kaiser, Detroit and Barium used this method of reporting beginning in 1954. Colorado Fuel and Iron and Lukens adopted the new method of reporting Profits in 1955. As a result, their Profits figures for these years are not entirely comparable with their Profits figures for some prior years. SOURCE.—AnnualReportsoftheCompanies;Moody’sIndustrials. Calculationsours. 197 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CHART 3 Net Profits 300 lndex(i947»ioo) Steel lasinc Based ts net irofits inthe last 9 years morsthi ntwio i as 250 rapidl fas All Manufi icturin gCorpi rations 'nrnnn tinns or/III ut nil wllWtf •Wllv 200 Steel—Y Industry y 150 £ 100 ja > \ AllCorpi(rations ( \ f __ // t ....... c AnWaniifscturing Corporitions 50 ; iin ipii Ifi IfA lr«t iff IfA *25majorcompaniesaccountingfor91.8%oftotalsteelcapacity, sourcb<annualandquarterlyreport* ofthesamecorporations **SOURCE:U.S.DepartmentofCommerce ECONOMIC REPORT OP THE PRESIDENT 198 appears that Net Profits will even exceed the rec ord established in 1955. The annual rate of Net Profits for 1956 is $1,153.4 million, which is 18.1% higher than record Net Profits for the full year 1955. It is interesting to note that 16 of these 25 Com panies reported record-breaking Net Profits in 1955. So far in 1956 a total of 17 of these Com panies are reporting Net Profits at an all time record-breaking rate. The unparalleled prosper ity that the Industry is enjoying is being shared by nearly all Companies, big and small. Again, it should be noted that the rate of growth of Net Profits in Steel between 1947 and 1956 has been more than twice as rapid as in All Corporations and in All Manufacturing Corporations. The supporting data are shown in TABLE 4 and CHART 3 (also TABLE 23). 3—Dividends their Common stockholders. The Dividend growth in Steel between 1947 and 1956 has been almost twice (1.8 times) as great as in All Corporations. The supporting data are in TABLE 5 and CHART 4 (also TABLE 24). Many Companies have also paid Stock Dividends in addition to, or in lieu of, Cash Dividends. In 1955, for instance, 6 Companies made such pay ments amounting to $13.7 million in value, an amount substantially greater than the Cash Divi dends paid by these same Companies to their stockholders in 1956. In addition to receiving handsome increases in Dividend payments, the Common stockholders have benefited from a sharp increase in the equity value of their stockholdings. The Net Worth of these Companies has increased from just over $3 billion as of the end of 1939 to almost $7.5 billion as of the end of 1955. This represents the book value increase. The actual market price in crease of Steel stocks has been much greater. Over the years the Common stockholders of the Industry (25 Companies) have fared extremely well. In 1939 Cash Dividends totalled $16.4 mil lion. In 1955, total cash payments had risen to $353.9 million. The annual rate of Cash Dividend payments for 1956 has risen to $412.9 million, some 25 times the level of 1939. This annual rate for 1956 likely understates probable pay ments for the full year since several Companies customarily declare year-end “ extra” Dividends which have been ignored in projecting the annual rate. Not only have total dollar Dividend payments shown a sharp increase, but the number of these Companies paying Cash Dividends to their stock holders has increased sharply since 1939. In that year only 7 of these Companies made a cash pay ment to their Common stockholders. In 1947 this number had increased to 19 and currently 22 of the 25 Companies are paying Cash Dividends to 4—Net Worth and Rate of Return on Net Worth The profit margin of the Steel Industry (25 Companies) is further demonstrated when Profits Before Taxes are measured as a rate of Return on Net Worth. This margin in 1955 was 27.6^ on each dollar of stockholder investment In 1956 it has climbed to 31.81 on the dollar. This reflects an inflationary Pricing policy for the Benefit of the Steel Industry only. These margins follow: PROFITS BEFORE TAXES AS A RATE OF RETURN ON NET WORTH STEEL INDUSTRY (25 Companies) Totals (25 Companies)------ 1956 1055 1954 31.8% 27.6% 17.0% 195S 25.4% 1952 1951 1950 1947 1989 15.8% 33.2% 29.6% 18.5% 5.2% 199 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Table 5 CASH DIVIDENDS* ON COMMON STOCK (dollars in millions) STEEL INDUSTRY 1956** U .S. Steel................. $139.2 Bethlehem................. 85.9 Republic.................... 38.6 Jones & Laughlin. . . 15.7 National.................... 29.5 Youngstown S and T. 13.5 22.0 Inland........................ Armco........................ 26.0 Colorado Fuel and Iron 6.1 Wheeling.................... 5.7 Sharon........................ 3.3 Kaisera...................... 1.3 Crucible..................... 5.4 McLouth.................... None Pittsburgh............... 1.5 Detroitb..................... 3.0 4.2 Granite City............. Barium....................... None Allegheny Ludlum... 6.0 Northwestern S&W.. 1.0 Lukens....................... 1.4 0.9 Alan Wood.............. Copperweld............. 1.5 Lone Star.................. None Laclede...................... 1.2 TOTALS....... $412.9 1955 $122.9 69.5 38.4 14.0 23.9 12.6 23.0 20.6 2.9 5.3 2.8 1.3 3.6 None 0.4 0.8 3.9 None 4.0 0.4 0.5 0.9 1.0 None 1.2 $353.9 (25 Companies) 1952 1954 1953 $ 85.5 $ 78.3 $ 78.3 55.1 38.3 38.3 26.7 28.9 23.6 12.1 12.4 11.2 23.9 22.0 22.0 12.6 12.6 10.1 18.9 17.2 14.7 15.6 15.6 15.6 3.5 3.1 1.9 4.3 4.3 4.3 4.4 2.8 4.4 1.6 0.8 1.6 None None None None None None None None None 2.4 1.8 None 1.5 None None 0.5 1.1 1.1 3.4 3.3 3.4 None None None 1.3 1.0 1.1 0.2 0.8 0.9 0.9 1.0 1.0 None None None 0.9 1.1 1.3 9.0 $248.7 8.8 1951 $ 78.3 38.3 23.6 10.7 22.0 10.1 17.1 14.8 3.2 4.3 3.4 None None None None 2.4 2.7 0.9 4.1 None 1.3 0.8 1.2 None 1.1 $240.3 1950 $ 92.7 39.3 25.1 7.1 20.9 10.1 17.1 15.7 1.8 2.8 2.9 None None None None 2.4 , 1.9 None 3.2 None 0.6 0.3 1.0 None 1.1 6.0 1947 $ 45.7 17.9 11.3 5.0 8.9 8.4 12.2 6.5 1.0 1.0 1.2 None None 0.4 None 2.9 0.4 None 2.6 1.1 0.4 None 0.4 None 0.5 $127.8 $16.4 *iontoT erfig ulie reusocof,veCraseh acD hiv Cid om pd asny(e’sxcfis ca rstoew ndsin gin aersdin dic$am ted .n Tsh eetoC ta lC an sh en d:sonly. StockDividendspaidin additR ,lich o— in en ep tlfoyreaS plit s) tah sevy aelu (in illio )ebyyatrh om pa ieD s,iv foid llo w e p u b 1 9 4 8 — $ 7 .7 (4 % ) J oanteiosn& La1 u9g4h8lin — 199.0 49(1 — 7.4 N al— — 0$)% ) (5%) A rom ca o— 1F 94 8e— $n1d$ 61 .2 (2 0% C lo r d o u l a I r o n — 1 9 5 19)54—$2.0(5%); 1951—$6.9(25%) W h ereolin g— 10 9— 55— $8.9 0)%);5— 19$510.1 —(2 $7.5 .1% (2);5% S h a nle — 1915 $8$.8 (5(8 0(1 % C r u c ib — 9 5 4 — 1 .5 % ); 1 9 5 3 — $ 1 .6 (8 % ); 19)52—$2.7(10%); 1951—$3.7(16%) M ctL ou trh — 19 5935— $1 5.7 (2 5 % );e1ly 95 0$— $5(3 .9% (1);00$% P it s b u g h — 1 5 -5 r e s p e c tiv : 1 .1 1.7(8%); $1.8(8%); $2.2(8%); $0.5(2%) D rnoitite— 95— 5— (4 );(61% 95);3— $503.6 (2 Gareratiu C1 ity 19$ 51 4.2 — $(5 1% .8 1 9 — $2% .9).5(1% 2);%1 );94 19 9— 52— $01.8(1(3 %)); 1949—$0.3(4%) B m — 1 9 5 5 — $ 0 .9 7 % ); 1 9 5 4 — $ 0 .9 1 (7 .9 0% Ala llengh en y L ud lu m — 109.4 53(3 — $1);.01(2 % );$109.4 52— $1);.11(2 % ) $$00.4 A W o o d — 1 9 5 5 — $ % 9 5 4 — (5 % 9 5 0 — (5 % ); 1949—$0.6(10%) L on ennual Star— 194based 9—$0.5 (2Dividends 5%) dedaredin1st half of calendar 1956 ** A rate on (except forKaiserwhichnormallydistributes onlyoneDividendper year).N.O.—NotOperating. «Kaiser, for all intentsandpurposes, hadnoCommonStockprior to October 1950. It hadonly1,000shares of CommonStock, all closely held, valuedat $100,000. Thestockissuedin1951carriedabookvalueof $3,200,000. bIncludesCommonStockCashDividendsforPortsmouth(acquiredin1949)for1947(alsofor1946,1948and1949nothereshown). SOURCE.—AnnualReportsoftheCompanies;Moody’sIndustrials;Moody'sDividendRecord. Calculations ours. 200 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CHART 4 DividendPaymentsinSteel v&All Corporations CornulonSti ckOiv dend }aymeiits in81eel 1 1 325 have edfarr torera lidly irnnrat thanf ulro Tfldlll ji mi unpufaii nnc «J Steet Inriirctrv 250 / 100 <£•••• •m in I.A \•• \ ■ 1 175 AllCop ations* u. Ipp ip« * oilcashdividendsofAllCorporations, «.U.S. D epartmentofCommerce **onlycashdividendsoncommonstocksof 25steelcorporationsaccountingfor91.8%oftotalsteelcapacity, souftciiAnnualandquarterlyreportsofthesamecorporations sourcs 201 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT A portion of these Profits Before Taxes do* not accrue to the Steel owners but are paid in taxes to the Federal Government. The amount avail able to the stockholders either for Dividends or as an increase in equity is shown in the Net Profits figures, which are also measured as a rate of Re turn on Net Worth. While the Steel Industry constantly complains of an inadequate return on its investment, the actual figures certainly do not bear this out It has long been accepted in accounting and financial circles that Net Profits After Taxes at 6% on Net Worth represent a fair and reason able rate of return. In 1939 the Steel Industry did not quite reach this standard. The rate of return that year was 4.2%. Since then the rate of Re turn on Net Worth has exceeded 6% in every year except during World War II. In most peacetime years since 1939, the rate has been in excess of 10%. In 1955 the over-all rate for the Industry Table 6 U. S. Steel................. Bethlehem................. Republic.................... Jones & Laughlin. .. National.................... Youngstown S and T. Inland........................ Armco........................ Colorado F and I.... Wheeling.................... Sharon........................ Kaiser......................... Crucible..................... McLouth.................... Pittsburgh................. Detroit8..................... Granite City............. Barium....................... Allegheny Ludlum... Northwestern S & W. Lukens....................... Alan Wood................ Copperweld............... Lone Star.................. Laclede...................... AVERAGES** NET PROFITS AS A RATE OF RETURN ON NET WORTH* STEEL INDUSTRY (25 Companies) 1956* 1955 1954 1953 1952 1951 9.9% 6.7% 8.8% 1 6A% 141% T ? % 15.2 15.2 12.3 13.3 9.9 12.2 16.5 14.2 12.1 9.8 10.1 13.0 12.9 11.9 6.5 8.3 5.5 8.9 14.2 12.1 8.1 13.5 11.4 14.4 11.5 6.1 9.5 11.2 7.5 10.4 16.9 15.8 14.4 13.6 10.2 15.4 20.4 16.7 12.1 10.8 10.6 12.5 13.9 9.5 6.6 7.8 6.9 13.5 9.6 6.1 8.2 11.8 7.5 12.3 13.5 10.7 4.9 11.7 8.5 15.0 7.4 5.4 7.6 9.1 10.9 8.5 15.1 4.2 13.5 5.9 6.5 10.6 15.4 13.0 2.9 17.3 16.9 25.2 11.6 8.7 2.8 5.8 6.9 10.2 15.3 10.9 2.2 13.3 12.1 31.2 23.2 18.5 6.6 11.3 9.7 11.3 26.3 3.1 10.9 13.8 23.0 -t 20.3 16.5 5.2 9.8 7.8 12.0 32.7 19.6 5.8 2.5 13.4 23.7 19.2 8.9 7.4 13.7 9.5 15.1 9.1 8.5 4.1 11.4 8.9 11.8 13.2 7.9 3.0 12.0 10.1 14.7 32.7 17.8 9.3 12.1 17.0 -t 20.3 18.4 15.4 15.7 13.5 19.4 15.6% 13.8% 8.8% 10.8% 8.4% 11.2% 1950 10.7% 15.2 16.3 13.0 19.9 14.9 18.4 20.6 6.5 14.0 19.7 26.6 8.7 37.7 12.0 34.8 21.1 10.0 16.1 27.0 9.1 12.1 15.3 16.5 25.2 14.1% 1947 8.4% 9.0 10.6 8.8 13.4 14.4 19.8 15.4 10.3 11.5 22.3 -t 3.2 41.9 9.3 33.1 11.9 16.5 15.1 40.8 17.6 11.6 12.5 12.5 19.2 10.5% 1939 3.1% 5.2 4.5 1.9 9.6 3.5 10.7 3.1 0.5 6.8 2.6 N.O. 2.9 20.0 1.7 18.5 2.5 -t 7.4 3.4 1.5 4.8 13.0 N.O. 3.4 4.2% om pluy ted yxdciv id fohrceoam chpuC yefobregein acnhinogfN theetfis arusreenw dain yeaasresdin dicN aettedPrboyfitN oreth asorotfhth eu erneds ofrfoem a*cp hCio fis ca asrb ep tin fogrN 19e5t6P fororfit wshic toam tiopnan th Wcoarlthyefig sgusin edt).heB on seatnW dN tW fig agbeele .o(e *— *rt— AvreL rT a s c m p u t e d b y d iv id in g t o ta l N e t W o r t h in to to ta l N e t P r o fit s fo r e a c h y e a r fo r a ll C o m p a n ie s fo r w h ic h d a t a w e r e a v a ila b le . osos.tOperating. N.O.— N clu heres•hIonw n).desNetProfitsasarateofReturnonNetWorthforPortsmouth(acquiredin1949)for1947(alsofortheyears1946,1948,and1949not SOURCE.—Annual Reportsof theCompanies; Moody’sIndustrials. Calculations ours. 202 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT (25 Companies) was a phenomenal 13.8% with only 2 Companies earning a rate of less than 6% and 17 Companies earning more than 10%. The annual rate for 1956 is 15.6%, a record high, with no Company earning less than 6% and 23 of the Companies earning more than 10%. These data appear in TABLE 6. As the Return on Net Worth was skyrocketing, the Industry was able to increase very sharply its combined Net Worth from $3,025.7 million as of the end of 1939 to $7,390.4 million as of the end of 1955—an increase of 144.3%—almost entirely from undistributed Profits. These facts are shown in TABLE 7. Table 7 NET WORTH* (dollars in millions) Republic...................... Jones & Laughlin. . . . National....................... Youngstown S and T . Inland........................... Armco........................... Colorado F and I . . . . Wheeling...................... Sharon.......................... Kaiser........................... Crucible....................... McLouth..................... Pittsburgh................... Detroit *....................... Granite City............... Barium......................... Allegheny Ludlum — Northwestern S & W . Lukens......................... Alan Wood.................. Copperweld................. Lone Star.................... Laclede......................... Increase in 1955 over other yearsb................................... 1955 $2,582.6 1,186.1 606.1 420.7 397.9 362.9 332.3 386.7 115.0 180.9 68.1 105.7 98.0 62.2 86.1 57.7 68.2 22.8 90.8 20.9 29.2 30.7 30.2 26.9 21.7 $7,390.4 STEEL INDUSTRY (25 Companies) 1954 1953 1952 1951 1950 1947 1939 $2,348.7 $2,254.7 $2,136.1 $2,096.0 $2,015.2 $1,510.8 $1,314.8 1,079.9 1,008.7 919.6 873.6 811.6 565.4 473.9 537.8 470.1 440.7 421.6 392.0 293.1 239.1 383.5 372.4 354.9 348.1 305.5 228.2 164.7 372.1 363.2 330.0 314.6 291.1 199.8 131.2 332.8 306.7 293.9 273.3 325.0 183.2 144.1 287.3 249.8 232.7 223.6 206.4 151.3 101.4 339.7 279.7 313.6 295.4 228.0 162.6 127.1 107.4 103.0 83.7 74.2 67.9 50.6 19.0 156.7 153.1 146.7 141.8 130.8 101.8 82.0 62.9 59.4 47.1 62.5 60.2 30.0 15.6 103.9 95.0 87.8 44.7 100.3 17.1 N.O. 88.6 82.6 79.3 72.8 85.9 65.3 97.3 58.0 30.0 24.8 20.6 15.4 4.3 1.5 80.0 79.1 75.8 71.9 53.5 43.2 35.0 33.7 25.6 40.2 39.1 35.6 24.2 2.7 60.6 45.3 27.0 57.3 51.4 14.3 11.8 22.2 18.3 15.0 21.1 19.6 10.3 .4 80.1 75.4 73.2 60.7 79.6 39.7 27.1 17.1 16.1 13.1 10.0 14.9 4.9 2.9 27.2 26.3 24.2 23.2 20.9 15.9 6.8 29.6 28.0 24.5 23.2 25.8 17.2 14.5 18.4 23.7 24.2 22.8 17.0 12.0 6.9 18.2 9.7 1.6 22.2 22.7 20.6 N.O. 17.2 14.4 18.8 15.6 12.7 7.3 5.9 $6,681.0 $6,303.0 $5,890.8 $5,668.4 $5,177.1 $3,754.1 $3,025.7 10.6% 17.3% 25.5% 30.4% 42.8% 96.9% 144.3% *rT efig reosrctohv”erorSt“S octkoh old rse’rE uit yitin bufig sinuersesh aa ssob fetehn eu en ecalu chdfis arofo an hnerbeyth eeC oom pp aa nn ieiessh figu eh“N eN tuoW hoeld s’qE qu y”thtehis seddo,fin ingcatlhyeem strreeacceh ntC roem vispio nys.shW ow th C m .avelabeled N .O .— tN OepterW atoin gh . ofck • I n c lu d e s r t P o r t s m o u t h (a c q u ir e d in 1 9 4 9 ) fo r 1 9 4 7 (a ls o fo r t h e y e a r s 1 9 4 6 , 1 9 4 8 a n d 1 9 4 9 n o t h e r e s h o w n ). ais errisaonndw Liton wearffe eecxtcelu dh frtolym eela eanr.s’ figures,thepercentageincreaseswouldbeveryslightlyaffected. Onlytheper centabgeIfcK om pa he1S 9t3a9ris ddselig atshh retesrhoyw a SOURCE.—AnnualReportsoftheCompanies; Moody’sIndustrials. Calculations ours. 203 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 5—Sales and Distribution of the Sales Dollar (a) Sales Sales of the Industry (25 Companies) are cur rently at an all-time peak. The annual rate of Sales for 1956 are $14.6 billion, which is 12.2% higher than record 1955 Sales. It is interesting to note that not only are total Sales at a record high, but the Sales for every one of the individual 25 Companies, with one exception, are at an annual rate for 1956 which exceeds Sales in any prior year. In part, these record Sales reflect an in creased volume of production; although the in crease in production has not come close to match ing the increases in Sales. In modest part, for the Table 8 1956** 1955 U. S. Steel................. $4,402.0 $4,097.7 Bethlehem................. 2,400.0 2,096.6 Republic..................... 1,330.4 1,188.6 Jones & Laughlin— 781.2 696.5 National..................... 682.4 622.0 Youngstown S and T. 704.0 617.4 659.7 Inland......................... 761.6 692.7 Armco......................... 760.0 Colorado F and I . . . 257.5 325.0 Wheeling.................... 271.6 246.7 Sharon........................ 199.2 171.2 Kaiser........................ 146.4 136.1 Crucible..................... 277.2 237.7 McLouth.................... 162.4 145.0 Pittsburgh................. 176.7 199.6 101.8 Detroit11..................... 120.8 116.3 144.0 Granite City............. Barium....................... 108.8 75.1 Allegheny Ludlum... 299.2 255.2 Northwestern S & W. 86.4 51.4 82.4 Lukens....................... 94.0 58.4 Alan Wood................ 69.2 100.4 78.5 Copperweld............... 74.5 Lone Star.................. 86.8 Laclede....................... 63.6 58.2 TOTALS $14,576.2 $12,993.9 Increase in 1956 over other yearsb.......... 12.2% Increase in 1955 over other yearsb................................................. SALES* (dollars in millions) STEEL INDUSTRY (25 Companies) 1954 1953 1952 1951 1950 1947 1939 $3,250.4 $3,861.0 $3,137.4 $3,524.1 $2,956.4 $2,122.8 $ 846.0 1,656.8 2,082.0 1,691.7 1,793.1 1,439.8 1,032.3 414.1 918.4 1,052.7 881.8 846.3 1,137.1 230.3 645.3 492.9 624.4 495.4 564.3 487.5 350.1 113.6 484.1 634.2 548.6 618.5 537.0 131.1 329.0 483.7 404.0 428.2 548.1 434.2 306.2 117.0 533.1 575.6 518.7 459.3 458.0 115.3 315.0 532.0 588.9 518.6 534.8 439.3 311.7 94.9 250.2 248.8 195.8 191.4 112.6 22.1 94.7 187.6 217.4 178.3 227.1 184.8 85.7 131.7 98.2 167.2 131.3 169.0 135.4 17.8 93.9 128.5 134.5 117.9 100.5 84.5 33.8 NO. 160.6 232.3 180.3 202.9 147.7 110.2 48.0 96.4 59.1 79.2 78.9 57.8 18.0 N.A. 124.0 140.7 149.3 129.0 118.0 85.1 28.6 51.7 93.4 87.4 113.7 92.9 4.6 75.2 69.3 87.9 74.6 86.6 10.2 59.8 25.8 89.7 99.1 91.6 53.5 53.5 41.4 0.1 169.6 241.6 189.2 228.7 177.4 37.3 106.6 35.6 44.3 34.0 40.9 28.9 21.5 5.8 75.0 97.9 69.6 80.5 52.9 52.8 11.9 36.1 59.8 60.5 58.8 45.0 36.0 14.7 49.7 83.8 76.2 10.4 71.6 55.6 53.3 37.2 27.3 19.6 18.7 12.8 2.9 N.O. 45.4 50.8 47.5 47.7 39.6 8.6 26.3 $9,855.1 $12,165.1 $9,966.3 $11,053.3 $9,064.3 $6,421.6 $2,368.1 47.9% 31.8% 19.8% 6.8% 46.3% 30.4% 31.9% 17.6% 60.8% 43.4% 127.0% 102.3% 515.5% 448.7% *w T fig C y’sO fis seen arusrein eosm sh eeN tsSeadlein seexvceerpytcin in antch eesyww heerree th eleh re.en oturreespocrotveedrseeapcahra toem lypfraonm thcearlIynecaorm .din Tg heinlattheestyefig sdaicsarteevdis.edTbhyetfig heurC poaw nn iesarw reeu asaefe inww hsicth a veay ila b **Annual rateprojectedonastraight-linebasisfrom1st calendar quarter of 1956except for Lukens (12weeks ended3/24/56), North w steN rn (3 mon th N.O .Ae.— Av leg.s. ended4/30/56), Kaiser (6monthsended12/31/55) andColoradoFuel andIron (estimatedbyCompany). N N oosttS O plea esrila aotb in »bIIfn.— cK lu d e a f Portsdm oun th (acq uireredein 194e9d)fr for19th 47(atlseroyfo rr6 monthsin1946,andfor1948and1949nothereshown). en a thepercentaaisgeerc,oM mcpL aoru isth onsan witL ho1 9e3S 9ta arrewaeffe ctxecdlusdlig htlyom asheerla eshow .s’figures,thepercentageincreaseswouldbeveryslightlyaffected. Only SOURCE.—AnnualReportsoftheCompanies;Moody’sIndustrials. Calculationsours. 204 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT full period, they probably reflect a net weighted change in product mix. The most important fac tor which accounts for the increased Sales figures for most years, however, is the Industry’s policy of constantly increasing Steel Prices. The old principle of classical Economics that increased Sales volume, since it permits greater efficiency and the spreading of certain so-called fixed costs, permits lower prices and lower profit margins per unit of product apparently is not subscribed to by the Steel Industry. In fact, the reverse appears to be true. This is reflected in the constantly in creasing Prices and widening profit margins which are being earned by the Steel Industry. The Sales figures are shown in T A B L E 8. (b) Shares of the Sales Dollar Measurement of the shares of the Sales Dollar which are used for Payrolls, Materials Costs, De preciation, Profits, and other items sheds consid erable further light on this matter of profit mar gins. T A B L E 9 and C H ART 5 (also T A B L E 25) show Profits Before Taxes as a share of the Sales Dollar for most of the Industry (22 Companies, including U. S. Steel Corporation, 89.1% of the In dustry’s capacity). Table 9 PROFITS BEFORE T A X E S * AS A SH ARE OF THE SALES DOLLAR Steel Industry (21 Companies excluding U. S. Steel).................. U. S. Steel............................................ 1955 1954 1953 1952 1951 15.8* 11.6* 13.1* 9 .1 * 17.0* 16.8* 10.9* 6 .6 * 14.8 18.0 11.5 11.9 12.6 14.1 9 .2 9 .0 16.7 17.7 17.0 16.4 10.5 11.5 6 .8 6 .4 1950 1947 1939 * The same 22 Companies are used for all years shown. They are the only Companies of the 25 major Companies for which data are available for all years. SOURCE.—Based on Profits Before Taxes and Sales figures fromprior Tables. Calculations ours. It is clear from these figures that U. S. Steel is widening its profit margin at an even more in defensible rate than is the Industry as a whole— although neither has grounds for complaint about the level of its profit margins. The Industry widened its profit margin from 6.6^ out of each Sales Dollar in 1939 to a peak of 17.0^ in the Ko rean inflation of 1951. The 1955 Profits share of 15.8^ out of each dollar of Sales is well above the return for most other years, and 1956 is at a rate of 16.2^. Like the rest of the Industry, U. S. Steel reached a high point in 1951 but, in 1955, it was able to widen its profit margin to a record high of 18.0^ Profits on every dollar of Sales. In 1956 it is even higher— 19.2^. But most significant is the fact that Steel’s share of the Sales Dollar Before Taxes between 1947 and 1956 has risen from 10.9^ to 16.2^ while the share of All Manufacturing has fallen from 9.3^ to 8.6^. Much the same pattern is evident when Net Profits (After Taxes) are examined as a share of the Sales Dollar for the same 22 Companies. TA B L E 10 shows these figures. Table 10 N ET PROFITS* HARE OF THE SALES DOLLAR Steel Industry (22 Companies). . Steel Industry (21 Companies excluding U. S. Steel)................ U. S. Steel.......................................... 1955 1954 1953 1952 1951 1950 1947 1939 7 .9 * 6 .1 * 5 .6 * 4 .9 * 5 .7 * 8 .0 * 6 .2 * 5 .3 * 7 .4 9 .0 6 .0 6 .0 5 .5 5 .8 5 .0 4 .6 5 .9 5 .2 8 .3 7 .3 6 ,3 6 .0 5 .6 4 .9 * The same 22 Companies are used for all years shown. They are the only Companies of the 25 major Companies for which data are available for all years. SOURCE.—Based on Net Profits and Sales figures from prior Tables. Calculations ours. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 205 CHART 5 Profits,Before&AfterTaxes asSharesoftlteSalesDollar 20% * source : annual quarterly reports of 2 5 Steel Companies accounting for 913% of total sted capacity * * source «U. S. Department o f Commerce 206 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT As can be seen from TABLE 10, the Industry has managed to push its return per Sales Dollar to a peak level. The Net Profits in 1955, and so far in 1956, of 7.9^ on each dollar of Sales are higher than for any of the years shown (except for 1950 when the return was fractionally higher at 8.(ty). U. S. Steel did even better than the In dustry. It earned 9.(ty in 1955 on each Sales Dollar compared with 7.3^ in 1950. In 1956 U. S. Steel is earning an even higher rate of 9.5$>. These are higher profit margins achieved through increasing productivity and higher Prices at the expense of the buying public. It is likewise evi dent here as in Profits Before Taxes that Steel is out of step with the rest of the Economy. Between 1947 and 1956, a time when the Net Profit mar gin of All Manufacturing was declining from 5.7^ to 4.3^, the Steel Industry’s share was pushed up from 6.2^ to 7.9^. While it is evident that over the years Profits have taken a larger share of the Sales Dollar, the same is clearly not true of Wages and Salaries. As noted in TABLE 11, Wages and Salaries in clude, for some Companies, money spent on the worker’s behalf, as well as money paid to him in wages. TABLE 11 shows the relationship of Wages and Salaries to the Sales Dollar. Table 11 WAGES AND SALARIES* AS A SHARE OF THE SALES DOLLAR 1955 Steel Industry (10 Companies excluding U. S. Steel)............... U. S. Steel.................................... 1953 1954 1952 1951 1950 1947 1939 35.5* 38.7*1 36.4* 37.8*5 34.7*5 35.2*5 38.8*5 40.5*5 33.0 39.4 36.0 42.7 33.6 40.6 34.9 42.1 31.9 39.0 32.0 39.9 36.2 42.6 36.7 45.7 * The Wages and Salaries figures are Total Employment Costs including Pensions, Social Security Taxes, Insurance, etc. for 5 of the Companies; for 5 others they exclude such additional items; and for 1 Company they include these additions from 1946 on and exclude them for 1939. The same 11 Companies are used for all years. They are the only Companies of the 25 major Compan ies for which data are available for all years. SOURCE.—Annual Reports of the Companies; Moody’s Industrials. Calculations ours. In 1939, Wages and Salaries of 11 major Steel Companies accounted for 40.5^ out of each Sales Dollar. In subsequent years the wage earner’s portion of the Sales Dollar has grown smaller and smaller, reaching a low of 34.7^ in 1951. There after, it fluctuated upward in 1952 and 1954 par ticularly because of the work stoppage in 1952 and the recession in 1954. It then dropped sharply to 35.5^ out of each Sales Dollar in 1955.* For U. S. Steel the trend was almost identical with that of the Industry. It shows an elapsed decline from 45.7^ in 1939 to 39.4$* in 1955. Materials costs followed a slightly different trend from Wages and Salaries. This is shown in TABLE 12. * There are not sufficient data available to show the full Industry trend in 1956. The 11 Companies here in cluded account for 72.3% of the Industry’s capacity. Table 12 MATERIALS COSTS* AS A SHARE OF THE SALES DOLLAR 1955 1954 1953 1952 1951 1950 1947 1939 Steel Industry (9 Companies). . . . 40.1*5 Steel Industry (8 Companies excluding U. S. Steel)........................ 44.9 U.S. Steel........................................ ..... 33.1 39.7*5 43.0*5 47.Off 43.6*5 42.9£ 45.2*5 40.8*5 43.2 34.9 47.3 36.7 50.6 41.7 47.6 37.7 46.5 37.8 49.2 39.5 45.3 34.7 * The Materials Costs figures are Materials (or Products) and Services Purchased (or a comparable item similarly labeled.) Where no such figure was shown separately, an approximate one was derived by deducting Employment Costs (or W- ges and Sal aries) from Cost of Goods Sold (or a similar item). Materials Costs were specifically listed for 4 Companies for all years, for 2 Com panies for all years except 1939 (computed for that year). They were computed for all years for 3 Companies. The same 9 Com panies are used for all years. They are the only Companies of the 25 major Companies for which data are available for all years. SOURCE.—Annual Reports of Companies; Moody’s Industrials. Calculations ours. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Materials costs for 9 Companies accounted for 40.8^ of the Sales Dollar in 1939. By 1947 this figure had risen to 45.2^ as a direct result of the inflation which followed the weakening of price controls. Thereafter these costs fluctuated down ward until 1952. In that year Materials costs rose abruptly and reached a peak of 47.0^. Since then, they have dropped sharply reaching lows of 39.7^ in 1954 and 40.1^ in 1955.* For U. S. Steel the pattern was much the sam e with one important exception— the downward trend, and a sharp one, continued through 1955. In that year Materials costs accounted for 33.1^ out of each Sales Dollar. 207 This was the lowest level for any of the years shown. It is readily apparent from these data that over the years the two major cost items, W ages and Salaries and Materials costs, have moved down ward. Profits, not the consumers, have bene fited. This conclusion is even more strikingly il lustrated by examination of the complete break down of the U. S. Steel’s Sales Dollar. This is shown for the same years in TABLE 13. * There are not sufficient data available to show the full Industry trend in 1956. The 9 Companies here in cluded account for 70.4% of the Industry’s capacity. Table 13 DISTRIBUTION OF THE SALES DOLLAR (100?) IN U. S. STEEL CORP. Payroll Costs............................................ Materials Costs........................................ Subtotals....................................... Depreciation............................................. Profits Before Taxes.............................. All Other Item s....................................... Totals............................................. 1955 39.4^ 33.1 72.5 1954 42.7* 34.9 77.6 1953 40.6* 36.7 77.3 1952 42.1* 41.7 83.8 1951 39.0* 37.7 76.7 1950 39.9* 37.8 77.7 1947 1939 42.6* 45.7* 39.5 34.7 82.1 80.4 7.0 8.1 6.1 4 .9 3 .5 3 .7 18.0 11.9 14.1 9 .0 17.7 16.4 2.5 2.4 2 .5 2.3 2.1 2 .2 100.0* 100.0* 100.0* 100.0* 100.0* 100.0* 4 .1 7 .5 11.5 6.4 2.3 5.7 100.0* 100.0* SOURCE.—Annual Reportsof U.S. Steel Corp. Payrolls and Materials costs, combined ac counted for 72.5^ out of each Sales Dollar in 1955 (and almost exactly the same amount in 1956)— the lowest portion for any of the years shown. Comparison with 1947— a good postwar year, and a relatively recent one— shows a decline by 1955 of 9.6^ per dollar of Sales in these combined costs. This decline was used largely by the Corporation to increase Profits Before Taxes which accounted for 11.5^ of the Sales Dollar in 1947 and 18.0$ in 1955— a rise of 6.5^. The rest of the decline was taken up by Depreciation charges, a non-cash ex pense, which rose from 4.1*1 in 1947 to 7.0^ in 1955 — a rise of ‘5.9^. This rise in Depreciation charges results largely from extraordinary charges for Rapid Amortization of emergency facilities which was first permitted by the Government in 1950 but which did not begin to have a significant impact until 1952. Had such a charge not been permitted in 1955, Depreciation would have ac counted for only 3.4^ * of each Sales Dollar. * This amount may have been as much as 4.1<f depend ing on the precise fashion in which U. S. Steel treats the item which it labels Rapid Amortization charges. 208 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 6-~Ability of the Steel Industry to Absorb a Wage “Cost” Increase The relatively small share of total costs rep resented by wage “costs” and the great profita bility of the Steel Industry would permit the ab sorption of a substantial wage increase in 1956. For varying wage “cost” increases effective for a full year the impact on the 1956 annual rates of Profits and Profit ratios is shown in the follow ing tabulation: EFFECT OF A WAGE INCREASE ON STEEL PROFITS (Assuming No Increase in Productivity) (dollars in millions) Resulting Profits and Profit Ratios Wage “Cost” Increase Per Hour 30* 40* 50* Gross “Cost” $465.0 $620.0 $775.0 Net “Cost” $223.2 $297.6 $372.0 Profits Before Taxes $1,885.7 $1,730.7 $1,575.7 The above computations show that within the, framework of its 1956 operations the Steel Indus try could absorb for a full year a wage “cost” in crease of as much as 50^ per hour, forego a Price increase and still have: Profits Before Taxes on the same level as in 1953, a banner year, N et Profits higher than for any year prior to 1955, a record year, Return on N et W orth of 10.6% which is well above the fair and reasonable rate of 6%, and Return on Sales of 5.4* which still is well above Net Profits $930.2 $855.8 $781.4 Net Profits as a % of Net Worth 12.6% 11.6% 10.6% Net Profits as a Share of the Sales Dollar 6.4* 5.9* 5.4* the 4.3* earned by All Manufacturing Corpo rations in 1956. But these computations ignore one very im portant factor— increased productivity. Even if only a modest 4% increase in Steel productivity in 1956 is assumed, this would result in increased Sales revenues of $583.0 million with the same number of em ployees and manhours. W hen this factor is taken into consideration, the impact on 1956 Profits and Profit ratios of varying wage “cost” increases effective for a full year would be as follows: EFFECT OF A WAGE INCREASE ON STEEL PROFITS Wage “Cost” Increase Per Hour 30* 40* 50* (Assuming a 4% Increase in Productivity) (dollars in millions) Resulting Profits and Profit Ratios Gross Net Net Net Change in Change in Profits Net Profits Revenue Profits Profits Profits as a % as a Gross Gain from Before After Before Net of Net Share of the “Cost” Productivity * Taxes Taxes Taxes Profits Worth Sales Dollar $349.2 -$ 1 1 5 .8 $465.0 7.2* -$ 5 4 .7 $2,234.9 $1,098.7 14.9% 620.0 349.2 -2 7 0 .8 -1 3 0 .0 2,080.0 1,023.4 13.8% 6.8* 775.0 349.2 -4 2 5 .8 -2 0 4 .4 1,924.9 949.0 12.8% 6.3* * Computed on the basis of a 4% increase in Sales less additional Materials Costs based on a 40.1% ratio of Materials Costs to Sales. 209 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Return on Net Worth would be more than dou ble the standard 6% rate; The implications are clear. Even with a modest 4% productivity increase the Industry could ab sorb a labor “ cost” increase of as much as 301 or 40^ per hour for a full year and still have Profits in excess of any prior full year. In fact, a labor “cost” increase of as much as 50# per hour could be absorbed with these results: Profits Before Taxes would top any previous full year, except 1955; Net Profits would top any previous full year, ex cept 1955; Return on the Sales Dollar would be well above the 5.7^ earned by the Industry in 1947 and the 4.3^ earned by All Corporations in 1956. The cost; computations made above should be halved to measure their actual impact on 1956 operations, since the wage “cost” increase would be in effect for only 6 months in 1956. B. THE PRODUCTIVITY OF STEELWORKERS The amount of Steel produced by each Steel worker for each hour worked has multiplied by leaps and bounds in recent years. This increased productivity, both per hour worked and per man, has had the result of lowering sharply the unit labor costs of the Industry. This means signifi cant cost savings which can be shared with the employees and the public if the Industry is will ing. The facts on increased productivity are shown in T.VBLE 14 and CHART 6. Table 14 PRODUCTIVITY INDEXES IN STEEL (1947-1949=100) Output per Manhours Production Worker Manhour Production Workers Per Unit 116.6 111.4 139.4 132.3 132.7 126.8 71.8 75.6 75.4 78.8 93.9 96.5 109.6 114.0 95.3 97.8 109.7 115.2 104.4 106.9 93.4 91.8 105.2 106.6 101.4 101.5 NOT AVAILABLE** 108.6 110.6 94.8 90.0 82.9 75.1 110.9 121.7 119.0 117.1 113.4 99.9 100.8 99.3 114.0 117.0 116.0 111.5 110.8 101.6 99.4 99.2 90.2 82.2 84.0 85.4 88.2 100.1 99.2 100.7 87.8 85.5 86.2 89.6 90.3 98.4 100.6 100.8 87.9 77.3 71.2 86.3 81.4 78.6 113.7 129.3 140.5 115.8 122.8 127.3 Weighted Production Production Workers 1956* 1955 154.7 141.3 111.0 106.8 1954 1953 1952 1951 1950 1949 1948 1947 1946-1942 1941 1940 1939 107.0 133.4 113.4 128.5 118.4 93.2 106.0 100.7 95.5 73.3 59.0 Unit Labor Requirements Manhou Per Uni * Based on projections of preliminary 1st quarter data. ** Not available because certain wartime production and manhours figures cannot be segregated to exclude the portion devoted to munitions manufacture. SOURCE.—Bureau of Labor Statistics. A Preliminary Index as released to the Productivity Conference and to the Industry and Union in mid-1950 and since revised and improved and extended through 1954. The figures have been extended by the Union through the 1st quarter of 1956 by use of the BLS production weights and American Iron and Steel Institute production data. 210 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CHART 6 Productivity in steel (Outputpermanhour) 140 Index(1947-49=100) 130 Oufrutp irhou worksdbye ach Steelworl erisir creasi igata laccelsratingrate 120 110 100 90 Ija Ija IrA in *basedonprojectionof preliminaryfirstquarterdata SOURCE: BLSdata- apreliminaryindex IrA IrA lr m 1rr •rA 211 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT It is now commonly accepted that, over long periods, wage gains and rising living standards must come largely from increased productivity, i.e., rising output per manhour. With this con cept the Union has no quarrel as long as one prior condition is met—namely, that the income shares as between management and investors on the one hand and labor on the other at the beginning of any period of computation of productivity changes are fair and equitable. There is no such equi table sharing in the Steel Industry today. The In dustry has taken as its share in Profits far too much of what should have gone to the workers in the mills and to the public. In our opinion the Steel Industry owes its employees a substantial wage increase this year—even if no further in crease in productivity were in prospect. But this is somewhat academic because, as noted, there has been a large and consistent increase in pro ductivity. In the Steel Industry, productivity has shown a pronounced growth in the past several decades. In the period from 1919 to 1929 it nearly doubled, according to the Index maintained by the United States Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). In 1939 productivity in the Industry was more than one-third above this 1929 figure. Thus, it had risen by 167% in 20 years, or at a rate approxi mating 5% per year compounded annually over a period which included the Great Depression. When this Index is brought up to date, as is done in the Preliminary Index set forth in TABLE 14, it shows that the individual Steelworker has continued, in the period since 1939, to produce more and more Steel for every hour worked. In the 1st quarter of 1956 he was producing nearly 70% more Steel than he did in 1939. Thus, de spite the ups and downs in particular years, the Steelworkers’ average output per manhour rose at a rate of 3.2% compounded annually over this period of more than 16 years. The year-by-year changes are shown in TABLE 15. Table 15 PRODUCTIVITY CHANGES IN STEEL (year to year) Increase Over Prior Year in Output per 1956*.............. 1955............... 1954..................... 1953..................... 1952..................... 1951..................... 1950..................... 1949..................... 1948..................... 1947 (re 1941).... 1946-1942............ 1941..................... 1940..................... 19 3 9 ;;................. Decrease From Prior Year in Unit Labor Requirements Production Worker Manhour Production Workers Per Unit Manhours Per Unit 5.4% 19.3% 4.7% 11.2% - 5.0% -1 6 .2 % - 4.3% -1 0 .3 % + 9.7% + 2.7% - 8 .9 % - 2 . 6% 2.3% 0. 9% 1.6% 4. 0% 3.3% 0. 6% 13.5% 9. 1% - 0 .9 % 2. 2% 1.5% 0. 2% 13.0% 14. NOT AVAILABLE 13.7% 6. 8.6% 3. * Based on projections of preliminary 1st quarter data. SOURCE.—Computed from indexes in prior Table. - 2.1% - 1.6% - 3.2% -1 1 .9 % + 0.9% - 1.5% -1 1 .4 % -12.1% - 8.0% - 0.8% 0.8% 8.2% 2.2% 0.2% 3.8% -1 3 .0 % - 5.7% 212 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Most significant, however, is the sharp acceler ation in the productivity rate in the most recent years. It is running currently at an annual rate 4.7% higher than in banner 1955. In 1955 alone, it was 11.2% above 1954. And, even when the small decline of 1954 is offset, the 2-year average from 1953 to 1955 was 4.2% per year. The fact that productivity is growing at an ac celerating rate in Steel is significant in connection with the Industry’s demand for a 5-year contract providing annual wage increases of a lesser amount than have been negotiated in the past Since even the wage increases negotiated up to now have been less than warranted by produc tivity growth, it is clear that the Industry seeks to provide its workers with an even smaller por tion of their share of increased output per manhour for the next 5 years. Increases in productivity mean simply that unit labor requirements decline—that each ton of Steel is produced with less hours of labor. Even if the cost of each hour of labor is increased by wage rate increases proportionate to rising produc tivity, these increases can be absorbed out of the gains in productivity. These productivity increases bluntly mean that the “ real” earnings level of Steelworkers can rise significantly without increasing Steel costs or necessitating an increase in Steel Prices. Un fortunately the Steel Industry has been unwilling to set its Prices within the bounds of its costs but has, instead, insisted on raising its Prices to in crease profit margins. This not only has caused inflation. It is inflation. It is true that the Steelworkers’ standard of living has risen during the last few years. But the increases received—and more—could have been met from the gains in productivity. Un willing to accept this fact, however, the Industry has insisted on raising Prices—on receiving in creases which have, in the main, added unwar ranted increments to Profits. Surely Steelworkers have every right to a fair share in the productivity gains which they have helped to achieve. This would permit stock holders and Steel users also to share in these gains. This is the fair way to divide up these gains. The Union has not asked for more. The Union has asked, as a basic floor, that Steelwork ers’ “ real” wages increase as rapidly percentage wise as the “real” productivity increases in Steel. This, the Union has not been able to achieve. Consistently “real” productivity increases have outrun the increases in “ real” wages. This is evi dent in the following moderately long range com parison which covers most of the period since the Union was founded: Increase In “BealM Productivity in Steel 1939-1956 (more than 16 years) 68.8% Increase in “Real” Straight Time Average Hourly Earnings in Steel 47.1% Currently, in 1956, productivity is running 4.7% higher than in the record year, 1955. Steel workers, of course, have received no wage adjust ments in 1956. In the past, the Union has often been forced to demand wage increases which in dollars and cents amount have exceeded the percentage increase in productivity. This has been forced on the Union because of the Industry’s Price Policy which has caused inflation in Steel and has contributed greatly to it in the Economy and has, thereby, robbed the workers of the wages they were al ready receiving. They and their Union have been forced to pursue these rising prices—the cost of living—just to maintain their “real” wage posi tion, i.e., their existing standard of living. This purely defensive role of a significant portion of many of the Union’s wage proposals in recent years is generally unknown or overlooked. If management, including Steel management, would refrain from insisting on its all too frequent, unnecessary, and inordinately large Price in creases so that there could be price stability, there would be no need to catch up constantly with a rising cost of living, and increased money wages would then bring increased “ real” wages. It would then be possible for labor to improve its wages, “fringes” and working conditions more nearly within the framework of rising productivity. Un til management is willing to abandon its inflation ary pricing policy, certainly, the Union has no choice but to insist on money wage increases greater in amount than the percentage productiv ity increases—if it is even to hold its own, let alone make any gains in “ real” wages and in its stand ards of living. As a corollary to this productivity story in Steel, 213 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CHART 7 PruductioaShipments &EmploymentinSteel 150 Index(I947»IQ0)_________________________________________ -r ~ 140 Produclion— i>/ n // The substantial i iseinp oductii m and shipments si ice 194r has mt /> 130 to jxpand producl on wit hnoapi ireciabl IMAQA n omnlf i/mon+ 6 A i% nil ncmpnlynreflr /\ /A \ f \\ A 120 > 110 a \\ \1 M / -------------------------------------------^ ------------------------------------ beenrefle ctedin employi nentlmireased pr ductivi y has enabled meStei il Indus Ty -Shipm:nts* l l W P V V V 100 I \ / Product onft Maintenance employnent’ * 90 *50 1947 ‘48 49 '51 * sounCEtAmericanIronandSteelInstitute **SOURCEtBLS '52 '53 ‘54 *55 '56 214 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT it is appropriate to examine the effect of produc tivity growth on Employment. In the first quarter of 1956 Shipments of Fin ished Steel were at an annual rate almost 48% higher than in 1947, and Production of Steel ingots was over 50% higher than 1947. But this sub stantially greater output in the 1st quarter of 1956 was produced by a work force only 9.5% larger than in 1947. Last year, in 1955, Shipments were at a record annual high level—34.3% above 1947, and Ingot Production was 37.9% above 1947. Employment, however, was only 5.3% higher. Despite record Production and Shipments in 1955, there were less production and maintenance workers in the Basic Steel Industry in that year than in 1953 or in 1951 when Production and Shipments were at a lower level. The relationship between Produc tion, Shipments and Employment from 1947 to 1955 is shown in CHART 7 and TABLE 26. C. STEEL PRICE INCREASES For an extended period the Steel Industry has defended the Price increases it has levied by pub licizing these claims: 1. Steel wage increases have forced higher Steel Prices; 2. A Steel wage increase always results in higher Materials costs equal to the cost of the wage increase; and 3. Steel profit margins traditionally have been too low. In recent years the Steel Industry has placed increasing emphasis on an additional fourth claim (really 2 claims) for Jugher Steel Prices—the alleged inadequacy of the charges permitted for Depreciation by the Federal Income Tax Law, and the “ need” for larger Profits to finance the Indus try’s expansion of Steel capacity. Each of these claims is examined in this section. 1—Steel Wages in Relation to Steel Prices The Industry habitually refers to wage in creases it has negotiated as “ rounds” of increases but understandably is reticent about reviewing its Price increases. In the 10 years from 1946 through 1955, Steel workers negotiated wage increases in 8 years. In one year, 1949, there was no wage increase, but pension and insurance programs were negotiated. In 1951 there was no wage increase or other bene fits of any sort. In contrast, in the same 10-year period the Steel Industry generally raised its Prices as follows: “ General” Price Increases (on most products) .................................... Selected Price Increases (on some products) ................................... “Extras” (increases other than in 12 times 3 times base prices) ................................ 3 times Total “ Rounds” of Price In- -----------creases.............................. 18 times This means simply that the Industry has raised its Prices twice for each wage or “ fringe” increase negotiated with its employees. This is evident from the facts shown in TABLE 16. The Bureau of Labor Statistics’ Index of Whole sale Prices of Steel Mill Products shows a rise in Steel Prices (including “Extras” on some prod ucts) in more than 36 months during that 10-year period (TABLE 16). The total hourly cost of all the wage and “ fringe” settlements in that period was $1,318. These facts and the data on revenue gained from Price increases in the same period are shown in TABLE 17 and CHART 8. As indicated in TABLE 17, there were more than 1.3 billion manhours worked in 1955 by all employees in the Industry. Accordingly, the cur rent annual “ cost” of all of the wage and “fringe” benefits negotiated from 1S46 through 1955 (based on 1955 manhours) equals slightly less than $1.8 billion. The cumulative increase in the Price of Steel products from January, 1946, through December, 1955, has been $67.25 a ton. Finished Steel Ship ments in 1955 totaled 84.7 million tons. There fore, the current annual revenue gain (based on 215 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Table 16 Date of Steel Price Index fJan., 1946 Feb., 1946. . j^Mar., 1946 Date of Steel Wage Increase April, 1947.. . j Feb., 1947 U ept., 1947 fMar., 1948 July, 1948 I June, 1948 LSept., 1948 fFeb., 1949 Oct., Nov., I Oct., 1949 '49 (Pens. & Ins.). . . I Jan., 1950 I fNov., 1950 Dec., 1950. j Feb., 1951 July, 1952. . . (May, 1952 {Aug., 1952 June, 1953.. .{ ........... 1 May, 1953 [July, 1953 July, 1954. . . (June, 1954 {July, 1954 July, 1955. . . (June, 1955 {July, 1955 PRICE CHANGES IN STEEL BLS Wholesale Price Index Months When % Change Most of the From Last Prior Date Cumulative Increase Index to Date Occurred (1947-49 = 100) Shown 70.3 Feb., Mar. 76.1 8.3% Dec., ’46, Jan., ’47 (“extras”) Dec., '46, 85.7 12.6% Jan., ’47 July, Aug. 92.9 8.4% Jan., Feb., Mar. 97.1 4.5% May 95.3 -1 .9 % July, Aug. 108.1 13.4% Jan. 110.4 2.1% Apr., M ay 109.4 -0 .9 % Dec., '49, 114.5 4.7% Jan., 50 July, Oct. 115.7 1.0% Dec., ’50 Jan., ’51 124.7 7.8% 125.2 0.4% Nov., ’51 131.1 4.7% July, Aug. May '53 (“extras”) 134.4 2.5% May 142.7 6.2% June, July 141.9 -0 .6 % Sept. ’53 145.6 2.6% July Oct., '54 145.9 0.2% 155.0 6.2% July Jan., Feb., '56 (“extras”) Oct., ’55, Jan., Feb., May, '56 158.2 (Mar.) 2.1% Steel Magazine Price Composite Change from Last Prior Date to Price Date Shown Per Ton $ % $55.20 60.48 $5.28 9.6% 6.00(est.) 9.9% 64.30 3.82 6.3% 69.88 5.58 8.7% 5.4% 73.64 3.76 72.90 - 0 .7 4 —1.0% 82.28 9.38 12.9% 84.00 1.72 2.1% 82.64 - 1 .3 6 -1 .6 % 2.4% 84.60 1.96 85.48 .88 1.0% 93.14 93.14 98.24 7.66 0 5.10 9.0% 0 5.5% 5.00(est.)* .50 3.86 .22 2.40 .18 7.08 5.1% 0.5% 3.9% 0.2% 2.3% 0.2% 6.7% 98.74 102.60 102.82 105.22 105.40 112.48 1.90(est.)* 1.1% July, 1956. . . j June, 1956 114.02 1.54 1.4% (?) IJuly, 1956 (?) CUMULATIVE INCREASE— $71.72** 129.9% *’ 125.0% Jan., 1946-M ay (Mar.), 1956................................... * Iron Age 7/2/53 and Steel Magazine 5/21/56 respectively. The $1.90 is computed from a $2.75 increase from 11/14/55 to 5/21/56 less the intervening base Price increase of 85tf. ♦♦Including $12.90 in “extras”. SOURCE.—BLS Index of Wholesale Prices of Steel Mill Products; Steel Magazine's Finished Steel Weighted Price Composite. Calculations ours. 87624 0—57------15 216 Table 17 C O M P A R I S O N S OF R E V E N U E GAINS A N D L A B O R COST INCREASES D U R I N G T H E L A S T 10 Y E A R S $5.93 8.91 12.24 1.56 7.11 2.20 5.08 4.57 2.60 7.78 $289 ,238,905 561 ,839,207 807 ,511,209 90 ,642,256 513 ,571,596 173 ,643,690 345 ,458,349 366 ,294,151 164 ,197,088 659 ,101,714 18.5* 15.0* 13.0* 12.5* 16.0* 0* 21.1* 8.5* 12.0* 15.2* 1,010,171,703 1,167,582,947 1,219,563,700 1,073,204,921 1,214,394,580 1,344,670,029 1,189,893,622 1,344,116,422 1,117,109,108 1,285,299,398 (100%) 1,079,935,538 $199,788,075 188,157,974 1,254,386,492 170,348,427 1,310,372,515 143,307,996 1,146,463,968 208,479,756 1,302,998,476 0 1,412,913,763 1,250,807,970 263,920,482 119,725,883 1,411,442,215 140,752,932 1,172,941,104 205,647,904 1,352,946,734 $1.45 2.99 4.74 0.63 2.46 $1,783,183,795 $3.19 i ’ 3i 3.06 1.17 3.21 Dec. 1945 to Dec. 1955......... THE CUMULATIVE INCREASE— IN BASE PRICES— $57.982 (INCLUDING SOME “EXTRAS”)— $67.254 Revenue and Labor Cost Impact for the 10-year period (based on 1955 operations)......... $5,697,248,109 $1,318 1American Iron and Steel Institute. * Derived from Steel Magazine’s Finished Steel Weighted Price Composite as of December, converted to dollars per ton. The Price Increase figures do not indude “extras.” * American Iron and Steel Institute data including Salaried hours for 93-95% of the Industry. Adjusted to 100% as indicated from the AISI reports. 4Between Dec. 1945 and Dec. 1955 “extras” have been raised generally on two occasions. The impact of these “extras” increases appears to have been at least $9.27 per ton in addition to the $57.98 shown by the Steel Magazine Index. This brings the total increase to $67.25. This difference was estimated for this purpose by using the difference between the increase (121.9% ) in the BLS Steel Mill Products Index (which includes some “extras” ) and the increase (105.1% ) in the Steel Magazine Index (which includes no “extras”). SOURCE.—The sources are indicated. Calculations ours. P R E S ID E N T C U M U L A T I V E INC R EA S ES — Dec. 1945 to Dec. 1955......... OF 48,775,532 63,057,150 65,973,138 58,104,010 72,232,292 78,928,950 68,003,612 80,151,893 63,152,726 84,717,444 $55.20 61.13 70.04 82.28 83.84 90.95 93.15 98.23 102.80 105.40 113.18 Increased Labor Cost (all empls.) $ Increase in Steel Prices Per $ Increase in Labor Costs REPORT 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 Adjusted Total Hours Worked * ECONOMIC Finished Steel Weighted Price Price Revenue Gain Hourly Cost of Wage & Finished Steel Composite2 Increase * from Total Hours Shipments1 ($ per ton in ($ per ton Price Increase “Fringe” Settlement (tons) Dec.) Dec. to Dec.) (per year) Worked8 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 217 CHART 8 Revenue GainedfromSteel Price Increases Cumulativetotal vs. Labor "Cost" Increases impactin1955 millions Ofdollars 1946 47 48 *50 '51 52 * AmericanIron&Steel InstituteandSteelMagazine **AmericanIrontSteel InetituteData '53 '54 '55 218 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 1955 Shipments) from Steel Price increases since early 1946 is $5.7 billion, or $3.9 billion more than increased labor costs (TABLE 17). In short, since 1945, Steel Prices were increased by $3.19 for each $1.00 increase in total labor costs —a ratio of more than 3 to 1. This is also evi dent in CHART 9 and TABLE 27 where labor costs measured from 1947 show an increase of 28.0% vs. a Price increase of 78.2% through March 1956— a 77.7 % average for the 1st quarter. 2—Steel Materials Costs in Relation to Steel Prices raised by 78.2%. Again Steel Prices have ex ceeded cost increases by a ratio of nearly 3 to 1. An additional indication of the far more rapid rise of Steel Prices than of Steel’s Materials costs since 1947 is the relationship of payments for Ma terials to the receipts from Sales. In 1947 Mate rials costs represented 45.2^ out of each Sales Dol lar, but by 1955 they had declined to 40.1^.* U. S. Steel’s Materials costs were 39.5$* of each Sales Dollar in 1947, but only 33.1^ in 1955. All available data establish not only that Steel Prices have risen far more rapidly than the Indus try’s Materials costs, but also that there is no validity to the claim that increased labor costs somehow have a one-to-one relationship with in creases in Materials costs. The Industry’s leading producer, United States Steel, demolished the Industry’s own contention with a Table contained in the Corporation’s 1952 Annual Report. It showed that the rise in aver age hourly employment costs had no fixed rela tionship to the rise in the average cost in Steel operations of purchased products and services (Materials) per ton of Steel Shipments. These comparisons from the Corporation’s own 1952 Annual Report are shown in TABLE 18. The cost of the Materials purchased by the Steel Industry has risen somewhat in the postwar pe riod. But this rise has been moderate in relation to the rise in the Price of Steel products sold by the Industry. The base period of the BLS Wholesale Price Indexes is 1947-49. From the base period to March, 1956 the Price of Steel Mill Products sold by the Industry has risen by 58.2%. This is equal to 78.2% on a 1947 basis. This is far in excess of the price rise of the most important products purchased by the Steel Indus try. Examples of the price increases of such prod ucts since 1947-49 include Scrap—22.3%, Bitu minous Coal—7.0%, Petroleum and Products— 16.8%, Gas—22.0%, Tin (pig)— 10.4%, Oxygen— 5.3%, Cement—38.5%, Sand, Gravel and Crushed Stone— 22.4%, Electricity— a decline of 5.7%, Ma terial Handling Equipment— 48.1%— all of which have risen far less than Steel Prices. The Annual Reports of the larger Steel Com panies do not break out separately their Materials costs relating solely to Steel production. Accord ingly, a precise estimate of such costs cannot be made. However, in t e s t i m o n y before the T.N.E.C., a United States Steel spokesman re ferred to the BLS Price Index of “All Commodi ties Other Than Farm and Food Products” (whfch the President’s Council of Economic Advisors refers to as “industrial prices” ) as a close indi cator of the movement of prices of the Materials purchased by the Corporation. That Index, from the year 1947 through the 1st quarter of 1956, rose by 26.7% (it was 27.6% by April). These figures are shown in CHART 9 and TABLE 27. The continued validity of that Index in relation to United States Steel’s purchases is indicated by the fact that, from 1947 to 1955, U. S. Steel’s total Materials costs (all materials) per ton of Steel products shipped increased by an almost identical amount—27.9%. Thus, while Materials costs have risen about 28.0% since the year 1947, Steel Prices have been * Based on the 9 of the 25 leading Companies for which Sales, Materials, and Wages and Salaries data are avail able for all years since 1939. Table 18 COMPARATIVE CHANGES IN MATERIALS AND EMPLOYMENT COSTS IN U. S. STEEL CORP. Increase as Percent of 1940 Period Covered Employment Cost of Cost Materials January, 1941-April, 1947............... 56% 47% April, 1947-July, 1948................... 16 42 July, 1948-November, 1949........... 14 18 November, 1949-December, 1950 19 3 December, 1950-July, 1952........... 23 24 July, 1952-December, 1952........... 27 4 219 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CH ART 9 Prices inSteel v&Material Labor Costs 2oo Index (1947=100) Therii lelprio is sine i 19471ias dwarfi d theri seintfi s2maj ir Steel costiti !ms>maFerials i ndlabor-byalr tost 31ll 175 i holesale rices oft rial steel nillprodu! t S ^ / 150 ( V 125 / > f ... Wholesale prices iifallcooii loditieS' otherthi nfarm & foodprodi icts** f 100 labor cost per uni tofprodui ffion** / N -S . . . tin lifl * SOURCE: BLSdote ** SOURCE: BLS •fa If A 1ra Of M iff If A 220 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Prior to the Corporation’s publication of its 1952 Annual Report, the Industry was involved in a public controversy on this matter. In 1952 the Industry sought a Price increase which, at that time, required approval of the Office of Price Sta bilization. The Steel Companies wanted a Price increase sufficient to cover an increased wage cost plus a mark-up to cover an “ anticipated” rise in Materials costs. The director of the Office of Price Stabilization, Mr. Ellis Arnall, testified on this matter before a Senate Committee. After noting that, although the Industry agreed that in creased labor costs would be less than $6 a ton, it demanded a price increase of $12 a ton, Mr. Arnall said in part: . . They justify this position by asserting that historically every increase in employment costs has been paralleled by an approximately equal increase in the cost of purchased goods and services. . . The fallacy of the Steel Industry’s po sition may be further demonstrated by looking at the record of the past few years. In the mid dle of 1948 there was a substantial wage in crease which raised employment costs per ton between $3 and $4. Material costs per ton, however, remained steady throughout the entire pe riod from the beginning of 1948 until the Korean outbreak. “ Similarly, the last general increase in steel wages occurred in December, 1950. This in- 3—Steel Profits in Relation to Price Increases The Industry is not quite fair in using Net Prof its as a measure of its profit margin in a labor cost dispute, since wage increases are paid out of Prof its Before Taxes, but the facts on Net Profits only have been analyzed here, in order to meet the In dustry’s argument directly on the Industry’s chosen ground. The Net Profits of the Steel Industry (25 Com panies) amounted to $126.4 million in 1939. The rate of Return on Net worth was 4.2%, a rela tively modest return. By 1947 Net Profits more than tripled to $394.3 million, which was equiva lent to a 10.5% Return on a 24% larger Net Worth—which is certainly a substantial Return. Since 1947, despite an ever-larger demand for Steel, and a tremendously expanded capacity which enabled the Industry to meet this demand, the Steel Industry has persisted in a policy de signed to widen already huge profit margins. crease raised employment costs per ton by about $3.80 on the average. At the same time, steel prices were raised by an amount in excess of $8 per ton. Yet, our figures indicate that since De cember, 1950 there has been virtually no net change in the cost of purchased services and materials for the steel industry. Actually, the cost of the most important single item purchased by the steel industry—steel scrap—was reduced . . . and is now lower than it was in December, 1950. “It is true that in the past the steel industry has often followed the practice, when granting wage increases, of raising its prices by a sub stantially greater amount than the increase in labor costs. The effects of this policy are clearly reflected in the steady increase in its profits per ton from a level of $9 in 1947 to an average of more than $20 in 1951. . . These are the words of an United States Gov ernment official who was in charge of the govern mental agency seeking to hold back the forces of inflation in time of war. It is apparent that the “ formula” by which the Industry has attempted to justify Steel Price in creases over a series of years—i.e., that the min imum amount by which Steel Prices must rise is double the cost of a wage increase (with no allow ance for increased productivity) in order to offset future increased Materials costs—is a “ formula” unrelated to reality. Thus, between 1947 and 1955 the Industry ex panded its Net Profits from $394.3 million to more than a billion dollars ($1,019.4 million). Its rate of Return on Net Worth climbed from 10.5% in 1947 to 13.8% in 1955. In the 1st quarter of 1956 Net Profits increased further to an annual rate of $1,153.4 million, and its rate of Return on Net Worth to 15.6%. Increased Net Profits were achieved not only as a result of increased Sales, but by virtue of increased Profits per Dollar of Sales. Net Profits of 22 of the largest Steel Com panies were equal to 6.2^ per Dollar of Sales in 1947 and 7.9?! in 1955. For U. S. Steel it was 6.0^ in 1947, 9.0^ in 1955, and 9.5^ in the 1st quarter of 1956. In this same period between 1947 and 1955 when the rate of Return on Net Worth in Steel increased from 10.5% to 13.8% (and to 15.6% in the 1st quarter of 1956), Net Profits in relation to Net ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Worth declined in All Manufacturing Industries from 15.1% in 1947 to 12.3% in 1955,* Net Prof its per Dollar of Sales which were 5.7^ in 1947 in All Manufacturing Corporations, declined to 4.1^ in 1955 and to 4.3^ in the 1st quarter of 1956.** * F.T.C.-S.E.C. Quarterly Industrial Financial Report Series for All Manufacturing Corporations. Data for 1st quarter 1956 were not available. ** U. S. Department of Commerce. 4—Replacement and Expansion Needs as a Basis for Price Increases For the past few years, and especially in recent months, the Industry has rested its case for even higher Prices and greater Profits on a new theory. Steel Industry spokesmen are attempting to “ sell” the proposition that (1) the Administration’s re fusal to revise the tax laws pertaining to Depreci ation along the lines desired by the Steel Compa 221 Since Net Profits in Steel have climbed by 706.5% from 1939 to 1955 (812.5% to 1956), by 158.5% from 1947 to 1955, and the rate of Return on Net Worth, as well as Net Profits per Dollar of Sales, has passed the average of All Manufac turing Industries, the Steel Industry understand ably has reached for a new rationale for further Price increases. nies requires the Industry to raise its Prices again in order to have sufficient funds to maintain and replace its properties, and (2) Steel Prices must be higher so that Profits will be great enough to pay for the cost of expanding the Industry’s ca pacity. The Industry has already applied this theory in some of the large Steel expansion of recent years. That expansion is shown in TABLE 19. Table 19 STEEL INGOT CAPACITY ON JANUARY 1st (millions of tons) 1956.......................................................... 1955......................................................... 1954......................................................... 1953......................................................... 1952......................................................... 1951......................................................... 1950......................................................... 1949 ......................................................... 1948 128.4 125.8 124.3 117.5 108.6 104.2 100.0* 96.1 94.2 * Average capacity as of January 1st and July 1st. 1947......................................................... 1 9 4 6 ...................................................... 1945 ......................................................... 1944 ......................................................... 1943 ......................................................... 1942 ......................................................... 1941......................................................... 1940 ......................................................... 1939 ......................................................... 91.2 91.9 95.5 93.9* 90.6 88.9* 85.2* 81.6 81.8 SOURCE.—AmericanIronandSteel Institute. This position of the Steel Industry on securing funds for maintaining facilities and for further ca pacity expansion—a position based on the Govern ment’s refusal to provide further special Deprecia tion allowances for the Industry—is an insistence that the public accept as a fair and equitable solu tion the proposition that the American consumers foot the bill in the form of higher Steel Prices. In addition, the American people are being told by the Steel Companies that a further boost in Steel Prices will be levied in order to pay for new Steel plants! Steel Companies’ stockholders, under this 222 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT plan, are to receive a gift—new Steel plants and enlarged facilities which will increase their equity in their Company, and, eventually, increase their Dividends—all at the expense of American con sumers who will pay the costs by paying higher Prices for Steel products. Gone, apparently, is the concept of “risk” capital, of financing indus trial expansion through flotation of stock or by means of borrowing on bond issues. Instead, the Steel Industry argues its right to collect “risk less” capital from unwilling consumers by forcing upon them higher Prices. Lip service is given to the desirability of en couraging greater participation by the public in the ownership of the Industry. But the Steel In dustry’s actions have no such effect. The Amer ican people are to be given no opportunity to share in the Steel Industry’s growth and prosperity. Raising funds for expansion through the sale of Common Stock to the public is rejected by the Steel Companies. The public is called upon to pro vide the funds, but it is shut out of participation in the Profits to be realized from the use of these funds. As for the allied contention that higher Steel Prices were required to pay for the cost merely of maintaining the Steel Companies’ existing prop erties (Depreciation), here again the Steel Com panies’ own financial reports demonstrate the falsity of the claim. For example, from 1952 through most of 1955, prices in general, except for Steel Prices, were relatively stable— i.e., the cost of maintaining Steel facilities, replacing outworn and obsolete equip ment, etc., was not appreciably different in 1953, 1954 and 1955. The financial reports of the Steel Companies to the Securities and Exchange Com mission for the last 3 years demonstrate con clusively that additional revenue in the form of higher Steel Prices was not required to enable the Industry to replace obsolete facilities. The higher Prices charged in these three years, and the resulting increase in Profits, were forced con sumer investments (without benefit of stock cer tificates) in the expansion of steel-making ca pacity, and were not necessary simply to replace and maintain existing facilities. This is shown in TABLE 20. Table 20 MONEY AVAILABLE 1953-55 FOR STEEL REPLACEMENT AND EXPANSION OF FACILITIES Totals for 1953,1954 and 1955 (millions) Reported Net Profits After Taxes..... $2,945 Charges for Depreciation................... -(-2,304 Cash available from operating Profits for Dividends, Replacement and Expansion of Facilities................... $5,249 Paid out in Dividends........................ —1,282 Cash available from operating Profits for Replacement and Expansion of Facilities......................................... =$3,967. Increase in long-term debt from end of 1952 to end of 1955.................... +167 Total Cash available for Replace ment and Expansion of Facilities... =$4,134 Thus, in the 3 years from 1953 through 1955 the Steel Industry had $4.1 billion available for reinvestment in the Industry, of which only about 4% represented borrowed “ outside” capital. In those 3 years the Industry accomplished the fol lowing: 1. Replaced obsolete capacity. 2. Expanded capacity by 10,815,620 ingot tons.* 3. Increased Dividends to stockholders by more than 30% (from $384 million in 1953 to $501 million in 1955). 4. Increased Working Capital by $1.5 billion. The fact that all of the foregoing purposes were accomplished by the Industry without floating stock or borrowing more than a negligible amount of capital effectively disposes of the assertion that even higher Steel Prices are now required in or der to yield sufficient funds for replacement. In stead of preparing for higher Prices the Steel Industry should be considering the extent of Steel Price reductions which it can and should put into effect. * An annual rate of expansion greater than is projected by the Steel Industry for the next 5 years. 223 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT D. THE INDUSTRY'S POSITION The position of the steel companies in the cur rent crisis is plain and unequivocal. They say flatly, as they did in making their offer of June 13, that “ no increase in employment costs at this time would be in the nation’s best interests . . .” because any such increase would set off “ another ruinous round of inflation.” It is plainly not true that increases in employ ment costs in steel would set off another round of inflation. Inflation is an increase in prices— and it is the companies’ price policies which have an inflationary effect, not its wage policies. As has been shown above, the steel industry—unlike almost every other American industry—has re fused to absorb wage increases in the past and has, instead, passed on to the consumer three times the cost of each wage increase. The steel industry—unlike almost every other American industry—has increased its profit on each dollar of sales, instead of lowering it, as volume in creased. The steel industry—unlike almost every other American industry—has refused to recog nize that wages should increase without a price increase when workers produce more steel for each hour they work. The steel industry, in short, can afford a sub stantial increase in employment costs without increasing prices, and without setting off any inflationary effect whatsoever. The steel companies, however, assumed in their proposals to the union that every wage increase must be accompanied by a price increase. On this false basis they did, on June 13, offer some increase in wages and some improvement in fringe benefits, but only on condition that the union agree to a “5-year non-reopenable” agreement. There has been much misinformation about this offer. The precise facts as to the nature of the offer were set forth in a letter by President McDonald to the membership of the Steelworkers Union. It is reproduced in part below: June 18, 1956 TO THE OFFICERS AND MEMBERS OF ALL LOCAL UNIONS OF THE UNITED STEELWORKERS OF AMERICA Dear Sir and Brother: I am writing this letter to each local union so that our members can have the facts— the straight facts—rather than industry propaganda—about the current situation in our bargaining with the basic steel industry. On June 13 the representatives of the industry made us a “ take-it-or-leave-it” offer. In making this offer the representatives of the industry stated quite clearly that, although we could bargain about details and the allocation of the costs of the fringe benefits, the total “ package” was a fixed “package” . They also said that the only basis upon which they would conclude an agreement with us was a fixed contract, without reopeners or room for later negotiations on any subject, for a 5-year term. • * * • * The industry has advertised far and wide that the “package” which they have offered us costs 17%* in the first year of the contract and, over the 5-year term, would cost 65* an hour. I want to label these industry figures as propaganda rather than fact: the industry has not offered us either 17%* this year or 65* for 5 years. This is what they have offered, in their own words: Effective Date Improvement July 1, 1956 Advance all job class 1 employees to job class 2 and combine the two classes. July 1, 1956 Increase all standard hourly wage rates by 6 cents and increase increments between job classes above job class 2 by .2 cent. 224 July 1, 1956 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Establish Supplemental Unemployment Benefits Plan in form attached, with company contributions of 5 cents per hour. November 1, 1956 Establish improved insurance program in accordance with insurance pro posal attached. July 1, 1957 Increase all standard hourly wage rates by 6 cents and increase increments between job classes above job class 2 by .2 cent. July 1, 1957 Add a seventh paid holiday. November 1, 1957 Increase pension benefits in accordance with pension proposal attached. January 1, 1958 Increase vacation pay of employees with 3 to 5 years of service to iy 2 weeks and increase vacation pay of employees with 10 to 15 years of serv ice to 2y2 weeks. July 1, 1958 Increase all standard hourly wage rates by 6 cents and increase incre ments between job classes above job class 2 by .2 cent. July 1, 1958 Increase shift premiums to 7 cents for afternoon shift and 10 cents for night shift. July 1, 1959 Increase all standard hourly wage rates by 6 cents and increase incre ments between job classes above job class 2 by .2 cent. July 1, 1959 Establish new premium for Sunday shifts equal to night shift premium. July 1, 1959 Grant jury pay. July 1, 1960 Increase all standard hourly wage rates by 6 cents and increase increments between job classes above job class 2 by .2 cent. July 1, 1960 Increase shift premiums to 8 cents for afternoon shift and 12 cents for night shift. July 1, 1960 Apply new night shift premium to Sunday shifts. The above does not tell the whole story. The actual increase for take home pay in the first year under this package would be less than 51 an hour. A steel worker in job class 8 (the average job class) would receive a wage increase of 6$f plus an increment increase of 1.2^, or a total of 7.2^. From this average wage increase would have to be subtracted 1.5^ which the companies insist must be added to the employee contributions under the insurance program. Therefore, the net increase for job class 8 would be 5.7^. When taxes are sub tracted from this net increase, the total in take home pay is less than 5^ per hour. The companies’ package includes a similar increase in each of the 4 years after this year. In addition, it provides for certain fringe benefits. I think you are entitled to know precisely what these other benefits are: 1. Supplemental Unemployment Benefits. Under the plan offered by the industry prac tically no benefits would be paid to any of our members. This is because the industry has invented a new gimmick in S.U.B. plans. Under other plans that have so far been nego tiated, such as our can plan, the total unemployment benefit (including state unemploy ment compensation) is 65% of 40 hours take-home pay. The steel companies propose that the total benefit should be 65% of take home pay for the hours actually worked in the 3month period immediately before the layoff. Since, in most cases, our members work a short week (often down to 32 hours) in the period before they are laid off, this would mean that in many cases the total benefit (including the state unemployment compensation) would be 65% of the take-home pay for 32 hours of work. In almost every state in which we have any number of members, this total benefit would hardly be larger than the state unemployment ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 225 benefit. Therefore, under the plan offered by the industry—unlike any other S.U.B. plan— virtually no benefits would be paid out of the fund. In addition, the companies refused to make adequate provisions by which our members in Ohio, Indiana and Virginia would be guaranteed benefits if the authorities in these states persist in their rulings that supplementation of state benefits is not permissible. Under the plan offered by the companies no benefits would be paid out of the fund in any state in which supplementation or the payment of substitute benefits is not permitted by state law. 2. Insurance. The industry offered us an improved insurance program. The actual cost of the new benefits which they offered us is $2.25 per employee per month. But they insist, as a condition of this improvement, that the average employee contribution be increased by $2.55 per month. They did agree to increase the company contributions, also by $2.55 per month, but all of their money would be retained as reserves. S. Holidays. The companies offered a 7th paid holiday, but not until the day before Christ mas in 1957. They refused even to consider our proposal that premium pay be paid, in ad dition to the holiday pay, for hours worked on the holiday. 4. Pensions. The companies offered to increase minimum pension benefits to $2.50 a month for each year of service, but they offered to make this effective only with respect to years actually worked after 1957. This means that it would be 1987 before an employee could retire with 30 years of service at $2.50 per month—the pension benefit we negotiated with the can industry last year. In can, a worker retiring today with 30 years of service, or more, receives a pension of $2.50 per month for each year of past service. For service up to November, 1957, the steel companies offered an increase in the minimum pension from the present $1.83 a month per year of service to $2.00 a month per year of service, effective next year. But even this small increase would not be given to present pen sioners. In the can industry we not only negotiated a $2.50 a month pension, effective last year, but the companies agreed to apply it retroactively for all present pensioners. 5. Vacations. The industry offered, effective 1958, to increase the vacations of em ployees with 3 and 4 years, and with 10-14 years of service, by one-half week. They coupled this offer with a new method of computing vacation pay on the basis of a percentage of the average of the previous year’s earnings. And they also required, as a price for this bene fit, that the companies be given the unilateral right to require employees to forego their va cations and take vacation pay instead. 6. Shift differentials. The companies offered to increase shift differentials by 1# per hour for the second and third shifts in 1958 and again to increase the differential by 11 for the second shift and 2$ for the third shift in 1960. 7. Sunday premium pay. In answer to our request for double time for Sunday work and time and one-half for Saturday, the companies offered to pay the night shift premium for Sunday work—that is, they offered a premium of 10^ per hour effective 1959, and a 12^ per hour premium effective 1960. Even this offer was carefully restricted. First, the com panies stipulated that not even this night shift premium would be paid for hours worked on Sunday if they were overtime hours. And to make sure that this restriction would apply wherever possible, they propose to change the regular work week, which now begins on Sun day, to a week beginning on Monday, so that Sunday instead of Saturday would be the 7th day. 8. Jury pay. The final fringe benefit offered by the companies was jury pay, and this not to be effective until July 1959. What is this whole “package” worth to the Steelworkers? Our Research Department has computed the value of each of these items, and, giving the companies the benefit of every doubt, estimates that ultimately the value of these benefits, when they all finally go into effect in 1961, would be 45.3 cents per hour. This includes not only the companies' 226 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT payments into the S. U. B. fund, which will average about 31 per hour, but also the com panies’ payments into the insurance fund of 1.5^ per hour—neither of which, as presently proposed by the companies, will provide any real benefits to the Steelworkers. But, even counting these in, while the “package” at the end of five years will be 45.3^, the average benefit over the 5-year term of 1956-1961 amounts only to 28.5^ per hour. The reason for this is simply that we will not get many of these benefits for several years. What this actually means is that the industry has offered a package worth, on the aver age, for the 5 years, a total of 28.5^ per hour. In return they insist that we execute a firm 5-year contract, forbidding us to negotiate on anything until 1961. We would have to give up, for 5 years, every one of the changes which we have asked be made in our contracts to bring them up to date. At the same time, the companies insist, as part of their offer, that if the government should impose controls at any time during the 5-year term, they would have the right to re-open and cancel all of the future benefits. In addition, the companies insist on an additional penalty clause, under which every worker who, during the 5 years, participates in a work stoppage or any interference with production, would lose, in addition to his wages, one day’s vacation and one week’s S. U. B. benefits for every day’s work lost. The industry’s 28.5^ package for 5 years is not a fair offer. This is a year of record prosperity. Despite this, the industry is offering us, for this year and each of the four following years, much less than we have received on the average during the past 10 years. The International Wage Policy Committee, in rejecting this offer, said that it was “too little, too late and too long.” In the words of the Wage Policy Committee: “The wage offer is too little and would result in a take-home pay increase to the average steel worker this year of about a nickel an hour—about 2%. This trifling 2% increase would be the steelworkers’ reward for increasing their pro ductivity by a record-breaking 11% last year.” In rejecting the industry’s offer, the Policy Committee reaffirmed the Union’s desire to achieve a fair and reasonable settlement. It said: “ Insofar as the union is concerned, the union’s negotiators, without stipulating any prior conditions, are ready to meet both day and night, with the industry rep resentatives for the purpose of hammering out a decent settlement. “ We call upon the leaders of the steel industry to meet with the union in the same spirit and without attaching conditions which roadblock ‘give-and-take’ bargaining.” I am confident that our membership will support this unanimous action of the Wage Policy Committee. Sincerely yours, [Since this letter was written, the Industry’s position has remained the same. On June 27, the companies did make one additional offer—but this involved a decrease in the benefits proposed rather than an increase. What the companies proposed, in their terms, was that the Union not strike—i.e. that the employees continue to work beyond June 30 without a contract. If the Union agreed, the companies said that they would be agreeable to reducing the term of the new contract to 4 years, 4 months—but with a proportionate reduction in benefits. The actual ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT reduction in benefits proposed would have amounted to more than 7% each year of the proposed 4 year, 4 month agreement. This was not a new offer intended to provide a possible basis for agreement. It was a step backward in tended only to fortify the “ take-it-or-leave-it” character of the industry’s first order.] The Steel Industry’s proposed wage increase is substantially below the rate of rising productivity in recent years. The change in productivity is likely to accelerate rather than slow down. Fur ther, the wage offer is deficient in denying the Steelworkers an opportunity to share reasonably in the Industry’s present phenomenal Profits. Since the Companies’ offer cannot stand on its merits, irrelevancies and exaggerations were in troduced. Thus, the Companies stated that Steel workers are among the highest paid workers in all of industry, that they have made more rapid prog ress than all other major American industries, that Steelworkers’ earnings are above the aver age for All Manufacturing workers, and that a typical, average Steelworker earns $6,000 a year. Steelworkers have made progress. They are proud of that progress—achieved as it has been with the greatest of effort. However, the United Steelworkers of America alone has negotiated wage increases in two other major industries which have exceeded the increases negotiated in Steel—in Aluminum and in Can Manufacturing. Steelworkers’ wages have improved through the years but there are higher earnings in a whole variety of industries such as Coal Mining, Petro leum and Natural Gas Production, Building Con struction, Petroleum Refining, Tire Manufactur ing, Plate Glass, and others. Steelworker hourly earnings undeniably are above the earnings of workers in numerous indus tries which make up the “All Manufacturing” av erage. Nor is it surprising that Steelworker earn ings are greater than earnings of workers in Grain-Mill Products, Beet Sugar, Tobacco and Snuff, Textiles, Logging Camps, Cosmetics, and in many other industries in which Profits and profit margins are lower and in which mechanization and productivity are far less advanced, or in which the factors of skill, hazard, training and responsi bility required of workers are far less than in Steel. A skilled worker in a profitable industry necessarily earns more than a less skilled worker in a less profitable industry. If comparisons be tween industries are to be made, the important question is what has happened to the relation ship between the industries. The present mar 227 gin of Steelworker hourly earnings over the av erage of earnings in All Manufacturing is equal to a little more than 26% as compared with a margin of more than 32% in 1939. (On the other hand, Steel’s Net Profit margin on Sales was more than 83% greater than the margin in All Manufac turing in 1955.) As for the Steel Industry’s claim that the typ ical, average Steelworker earns $6,000 a year, it can only be said that in citing this figure the In dustry was more careless than ever with the truth. In an advertisement which appeared in a large number of American newspapers on May 14 and 15, 1956, the American Iron and Steel Institute set forth some facts about an individual mill wright in a Steel plant. It described his normal living routine, his family’s budget and his income. The advertisement noted that his income was $500 a month ($6,000 a year), and described him as a typical, average worker. An income of $6,000 a year requires earnings of $3.00 an hour for 2,000 hours a year. Aver age gross earnings of workers in the Steel Indus try are $2.46 an hour (March, 1956— Bureau of Labor Statistics), or 54^ an hour less than the earnings of the “average” worker described in the American Iron and Steel Institute’s advertise ment. In 1955, a full 84% of the workers in the Basic Steel Industry had gross earnings of less than $6,000. Only 1 worker in 6 had earnings equal to the “average” worker described by the American Iron and Steel Institute. It is this type of propa ganda, which the Industry has substituted for collective bargaining, and which contributes to the difficulty of reaching an agreement. These facts are set forth in TABLE 21. One defense the Steel Companies have offered for their meager contract proposal indicates that its inadequacy is known to them. That defense is the allegation that Steelworkers received “too much” in 1955— a wage increase of 15^ an hour. Apparently the Industry, in effect, wants to re cover a mythical “excess” which the Steelworkers received last year. The Industry’s claim cannot stand examination. The Steelworkers Union negotiated a 15^ an hour wage rate increase with the Steel Companies in 1955. The Steel Companies, along with other Bituminous Coal operators negotiated a 15^ an hour wage increase with the United Mine Work ers of America in 1955 and, in addition, granted an increase in vacation pay equal to a cost of 2%^ 228 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT to 3^ an hour, an additional 10^ an hour wage in crease effective April 1, 1956, and a wage reopen ing in September, 1956! The Steelworkers Union negotiated a 15^ wage increase with the 3 leading Basic Aluminum Companies in 1955. The Marine and Shipbuilding Workers negotiated a 15*5 in crease with Bethlehem-Atlantic Shipyards. The Rubber Workers negotiated a wage increase which averaged 14.5< with B. F. Goodrich and the Pack inghouse Workers gained a 14*! wage increase in negotiations with the “ Big Four” Meatpackers in 1955. The Auto Workers negotiated an average of 15*f (including geographical differential adjust ments) with International Harvester in 1955. Fur thermore, some of these settlements were supple mented by “fringe” adjustments. These and numerous other wage settlements in 1955 approxi mated the 151 wage increase in Steel. Settlements in the Can Industry far exceeded the wage in crease in Steel. But the Steel Industry has pre tended, nevertheless, that 15^ granted in 1955 jus tifies a substandard wage increase in 1956 and in every one of the subsequent years through 1960. 229 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Table 21 STEELWORKERS WITH EARNINGS IN 1955 BELOW $6,000* Company** Total employees for whom earnings were reported Pittsburgh Steel Co................................................ Northwestern Steel & Wire Co.............................. Detroit Steel Corp.................................................. Inland Steel Co...................................................... National Steel Corp............................................... Allegheny Ludlum Steel Corp................................ Armco Steel Corp................................................... Sharon Steel Corp.................................................. Republic Steel Corp............................................... Youngstown Sheet and Tube Co........................... Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp................................. McLouth Steel Corp.............................................. Granite City Steel Co............................................ U. S. Steel Corp..................................................... Colorado Fuel and Iron Corp................................ Wheeling Steel Corp............................................... Lukens Steel Co..................................................... Merritt-Chapman & Scott Corp............................ Bethlehem Steel Corp............................................ Kaiser Steel Corp................................................... TOTALS..................................................... 9,300 2,258 3,814 13,695 9,954 10,736 12,702 8,132 40,302 19,511 22,833 3,049 3,968 135,585 16,787 13,262 4,020 1,754 77,544 7,427 416,633 **Steelworkers with earnings in 1955 below $6,000 ------------------------------------------------Number Percentage 5,944 1,499 2,822 10,532 7,663 8,306 9,870 6,476 32,517 15,786 18,572 2,514 3,307 114,186 14,187 11,898 3,623 1,605 71,851 6,912 63.9% 66.4% 74.0% 76.9% 77.0% 77.4% 77.7% 79.6% 80.7% 80.9% 81.3% 82.5% 83.3% 84.2% 84.5% 89.7% 90.1% 91.5% 92.7% 93.1% 350,070 84.0% * The data shown are based on 1955 earnings data supplied by the individual Companies. Data were requested by the Union from the 25 largest Steel Companies (except Ford and International Harvester whose operations are not primarily in the Steel Indus try). Data from Crucible, Barium and Timken have not been received. The earnings include all payments made to employees including such additional payments (over and above base pay, incentive earnings and vacation pay) as overtime, shift premiums, holiday pay and vacation payments in lieu of vacations. Only Production and Maintenance employees represented by tne United Steelworlcers of America are included. Exceptions and qualifications are noted below: U. S. Steel.—Basic Steel Producing Operations only; excludes employees hired or terminated during the year. Bethlehem.—Steel Plants and Fabricating Works; excludes employees hired or terminated during the year and 1,538 employees on layoff or otherwise absent during the year. Republic.—Steel Operations; excludes employees hired or terminated during the year. Jones and Laughlin.—Steel Works Divisions—Aliquippa, Pittsburgh and Cleveland; excludes employees with less than one year of service and 29 employees with no earnings. National.—Great Lakes Detroit Area Plants, Hanna Furnace and Stran-Steel—Terre Haute; excludes employees hired or terminated during the year. Youngstown.—Employees covered by Master P&M Agreement. Inland.—Indiana Harbor Works only. Armco.—Houston, Sand Springs and Kansas City plants of Sheffield Steel Div., Baltimore plant of Rustless Div. and Ashland Works; latter includes 857 employees who did not work the full year. Colorado F and I.—Includes Clinton, Palmer, Morgan, Buffalo, Claymont and Pueblo and Roebling and Trenton plants of Roebling’s Sons, Corp. Wheeling.—Steel Mills and Factories; excludes employees hired or terminated during the year. Sharon.—Roemer and Lowellville Works, Detroit Tube and Steel Div. and Brainara Steel Div. Kaiser.—Fontana, California. McLouth.—Company states earnings were exceptionally high because 1955 was the first year of operation of many new facilities and, therefore, there was an unusual amount of overtime and vacation payments in lieu of vacations. Pittsburgh.—Allenport and Monessen, Pa., and Warren, Ohio. Detroit.—Portsmouth Div. only; excludes employees terminated during the year. Granite City.—Granite City, 111. Allegheny Ludlum.—Includes only employees with continuous service the entire year. NorthwesternSteel &Wire.—Includes Parrish-Alford Fence & Machine Co. Northwestern Steel &Wire data excludes employees hired or terminated during the year. Parrish-Alford Fence & Machine data includes all employees who worked any part of the year. Merritt-Chapman & Scott.—Newport Steel only. Lukens.—Coatesville, Pa. ** Listed in ascending order of the percentage of employees with gross earnings below $6,000. 230 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT E. THE STEELWORKERS' POSITION The position of the Union throughout has been that it desired to negotiate, on a basis of genuine collective bargaining, a fair and reasonable settle ment. The proposals made by the Union for im provement of the existing contracts with the Steel Industry were reasonable, practical and en tirely justifiable. In essence, the Union has proposed that Steel workers share equitably in the unparalleled pros perity of the Steel Industry which has been made possible by greatly increased productivity. It has proposed that the working provisions of the Steel contracts be modernized in line with present-day practices in American Industry. The facts clearly show that the Profit position of the Steel Companies has never been better. Their Profits—Before Taxes or After Taxes—in dollars, or as a percentage of Net Worth, or as a share of the Sales Dollar, or by any other con ceivable measure, are tremendous. The growth of Steel Industry Profits has been at double the rate of All Manufacturing Industries combined in the past 8 years. The facts clearly support the Union’s position that: 1. Steelworkers have earned the right to higher wages by their greatly increased productivity. 2. All proposals made by the Union for contract improvements are in line with conditions and working practices which prevail in major parts of American Industry. 3. No Price increase whatsoever should occur as a result of granting the Union’s proposals. A Steel Price increase this year cannot be justified on any basis. Only the force of public opinion, alert to the Industry’s profit-taking, can hope to prevent Steel Management from continuing its past policy of making a profit on a wage increase —usually on a 3 to 1 ratio. 4. Higher wages and salaries are in the public interest. The wider distribution of purchasing power throughout our Nation has been a major and indispensable factor in the growth of produc tion in this country. 5. The Steel Companies must undertake serious collective bargaining. The companies have cre ated the present crisis by their refusal to engage in such bargaining. They made their position clear when they refused the Union’s offer to ex tend its contracts for 15 days so as to permit sufficient time for a bargained settlement to be reached without a shutdown. Now that they have achieved their purpose of causing a cessation of steel production, it is their plain duty, not only to their employees, but to the nation as well, to begin—for the first time—the process of giveand-take negotiation which alone can end the present crisis. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 231 APPENDIX TABLES Table 22 PROFITS BEFORE TAXES OF ALL CORPORATIONS, ALL MANUFACTURING CORPORATIONS, AND STEEL CORPORATIONS All Manufacturing All Corporations Corporations Steel Industry Billion Index Billion Index Index Million Dollarsa (1947 = 100) Dollarsft (1947 = 100) Dollars b (1947 = 100) 1956*.............. $46.2 156.6 $25.7 $2,350.7 338.3 155.8 1955................ 148.5 24.4 43.8 293.4 147.9 2,0 38.5 1954................ 34.0 115.3 17.8 1,133.6 163.1 107.9 1953.......... 38.3 129.8 21.4 129.7 1,600.7 230.3 1952................ 35.9 121.7 20.0 929.6 133.8 121.2 139.7 1951................ 41.2 271.1 24.5 148.5 1,884.0 1950................ 40.0 135.6 23.3 141.2 1,530.7 220.3 1949............ 26.2 88.8 14.1 933.3 134.3 85.5 1948................ 32.8 111.2 18.1 985.9 141.9 109.7 1947................ 29.5 100.0 16.5 100.0 694.9 100.0 * Annual rates based on projections from 1st quarter 1956. (Average of 4th quarter 1955 and 1st quarter 1956 used for U. S. Department of Commerce figures.) SOURCE.—•U.S.DepartmentofCommerce. Calculationsours. bBasedondatainpriorTablesfor25majorSteelCompanies. Table 23 NET PROFITS OF ALL CORPORATIONS, ALL MANUFACTURING CORPORATIONS, AND STEEL CORPORATIONS All manufacturing All Corporations Corporations Steel Industry Billion Index Billion Index Million Index Dollars* (1947 = 100) Dollars ‘ (1947 = 100) Dollars'5 (1947 = 100) $23.0 126.4 $12.6 124.8 $1,153.4 292.5 1955. 21.8 119.8 11.9 117.8 1,019.4 258.5 1954. 17.0 93.4 8.8 87.1 589.8 149.6 1953. 93.4 17.0 8.8 87.1 679.4 172.3 16.1 88.5 1952. 8.3 82.2 492.5 124.9 1951. 18.7 102.7 10.3 102.0 633.5 160.7 22.1 1950. 121.4 12.4 122.8 728.5 184.8 15.8 1949. 86.8 8.4 83.2 521.8 132.3 20.3 1948. 111.5 11.0 108.9 534.9 135.7 18.2 1947. 100.0 10.1 100.0 394.3 100.0 based on projections from 1st quarter 1956. (Average of 4th quarter 1955 and 1st quarter 1956 used for U. S. Department of Commerce figures.) SOURCE.—» U.S.DepartmentofCommerce. Calculationsours. ’ Basedondatainpriortablesfor25majorSteel Companies. 87624 0—57------16 232 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Table 24 DIVIDEND PAYMENTS IN ALL CORPORATIONS VS. STEEL CORPORATIONS All Corporations * 1956*....................................................... 1955............................... ......................... 1954............................... ......................... 1953............................... ......................... 1952............................... ......................... 1951............................... ......................... 1950......................................................... 1949............................... ......................... 1948............................... ......................... 1947............................... ......................... Steelb Billions of Dollars Index (1947 = 100) Millions of Dollars $11.7 11.2 10.0 9.3 9.0 9.1 9.2 7.5 7.2 6.5 180.0 172.3 153.8 143.1 138.5 140.0 141.5 115.4 110.8 100.0 $412.9 353.9 269.0 248.7 238.8 240.3 246.0 167.9 150.2 127.8 Index (1947 = 10< 323.1 276.9 210.5 194.6 186.9 188.0 192.5 131.4 117.5 100.0 * Annual rates based on projections from 1st quarter 1956. SOURCE.— • U. S. Department of Commerce. Includes all CashDividends. Calculations ours. b Based on datain prior Tables for 25 major Steel Companies. Includes Cash Dividends on Common Stock only. Table 25 PROFITS BEFORE AND AFTER TAXES AS SHARES OF THE SALES DOLLAR FOR ALL MANUFACTURING CORPS. VS. STEEL CORPS. Profits Before Taxes 1956*........................................................ 1955......................................................... 1954 ......................................................... 1953 ......................................................... 1952......................................................... 1951......................................................... 1950......................................................... 1947 ......................................................... Steel Industryb All Manufacturing Corporations * 8.6* 8.5 6.9 7.8 7.8 9.8 10.7 9.3 16.2* 15.8 11.6 13.1 9.1 17.0 16.8 10.9 4JJ* 4.1 3.4 3.2 3.2 4.1 5.7 5.7 * Annual rates based on projections from 1st quarter 1956. SOURCE.— * U. S. Department of Commerce. Profit and Sales data. for it major Steel Companies. Net Profits All Manufacturing Corporations* Steel Industry b 7.9* 7.9 6.1 5.6 4.9 5.7 8.0 6.2 Calculations ours. b Based on data from prior Tablet ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 233 Table 26 PRODUCTION, SHIPMENTS AND EMPLOYMENT IN STEEL Production and Ingot Production a Shipments* Maintenance Employmentb Operating Millions Index Millions Index Thousands Index of Tons (1947 = 100) Rate* of Tons (1947 = 100) of Empls. (1947 = 101 1956* .. 99.6% 127.49 150.2 93.23 147.8 566.9 109.5 1955 93.0 117.04 137.9 84.72 134.3 545.0 105.3 88.31 1954 71.0 104.0 63.15 100.1 492.7 95.2 127.1 1953 94.9 111.61 131.5 80.15 559.6 108.1 1952 85.8 93.17 109.8 68.00 107.8 486.5 94.0 1951 100.9 105.20 123.9 78.93 125.2 560.2 108.2 96.84 114.1 1950 72.23 114.5 532.9 96.9 103.0 92.1 1949 476.7 81.1 77.98 91.9 58.10 92.1 88.64 1948 94.1 104.4 65.97 104.6 536.3 103.6 1947 93.0 84.89 100.0 63.06 100.0 517.6 100.0 * Annual rates based on straight-line projections from the 1st quarter of 1956. SOURCES.— * American Iron and Steel Institute. Calculations ours. b Bureau of Labor Statistics. Calculations ours. Table 27 PRICES IN STEEL YS. MATERIALS AND LABOR COSTS Manhoursa Average Hourly Eam ingsb (per unit) 75.4 $2,463 1956*............... 2.380 78.8 1955.......... 2.200 1954................. 87.8 2.160 85.5 1953................ 86.2 1.990 1952................ 1.890 89.6 1951................ 1.691 90.3 1950................ 98.4 1.646 1949................. 1.580 100.6 1948................. 1947................. 100.8 1.439 * Annual rates based on projections from 1st quarter 1956. Labor Cost Index0 (1947 = 100) 128.0 129.3 133.2 127.3 118.3 116.7 105.3 111.7 109.6 100.0 All Commodities other than Farm and Food Wholesale Price Indexb (1947 = 100) 126.7 122.8 120.1 119.6 118.8 121.6 110.2 106.3 108.5 100.0 Steel Mill Price Indexb (1947 = 100) 177. 1* 169.7 161.9 155.0 143.6 140.5 130.3 123.8 114.2 100.0 SOURCES—aBased on data in the prior Steel Productivity Table, bBureau of Labor Statistics. Calculations ours, cBased on Columns 1 and2 above. Calculations ours. dIndexforMarch1956is178.2. STEEL and THE NATIONAL ECONOMY 1 9 5 6 UNITED STEELWORKERS OF AMERICA 1 5 0 0 COMMONWEALTH BUILDING PITTSBURGH 2 2 , PENNSYLVANIA Printed In U.S.A. JULY, 1 9 5 6 235 236 ECONOMIC REPOBT OF THE PRESIDENT Summary 1. Economic conditions in the United States in mid-1956 were varied. Despite continued heavy defense spending and sharply rising business in vestment expenditures, the economy has been on a plateau for some nine months. Even the pre carious support from inventory accumulation and higher consumer debt has not resulted in the de gree of full employment of 1952 and 1953. Con sumer purchases are lagging. Personal income must increase if economic expansion is to be re sumed. 2. A growing labor force and rising productivity make possible a doubling of our production and our standard of living within the next 20 years. These can be achieved only if there is an active market for the goods and services we can produce. 3. Consumers buy five out of every six dollars worth of goods and services purchased privately. Wages and salaries largely determine how much money consumers have for expenditures. Wages and salaries must increase if the growing produc tive capacity of American industry is to be uti lized. 4. Wage and salary increases and labor’s rising share of total income over much of the last dec ade provided consumers with the income needed for the profitable prosperity we have enjoyed. Labor’s share has fallen in the last year and, un less corrected, this could spell economic trouble. 5. Experience has proved that wage increases have not caused inflation, that wages can be in creased without prices being raised, and that ris ing real wages give us stable prosperity and growth. 6. The inflation in 1946-48 resulted from an ac cumulated backlog of demands. The Korean in flation was caused by speculation and scare buy ing. In both instances, wage increases lagged be hind price increases and did not cause the infla tion. 7. In the two periods of inflation—from 1946 to 1948, and again in 1950-51—wages lagged behind prices. Labor struggled to keep up with the in flation and barely succeeded in restoring the pur chasing power eroded by rising prices. On the other hand, in the two periods of stability from 1948 to 1950 and again after mid-1951, wages and salaries increased while prices remained stable. Since mid-1951 wage rates in manufacturing have risen 23 percent while living costs are up less than 4 percent and industrial prices 4 percent. Total profits before taxes reached record levels in 1955. 8. Productivity in the economy has been increas ing more than 3 percent per year. In manufac turing industries, the annual rate has been ex ceeding 4 percent. Automation will increase the pace. Greater prosperity will come if the bene fits of rising productivity are shared with the workers. Real hourly earnings in manufacturing fell behind the rise in productivity at the time of the Korean War and have not caught up yet. This disparity must be corrected through rising real wages. 9. From 1946 to 1948, hourly earnings in manu facturing rose 24 percent in current prices, but remained unchanged in real terms. Manufactur ing profits increased 60 percent. Pay to all cor porate employees rose 30 percent, industrial prices increased one-third, and corporate profits in creased 45 percent. That is the pattern of infla tion—rising prices, rising real profits and lagging real wages. 10. Except for the immediate post-war and Ko rean inflations, the rising volume of business in industry generally, but not in steel, tended to be associated with lower profit margins. This policy yielded prosperity and high total profits. Price stability and sustained high profits ought to be more attractive to business than alternating booming and falling profits which result in part from inflationary pricing policies. 11. In only one year from 1947 to date did the rate of profits after taxes of all manufacturing corporations combined fall below 10 percent of stockholders’ equity and that was in the recession year of 1954. In only two years of the last nine did the rate of manufacturing profits before taxes fall below 20 percent of stockholders’ equity. Higher volume and lower margins can provide high and sustained profits. 12. In mid-1955 industrial prices started to rise and again spurted ahead of wages. Profits in the first quarter of 1955 were at the 1951 Korean peak, but higher pricing brought a 15 percent in crease in profits from the first to the fourth quar ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT ter of 1955. Employees' compensation rose 7 per cent in the same period. Profit margins rose sharply after four years of a moderate decline. This tendency can spell trouble. It must be re versed. 13. The contrast between the pricing policies of the steel industry and of all manufacturing in dustries as a whole is rather startling. Steel prices have increased proportionately with wage rates since 1947 ignoring rapidly rising productiv ity in its pricing policies. For all manufacturing, industrial prices increased considerably less than half as much as wage rates from 1947 to 1955. From 1951 to 1955, hourly earnings in all manu facturing rose 18 percent while industrial prices went up 1 percent. In marked contrast, wage rates in steel were 25 percent higher in 1955 than in 1951, and steel prices were 20 percent higher. 14. Profit margins in steel were 30 percent higher in 1955 than in 1947-49. In all manufacturing, profit margins decreased slightly over this span. Total profits in steel rose more rapidly than in all manufacturing industries. 15. All major categories of steel-users increased their prices far less than did the steel industry. Part of the skyrocketing steel prices were appar ently absorbed by steel-fabricating industries. 16* The steel industry does not follow the prin ciple of higher volume and lower margins. If there is any single industry that has followed in flationary pricing practices; that has shown a dis regard for the economic welfare of the country, especially relative to its key role in the economy; that has truly practiced inflation; that has the 237 least right to hide behind the cloak of favoring a sound dollar and to contend that wage increases are inflationary; it is the steel industry. 17. Contentions that there have been uniform rounds and patterns of wage increases since the end of World War n are not based on fact All workers strived for higher wages in 1946-48 and 1950-51 to regain the losses in real income from rising prices. In between those years and since, all workers justly sought to share in our rising productivity. However, the size of wage increases has varied in substantial degree from industry to industry. There has been neither rigid patterns nor uniform rounds of wage and fringe benefit improvements. 18. High and accelerated depreciation charges permitted generally under the new 1954 tax law and specifically for plants related to national secu rity, have resulted in a probable understatement of reported profits relative to actual profits. De preciation allowances provide a significant source of funds for investment 19. Contentions by leaders of the steel industry and other industries that prices must be increased so that there will be more profits with which to finance expansion are astounding. Raising prices to secure funds for new plant and equip ment in effect forces the consumer to put up the money for new plants for the benefit of existing stockholders. The consumer gets nothing for his forced “investment.” The opportunity for Amer ican citizens to participate in the growth of Amer ican industry is denied when expansion is financed entirely through exorbitant profits rather than security flotations. 238 ECONOMIC REPORT OP THE PRESIDENT ECONOMIC FACTS 1—Economic Objectives and Wage Policies In mid-1956 the United States finds itself in a mixed situation of reasonably high levels of gen eral employment and serious unemployment in some key industrial centers, rapidly rising capital investment and continuing weakness in consumer durable goods and home building markets, slowly increasing total income and a depressed farm community, rising industrial prices in the face of larger inventories, and new record profits while over-all business has been on a plateau. Since V-J Day, we have enjoyed unprecedented improvements in living standards and, with the exception o f brief periods, continuing high levels of production and employment The American economy has demonstrated its immense power to produce. Equally important, better under standing of the functioning of our free enterprise system and increased determination to overcome booms and busts have led to greater confidence in a future o f sustained expansion without re currences of mass unemployment and idle re sources. Since World War n , there have been two peri ods of inflation and two recessions of moderate intensity and duration. A precipitous rise in prices immediately followed decontrol after the war. A brief but pronounced inflation was asso ciated with the war in Korea. The past five years have been characterized by a considerable de gree of price stability, although in the last half of 1955 and early 1956 prices have moved up in some sectors. With some exceptions, especially the depressed status of agriculture and the moder ate recession of 1953-1954, the types and degrees of distortions which have tended to be associated with periods of prosperity in the past and which in turn have brought on recessions and depres sions did not emerge in the period from June 1951 to mid-1955. On the whole, there is considerable basis for confidence that we can and will have a future of marked growth with sustained high levels of production and employment provided the dis tortions that have emerged in recent months are promptly reversed. A sharp rise in 1955 in consumer expenditures based in measurable degree on credit buying, helped to lift the national economy out of the 1953-1954 downturn. This rapid surge in con sumer borrowing has left many American families with debts that will probably remain a heavy burden for months to come. The general weak ness in consumer markets at present—most pro nounced in the markets for homes, automobiles and other consumer durable goods—has created a good deal of concern about the health of the na tional economy. This concern about the course of economic de velopments in the period immediately ahead is heightened by a growing distortion between the capital investment and consumer sectors. Weak ness in the consumer sector has been accompanied by sharply rising business expenditures for new factories, machines and instruments. Further substantial and rapid increases in these expendi tures are predicted for the remainder of the year. This soaring capital investment has helped pre vent an over-all economic decline during the past six months. But a continuation of this distorted condition can bring difficulties in the months ahead. Moreover, even with the high rate of business spending, there has been a relatively less full use of our labor force in 1955 and early 1956 than in 1952 and 1953 when investment rose far less sharply. New plant and equipment now being built will soon be placed into productive use. They rep resent not merely additions to our stock of capital equipment, but the planned installation of efficient and increasingly automatic productive machinery. Larger volume of goods and serv ices will be available in the coming months as this equipment is put into operation. There must be a growing market for this growing output. Consumer markets require immediate strengthen ing for the resumption of economic expansion. No single segment of the American community can wholly determine the character and pattern, the strength and weaknesses, or the well-being of our free enterprise economy. Yet, each group —workers, farmers, management, consumers and all branches and levels of the government—play a vital role in our economic development. Each group should gear its policies and actions toward a strong and growing system of free enterprise which affords a more abundant life for the Amer ican citizen. Labor must continue to play its full part with responsibility and dedication to the best interests of the nation. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Wage earners and salaried workers serve the whole community not only in devoting their ef forts and talents to the productive process but as members of unions they use their strength to achieve a better functioning and more equitable and humane society. They seek a fair share of the product of their toil for themselves and their families—an adequate share which is basic to the growth of mass markets to parallel our mass production. They strive to help attain and main tain economic relationships essential to a stable and expanding economy. Labor has no illusions that in its bargaining functions, it can overcome all the flaws and weaknesses in our system. But it can and does make a measurable contribution toward a stronger and healthier economy. Labor believes that its performance in the past decade has not only served to raise living standards of all workers, but more importantly, its wage policies have contributed to the accelera tion in expansion and to moving in the direction of a more stable and depression-proof economy. The progress of the past twenty-five years toward overcoming depressions and expanding the rate of growth has been gratifying, but there is still much to be done before the waste and hardships of booms and busts are fully overcome. Labor’s wage policies will continue to be de signed primarily to increase the size of our total production so that workers and farmers and man agement can enjoy increasing abundance. Labor will continue to strive for rising real wages so that there will be markets for our expanding production. The record of the past decade es pecially gives evidence of the success of such pol icies. The short duration and limited degree of the recessions in 1949 and 1954 can in consider able measure be attributed to stable wages—some wage rates even increased—in those years. The road ahead will require continued determination and dedication if the potentialities of our tremen dous productive capacity are to be realized. It is toward this end that union wage policies must be dedicated. 2— Keeping the Economy Expanding The most unique characteristic of the Ameri can economy is its extraordinary rate of dynamic growth. Since 1939, the gross national product of the United States has more than quadrupled in value, increasing from less than $100 billion to approximately $400 billion annually. Part of this increase reflects higher prices, but even after allowing for price advances, the real value of the 239 total output of goods and services has more than doubled. In the eight years from 1947 to 1955, an increase of nearly 40 percent has been reg istered in the output of goods and services. We are nearly one-fourth above the peak of total production during World War n . At the close of 1955, the economy was pro ducing at the rate of nearly $2,400 per year for every man, woman and child in the country. The production per gainfully employed person is now $6,000 per year. These are levels virtually un dreamed of only a generation ago. The rise in output not only underlies our present high living standards, but points the way to the more abund ant life that lies ahead. Especially rapid has been the growth in the industrial sector of the economy. Manufactur ing production is now more than two and onehalf times what it was in 1939. The production of durable goods has increased over 50 percent since 1947 and has more than trebled in the past 17 years. Electric power production has doubled since 1947 and quadrupled since 1939. Part of these phenomenal increases occurred during World War II. Since the war ended, how ever, our growth has continued at a rapid rate. Total output of goods and services has risen an average of more than 3 y% percent a year since 1946. For the years after 1949, the annual in crease averaged 4% percent for total production. These are real rates of growth, measuring the value of production after eliminating the influ ence of higher prices. Industrial production has grown over 5 percent per year since the end of World War n and, since 1949, the rate of increase has been 6 percent a year. The output of durable goods has expanded an average of 6% percent a year since 1946 and at an annual rate of 8% percent since 1949. If ever there were doubts about the possibility of banishing poverty, our past record and future prospects should serve to eradicate such doubts. If America's economic expansion can be main tained at the 1946-55 average of 3% percent, a $500 billion economy— at present prices—is in sight as early as 1963 and over $600 billion can be reached before 1970. At the 4V2 percent rate actually achieved in the years since 1949, the $500 billion level can be reached soon after 1960, with $600 billion accomplished by 1965 and an incredible $750 billion by 1970. These levels may seem astronomical, but recent accomplish ments demonstrate their feasibility. Our recent growth is reflected in, and has been 240 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT sustained by, marked increases in employment and wages. Higher wages place in the hands of the nation’s consumers the purchasing power necessary to absorb the country’s ever-increasing output Since the end of World War n , personal consumption expenditures have increased more than 100 percent. Adjusting for price changes, consumer purchases in the aggregate have in creased more than 40 percent since 1945 and on a per capita basis have risen approximately 20 per cent. There has been a broadening of mass mar kets with millions of families getting higher in comes and adding to the markets for improved housing, cars, appliances, leisure-time activities, more and better foods and clothing and services. Had this increase in buying power not occurred, our economic expansion could not have been sus tained. Rising employment accounted for only part of the expansion in consumer expenditures; a major contributing factor was the steadily ris ing wage level reflecting effective collective bar gaining between labor and management. To attain the achievable targets in the years ahead, the rise in purchasing power must keep pace with the rise in production. Given a market for its products and services, American industry can be expected to employ our growing labor force. Together, management and workers can achieve further marked progress in productivity. To provide the market for an output of $600 bil lion per year in the next decade, assuming peace time conditions, consumer purchases would have to rise well over 50 percent. Increased employ ment will contribute in part to this increasing buy ing power, but the bulk must come from higher wages and higher salaries. 3—Purchasing Power and Wage Policy Total demand for goods and services is the most important single determinant of the level of total production. Our growth in production rests on the combination of employing the growing labor force, expanding our industrial capacity, and increasing the level of productivity. Whether these resources are used, in turn depends on the ultimate key to our prosperity—an adequate mar ket for the goods and services our economy can produce. Labor recognizes that wages represent income to workers and costs to employers. Strongly favoring the free enterprise system, American labor appreciates the need for and desirability of profits as incentives and rewards to business. La bor wants its employers to earn fair profits. At the same time, labor insists that employers pay sufficiently high wages so that workers can share reasonably in the benefits of our mass produc tion and can provide a market for the goods which business produces. Such a market is neces sary if there is to be sustained employment and profit opportunities. Excluding government purchases, over fourfifths of our total output of goods and services is absorbed by personal consumption expendi tures. Outlays made by individuals and families in the purchase of residential housing are not normally counted as consumption expenditures. They appear in the national income accounts in the category of investment expenditures. If dis bursements for housing were added to expendi tures for consumption, then consumers would account for over 85 percent of all non-govemment purchases. Five out of every six dollars worth of goods and services produced in the United States that are available for private pur chase are bought for personal consumption. The balance is purchased largely by business. These figures make crystal clear the need for focusing our attention on consumer buying power in de termining sound economic policies. Labor income accounts for more than 70 per cent of total personal income in the United States. Expenditures by farmers and executives and in dependent professionals are obviously important, but the largest single factor determining the mag nitude of disposable personal income is the level of total wages and salaries. In turn, the level of wage rates directly influences total labor in come and total personal income. The vast major ity of American families are dependent on wages and salaries for their livelihood. Over 70 percent of all gainfully employed persons are wage and salary earners. Since 1950, the trend of disposable personal in come has almost precisely paralleled that of man ufacturing wage rates. The indexs of disposable income and of hourly wages in manufacturing on the next page reveal this close relationship. From 1950 to 1955, total disposable income rose 31 percent, while hourly wage rates of manufac turing workers advanced 29 percent For each of the intervening years, the proportionate changes in the two series were nearly identical. It is not meant to imply that manufacturing wage rates determine the income of all persons. There are, of course, a great many elements influencing changes in buying power such as increases in pop ulation and employment, incomes of other groups ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CHANGES IN DISPOSABLE INCOME AND HOURLY WAGES IN MANUFACTURING, 1950-55 (percentage change from preceding year) Total disposable income Period 195 195 195 195 195 1 2 3 4 5 + 10 ............ + 5 + 6 ........... + 2 ........ + 6 1950-55............... + 31 Manufacturing wage rates + + + + + 8 5 6 2 4 +29 Source: United States Departments of Commerce and Labor. in the population, changes in taxes, variations in savings, the length of the work week and the like. Nevertheless, the parallel is so close as to make clearly apparent the importance of wage rates in manufacturing industries in influencing wage rates and incomes in other endeavors. Im provements in wage levels in key industries have a profound effect on wages and salaries else where in the economy, though amounts, timing and specific terms of the multitude of wage and salaried changes vary widely. The rapid growth in the economy over the past decade and especially in the last five years has been associated with rising real wages. There has been a modest but definite increase in labor’s share of our national income. Labor income was 63 percent of the total national income in 1946. Since 1953, labor’s share has averaged about 67 percent. Similarly, labor income was less than two-thirds of total personal income in the period 1946-50, whereas from 1952 to the present, it has been over 70 percent. Compared with total non agricultural income, labor’s share has also risen. It is also noteworthy that income of employees of all corporations has tended to rise relative to profits before taxes. The rise in real wages and the shifts in total income distribution over the full span of the past decade in favor of labor contributed materially to our economic growth and relatively stable prosperity. Our progress would have been neither as steady nor as rapid had it not been for these stimulating influences which provided for growing mass markets. Unfortunately, there has been some retrogression in these relationships in the past year. Profits have persisted since World War II at 241 highly favorable levels. The rising national in come has been associated with rising profits, though the increase in total labor income has exceeded that of total profits. In essence, larger volume of business at slightly lower margins has yielded increasing profits. The high levels and rising trends of investment expenditures by bus iness provide ample proof that attractive in centives for new investments have prevailed. Busi nessmen and investors benefit more from grad ually rising and persistent profits than from sensational profits in boom times followed by bankruptcy in depressions. Labor’s wage policies have made a contribu tion to sustained profitability. This contribution has been less pronounced in the past nine months, as precarious distortions have tended to emerge. These include a declining share of income for labor, a very marked rise in plant and equipment outlays in the face of very slight increases in con sumer income and expenditures, and irresponsible pricing policies in some of the more monopolistic sectors of the economy. It is increasingly clear that trends in favor of labor income and consumer purchasing power must go further to support a continuation of the rate of progress achieved in the past five years. While consumer incomes have increased substan tially, they have still not expanded at a rate com mensurate with our growing output of goods and services. The volume of goods and services avail able for domestic civilian purchase (i.e., gross national product minus government purchases minus net exports) has been rising more rapidly than personal disposable income which is the in come available for personal expenditures (i.e., total personal income minus personal taxes). In 1953 and 1954 American individuals and families received enough income, after paying personal taxes, to buy nearly 90 percent of total produc tion available for domestic civilian use. The ratio dropped to 86 percent in 1955 where it remained in the first quarter of 1956. This fall-off in con sumer purchasing power relative to production is an unhealthy tendency. The lack of adequate consumer buying power has been increasingly marked in recent months. Inventories at all levels of business activity have risen sharply in relation to sales. The rise in inventories has been particularly pronounced in consumer durable goods. Production will not stay high for long when an increasing portion of the output is merely serving to increase the sup ply of goods and services on the shelves of man- 242 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Disposable personal Incomeas «;{. of gross national product expendituresas % of gross national product availablefor 194 7 ..87 194 8 :...............86 194 9 ..88 195 0 ..84 ..85 195 1 195 2 ..88 195 3 ..89 195 4 ..90 1955.............. ......86 85 81 85 79 79 82 82 83 81 1956*..................86 80 * Annual rate, seasonally adjusted, for six months end ing March 1956. ufacturers and wholesalers and retailers. Man ufacturing and trade sales, on a seasonally ad justed basis, are no higher than they were last fall, but inventories jumped almost $4y2 billion from September 1955 to April 1956. Such an in ventory accumulation was hardly purposeful. It reflects a lack of customers; not because the fam ilies of America do not need and want more goods, but rather because they lack the income to buy this larger flow of goods. Manufacturers and storekeepers will cut production and purchases if consumer buying does not increase more rap idly. And consumer purchases will not increase until and unless wages are raised. Expansion of the economy seems to have lost its momentum in the past six to nine months. Since September, 1955, we appear to have come to a halt on an economic plateau. The general level of industrial production has remained barely stable, with capital goods output rising and consumer durables declining. National income and personal consumption expenditures have advanced very slightly. Numerous weak spots are appearing in the economy despite continued high defense spending and a rather phenomenal increase in business investment in plant and equipment. The total level of expenditures for new plant and equipment is officially expected to total $35 billion in 1956, representing an increase of nearly one-quarter over 1955. In the first half of 1956, these expenditures are running one-third above the first half of 1955. In the face of sustained government spending and the extraordinary rise in plant and equipment expenditures, any softness in the business picture can. lead to only one con clusion, namely, that consumer incomes and con sumer expenditures are inadequate to maintain high levels of employment and to restore the mo mentum of the expansion. Not only has huge business spending for modernizing and enlarging our productive capacity failed to bring truly full employment, but such expenditures will not con tinue to increase unless consumer demand rises. Almost 4y2 percent of our civilian labor force was unemployed in the first quarter of 1956, as compared with 3 percent in the fall of 1955 and only 2 y2 percent in 1952 and 1953. In some areas, such as Detroit, Flint and South Bend, local unemployment has reached serious propor tions. Further evidence of the inadequacy of con sumer purchasing power is the fact that a con stantly growing share of consumer purchases has had to be financed by credit. Consumer debt out standing at the end of the first quarter of 1956 was $35.5 billion, or nearly 20 percent higher than a year earlier. Over the same period consumers had 6 percent more income to spend. Between the first quarter of 1952 and the first quarter of 1956, consumer expenditures increased 21 per cent, but consumer indebtedness jumped 71 per cent Mortgage debt on l-to-4 family houses also increased by more than 70 percent. The increase in mortgage debt on l-to-4 family houses in 1951 equaled 59 percent of the value of private nonfarm residences built in that year. The ratio in creased every year and in 1955 was almost 77 percent. At the beginning of 1952, the ratio of consumer credit outstanding to total disposable income was 9 percent. By the beginning of 1956, it had risen to 13.2 percent At the beginning of 1952 out standing consumer credit equalled 10.2 percent of the annual rate of consumer purchases. By the start of 1956 it had increased to 14.2 percent. Some expansion of credit is, of course, a normal sign of a growing, healthy economy. There can be no fixed rule defining how much expansion is safe. At some point, however, if an individual’s indebtedness rises much more rapidly than his income, his credit-worthiness becomes impaired. Further, his burden of paying off debts becomes excessive and limits his ability to make current purchases of essential goods and services for cur rent consumption. It seems reasonable to con clude that the rate of increase in consumer debt in recent years was excessive. Certainly, the decline in automobile and other consumer durable goods sales can be traced in some measure to the fact that many consumers became over-extended. Our economic growth may well have relied too ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT heavily upon credit and not enough on increased income over the past few years. We may have reached the limit of that road. If so, this leaves us with only two possible alternatives. One is to lower our sights and gear our output to what can be sold on the baas of the present trend of consumer incomes. That road leads at best to a slower rate of progress than we can attain and more probably to declining business and rising unemployment in the face of the economy’s tre mendous growth potential. The second alterna tive is to attack the problem at its root, which is to increase wages and purchasing power so that there are mass markets for the rising output made possible by the growth of our labor force, the increase in our productive capacity and the improvement in our efficiency. This clearly means that real wages must be raised more rapidly. It requires higher wages without higher prices. We have seen not only that wages can be raised without increasing prices, but it is clear that increasing real wages are absolutely essen tial for prosperity and growth. Only in this man ner can our economy be soundly supported on the solid basis of rising buying power, widely dis tributed, rather than excessive credit. Only if we take this road can we continue to enjoy the fruits of steady and dynamic economic expansion. 4—Inflation or Stabilization? Contentions by management and by anti-labor spokesmen that all wage increases must result in price increases—that higher wages must lead to inflation—are without basis in theory, in prac tice and in fa ct Rising wages and inflation are not part and parcel of a single phenomenon. In dustry need not, and most employers do not, raise prices every time wages are increased. So much has been said and written proving that wages must rise relative to prices, that only economic isola tionists in their remote-from-reality hideouts con tinue to prattle about higher wages causing infla tion. Contentions that wage rates can be increased without limit and still have no impact on prices are equally irresponsible. But, a healthy econ omy requires that wages and salaries must rise relative to prices and the only meaningful ques tion is the degree to which wages can and must increase relative to prices. Unions have never contended that higher wages could be paid without higher prices re gardless o f the size of the wage increase. Rather, labor has contended that the level of profits and 243 changes in productivity should be taken into ac count in determining how much wages can be in creased without increasing the general price level. On the other hand, those who steadfastly fight against wage increases attempt to propagate the view that every wage increase must result in a price increase. It is unequivocally clear that unless wages and salaries increase somewhat more than prices, our economic growth will be halted. As our produc tive capacity and output of goods and services expand, there must be an increase in the real buy ing power of consumers. Except for inventory and investment booms which cause busts, our economy can grow no faster than the market for its products. The mainstay of that market is the purchasing power of our workers. As already pointed out, more than four-fifths of America’s total output of goods and services, excluding what is bought by the Government, is purchased for personal consumption. It is the income of the wage and salary earners that accounts for the bulk of personal consumption. Rising real wages are an absolute prerequisite to economic pros perity and economic growth. The history of our industrial development is a history of rising output per man-hour of work. The rate of change in productivity has varied from time to time, but the increase in efficiency —in production per man-hour—has been persist ent and substantial. Workers can share in the benefits of rising productivity only through ris ing real wages. But even more important from the economic point of view is the continuing need for higher real wages as a basis for sustained high levels of production and income and em ployment. Economists have long argued whether the bene fits of rising productivity should be shared through constant prices and higher wages or through constant wages and lower prices, or a combination of the two. Most economists are at least dubious, if not firmly opposed, to a goal of declining prices. Falling prices tend to discourage investment and to retard economic expansion. Even if general price declines were desirable, it is doubtful that prices would actually be reduced by those industries which can best afford it— those whose firm grip on the market has permit ted them to reap the largest profits by setting their prices high. As the economy has grown, business enter prises have developed in size and scale and in or ganization, bringing much less price flexibility 244 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT than was true in the past. Many objective anal yses have been made demonstrating the grow ing stickiness of prices, especially for industrial products. Even when economic activity and pro ductivity have risen relative to wages, there is little evidence of a readiness by the large indus trial corporations to cut prices. Rather, our in creasingly monopolistic industries tend to change their prices only in one direction, namely upward. If labor were to forego demands for higher wages and wait for employers to pass on the benefits of higher productivity through lower prices, we would surely experience short and intensive booms with tremendous profits and inadequate buying power, followed by severe depressions and mass unemployment. This is not a promising path to economic progress. Labor often seeks wage increases that are pro portionately higher than the rise in productivity, because wages have lagged in the past and profits have become exorbitant. Once labor’s share is reasonable, increases should primarily take into consideration changes in productivity. In indus tries where productivity is rising at a lesser rate than for the total economy, wages should be in creased in proportion to the over-all rate, even though some price increase might be necessary. In industries where productivity is increasing very rapidly, wages should rise more than in pro portion to the national increase in productivity. This might well leave room for price declines. The above policies would permit all workers to share in the improving productivity of the economy with extra benefits to workers in those industries where technological advancements are most rapid. It would result in only a slight up ward trend in prices. It should be noted that a percentage increase in wage rates proportionate with changes in pro ductivity results in a sharing of the benefits of productivity between management, labor and in vestors. Not all the benefits of increased effi ciency and mechanization are expected nor sought by labor. History has demonstrated not only that wages can rise relative to prices, thus providing the in creased purchasing power without which our economy would stagnate, but also that there can be substantial increases in wages with virtually no change in prices or living costs. The experi ences of the immediate pre-Korea and post-Korea years are significant in this respect. Since the end of World War n , there have been two periods of general price advances, both oc casioned by factors other than higher wages. Also in this decade, there have been two longer periods of general price stability. Prices rose sharply during the immediate post war years of 1946 and 1947, following the re moval of wartime price controls. This inflation reflected principally the release of accumulated demands for goods of all kinds following the re moval of wartime restrictions on consumption and output. As shown in the following table, con sumer prices increased 30 percent from January 1946 to January 1948. Wholesale prices for all commodities skyrocketed 50 percent. For all commodities other than farm and food items, the rise was 41.5 percent in these 24 months. Wages increased 30 percent during the same period, seriously lagging behind prices and barely provid ing workers with the same purchasing power per hour of work in January 1948 as in January 1946. Because of shortening of the work week, real buy ing power of weekly earnings declined markedly for a time following World War II. MAJOR PRICE AND WAGE MOVEMENTS SINGE THE END OF WORLD WAR II (Index Numbers, 1947-49=100) Wholesalepriwn wages*in Consumer All com* All except m&nutec_____ Period___________prices wodltlw farmand food taring 1 1. The immediate postwar boom: Jan. 1946 ..... 77.8 Jan. 1948..... 101.3 Percent --------change........... +30.2 2. Thirty months of stability: Jan. 1948..... 101.3 June 1950 ... 101.8 Percent --------change........... + 0.5 3. The Korean boom: June 1950 ... 101.8 June 1951... 110.8 --------Percent change.......... + 8.8 4. Five years of stability: June 19 51... 110.8 April 1956 ... 114.9 Percent --------change........... + 3.7 69.6 72.1 75.0 104.5 102.0 97.8 --------- --------- ---------f-50.2 +41.5 +30.4 104.5 102.0 97.8 100.2 102.2 109.0 --------- ---------- --------— 4.1 + 0.2 +11.5 100.2 102.2 109.0 115.1 116.2 118.8 --------- --------- --------+14.9 +13.7 + 9.0 115.1 116.8 118.8 113.7 121.7 146.0 --------- --------- --------— 1.2 + 4.2 +22.9 'Index of straight-time hourly earnings in manufactur ing industries. Source: United States Department of Labor. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT The increase in personal consumption in 1946 and 1947 was made possible by spending the savings that had been accumulated during the war. Wage increases were not the cause of the inflation. Clearly, during these two years, wages were in creased after prices were increased. Labor was on a treadmill trying to catch up with the gallop ing price level. Inflation appeared again following the Korean outbreak in June 1950 largely because of specula tion and scare buying. The rise in wholesale prices after Korea was, in fact, arrested by the end of January 1951 with the imposition of price controls, though living costs continued to advance for a few months longer. Again, as shown in the tabulation, wage rates barely kept pace with con sumer prices. The figures show that between June 1950 and June 1951, both wage rates and retail prices increased 9 percent and wholesale prices of all commodities advanced almost 15 per cent Between and after these periods of inflation, prices generally remained stable while wages con tinued to advance as labor productivity steadily improved. In the two and one-half years be tween January 1948 and June 1950 there was an 11.5 percent rise in hourly wages in all manu facturing industries while living costs advanced only one half of one percent and wholesale prices of all commodities actually declined. This de cline was confined largely to farm products and food. Industrial wholesale prices showed little change over the period. Most striking is the record of the years since the middle of 1951. During this interval of almost five years, wage rates in manufacturing industries rose 23 percent while living costs in creased less than 4 percent and wholesale prices declined slightly. Again, food and farm prices dropped, whereas wholesale prices of industrial commodities rose a bit over 4 percent in the 58 months from June 1951 to April 1956. The in crease occurred after the middle of 1955. The rise in the last five years in the consumer price index took place largely in the second half of 1951 and in 1952 as a result of the spill-over of the inflationary impact of the Korean War. Consumer prices are today at practically the same level as they were four years ago. The rise in non-agricultural wholesale prices in the past nine months is difficult to justify. In the middle of 1955, prices of industrial goods were actually lower than at the beginning of 1951. Profits 245 were already near an all-time peak in mid-1955 when the price advances were put into effect. This picture covering the past decade, espe cially most of the last five years and the two and one-half years from the beginning of 1948 to mid1950, clearly demonstrate that wages can be raised progressively without inflation. Not only have these wage increases during these years been associated with over-all price stabilization, but the fact is that in essence they have made our economic growth possible. There is no better way to generate the increase in consumer pur chasing power needed to buy the products of our expanded economy than to raise reed wages and salaries of workers. The general pattern described above has not been characteristic of each and every industry nor of each and every employer. In many areas where prices are not truly free, such as the steel indus try, but are subject to some degree of control— control by monopolistic firms—wage increases have been passed on in the form of higher prices, with consequent booming profits. Some evidence of variation in pricing practices will be analyzed below. The data show that the absorption of wage increases over the past five years in most industries has not resulted in a “profitless pros perity.” On the contrary, total profits have re mained high and we seem to have experienced a general demonstration, with some exceptions, of the thesis that American business firms are in terested in large volume at moderate margins. It is unfortunate that not all industries have re vealed their belief in the practice of making more profits by producing and selling more and more goods with smaller margins rather than push ing prices and profit margins higher and higher, ignoring the general well-being of the over-all economy. Some corporations try to justify their price gouging on the grounds that they need more prof its to finance expansion. This aspect will be dis cussed later. Other companies frankly say that they seek to make all the profits they possibly can so that when depressions come they will be better able to weather the storm. This is truly a cynical and dangerous view because such be havior, if widespread, will induce depressions. We need wage and price policies based on confidence in America’s future and on a sense of responsi bility for the welfare of the entire nation. There are still too many employers who deviate from such policies. 246 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 5—Productivity There are three factors which directly influ ence the ability of the economy to increase out put. One is the growth in the size of the labor force. Second is the degree to which the labor force is employed, i.e., the number at work and length of the work week. Third is the quantity of production per man-hour of input. If we maintain high levels of employment, then our. expanding labor force and rising productivity make it entirely feasible to raise the level of pro duction from the current annual rate of approxi mately $400 billion to nearly $500 billion in 1960 and to $600 billion by 1965. We can double our output in less than 20 years if we maintain rela tively full employment and continue to enjoy the increases of productivity which have occurred in the past few years. Of course, while these levels of output can be reached, they will be reached only if the market demand expands along with our capacity to produce. The rise in the size of the labor force is a func tion of our growing population. Despite the fact that larger numbers of our younger people remain in school for more years so as to secure the benefits of advanced education, there is a sub stantial increase in the working population year by year. Even if productivity were to remain unchanged, our national output would increase be cause of this expanding labor force. Actually, however, increasing productivity has contributed more to our rising production than has the growth in the labor force. Productivity gives promise of playing an even more important role in the future. Productivity is difficult to measure, especially for many sectors of the economy. However, the figures that are available indicate that improved skills, increased mechanization and greater effi ciency have tended to accelerate the rise in pro ductivity. With the coming of automation, even faster rates of rising productivity are in prospect A few months ago the Joint Committee on the Economic Report held hearings on automation and startling evidence was revealed of the shrink ing labor input per unit of output which will re sult from automation. Rising productivity, even at a more rapid rate through automation, can and should prove to be a blessing. Price and wage policies will largely determine whether automation will be associated with sustained full employment, an accelerated rise in living standards, more leisure and less physical exertion, or whether it will bring only bulging profits and widespread unemployment. If employers will share the benefits of automation in adequate degree with workers and consumers there is every reason to expect that this phenom enon can and will give us a rate of increasing abundance unparalleled in the past. It is in the self-interest of employers to share these benefits if they are to enjoy continued profitability. The following tabulation indicates that in the years between 1952 and 1955, real total output per man-hour rose more than 3 percent per year. REAL PRIVATE PRODUCT PER MAN-HOUR In 1947 Year-to-year Year_____ dollars______ change_______Index 1952.... ..... $2.28 1953___......2.38 1954.__ ..... 2.43 2.51 1955 — +4.4% + 2.1% +3.3% 100.0 104.4 106.6 110.1 Source: Based on data in Table 1, Joint Economic Re port, Joint Committee on the Economic Report, March 14,1956, p. 86. The following indexes of production, man-hours and output per man-hour for all manufacturing industries for the years 1947-53 were submitted by the United States Department of Labor to the Joint Committee on the Economic Report in the Automation Hearings. In the six years between 1947 and 1953, output per man-hour in manufac turing increased 22 percent. Preliminary figures indicate a rise of 10 percent in productivity in manufacturing between 1953 and 1955. On the basis of these data, the rate of increase from 1947 to 1955 exceeded 4 percent per year. INDEX OF PHYSICAL. OUTPUT PER MAN-HOUR—ALL MFG.1 (1947=100) Year 1947................. 1949...... 1950................. 195 1 195 2 ......... 195 3 195 4 195 5 Output per Man-hour Production Manhours 100.0 108.6 117.7 117.5 119.1 122.7 127.53 135.02 100.0 96.8 114.4 121.0 123.1 133.2 n.a. n.a. 100.0 89.1 97.2 103.0 103.4 108.6 n.a. aa. 1 Current year weights. 2 Preliminary estimates. n.a. Not available. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT The rise in productivity (35 percent) in man ufacturing since 1947 has been greater than the increase in average hourly earnings, adjusted for changes in consumer prices (26.8 percent). This means that the buying power received by work ers in manufacturing industries for each hour worked has increased less than the output per hour worked. It means that workers in factories have not shared fully in the benefits of rising in dustrial efficiency. A review of available information indicates that the increase in output per man-hour for the economy as a whole has averaged about 3 percent per year since 1939 and that the rate has been slightly higher in the past decade. In manufac turing the annual rate of increase in the last few years has certainly exceeded 4 percent. Unless the real wages of workers increase at least proportionate to the rise in productivity, the expansion of the economy will be stymied. This clearly means that wage rates must rise relative to prices. It means that employers generally not only can but must increase wages at least equal to the increase in productivity without increasing prices. If all industries follow the practice of some employers, such as the steel industry, in raising prices every time that wages are in creased, not only would we have inflation, but, more seriously, we would have booms and busts and a cessation of expansion in the economy. Over the years since 1947, real hourly earnings in manufacturing have lagged behind the rise in productivity. There was widening disparity until 1950; then the gap narrowed until 1953; and it has widened again in the past two years. Un doubtedly, the relationship between changing real wage rates and changing productivity has varied from industry to industry. In some sectors where productivity has risen slowly, workers probably have secured real wage increases which have ex ceeded rising productivity. On the other hand, there are many industries where real wages have unquestionably fallen far behind the improving output per man-hour. Dollar wage rates have increased far more than real wage rates. Rising prices ate into the buying power of the pay envelope. It was dur ing the 1946-48 and Korean periods of inflation when workers did not get higher real earnings. It was during the periods of price stability in 1948-50 and again after mid-1951 when real earn ings moved up with productivity. Labor suffers during inflation and that is why labor fights against inflation. Labor seeks higher wages 87624 0— 57------ 17 247 which can be clearly justified in relation to profits and rising productivity and which can be granted without precipitating general price increases. Monopolistic conditions too often permit arbitrary control over prices, as in the steel industry, with the result that a fair share of the benefits of ex panding productivity go neither adequately to workers in the form of higher wages nor to con sumers in the form of lower prices, but rather serve to increase profits further. The past and prospective growth in produc tivity lends great weight to the conclusions that wages can be increased without rising prices; that increasing wages in relation to productivity and reasonable profits are not inflationary; that wages can be raised without increasing labor costs per unit of output. These conclusions stand in support of the fundamental principle that wages and salaries must be increased without higher prices if we are to have a prosperous and expanding economy with a stable price level. 6—Wage-Price-Profit Relationships As already demonstrated, the years since the end of World War n were characterized by two periods of inflation and two periods of relative price stability. Over the entire interval, the out put of the economy expanded substantially. De spite two recessions, the country has enjoyed a degree of growth and relatively persistent pros perity probably unparalleled in any previous eleven-year span in the history of the United States. The changing economic relationships within the private economy undoubtedly contrib uted in considerable measure to this sustained growth. The study of these relationships should be revealing. Wage rates increased steadily from $1.02 per hour in all manufacturing industries in 1945 to $1.88 in 1955. Part of this increase was dissi pated through rising prices. In terms of goods and services which workers could buy with their income, hourly earnings in manufacturing dropped with the ending of overtime work in the immediate post-war period. Since 1947, real hourly earnings of factory workers have in creased by one-fourth. Weekly earnings have also been rising over the past few years. Because of the reduced work week, the pay envelope in manufacturing indus tries shrank considerably immediately after the War. It shrank in actual dollars, but dropped even more in buying power. In 1947, the weekly pay of the average factory worker commanded 248 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 15 percent less goods and services in the market than it did in 1944. After 1947, the change was favorable to employees. Average weekly earn ings of production workers in all manufacturing industries increased from just under $44 per week in 1946 to over $78 early in 1956. Rising living costs took away part of this increase, especially during the war in Korea. It was not until 1953 that the average production worker in manufac turing industries received as much purchasing power in his pay envelope as he did in 1944. He can now buy about 10 percent more goods and services with his weekly pay than he could in 1944. Of course, the length of the work week is shorter. Since the post-war low of 1947, real weekly earnings in manufacturing industries have increased over 30 percent. CHANGES IN REAL HOURLY AND WEEKLY EARNINGS IN MANUFACTURING INDUS TRIES SINCE WORLD WAR H Period (1947-49 dollars) Hourly earnings Weekly earnings 1. The Immediate post-war boom: 1946 ................................. $1.31 1.31 1948 ........................... 0 Percent change............ $52.54 52.67 +0.25 2. Pre-Korean stability: 1948 .................................. 1.31 1950 ............................... 1.43 Percent change............ +9.2 52.67 57.71 +9.6 3. The Korean boom: 1950 ............................. 1.43 1951 ............................... 1.43 0 Percent change........... 57.71 58.30 +1.0 4. Post-Korean stability: 1951 .......... ...........-..... .. 1.43 1955 _____ __________ .. 1.64 Percent change----------..+14.7 58.30 66.83 +14.6 It is significant to note that workers lost ground, in terms of purchasing power, during the imme diate post war inflation and barely held their own during the Korean price spurt. On the other hand, immediately before Korea and most of the time since Korea—when there was considerable price stability—real hourly and weekly earnings moved upward with some momentum. Labor's abhorrence of inflation appears to be well justified by the evidence at hand. Since the end of World War n , corporate profits have varied somewhat from year to year, gener ally moving in relation to changes in total busi ness activity. On the whole, however, they have increased measurably. The rise in profits after taxes has been less marked than the increase be fore taxes. This, of course, has been true for in dividuals as well as for corporations. Larger military expenditures have placed a heavy tax burden on all groups in the population. Personal taxes have increased more than cor porate taxes. However, the burden of personal taxation has not increased relative to personal in come as much as corporate taxes in relation to corporate profits. Personal taxes absorbed 11 percent of total personal income both in 1947 and in 1955. Corporate tax liability was 38 percent of corporate profits in 1947 and approximately 50 percent in 1955. Total corporate profits before taxes increased from $6.4 billion in 1939 to $22.6 billion in 1946 and then more than doubled to a record annual rate of over $46 billion in the six months ending March 1956. Corporate profits after taxes in creased nearly two and one-half fold from $8.3 billion in 1945 to $20.3 billion in 1948. There after, the range of fluctuations was more moder ate. In the six months ending March 1956, a new peak in the annual rate of corporate earnings after taxes of $23 billion was readied. Corporate profits before taxes are now about seven times what they were in 1939; after taxes they are ap proximately four and one-half times the 1939 level. Total compensation of all employees is currently not quite five times what it was in 1939. In the years after World War II, profits gener ally tended to rise rapidly during periods of price inflation. For example, between 1946 and 1948, corporate profits before taxes rose 45 percent Corporate profits after taxes increased over 50 percent During the same years, namely from 1946 to 1948, total compensation of corporate em ployees increased 30 percent. This distortion may well have been the most important single factor precipitating the recession of 1949. Profits dropped about 20 percent in 1949 while labor in come remained unchanged from 1948. The main tenance of labor income helped to prevent the re cession from deepening and lengthening. Again, the Korean inflation favored profits over wages. From the first half of 1950 to the year 1951, corporate earnings before taxes increased ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 30 percent, whereas total compensation of all em ployees rose less than 25 percent. Profits were far less volatile when prices were not booming. From early 1948 to early 1950, profits tended downward while the compensation of employees rose slightly. Between 1951 and the first half of 1955, labor income rose significantly relative to profits. In the first quarter of 1955, corporate profits before taxes were at about the same level as in 1951 while employees’ compensa tion had increased more than one-sixth. As industrial prices started to rise in the middle of 1955, profits moved ahead relatively more than wages. From the first quarter to the fourth quar ter of 1955, profits before taxes increased nearly 15 percent whereas the compensation of employees increased only 7 percent, both computed after sea sonal adjustment. It is generally agreed that inflation is harmful to the economy and especially to fixed income re cipients and should be prevented. From an analy sis of the data since the end of World War n , pe riods of inflation have definitely worked in favor of profits as against labor income. Perhaps some businessmen and groups really favor inflation and have helped fan inflation by their pricing policies. They then follow the maxim that the best defense is the good offense and try to pin the blame on labor, which suffers from inflation and wants no part of it. Corporate profits are now considerably higher in relationship to corporate payrolls than pre-war. These data again demonstrate that corporate profits increase relative to wages of corporation employees during periods of inflation and tend to decline or remain stable when there is no infla tion. The trends within the past year are hardly conducive to sustained prosperity. Corporate profits, before taxes, amounted to 29 cents per dollar of compensation of corporate employees in 1953, slightly over 26 cents in 1954, and then rose to nearly 33 cents late in 1955 and early 1956. Profits of manufacturing corporations tend to be even more volatile than the profits of all corpora tions. In 1955, profits before taxes for all manu facturing corporations were nearly seven times the level of 1939 and more than double those of 1946. The series shows a very sharp rise in manufacturing profits as prices increase and a leveling off when prices are stable. Data are not yet available for the first quarter of 1956, but the trend in 1955, especially the second half, was markedly upward, reflecting the increase in indus trial prices. Profits before taxes of all manufac 249 turing corporations increased 44 percent from the final quarter of 1954 to the final quarter of 1955. Over the same interval, profits per dollar of sales jumped one-fourth and the rate of profit on stock holders’ equity increased by one-third. These are dangerous distortions which must be corrected promptly if a down-tum in business activity is to be avoided. Taking the last five years as a whole, profits before taxes as a ratio to sales of all manufactur ing corporations have been somewhat lower than they were in the immediate post-war years. From a post-war peak of 10.7 percent in 1950, there was a decline to 6.9 percent in 1954 and a rise to 8.5 percent in 1955 with an even higher figure indi cated for the last quarter. In the years imme diately following the war in Korea, a good many manufacturing corporations apparently were op erating under the sound principle of earning size able profits through a rising volume of sales with lower margins. The application of this principle yielded very satisfactory profits in 1952 and 1953. The recession in 1954, attributable to reduced de fense spending and other factors, brought tempo rarily lower profits. Since the second half of 1955, the policy of a rising volume of production and sales associated with lower profit margins has given way to some degree of opportunistic pricing. Persistence in this direction may well precipitate a recession. Declining profit margins were associated with high profits in manufacturing industries over the past decade. In only one year since 1947, namely, the 1954 recession year, did the rate of profits after taxes fall below 10 percent of stockholders’ equity. In only two years did the rate of profits before taxes on stockholders’ equity fall below 20 percent. These are truly very high profit rates and it is clear that manufacturers can cut profit margins much more and still earn handsomely on their investment. The relationship between prices, wages, and profits for all manufacturing corporations com bined is particularly interesting. Between 1947 and 1955, hourly earnings in all manufacturing industries increased a little more than 50 percent and total wages in manufacturing increased 70 percent, whereas prices of industrial products (wholesale prices of all commodities, excluding farm products and food) rose about 23 percent. Profits before taxes based on the Department of Commerce estimates rose almost 50 percent and profits based on the FTC-SEC series increased over 60 percent. Over the period, the ratio of 250 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT profits to sales tended downward. From 1951 to 1955, hourly earnings in all manufacturing industries went up 18 percent whereas prices of industrial goods rose about 1 percent. Corporate profits after taxes in 1955 equalled or exceeded the all-time peak of 1951, but the profit margin on sales dropped measurably. If this general trend of rising wages, stable prices, declining profit margins, and sustained attractive profits were maintained, the economy would be far better off than when suffering the distortions which occur during times of boom and inflation and which bring about recessions and depressions. The data and analyses reveal again and again that periods of rising prices serve to bring marked increases in profits, but operate to the detriment of employees. Periods of price stability bring in creased purchasing power to workers and simul taneously permit employers to earn excellent prof its. It may be exhilarating for executives of cor porations to push up prices and enjoy short-lived big jumps in profits, but such periods are usually followed by sharp declines in profitability. Clearly, history shows the consequences do not justify this policy, but the pattern is often repeated. Perhaps business leaders will ultimately come to recognize the desirability of good profits year in and year out, rather than phenomenal boom-time earnings followed by sharply reduced profits during reces sions which such policies tend to precipitate. Busi nessmen, in considerable measure, can exercise a choice between these two alternatives. Some businessmen have acted sensibly or have been forced to do so because of competition. It is to be hoped that for the best interests of the country as well as for their own benefit, the others will learn to refrain from unnecessary and unwarranted price increases. An analysis of a few manufacturing industries indicates that the iron and steel industry followed highly arbitrary and inflationary pricing policies. Since 1947, steel prices have very closely paralleled steel wage increases. This has happened despite the very marked increase in productivity per manhour in the steel industry. Steel prices have risen far, far more than labor costs per unit of output. The steel industry has repeatedly pushed its prices up far more than the rise in prices for materials used by the steel industry. In 1955, profits before taxes per dollar of sales in the steel industry were nearly 30 percent higher than in 1947-49. The evidence is abundantly clear that the leaders of the steel industry do not believe at all in the con cept of increased volume and lower or even level margins of profit. Instead, the industry has pushed prices upward without any concern for the public interest. The contrast between the price policies of the steel industry and price policies of all manufac turing industries combined is rather startling. Whereas price increases of the steel industry re sulted in parallel movements of steel wage rates and steel prices, the data for all manufacturing shows that from 1947 to 1955, average hourly earnings rose over 50 percent as compared with an increase in prices of manufactured products of less than one-fourth. From 1947 to the first half of 1955, the difference was even greater. This means that manufacturing industries as a whole did share some of the benefits of rising productiv ity with workers. But the steel industry refused to do so. Only because some of the steel price increases were absorbed along the line in fabricat ing industries and because other industries could not or did not engage in the same pricing practices as steel, there were periods of general price sta bility in the past decade and real wages of steel workers and other workers increased. The difference between steel’s pricing policies and that of other industries is revealed in the price data. Finished steel prices in the six months end ing March 1956 were about 75 percent higher than in 1947. Wholesale prices of all commodities other than farm products and foods rose 26 percent over the same period. All the major steel-using indus tries show price increases less than in steel, in some instances substantially less. Heating equip ment prices were 23 percent higher in 1955 than in 1947. For agricultural machinery and equip ment, motor vehicles and electrical machinery, the price increases were between 30 and 40 percent. In construction machinery and equipment, they were nearly 60 percent. These compare with about 75 percent for steel. In some of these steelusing industries, there is a considerable degree of price control by corporations, and more restraint could have been exercised, but in no instance is the record comparable with that of the steel in dustry. The steel industry cannot blame labor for high prices, although wage increases in the steel in dustry have been larger than in manufacturing industries as a whole. Steelworkers have fought to get a fair share of the industry’s huge profits. The workers have been trying to “catch up,” to es tablish a reasonable relationship with profits. The comparison with other industries shows that the ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT blame for the price inflation in steel rests squarely on the employers. The steel industry has demonstrated its dis belief in the principle of higher volume and lower margins. It seeks ever higher profit margins, which its generally monopolistic nature has made possible. For all manufacturing industries com bined, profit margins have tended downward, but not for steel. Despite a spurt in 1955, the ratio of profits before taxes to sales was still lower in 1955 than in 1947-49 for all manufacturing in dustries combined, but for steel it was up 30 percent. It can be stated again and again that if there is any single industry that has followed infla tionary pricing practices, that has shown a cold disdain for the economic welfare of the country, that has truly practiced inflation, that has the least right to hide behind the cloak of favoring a sound dollar and to contend that wage increases are inflationary, it is the steel industry. 7—Uniform Rounds and Patterns? Business sources claim there have been annual “ rounds” of wage increases in every single year since the end of World War n , implying every union has negotiated a higher wage or better fringe benefits for its membership in every year. Further, it is contended that one settlement sets the pattern for every succeeding negotiation. It is implied, if not always expressly stated, that in creases in wages are uniform among different unions and different industries. In all industries wages and salaries have been raised many times and sometimes by sizable amounts over the past decade. Different factors have been influential at different times. As al ready demonstrated, higher wages in the imimediate post-war period were sought almost uni versally by labor in the struggle to keep pace with rising living costs. If there has been a tend ency for “rounds” of wage increases to develop, employers can hardly criticize unions when the initial cause lay in the inflationary swing. Again, in the year following the outbreak of war in Korea, unions struggled to prevent rising prices and booming profits from squeezing the wage earner. In both of these periods of inflation, real wages did not rise. Workers had to push for wage increases to avoid a sharp drop in buying power and an even bigger increase in profits than did occur. The wage increases which brought greater pur chasing power to workers occurred in the two 251 and one-half years before Korea and again after the middle of 1951. The struggle to make up for the lag in the preceding periods carried on for some time. Then, the continued improvements in productivity justified further increases in wages. Labor’s continuing efforts to share in the benefits derived from rising productivity have had a beneficial effect in the total economy. The resulting increase in buying power of consumers gave support to our expanded prosperity. In every year since World War IT, there were wage increases in varying numbers of industries, but there was no fixed pattern. Wage and fringe benefit improvements in key industries or in major corporations have been a guiding and prod ding force for improvements in other industries. But these improvements have not been adopted bodily by one industry from another. There have been broad variations in amounts, timing and spe cific terms. There have been neither rigid wage and fringe benefit patterns, nor uniform economywide rounds of wage increases. In an economic system as varied as ours, such uniformity, except for decent minimum standards, are not possible. A complete analysis of each union settlement or even of the wage changes in each specific in dustry can not readily be made. However, the analysis of only a few wage contracts in one or two years indicates that the variations among companies and industries have been substantial. In 1951 and 1952, the employees in the men’s clothing industry received no wage increases. In 1952, employees of the American Woolen Com pany received a 5 cents per hour increase under the escalator provisions of an earlier contract. In that same year, automobile workers received an advance of 4 cents per hour as an annual im provement factor and 4 cents under the escala tor provisions. On the other hand, in 1952 coal mining workers negotiated an increase of $1.90 per day or nearly 25 cents per hour and the Sin clair Oil contract provided for a 17 cents per hour increase for its employees. Variations similar to these can be found in practically every year. An analysis of changes in average hourly earn ings among major industrial groups does not fully reveal the degree of spread among wage settlements, because variations among industries within each group are obscured by group aver ages. Nonetheless, the figures are significant. Among durable goods industries, between 1947 and 1955, hourly earnings in the primary metal industry increased 85 cents as compared with 51 cents among furniture and fixture producers. In 252 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT the non-durable goods categories, there was a range from 86 cents per hour increase in petro leum and coal products to 35 cents in textile-mill products. In non-manufacturing industries, in creases ranged from 92 cents in bituminous coal mining to 24 cents in laundries. On a percentage basis, the increases also show considerable varia tion from industry to industry. Among major manufacturing groups, hourly earnings between 1947 and 1955 increased from 62 percent in print ing and publishing to 34 percent in textile-mill products. A separate analysis of the periods from 1947 through 1951 and from 1951 to 1955 likewise shows considerable variations among major in dustry groups. Again, it should be emphasized that if the variations were presented for more detailed industrial classifications, the dispersion would be much greater. If the analysis covered each different contract, there would be an even more pronounced variation. Generally, it is those same anti-labor sources who expound the false thesis that wage increases are the cause of inflation, who also misrepresent the facts concerning rounds and patterns of wage increases. Certainly, the last ten years have not only justified, but have necessitated higher wages, and it is to be expected that all workers in all industries would have shared in varying measure in the rising income, increasing productivity and expanding prosperity of the country. In view of the marked expansion of the economy in recent years, it is significant that the variations have been so great among different industries and companies. 8—Pricing Policies and Financing Expansion Risk capital, according to most business spokes men and economic textbooks, is the source of funds for business investment in the American economy. A business firm that seeks to expand its productive capacity floats new stock issues and sells them to investors. In that way, the company increases its funds for expansion and spreads its ownership. This is a good theory, but it does not seem to be working in practice. New stock issues pro vide less and less of a source of money for ad ditional investment. Actually, this source of funds has become relatively insignificant as com pared with total investment outlays. In the dec ade from 1946 through 1955, all corporations in the United States, excluding banks and insurance companies, invested nearly $200 billion in new plants and equipment It is startling to note that less than 10 percent of the funds needed for these purposes was raised by the sale of common and preferred stocks. The major source of corporate funds for ex pansion is internal financing—retained profits after the distribution of dividends and deprecia tion allowances. There has been some borrowing from banks and insurance companies and very limited flotations of corporate bonds. The over whelming portion of funds for corporate expan sion has come from retained profits and deprecia tion charges. During World War n and during and after Korea, industry was given the opportunity to ac celerate depreciation charges on investments deemed essential for the national security. Further, the tax laws of the United States have been revised to allow all plant and equipment outlays to be depreciated at a more rapid than normal rate. This means more internal money for investment. The March, 1955 Newsletter of the National City Bank of New York stated: “Depredation charges are important be cause they constitute an increasing ‘internal’ source of funds for financing business. This is due to the fact that they are an expense item involving no cash outlay at the time but representing instead the recovery in piece meal fashion of the original capital invest ment in plant and equipment.” In the ten years from 1946 to 1955 depreda tion allowances of United States corporations totaled nearly $90 billion, thus providing nearly half of the money needed for all of the new plants and equipment built and installed. Normal de predation charges would have been far less. The larger depreciation allowances might be looked upon as extra profits. For a time after World War II, business spokes men contended that actual profits were less than reported profits because depreciation charges, based on original cost rather than replacement cost, understated the cost of fixed assets being consumed in the process of production. As a re sult of the special accelerated depredation allowed liberally for all investments related to defense, and the liberalization provided for in the new tax legislation, it is likely that profit figures at the present time understate, if anything, the true level of profits. Total depreciation charges now are probably too high, even on the basis of replacement cost, in relation to the life of depre ciable assets. In any case, the old argument on ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT this point is not presented any more except as a last resort type of exhortation. Undistributed profits of corporations have pro vided approximately as much funds for invest ment over the past decade as have depreciation allowances. Retained earnings have risen sub stantially in the past year. In 1955, undistributed profits were about 50 percent higher than the average for the years 1952 through 1954, even though dividends paid in 1955 were about 25 per cent higher than in 1952. Increasingly, business spokesmen have con tended that prices must be increased so that higher profits can be earned in order that all in vestment outlays of existing corporations can be financed internally. The Wall Street Journal of March 23,1956 reports: “Ernest T. Weir, veteran steel maker urged industry to raise steel prices enough to get the money needed for expansion, and sug gested steel company managements do so without waiting for price leadership from the U. S. Steel Corporation, the largest producer. . . . He said higher prices are necessary to obtain the money for construction of new steelmaking facilities the country needs.” An editorial in the March 8, 1955 issue of the Journal of Commerce declares: “The ability of business to meet an increase in its aggregate capital requirements that may reach $12 billion this year without re course to external financing seems an anom aly . . . It demonstrates how far American industry has gone in securing sources of funds outside the bank and capital market In essence, the leaders of the steel industry and of other industries are asking the American people to finance plant expansion through higher and higher prices. In effect, they propose that risk capital be supplied by consumers without any obligation whatsoever on the part of corporations and without the consumers getting any evidences of ownership or any benefit from their forced “ investment.” Instead of charging reasonable prices and making reasonable profits and giving the American investor an opportunity to partici pate in the growth of American industry, these so-called “venturesome” businessmen propose a sort of levy for investment on the consumer. The big trouble is that the consumer gets nothing for his “investment.” Corporate executives, in es sence, admit that they can fix prices at will, ir respective of market conditions, and they propose 253 to “fix” prices higher and higher. This is “the public be damned” view with a vengeance. If American business is not going to float new securities to provide some portion of the funds needed for new and expanded facilities, how can the American investor participate in the growth of the American economy? Of course, he can buy stocks that now exist, but this is merely a matter of transferring shares from one investor to an other and does not really make funds directly available for industrial expansion of existing cor porations. What will happen to the money that investors are putting into mutual funds? These funds will have to buy existing securities from other investors. This is hardly the process for permitting or encouraging private investment in American expansion. Where is the virtue in sav ing? How will Americans use their savings to own shares in our expanding economy? Where is the “ democracy of corporate ownership” so often espoused? If ever there was a proposal that strikes at the very heart of free enterprise and of democratic ownership of large corporations, this proposal to raise prices and further increase prof its to finance expansion is it. Also, from an economic point of view, the sug gestion of the steel industry and other industries is totally unsound. Prices would be raised to a point where purchasing power would be inade quate to take the goods and services of American industry off the market. Where does industry expect to find a market for its growing output if it prices more and more customers out of the mar ket? Further, what will the higher income indi viduals do with their savings? Mortgage financ ing cannot provide the entire outlet. Government deficit financing is hardly desirable in itself and if deficits can be avoided there will not be additional government bonds to absorb savings. In effect, this proposal is a sure way to stop the growth of the American economy and create depressions and mass unemployment. Some of the spokesmen for higher prices and exclusive financing of expansion of existing cor porations from internal sources have even sug gested that security prices are not high enough to warrant new equity flotations. Such state ments, made in the face of a doubling of stock market prices in the past three years, obviously do not warrant any serious hearing. It is high time that the insatiable seeking for ever-higher profits by some of our business lead ers give way to some concern for consumers and investors and for the general health of the Amer ican economy. 254 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CHARTS A N D TABLES CHART 1 Total Grass National ProductinCorrent&1 9 5 5 Prices 400 billions ofdollars *¥annualrata,seasonallyadjusted,6m os.endingMarchW56 SOURCE: UnitedStatesDepartmentofGommeroe 255 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT TABLE 1 GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT, TOTAL AND PER CAPITA IN CURRENT AND 1955 PRICES, 1929-56 Gross national product ($ Billions) Per capita Current prices 1955 prices Current prices 1955 prices 1929..................................... ............................. 104.4 181.9 857 1,493 1939..................................... ............................. 1940..................................... ............................. 91.1 100.6 190.4 207 7 696 761 1,453 1,572 1941..................................... 1942..................................... 1943..................................... 1944..................................... 1945..................................... ............................. ............................. 125.8 159.1 192.5 211.4 213.6 240.3 271.1 301.2 324.1 317.5 943 1,179 1,408 1,527 1,526 1,801 2,010 2,203 2,342 2,269 1946..................................... 1947..................................... 1948..................................... 1949..................................... 1950..................................... ............................. ............................. ............................. ............................. ............................. 209.2 232.2 257.3 257.3 285.1 283.1 282.7 295.8 294.9 321.8 1,480 1,611 1,755 1,725 1,880 2,002 1,961 2,017 1,977 2,122 1951..................................... 1952..................................... 1953..................................... 1954..................................... 1955..................................... ............................. ............................. ............................. ............................. ............................. 328.2 345.2 364.5 360.5 387.2 345.4 357.5 374.3 365.4 387.2 2,126 2,198 2,283 2,220 2,343 2,238 2,277 2,345 2,250 2,343 1956‘ ................................... ............................. 397.9 397.2 2,386 2,382 Year ............................. ............................. * Annual rate, seasonally adjusted, six months ending March 1956. SOURCE.—UnitedStatesDepartmentofCommerce. 256 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CHART 2 Evidence of America's Economic6 (owth 1 9 2 9 - 5 6 Index1947-49*100 '40 '41 42 '43 '44 45 46 47 48 49 '50 '51 '52 '53 154 '55 56 onnuol rote,seasonally adjusted, 6 mos.endingMarch 1956 VMonthly overage 6 mos. ending March 1956 SOURCE: United Stott* Department of Commerce ; Board of Governors, f ederet Reserve System 257 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT TABLE 2 EVIDENCES OF AMERICA’S ECONOMIC GROWTH, 1929-56 FRB Index (1947-49 = 100) Total industrial production Year Durable manufactures Index (1947-49 = 100) Non-durable manufactures Electric power production, (monthly avg.) 1929...................... .................. 59 60 56 41.0 1939...................... .................. 1940...................... .................. 58 67 49 63 66 69 48.9 54.6 1941...................... 1942...................... 1943...................... 1944...................... 1945...................... .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 87 106 127 125 107 91 126 162 159 123 84 93 103 99 96 63.2 70.7 81.1 84.8 82.3 1946...................... 1947...................... 1948...................... 1949...................... 1950...................... .................. . ............... .................. .................. .................. 90 100 104 97 112 86 101 104 95 116 95 99 102 99 111 81.8 93.2 102.1 104.6 117.9 1951...................... 1952...................... 1953...................... 1954...................... 1955...................... .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 120 124 134 125 139 128 136 153 137 155 114 114 118 116 126 131.4 140.4 155.9 165.2 189.5 143* 160a 129* 204.0b 1956....................... .................. * Monthly average, six months ending March 1956, seasonally adjusted. b Monthly average, six months ending March 1956. SOURCE.—UnitedStatesDepartmentofCommerce; BoardofGovernors, FederalReserveSystem. 258 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CHART 3 LaborForce and Employment 1929*1956 °fannual rate, seasonally adjusted,6 mos. ending March 1956 source i United States Deportments of Labor and Commerce ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 259 TABLE 3 THE LABOR FORCE, 1929-56 (Thousands of persons) Non-agri cultural Non-agriemployment cultural ias % of total employment employment Civilian employment Unemployment: Year Total labor force (includ ing armed forces) Civilian labor force Total 1929 49,440 49,180 47,630 37,180 78.1 1,550 3.2 1939 1940 55,600 56,180 55,230 55,640 45,750 47,520 36,140 37,980 79.0 80.0 9,480 8,120 17.2 14.6 1941 1942 1943 1944........... 1945 57,530 60,380 64,560 66,040 65,290 55,910 56,410 55,540 54,630 53,860 50,350 53,750 54,470 53,960 52,820 41,250 44,500 45,390 45,010 44,240 81.9 82.8 83.3 83.3 83.8 5,560 2,660 1,070 670 1,040 9.9 4.7 1.9 1.2 1.9 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 60,970 61,758 62,898 63,721 64,749 57,520 60,168 61,442 62,105 63,099 55,250 58,027 59,378 58,710 59,957 46,930 49,761 51,405 50,684 52,450 85.0 85.8 86.6 86.3 87.5 2,270 2,142 2,064 3,395 3,142 3.9 3.6 3.4 5.5 5.0 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 65,983 66,560 67,362 67,818 68,896 62,884 62,966 63,815 64,468 65,847 61,005 61,293 62,213 61,238 63,193 53,951 54,488 55,651 54,734 56,464 88.4 88.9 89.5 89.4 89.4 1,879 1,673 1,602 3,230 2,654 3.0 2.7 2.5 5.0 4.0 69,307 66,378 63,780 57,531 90.2 2,598 3.9 1956* Annual rate, seasonally adjusted, six months ending March 1956. SOURCE.—United States Departments of Labor and Commerce. Number % of civilian labor force 260 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT CHART 4 PerCapitaDisposable ncomeSConsumptionExpenditures $2000 (in 1955 prices, 1939-56) '40 41 42 43 44 45 '46 47 48 49 '50 '51 152 ‘53 '54 '55 '56 a/annual rate, seasonally adjusted, 6 mot.ending March 1956 SO u RCE: United States Department of Commerce ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 261 TABLE 4 TOTAL AND PER CAPITA DISPOSABLE INCOME AND PERSONAL CONSUMPTION EXPENDITURES IN 1955 PRICES, 1939-56 Disposable personal income Personal consumption expenditures Total ($ Billion) Per capita ($) Total ($ Billion) 1939........................................ ................................ 135.6 1,037 130.3 994 1940........................................ 1941........................................ 1942........................................ 1943........................................ 1944........................................ ................................ ................................ ................................ ................................ ................................ 145.5 169.4 192.9 206.7 223.4 1,101 1,270 1,430 1,512 1,613 137.5 149.2 147.3 155.6 167.1 1,040 1,118 1,092 1,138 1,207 1945........................................ 1946........................................ 1947........................................ 1948........................................ 1949........................................ ................................ ................................ ................................ ................................ ................................ 223.8 218.7 202.6 208.9 211.7 1,600 1,547 1,406 1,424 1,418 181.1 201.4 197.8 197.8 203.1 1,295 1,424 1,373 1,349 1,361 1950........................................ 1951........................................ 1952........................................ 1953........................................ 1954........................................ 1955........................................ ................................ ................................ ................................ ................................ ................................ ................................ 229.5 233.3 238.8 250.7 254.0 269.3 1,513 1,512 1,522 1,570 1,564 1,629 216.0 215.0 220.3 230.8 235.8 252.4 1,424 1,393 1,403 1,446 1,452 1,527 1956a...................................... ................................ 276.0 1,655 257.5 1,543 Year * Annual rate, seasonally adjusted, six months ending March 1950. SOURCE.—UnitedStatesDepartmentofCommerce. Per capita ($) 262 ECONOMIC C H AR T REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 5 L a b o r 's S h a r e o f N a t i o n a l I n c o m e , P e r s o n a l J n c o m f t a n d N o n - a g r i c u l t u r a l In c o m e 1 9 4 6 * 5 6 Non-agricultural Income-*... Personal Income 60 Labor's share of income f i a s g M y ripens nee the late 1940‘s, bux recently the mproyement has halted or been reversed 50 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 °/onnuot rate, seasonally adjusted, 6 mos. ending March 1956 SOURCE: United States Department of Commerce ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 263 TABLE 5 LABOR’S SHARE OF NATIONAL INCOME, PERSONAL INCOME AND NONAGRICULTURAL INCOME, 1946-56 Billions of dollars Year Total national income Total personal income Total nonagric. personal income1 Labor income2 National income Labor income as percent of: Personal income Nonagric. income 1946.................. 1947.................. 1948.................. 1949.................. 1950.................. .............. .............. .............. .............. .............. 179.6 197.2 221.6 216.2 240.0 178.0 190.5 208.7 206.8 227.1 161.1 172.8 188.5 190.8 210.5 113.8 125.2 137.9 137.4 150.3 63.4 63.5 62.2 63.6 62.6 63.9 65.7 66.1 66.4 66.2 70.6 72.5 73.2 72.0 71.4 1951................... 1952.................. 1953.................. 1954.................. 1955.................. .............. .............. .............. .............. .............. 277.0 289.5 303.6 299.7 322.6 255.3 271.1 286.2 287.6 303.2 235.7 253.1 270.2 271.9 288.4 175.6 190.5 204.6 202.8 215.5 63.4 65.8 67.4 67.7 66.8 68.8 70.3 71.5 70.5 71.1 74.5 75.3 75.7 74.6 74.7 1956“................ .............. 333.0 312.6 298.2 222.9 66.9 71.3 74.7 1Personal income exclusive of net income of unincorporated farm enterprises, farm wages, agricultural net interest, and net div idends paid by agricultural corporations. J Compensation of employees, excluding employer contributions for social insurance. * Annual rate, seasonally adjusted, six months ending March 1956. SOURCE.—United States Department of Commerce. 264 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E C H A R T PRESIDENT 6 Disposable Income,ConsumerExpendituresand m ConsumerDebt 1 9 4 6 - 5 6 (index 1947-49- 100) Consumer Debt rose from93 of Disposable Incomeattse begi ining of 95?,to 11%at i 1beginni igof 1955.Duringthese four years,Disposable Income & Consumer Expenditures rose 20%, while Consumer Debt ju nped ovir 70% 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 ° / annual rata, seasonally adjusted, 6 b/ end of Morch 1956 mos.ending March 1936 SOURCIS United States Department of Commerce; Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 265 TABLE 6 DISPOSABLE PERSONAL INCOME, CONSUMER EXPENDITURES AND CONSUMER DEBT, 1946-56 Indexes (1947-49 = 100) Billions of dollars Period Personal Disposable consumption income expenditures Consumer debt1 Personal Disposable consumption expenditures income Consumer debt1 1946................... 1947................... 1948................... 1949................... 1950................... 1951................... 1952................... 1953................... 1954................... 1955................... 159.2 169.0 187.6 188.2 206.1 226.1 236.7 250.4 254.8 269.3 146.6 165.0 177.6 180.6 194.0 208.3 218.3 230.6 236.5 252.3 8.4 11.6 14.4 17.1 20.8 21.4 25.8 29.5 30.1 36.2 88 93 103 104 114 125 130 138 140 148 84 95 102 104 111 119 125 132 136 145 58 81 100 119 145 149 180 205 210 252 1954: 1 Q........... 2 Q........... 3 Q........... 4 Q........... 1955:1 Q........... 2 Q........... 3 Q........... 4 Q........... 1956................... 253.1 253.9 254.5 257.8 261.0 267.1 271.7 276.0 276.5“ 232.2 235.1 237.9 241.0 245.8 250.5 255.7 257.2 258.0b 27.3 28.7 28.9 30.1 29.9 32.5 34.3 36.2 35.5b 139 140 140 142 144 147 149 152 152* 133 135 136 138 141 144 147 147 148 ‘ 190 200 201 210 208 226 239 252 247b 1 End of period. • Annual rate, seasonally adjusted, six months ending March 1956. fc End of March 1956. SOURCE.—UnitedStatesDepartment of Commerce; Boardof Governors, Federal Reserve System. 266 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE C H A R T PRESIDENT 7 Major Wage and Price Movements Since the end of World War II (Index 1947-49- looj 150 Manufaduring 1ourlyeainings,/ 140 130 /' / ( Tkf.i\sofmMlitiM1 Jan.l» 0 120 110 90 tf' / 't/ /j /j! /] // 70 60 SOURCE sU.S.Department of Labor esalepriiea^nm-faim&food-w / V Consulter Prices / _ ry / ji / / / 4t -Af' r ~ ~ V V / 100 80 /•** | PostwarBoom dan.1946- Jan.1948 Whoesakpr ces,8llciimmditiis Kom om - Jur r el950 -Julimi f 5yean ofpricestablity July 1951March19!6 fk ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 267 TABLE 7 PRICES AND MANUFACTURING HOURLY EARNINGS, END OF EACH QUARTER, 1946-56 (1947-49 = 100) Wholesale price index Period Consumer price index All com modities Other than food & farm products Index of straighttime hourly earnings in manufacturing 1946: Mar..................... June.................... Sept..................... Dec...................... 1947: Mar..................... June.................... Sept..................... Dec..................... 1948: Mar..................... June.................... Sept..................... Dec...................... 1949: Mar..................... June.................... Sept..................... Dec...................... 1950: Mar..................... June.................... Sept.................... Dec..................... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ....... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... 78.0 79.8 87.4 91.9 93.7 94.2 98.3 100.2 100.2 103.1 104.8 103.0 101.9 102.0 102.1 101.0 100.7 101.8 104.4 106.9 70.8 73.3 80.6 91.6 95.4 94.3 98.4 102.6 102.5 104.6 106.1 104.0 100.9 98.2 98.3 97.7 98.5 100.2 107.1 112.1 73.1 75.5 80.2 89.2 93.6 93.9 96.9 100.4 101.6 102.5 105.1 105.4 103.3 100.1 100.0 101.3 100.7 102.2 108.2 114.1 77.6 81.8 85.1 86.6 89.8 93.5 95.3 96.7 98.5 100.9 104.7 105.4 106.2 106.6 106.3 106.2 107.5 109.0 110.6 114.8 1961: Mar............. : . . . Juno.................... Sept..................... Dec...................... 1952: Mar..................... June.................... Sept..................... Dec...................... 1953: Mar..................... June.................... Sept..................... Dec...................... 1954: Mar..................... June.................... Sept..................... Dec...................... 1955: Mar..................... June.................... Sept..................... Dec...................... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... 110.3 110.8 111.6 113.1 112.4 113.4 114.1 114.1 113.6 114.5 115.2 114.9 114.8 115.1 114.7 114.3 114.3 114.4 114.9 114.7 116.5 115.1 113.4 113.5 112.3 111.2 111.8 109.6 110.0 109.5 111.0 110.1 110.5 110.0 110.0 109.5 110.0 110.3 111.7 111.3 117.3 116.2 114.8 114.6 113.8 112.6 113.2 112.9 113.4 113.9 114.7 114.6 114.2 114.2 114.4 114.9 115.6 115.6 118.5 119.8 116.5 118.8 120.3 121.9 123.4 124.2 126.6 128.1 130.4 132.0 134.3 135.1 135.9 136.6 136.6 137.4 139.0 139.8 142.1 143.6 1956: Mar..................... ............... 114.7 112.8 121.0 146.0 SOURCE.—United States Department of Labor. 268 ECONOMIC REPORT OF T H E PRESIDENT CHART 8 Productivity^ Real HourlyEarnings in Manufacturing 1947-1955 140 lndex(i947»ioo) y? 130 X 120 0ut| lutpermi n-hour/ 110 — Real griss hourly earnings 100 / w 90 / 80 / / 70 1939 / / / erofw anuficturing Purchasiigpow agesinm ithrisirgproductivity hasnotkeptpacew IS47 IS49 IS50 1951 Vpreliminary source : United States Department of Labor IS52 1953 1954 195! ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 269 TABLE 8 PHYSICAL O U T P U T P E R M A N - H O U R A N D R E A L GROSS H O U R L Y EARNINGS IN MANUFACTURING, 1939-55 (1947=100) Output per man-hour Year Real gross hourly earnings 96.0 82.3 1947........... 100.0 100.0 194 9 108.6 106.3 195 0 117.7 110.0 1939.............. 195 1 ...... 117.5 110.6 195 2 ..... 119.1 114.0 195 3 ..... 122.7 119.4 195 4 ..... 127.5P 121.4 195 5 .....135.0P 126.8 i’ Preliminary. SOURCE.— United States Department of Labor. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE 270 PRESIDENT CHART 9 Indexes of ProductionandTotal Man-hours WorkedinManufacturing Industries 1946-55 150 Index (1947-49*100) 140 130 120 Miinufactu ing prodiction y / 110 / 100 // / \> V 90 / / __ / / / Aggrei late man hours // Rising output with ierclemplD|fment Man-lii tursreqi ired per unit of output have dr opped substanf ially 80 SOURCE * Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System; U.S.Department of Labor ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 271 TABLE 9 INDEXES OF PRODUCTION AND TOTAL MAN-HOURS WORKED IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES, 1946-55 (1947-49=100) Manufacturing production Year 1946 Aggregate man-hours 90 99 100 105 103 103 1949 97 92 195 0 113 101 194 7 194 8 . 195 1 ........... 121 108 195 2 ........... 125 108 195 3 ........... 136 114 195 4 ........... 127 101 195 5 ........... 141 108 SOURCE.—Board of Governors,Federal Reserve System; United State* Department of Labor. 272 ECONOMIC C H A R T REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 10 Average GrossHourlyandWeeklyEarnings in ManufacturinginCurrent and1947-49 dollars foOOdollars per hour 1.50 r ________________________ — -194;'-49foliars & £ J .50 C O .. £2 1.00 -Cuirent dolla Re )rniigsIsem ost wlen|iricesari!St<ble .00 8O.00 dollarsperweiik — r - 194;'-491ollar5 6O.00 1 4O.00 '■*£ -Cu rrent dollsrs 20.00 Wo rkers'w artiinebjyin )P0 wer ha: beenre achedan lexi:eedsd .00 19:39'4 4 4 4 % 4 4 4 4 4!) '5 '5 ‘52 ‘53 '54 '55 '56 SOURCE: United States Department of Labor ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 273 TABLE 10 AVERAGE GROSS HOURLY AND WEEKLY EARNINGS IN MANUFACTURING, IN CURRENT AND 1947-49 DOLLARS, 1939-55 Current dollars 1947-49 dollars Avg. gross hourly earnings Avg. gross weekly earnings Avg. gross hourly earnings Avg. gross weekly earnings 1939..................................... ................................. 1940..................................... ................................. 0.63 0.66 23.86 25.20 1.06 1.10 40.17 42.07 1941......................... ........... 1942..................................... 1943..................................... 1944..................................... 1945..................................... ................................. ................................. ................................. ................................. ................................. 0.73 0.85 0.96 1.02 1.02 29.58 36.65 43.14 46.08 44.39 1.16 1.22 1.30 1.36 1.33 47.03 52.58 58.30 61.28 57.72 1946..................................... 1947..................................... 1948..................................... 1949..................................... 1950..................................... ................................. ................................. ................................. ................................. ................................. 1.09 1.24 1.35 1.40 1.47 43.82 49.97 54.14 54.92 59.33 1.31 1.30 1.31 1.38 1.43 52.54 52.32 52.67 53.95 57.71 1951..................................... 1952..................................... 1953..................................... 1954..................................... 1955..................................... ................................. ................................. ................................. ................................. ....... ...................... 1.59 1.67 1.77 1.81 1.88 64.71 67.97 71.69 71.86 76.52 1.43 1.47 1.55 1.58 1.64 58.30 59.89 62.67 62.60 66.83 Year SOURCE.—United States Department of Labor. 274 ECONOMIC CHART REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 11 Personal Taxes and Corporate Taxes 1939-56 40 billions of dollars / * \ 30 /f Pe sons IT©ces- / / / \ / t 20 10 | jf / / 0 / / b A \ L / \ : i j \ 4 \ 48 49 ‘5 ‘51 ‘52 ’53 '54 '55 '56 ° / annual rate, seasonally adjusted, 6 mos. ending March 1956 SOUR.C E: U.S. Department of Commerce i A ■Cor iorat i Taxi \ // > / i As betv reen indii idua ls& :orp iratibos, th irelijtive burijen cfta> atio iha; s beenbi me ncn asin f t i fm ividipals / 1939 '4 '4 42 43 N / / 1 V\ ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E TA B LE PRESIDENT 275 11 PERSO N AL T A X E S AN D CORPORATE TA X E S, 1939-56 Billions of dollars Personal taxes Year 1939 1940 Corporate taxes 2 .4 2 .6 1.4 2 .8 194 1 1942 194 3 194 4 1945 3 .3 6 .0 17.8 18.9 20.9 7 .6 11.4 14.1 12.9 10.7 194 6 1947 194 8 194 9 1950 18.8 21.5 21.1 18.7 20.9 9 .1 11.3 12.5 10.4 17.8 29.3 34.4 3 5 .8 32.8 33.9 22.5 19.8 21.3 17.1 22.0 36.0 23.1 195 1 195 2 195 3 1954 1955 ........ ...................................... 1956*...................................................... * Annual rate, seasonally adjusted, six months ending March 1956. SOURCE.—United States Department of Commerce. 276 ECONOMIC C H A R T REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 12 Profits for all Corporations 1939-56 ° / annual rate, seasonally adjusted, 6 mos. ending M arch 1956 source : United S ta te s D e p a rtm e n t o f C o m m erce ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 277 TABLE 12 PROFITS FOR ALL CORPORATIONS, 1939-56 (Billions of dollars) Profits Profits Profits before taxes, before after after inventory Year taxes taxes valuation ____________________________________________________________________________________________ adjustment 193 9 1940 6.4 9.3 5.0 6.5 5.7 9.1 1 2 3 4 5 17.0 20.9 24.6 23.3 19.0 9.4 9.5 10.5 10.4 8.3 14.5 19.7 23.8 23.0 18.4 1946 194 7 194 8 194 9 195 0 22.6 29.5 32.8 26.2 40.0 13.4 18.2 20.3 15.8 22.1 17.3 23.6 30.6 28.1 35.1 1 9 51:........................................................................................................ 195 2 195 3 1 9 5 4 . . . . ................................................................................................. 1 955:................................ ....................................................................... 41.2 35.9 38.3 34.0 43.8 18.7 16.1 17.0 17.0 21.8 39.9 36.9 37.2 33.8 41.8 1956“ ........................................................................................................ 46.2 23.0 42.8 194 194 194 194 194 * Annual rate, seasonally adjusted, six months ending March 1956. SOURCE.—United States Department of Commerce. 278 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT CHART 13 Corporate Profits8 CorporatePayrolls 1939-56 * Estimated °fannualrate,seasonally adjusted, 6 mos. ending March 1956 SOURC E»United States Department of Commerce ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 279 T A B L E 13 CORPORATE PROFITS AND CORPORATE PAYROLLS, 1939-56 Profits Before After taxes taxes ($ Billion) Year Compensation of employees Cents of corporate profit per dollar of employee compensation ($ Billion) Before taxes After taxes 1939........................ ................ 1940........................ ................ 6.4 9.3 5.0 6.5 29.3 32.3 21.8 28.8 17.1 20.1 1941........................ 1942........................ 1943........................ 1944........................ 1945........................ ................ ................ ................ ................ ................ 17.0 20.9 24.6 23.3 19.0 9.4 9.5 10.5 10.4 8.3 41.1 52.3 63.6 66.5 63.5 41.4 40.0 38.7 35.0 29.9 22.9 18.2 16.5 15.6 13.1 1946........................ 1947........................ 1948........................ 1949........................ 1950........................ ................ ................ ................ ................ ................ 22.6 29.5 32.8 26.2 40.0 13.4 18.2 20.3 15.8 22.1 69.0 b l.2 90.0 87.4 96.9 32.8 36.3 36.4 30.0 41.3 19.4 22.4 22.6 18.1 22.8 1951........................ 1952........................ 1953........................ 1954........................ 1955........................ ................ ................ ................ ................ ................ 41.2 35.9 38.3 34.0 43.8 18.7 16.1 17.0 17.0 21.8 111.9 120.5 131.0 128.8 137.0* 36.8 29.8 29.2 26.4 32.0 16.7 13.4 13.0 13.2 15.9 1956*...................... ................ 46.2 23.0 141.7* 32.6* 16.2* * Estimated. ■ Annual rate, seasonally adjusted, six months ending March 1956. SOURCE.—UnitedStatesDepartmentofCommerce. 280 ECONOMIC REPORT OF T H E PRESIDENT C H A R T 14 CorporateProfits8 RatioofProfits toSales, All Manufacturing Industries 1939-56 billions of dollars * Estimated ? annual rate. 6 mos. ending March 1956 SOURCE-' United States Department of Commerce percent ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 281 TABLE 14 CORPORATE PROFITS AND RATIO OF PROFITS TO SALES, ALL CORPORATE MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES, 1939-56 Year 1939........................................ .................................... 1940........................................ .................................... Ratio to sales (%) Profits before taxes ($ Billion) Profits after taxes ($ Billion) Before taxes After taxes 3.6 5.5 2.9 3.8 6.3 8.4 5.1 5.8 1941........................................ 1942............................ ........... 1943........................................ 1944........................................ 1945........................................ .................................... .................................... .................................... .................................... .................................... 10.8 12.4 14.2 13.2 9.9 5.6 5.1 5.6 5.5 4.0 11.7 10.7 10.0 8.7 7.1 6.1 4.4 3.9 3.6 2.9 1946.......... .......................... 1947............................ ........... 1948........................................ 1949....................................... 1950........................................ .................................... .................................... .................................... .................................... .................................... 11.4 16.5 18.1 14.1 23.3 6.7 10.1 11.0 8.4 12.4 8.3 9.3 9.2 7.6 10.7 4.9 5.7 5.6 4.6 5.7 1951........................................ 1952........................................ 19&3........................................ 1954........................................ 1955........................................ .................................... .................................... .................................... .................................... .................................... 24.5 20.0 21.4 17.8 24.4* 10.3 8.3 8.8 8.8 11.9* 9.8 7.8 7.8 6.9 8.5* 4.1 3.2 3.2 3.4 4.1* 1956*...................................... .................................... 25.7* 12.6* 8.6* 4.3* * Estimated. * Annual rate, seasonally adjusted, six months ending March 1956. SOURCE.—UnitedStalesDepartmentofCommerce. 282 ECONOMIC REPORT OF T H E PRESIDENT C H A R T 15 Annual Rates of Profit onStockholders' Equity, All ManufacturingCorporations. 1947-56 30% ° / annual rate,6 mos. ending M arch 1956 SOURCE* Federal Trade C om m ission-S ecu rities & Exchange Commission ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 283 TABLE IS ANNUAL RATES OP PROFITS ON STOCKHOLDERS’ EQUITY, ALL MANUFACTURING CORPORATIONS, 1947-56 Before taxes (%) Year After taxes (%) 1947 1948 194 9 1950 ...... 25.0 ...... 25.1 ...... 18.1 ...... 27.2 15.1 15.6 11.3 14.9 195 1 1952 1953 195 4 195 5 ...... 28.0 ...... 22.1 ...... 22.6 ...... 18.0 ...... 23.8 12.1 10.3 10.5 9.9 12.6 1956*................................................ ...... 25.0 13.5 Annual rate, six months ending March 1956. SOURCE.— Federal Trade Commission— Securities & Exchange Commission. 284 ECONOMIC REPORT OF T H E PRESIDENT C H A R T 16 Trends of Prices, Profits 8 HourlyEarnings InManufacturingIndustries 1939-56 175 Index(i947-49’ I00) 44 45 '46 47 48 49 '50 '51 '52 '53 ‘54 155 '56 # Estimated ^annual rate,seasonally adjusted, 6 mos. ending March 1956 source : United States *>/ average,6 mos.ending March 1956 Departments of Labor and Commerce ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 285 TABLE 16 TRENDS OF PRICES, PROFITS AND HOURLY EARNINGS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES, 1939-56 (1947-49=100) Wholesale prices, other than farm products and food Year Index of manufacturing corporate income Before taxes After taxes Index of average gross hourly earnings, manufacturing industries Index of manufacturing wages and salaries 1939............. ............ 1940............ ............ 58.1 59.4 22 34 30 39 47.6 49.7 30.7 35.2 ............ ............ ............ ............ ............ 63.7 68.3 69.3 70.4 71.3 66 76 87 81 60 52 52 57 56 41 54.9 64.2 72.3 76.7 77.0 49.0 69.8 92.3 96.9 86.3 1946.............. ............ 1947.............. ............ 1948............ ............ 1949.............. ............ 1950.............. ............ 78.3 95.3 103.4 101.3 105.0 70 101 110 86 142 68 103 112 86 126 81.7 93.1 101.6 105.4 110.2 82.4 96.0 104.9 99.1 111.6 1951.............. ............ 1952.............. ............ 1953.............. ............ 1954.............. ............ 1955.............. ............ 115.9 113.2 114.0 114.5 117.0 149 122 130 109 149* 105 84 90 90 121* 119.6 125.7 133.2 136.2 141.5 131.5 142.1 157.7 149.2 162.9 1 9 5 6 ..:.................... 120.0“ 157* 128* 145.3 171.5* 1941............. 1942............ 1943............. 1944............ 1945............ » Average, six months ending March 1956. * Estimated. SOURCE.—United States Department of Labor; United States Department of Commerce. 286 ECONOMIC CHART REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 17 Prices,Wages8 Profits,Steel Industryandall ManufacturingCorporations 1947*56 (m m ) PRIMARY IRON 4STEEL INDUSTRY ALL MANUFACTURING CORPORATIONS 220 200 180 160 Gross hou ly r a m in a i ^ / S 140 a $ profit i before tm 7 120 ...... — ^ W t o T e i atepiices"i tderthsnfi rm ifo o d p 100 — b Profits i s W 8 8 l e s - 80 I.M u« ip. ip> i * production workers in blast furnace*, steel works, and rolling mill* monthly average, 6 mos. ending March 1956 annual rat#, lost quarter 1955 SOURCCi United States Department of Labor; Federal Ttode Commission-Securities Exchange Commission ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 287 TABLE 17 PRICES, WAGES AND PROFITS, STEEL INDUSTRY AND ALL MANUFACTURING CORPORATIONS, 1947-56 (1947-49=100) Primary iron and steel industry Year 1947............. 1948............. 1949............. 1950............. All manufacturing corporations Finished Profits before taxes Gross hourly wholesale earnings 1 prices $ As % of sales Wholesale Gross prices other hourly than farms and earnings food products Profits before taxes $ As % of sales .......... .......... .......... .......... 92.5 101.6 105.8 108.7 89.1 101.3 109.7 115.2 89.1 118.0 92.9 165.5 96.5 108.0 95.6 113.3 93.0 101.6 105.4 110.2 95.3 103.4 101.3 105.0 100.6 111.7 87.6 140.9 105.7 105.7 88.6 120.0 1951............. .......... 1952............. 1953............. 1954............. .......... 1955............. .......... 121.5 128.0 138.9 141.5 152.4 124.5 127.2 136.9 142.8 149.5 210.3 113.0 173.0 114.3 207.7 140.7 82.3 109.7 92.9 128.3 119.6 125.7 133.2 136.2 141.5 115.9 113.2 114.0 114.5 117.0 157.3 131.4 139.9 120.0 163.8 116.2 80.0 87.6 80.0 97.1 1956............. .......... 155.0“ 155.6* 234.9“ 134. St- 145.3* 120.0* 173.5b I Production workers in blast furnaces, steel works and rolling mills. * M o n th ly average, six months ending March 1956. II Annual rate, last quarter 1955. SOURCE.—United StalesDepartment of Labor; Federal Trade Commission-Securities Exchange Commission. 98. l b ECONOMIC 288 C H A R T REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 18 Wholesale PricestorFinished Steel Products andSteel UsingIndustnes 1945-56 160 Index (I947-49»[Q0) /.a 150 Finishet steel pr jd u cf8 r / / / -a ,y‘‘ y‘ 140 y‘ / Constn ictionma thim ryi equipmer t --------13 0 y J , A _____ 120 fa . 110 / rcllrvlCS lYIUIUi uohiidae ^0 / -------— y Hea ting equi wnent® — Agr cull ural m :hinery< lequipm ent 100 Electric ilm achi 90 V 80 Jf/ f V' S t e e l p r ic e : ; h a v e r is e n f a r m o re 70 th a n J O Ian li> ll A IfiA © comparable data for 1 9 4 5 -4 6 not available ° / monthly average, 6 mos. ending March 1956 SOURCE j United States Department of Labor t r ic e s o f p r o d u c t s u s i n g p e H 1 , ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 289 TABLE 18 WHOLESALE PRICES FOR FINISHED STEEL PRODUCTS AND STEEL USING INDUSTRIES, 1945-56 (1947-49=100) Year Finished steel products Agri. mach. & equip. Construc tion mach. & equip. Motor vehicles Electrical machinery Heating equip. 1945 70.2 72.9 72.9 68.8 68.9 n.a. 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 76.4 89.1 101.3 109.7 115.2 78.1 90.3 101.4 108.3 110.7 79.2 90.0 101.8 108.3 111.5 79.7 91.3 100.8 107.9 107.2 78.9 96.1 100.7 103.2 106.4 n.a. 95.3 101.2 103.6 105.1 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 124.5 127.2 136.9 142.8 149.5 120.1 121.6 122.3 122.2 123.2 123.6 125.4 129.3 131.6 137.1 112.9 119.6 118.9 119.3 122.9 121.9 120.3 123.7 126.2 128.2 114.6 113.8 114.8 114.3 115.0 1956“ 155.6 126.5 143.6 126.8 132.2 117.2 n.a. Not available. • Monthly average, six months ending March 1956. SOURCE.—United States Department of Labor. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE 290 CHART PRESIDENT 19 PercentageIncreaseinHourlyEarnings 1947-55 ,0 TOTAL MANUFACTURING OURABLE 6000 INDUSTRIES M a c h in e ry (exc. e le c tric a l) F a b rica te d m e ta l p ro d u cts Tran sportation equ ipm en t Electrical m ach in e ry Furniture ^fixtures NONDURABLE GOOD INDUSTRIES P rin tin g ^ publishin g Rubber products Tobacco m an ufactu res Textile-mill products NON-MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES B itu m in ou s coal m in in g Hotels W h o le s a le tra d e R e ta il tra d e Cleaning & dyeing Lau n d rie s SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor 10 20 30 SO 60 70 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 291 INCREASES IN AVERAGE GROSS HOURLY EARNINGS IN MAJOR MANUFACTURING AND NON-MANUFACTURING GROUPS, SELECTED YEARS, 1947-55 Average hourly earnings Industry Total manufacturing....................... 1947 1951 1955 Cents increase between: 1947-55 1947-51 1951-55 Percent increase between: 1947-55 1947-51 1951-55 $1.24 $1.59 $1.88 $.64 $.35 $.29 51.6 28.2 18.2 Durable-goods industries: Lumber & wood products. . . Furniture & fixtures................ Stone, clay & glass products.. . Primary metal industries........ Fabricated metal products Machinery (excl. electrical). .. . Electrical machinery............... Transportation equipment 1.13 1.10 1.19 1.39 1.28 1.35 1.26 1.45 1.47 1.39 1.54 1.81 1.65 1.76 1.58 1.85 1.69 1.61 1.85 2.24 1.98 2.09 1.88 2.23 .56 .51 .66 .85 .70 .74 .62 .78 .34 .29 .35 .42 .37 .41 .32 .40 .22 .22 .31 .43 .33 .33 .30 .38 49.6 46.4 55.5 61.2 54.7 54.8 49.2 53.8 30.1 26.4 29.4 30.2 28.9 30.4 25.4 27.6 15.0 15.8 20.1 23.8 20.0 18.8 19.0 20.5 Nondurable-goods industries: Food & kindred products....... Tobacco manufactures............ Textile-mill products............... Paper & allied products.......... Printing & publishing............. Chemicals & allied products. . . Petroleum & coal products. .. . Rubber products...................... Leather & leather products... . 1.12 .90 1.04 1.16 1.54 1.23 1.50 1.39 1.05 1.43 1.13 1.33 1.52 1.99 1.63 1.98 1.69 1.27 1.75 1.34 1.39 1.83 2.35 1.99 2.36 2.09 1.41 .63 .44 .35 .67 .81 .76 .86 .70 .36 .31 .23 .29 .36 .45 .40 .48 . .30 .22 .32 .21 .06 .31 .36 .36 .38 .40 .14 56.3 48.9 33.7 57.8 52.6 61.8 57.3 50.4 34.3 27.7 25.6 27.9 31.0 29.2 32.5 32.0 21.6 21.0 22.4 18.6 4.5 20.4 18.1 22.1 19.2 23.7 11.0 Non-manufacturing industries: Bituminous coal mining.......... Wholesale trade....................... Retail trade.............................. Laundries.................................. Hotels....................................... Cleaning & dyeing................... 1.64 1.27 1.01 .77 .65 .91 2.21 1.58 1.26 .92 .82 1.06 2.56 1.91 1.50 1.01 .99 1.20 .92 .64 .49 .24 .34 .29 .57 .31 .25 .15 .17 .15 .35 .33 .24 .09 .17 .14 56.1 50.4 48.5 31.2 52.3 31.9 34.8 24.4 24.8 19.5 26.2 16.5 15.8 20.9 19.0 9.8 20.7 13.2 SOURCE.—UnitedStatesDepartmentofLabor. 292 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT Mr. B r u b a k e r . We do not hope that the committee members will look at them carefully. We think they have a tremendous amount of detailed information in them on this question of inflation and steel and the causes for it. Now we would like to direct your attention very quickly to the con clusions that come from our study. We think if you will examine the study carefully you will find that the facts set forth in that study show, first, that wage increases in steel have not caused even a single steel-price increase since the formation of the steelworkers union 20 years ago. That we say flatly. Two, wage increases over the years have been moderate and have been well within the capacity of the steel industry to grant and to absorb out of productivity gains and excessive profit margins. Three, wage increases have been more than earned by steelworkers throughout the union’s history, by the constantly and sharply rising productivity, that is, output per man-hour of the workers. The real productivity increases in steel have significantly exceeded the real wages of steelworkers. Four, the inflation in steel, that is, the rise in steel prices, has arisen because the industry has been determined to widen its already exces sive profit margins. It has not only refused to absorb increased wage costs out of increased productivity, as it could well have done, but it has also raised steel prices more than $3 for every $1 of increased wages and fringes granted to its employees. It literally makes a net profit—and a very big one—on every wage increase which it grants to the union and to its employees. Five, if there is any significant relationship in the steel industry between wages, prices, and profits, it is one of coincidence in timing only. The union’s wage increases are made the excuse and the occa sion for wholly unnecessary and excessive price increases which result in ever-increasing profits. The facts simply do not support the wholly fallacious hypothesis that steel wage increases cause steel price increases. Let us look briefly at some of the facts shown in our study. These are elaborated much more particularly in this wThite book which you have. First, look at profits before taxes. For 1956, the industry and for this purpose we actually used the financial reports of the 25 companies which make up nearly 92 percent of the industry’s ingot capacity, are estimated at approximately $2 billion. You will notice the com parisons below with other prior years. In 1956, profits before taxes are almost on a par with 1955, which was the highest year on record, prior to this last year. They are nearly 200 percent above 1947. They are more than 1,100 percent above 1939. During the first half of 1956, prior to the strike in steel, profits before taxes were running at an annual rate of more than 15 percent above the prior alltime-peak year. There is every reason to believe they w^ould have ended up the year that high except for the strike which was forced upon us. We also have noted for you that just prior to the strike last year, the steel industry was making a profit before taxes of $1.52 on every man-hour worked by all employees in the industry. This is nearly 60 percent of the amount which the industry was paying per hour of labor. This should be some measure of the leeway which they had from which to grant wage increases. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 293 Now turn to net profits. They present much the same picture as profits before taxes. Profits for 1956 are estimated at a billion dollars— net profits after all taxes. That is on a par with 1955, which was an alltime peak year. Again, profits after taxes were running at a rate 13 percent during the first half of 1956 above the prior peak year, and they would well have ended up that way but for the strike. Now let us turn to profit margins briefly. Profit margins in the steel industry have widened sharply in recent years. For all manu facturing industries they have gone in the other direction. They have narrowed. This is evident from an examination of the industry’s favorite comparison, profit per dollar of sales. In steel, net profits have risen from 6.2 cents per dollar of sales in 1947 to 7.9 cents in 1955, and early 1956. In all manufacturing they have gone the opposite way, from 5.7 cents in 1947 down to 4 cents in 1955, and an estimated 4.3 in early 1956. The sounder measure, the rate of return on net worth, or owner’s equity, shows much the same picture. Net profits in steel rose from 10.5 percent in 1947 up to 16.1 percent in the first half of 1956. In all manufacturing they went in the opposite direction, down from 15.1 percent in 1947 to 12 percent in the first part of 1956. Clearly the rates of return on net worth in both steel and all manu facturing are excessive by almost any standard. They are far exceed ing the 6-percent rate of return which was once generally accepted as a fair and reasonable rate of return. They would readily permit significant price reductions and still leave more than adequate profit margins. There is little excuse for industry generally, or for the steel industry, to insist on earning 10 to 15 percent as it has done in most peacetime years since 1939—rates of return which would permit the industry to double its investment out of earnings every 7 to 10 years. On dividends, the industry’s owners have done well. The com panies were paying dividends to the stockholders at a rate in excess of $400 million in early 1956. Dividends, however, did not go down when the strike came. They not only paid dividends as usual; they raised the rate of dividends. So that we have a picture here of dividends having increased since 1947 in steel by 229 percent, at the same time that the dividends of all corporations were going up only 86 percent. On productivity, it is imperative that you have these figures before you. There has been a constantly rising productivity rate in the steel industry in recent years. We have a new study by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, which both the industry and wg have cooperated in developing, which show's the figures that we have given you in our statement, a 4.5-percent rise in early 1956, an 1.1.4-percent rise in 1955, and a total rise of 68.8 percent since 1939. In contrast with this—and this is a most important figure—the “real” straight time average earnings of steelworkers, also BLS figures, show an increase from 1939 as contrasted with the first 10 months of 1956, of 48.3 percent. So that there has been a “ real” lag in straight-time earnings as contrasted with productivity. This is a very simple figure, and it is one that nobody I think can get around, namely, wages in steel simply have not fully kept up with produc tivity, if you are talking about “ real” wages and “real” output. 294 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT These are official figures. This ought to settle this controversy of whether wages are going up faster than productivity in steel. We have given you some other demonstrations of this. I want to urge you greatly to take a look at this white book when you get a chance, at table 16, which lists the price increases in the steel industry since the war. We have detailed them for you year by year, as contrasted with the wage increases that came along at the same time. I f anyone can look at that and reach any other conclusion than that which we have reached, I would be very, very much surprised. Chairman P a t m a n . Y o u may insert your entire statement. Thank you very much. (The statement follows:) S t a t e m e n t o n W a g e s , P r ic e s , P r o f it s , a n d I n f l a t io n o n B e h a l f of t h e U n it e d S t e e l w o r k e r s of A m e r i c a b y O t i s B r u b a k e r , D ir e c t o r of R e s e a r c h The steelworkers union is delighted to accept the invitation of the Joint Economic Committee to participate in this panel discussion on the question of the so-called wage-price inflation spiral mentioned prominently in two recent Presi dential statements. This panel discussion can be, and w e hope it will be, the beginning of a serious investigation by the Joint Economic Committee of the causes of inflation and what can be done about them. N o one wants inflation— or so nearly everyone says. Those few w h o favor it, or a little of it, fail to appreciate its insidious character and its thoroughly harmful results. Certainly our union, the United Steelworkers of America, does not now, and never has, favored inflation. The members of our union and the retired former members suffer as much as do other members of the public when pay checks and pension checks buy less and less because inflation, i. e., higher prices of food, clothing, shelter, and the other necessities of life, is constantly nibbling away at the “real” buying power of their incomes. Unfortunately, however, there is much misinformation about inflation and its causes. There is a deliberate, widespread, and systematic attempt in our country by such groups as the National Association of Manufacturers, the chambers of commerce, many newspapers, and other large employers to lay the blame for inflation on the efforts of wage earners and their unions to secure wage and fringe improvements in order to raise the standard of living of the American worker. In fact, so one sided and so prevalent is this propaganda, that some persons wh o should know better are beginning to have doubts and are wondering if perchance wage increases do contribute to inflation. The cause of elemental economic education never has needed so badly an assist in getting the facts out on the table for all to see. Congress can do much in this regard if it will search out the facts concerning wages, prices and profits, their roles in our economic system, and assess the blame on those w h o cause and those w h o profit from inflation. In fact, if the spotlight of congressional publicity is kept focused on those wh o would like to raise prices and constantly increase profit margins, it m a y have a salutary effect in curbing price increases. W e were asked to participate in this panel for the sole purpose of telling the committee what w e know concerning wage and price relationships in steel. There are, of course, many facts concerning inflation in the steel industry about which the Steelworkers Union has firsthand knowledge. In order to carry out our collective bargaining responsibilities w e must constantly study the industry and its economics. W e must and w e do know much about its profit margins, about ho w much it can afford to raise the wages of its employees without raising its prices, about the limits there are on the latitudes of our collective bargaining. This is a major function of the union's research department. W e made careful studies in 1956 prior to and during our bargaining sessions. These facts were important in framing our demands on the industry and our settlement with it. Some of this material w e prepared for publication with the aid and assistance of Robert Nathan and some of his associates. It was released in late July 1956. Fortunately, the steel strike was settled shortly thereafter and unfortunately, as a result of the settlement, the public lost interest in steel and the facts relating to wages and prices in the industry. In our opinion, the facts of this study deserved more careful and widespread public scrutiny than they received. W e ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT 295 have made that study available to the Joint Economic Committee. While we could not redo that study in the few days following notice of this panel session, we have attempted to bring the more important of the early 1956 figures in the study as much up to date as possible in this brief presentation. TH E U N IO N 'S STUDY OF TH E STEEL INDUSTRY AND INFLATIO N A. Our conclusions Several important conclusions arise from our study of the facts: 1. Wage increases in steel have not caused even a single steel price increase since the formation of the Steelworkers Union 20 years ago. 2. Wage increases over the years have been moderate and have been well within the capacity of the industry to grant and absorb out of productivity gains and ex cessive profit margins. 3. Wage increases have been more than earned by steelworkers throughout the union’s history by the constantly and sharply rising productivity, i. e. output per man-hour of the workers. The real productivity increases have significantly ex ceeded the real wage gains of steelworkers. 4. The inflation in steel, i. e. the rise in steel prices, has arisen because the industry has been determined to widen its already excessive profit margins. It has not only refused to absorb increased wage costs out of increased productivity, as it could well have done, but it has also raised steel prices more than $3.00 for every $1.00 of increased wages and fringes granted to its employees. It literally makes a net profit, and a big one, on every wage increase it grants. 5. If there is any significant relationship in the steel industry between wages, prices, and profits, it is one of coincidence in timing only. The union’s wage increases are made the excuse and occasion for wholly unnecessary and excessive price increases which result in ever increasing profits. The facts simply do not support the wholly fallacious hypothesis that steel wage increases cause steel price increases. B. The facts 1. Profits.— Profits before taxes for 1956 for the steel industry (25 companies which in 1956 had 91.8 percent of the industry’s ingot capacity) are estimated at about $2 billion. This rate of profits was on a par with 1955 ($2,038.5 million), the prior all time peak year— 76percent higher than 1954 ($1,133.6 million) 188 percent higher than 1947 ($694.9 million) 1,168 percent higher than 1939 ($157.7 million) The level of profits before taxes was at an annual rate of $2,350.7 million in first quarter 1956 and $2,386.4 million in first half 1956. The strike in the third quarter pulled the annual rate down to $1,814.4 million. But a fourth quarter, which was the equivalent of each of the prestrike first two quarters, should pull the full year up to about $2 billion, which is on a par with the 1955 level. Except for the strike, profits before taxes in 1956 would have easily been at an all-time high, more than. 15 percent above the prior peak of 1955. It is out of these high profits before taxes that wage or other cost increases can be absorbed if the increase in productivity is, in any particular year, insufficient to offset these costs. Obviously an industry can absorb additional costs when its profits are at an all time peak. The steel industry (25 companies) was making profits before taxes during the first quarter of 1956 just prior to our 1956 wage negotiations of $1.52 per manhour worked, by all employees, a profit of more than 60 percent of the amount it paid for each hour of labor. Thus, it could increase hourly rates substantially without endangering its profits, even if it had had to absorb any added wage costs out of profits, which it did not have to do because of rising productivity. Net profits presented a similar picture. The net profits for the steel industry (the same 25 companies) for 1956 are estimated at $1 billion. This was on a par with 1955 ($1,019.4 million), the prior peak year— 70 percent higher than 1954 ($589.8 million) 154 percent higher than 1947 ($394.3 million) 691 percent higher than 1939 ($126.4 million) The level of net profits was at an annual rate of $1,153.4 million in the first quarter of 1956 and $1,190.6 million in the first half. The strike in the third quarter lowered the annual rate to $920.5 million. The fourth quarter should pull the annual rate up to about $1 billion, which is on a par with the 1955 level. Except for the strike, net profits in 1956 would have easily set a new record, 87624 0 — 57-------20 296 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT more than 13 percent higher than the prior peak in 1955. These high net profits are the direct result of already too high prices and rapidly advancing productivity. The profit figures discussed above do not fully reveal the profitability of the steel industry. In recent years the various steel companies have been permitted to depreciate defense facilities at a faster than normal rate. Commonly, this is referred to as rapid amortization. In 1955,12 of these 25 companies reported rapid amortiza tion charges of $310 million, of which at least $250 million was in excess of normal depreciation charges. This means that, had there been no rapid amortization in 1955, profits before taxes would have been some $250 million higher than reported and net profits some $120 million higher. Data are not yet available for 1956, but rapid amortization charges should not differ too significantly from 1955 charges. 2. Profit margins— Profit margins for the steel industry (22 companies) have widened sharply in recent years. For all manufacturing industries they have narrowed. This is evident from an examination of industry’s favorite com parison, profit per dollar of sales. In steel (22 companies) : net profits as a share of the sales dollar rose from 6.2 cents in 1947 to 7.9 cents in 1955 and first half 1956 In all manufacturing: Net profits as a share of the sales dollar declined from 5.7 cents in 1947 to 4.0 cents in 1955 and to 4.3 cents in early 1956 (estimated) This steel rate in 1955 and early 1956 was the peak rate for any recent year except 1950, which was fractionally higher (8.0 cents). The strike in the third quarter brought the 9-month rate down to 6.7 cents, but the fourth quarter should bring it back up to about 7.1 cents, a most creditable profit margin when com pared with all manufacturing. The rate of net profits as a return on net worth (owners’ equity) also shows steel1 running contrary to the general trend in industry. The comparisons show: In steel (22 companies) : Net profits as a rate of return on net worth rose from 10.5 percent in 1947 to 13.8 percent in 1955 and 16.1 percent1 in first half 1956 In all manufacturing: Net profits as a rate of return on net worth de clined from 15.1 percent in 1947 to 12.6 percent in 1955 and 12.0 percent in 1956 (average of first 3 quarters) The steel rate of return in first quarter 1956 was at a peak for recent years at 15.6 percent. For the first half it rose even further to 16.1 percent. It fell in the third quarter because of the strike to a 9-month level of 12.5 percent. The fourth quarter should bring the rate to about 13.4 percent for the year, a near record rate for recent years despite the 1956 stike. Clearly the rates of return on net worth in both steel and all manufacturing are excessive by almost any standard. They far exceed the 6 percent return once generally accepted as a fair and reasonable rate of return. They would readily permit significant price reductions and still leave more than adequate profit margins. There is little excuse for industry generally, or the steel industry, to insist on earning 10 to 15 percent as it has done in most peacetime years since 1939— rates of return which permit industry to double its investment out of earnings every 7 to 10 years. 3. Dividends.— The steel industry (25 companies) has dealt generously with its stockholders. Cash dividend payments to common-stock holders in first quar ter 1956 were at an annual rate of $412.9 million, a record high. Unlike the workers wh o lost wages because of the third quarter strike, the stockholders con tinued to receive dividends as usual. In fact, the annual rate for the first 9 months actually exceeded the first quarter rate. It was $420.3 million. This was an increase of 229 percent since 1947— a period during which all corpora tions showed an increase of only 86 percent. In addition to the cash dividends ma n y stockholders also received stock dividends, and nearly all benefited from sharp increases in the equity value of their stockholdings. 4. Productivity.— The steelworker has increased his productivity, output per manhour, sharply in recent years: B y 4.5 percent in the first quarter of 1956. B y 11.4 percent in 1955 (a record high for any year). B y 68.8 percent since 1939. 1 T he steel rates o f return on net worth fo r 1956 have not been adjusted to reflect the 1956 additions to net worth. These adjustm ents w ould not change at all significantly the picture here shown. ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT 297 These increases in “real” output per hour of work by steelworkers significantly exceed the “real” straight-time earnings increase received by these same steel workers for each hour of work. For the entire period of more than 16 years, 1939 through part of 1956, “real” productivity in steel rose 68.8 percent (1939 re 1st quarter 1956), whereas “real” straight-time average hourly earnings rose only 48.3 percent (1939 vs. 1st 10 months 1956). Even if allowance is made for “fringe” gains during this period, productivity gains still significantly exceed wage and “fringe” gains together. Obviously steelworkers have not only “earned” their wage and “fringe” improvements over the years, but they have not even received their proportionate share of the productivity gains made in the industry. These are the facts, based^pn Department of Labor studies, and they are in sharp contrast to the fiction which the industry has attempted to persuade the public to believe. These large gains in productivity mean lower unit labor costs and would permit wage increases without price increases— if prices are set in terms of costs, insofar as possible, instead of in terms of whatever the market will bear. 5. Steel prices versus wages.— The entire steel industry has reaped a profit bonanza from the steel price increases of recent years— increases which are out of all proportion to increased costs. Since 1945, there has been 10 rounds of wage increases (including the pension and insurance round in 1949), but there have been 17 rounds of general (base) steel price increases and 4 major increases in price “extras” (including 2 which coincided with base price increases). Thus, there have been an average of 2 price increases for every wage increase— custom arily an anticipatory one preceding the wage increase and another one following the wage increase. The cumulative impact of the price and wage increases since 1945, measured in terms of 1956 operations, meant for the entire steel industry: Million Additional revenues. .$6,572.2 Additional labor cost. . 2,027.9 Total gain. $4,544.3 Expressed differently this means that, for every $1 increase in labor “costs”— “costs” which have actually been offset by greater output per man-hour— the steel industry has generated for itself $3.24 in additional revenues, achieved by reason of its unjustifiably large price increases. There was criticism of the steel wage and price increases of August 1956 both from industry sources and much of the press. The steel industry used the wage increase, as usual, as the excuse for large steel price increases. This excuse was generally, uncritically, and quite erroneously accepted as fact. The union said at the time, that the steel industry could grant a substantial wage increase and absorb the “cost” without serious reduction in profits. W e were willing to, and did, settle our negotiations on a basis which required no price increase. Our 1956 contract provided for a wage increase and other benefits at a cost of approxi mately 20 cents per hour for the 1st year of the contract. For all 775,000 e m ployees of the steel industry (25 companies), even if no productivity increase is assumed, the gross “cost” of the wage increase for a year would have been $310 million, the net “cost” $148.8 million. At the level of profits before taxes and after taxes of the industry in the 1st quarter of 1956 (the latest data available at the time of our negotiations), these figures would have been reduced from $2,350.7 million and $1,153.4 million respectively to $2,040.7 million profits before taxes and $1,004.6 million net profits. The rate of net profits as a return on net worth would have been 13.6 percent and the net profit per dollar of sales 6.9 cents. These would have been highly satisfactory rates of return. But productivity was increasing sharply enough to permit absorption of a substantial wage increase without a price increase and without any reduction in profits. Even at a 4-percent rate of productivity gain in the year, output and revenue would have increased by 4 percent ($349.2 million at the first quarter rate). This amount exceeded the gross “cost” of a 20-cent wage increase by $39.2 million and the net “cost” by $18.8 million. Thus, the industry could have granted and absorbed a 20-cent wage increase and still have increased both its profits before taxes and its net profits out of a 4-percent gain in productivity alone. Instead, it chose to provoke a strike, lose some of the productivity gain, lower its profits, but, most importantly, add to inflation by a substantial steel price hike. The steel price increase in August 1956 was announced as $8.50 per ton (about 7 percent). This increase was sufficient to offset the “cost” of the wage increase 298 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT by nearly $3 of price increase to every $1 of wage increase. But it was unneces sary to make any price increase in 1956 since the productivity increase just recorded in 1955 prior to the negotiations was 11.4 percent— an amount more than sufficient to pay for the “cost’' of the wage increase— just out of labor’s share of the productivity rise. Apparently the industry is willing to pay much lipservice to the theory that wage increases be limited to productivity gains but is quite unwilling to accept its corollary, that it should not raise its prices when unit wage costs are decreased because of increased output per man-hour. In recent months, particularly in December 1956 and January 1957, the industry has launched another series of price increases. M a n y of these increases are in so-called extras and are not reflected in*the price indexes maintained by the trade press. The American Metal Market (January 18, 1957) estimated the overall effect of the “extra” increases in structurals at 4y2 percent, in plates at 5 y2 percent, in large pipe 3 ^ percent, etc. The cumulative impact of the increases has been to raise the B L S Finished Steel Price Index by 1.5 percent already (about $2.25 per ton)— with more increases in prospect. These Decem ber-January price increases have no more justification than did the $8.50 per ton in-crease of last August. While, as indicated, no price increase was necessary to offset the “cost” of the 1956 wage increase, the industry did raise prices by about $8.50 per ton. Based on the American Iron and Steel Institute’s definition of the basic steel industry and on its first half steel shipments and man-hours for the entire industry, the price increase yielded about $800 million in additional revenue. The wage increase, which appeared to raise the wage bill by $285 million, actually “cost” nothing because it was offset by a reduction in unit costs caused by increased productivity. The profit of the industry from this little operation is obvious. 6. Steel prices vs. materials and other costs.— Steelmaking costs, other than wages, have not risen nearly as fast as steel prices. The unit cost of materials purchased2 in the steel industry rose 30.7 percent between 1947 and December 1956. But steel prices increased 91.3 percent in the same period— an increase of prices re materials costs of 3 to 1. For years the industry has argued that whenever wages rise, its materials costs increase by a like and identical amount because of the wage increase. This argument is not supported by the facts— even those drawn by the industry from its own financial records. Even if there were coincidence in timing of the increases, it would not be evidence that wage increase caused the materialscost increase. But there is no such coincidence or cause. United States Steel’s annual report for 1952 disproved any such argument in the following tabulation : Comparative changes in materials and employment costs in United States Steel Corp. Increase as percent of 1940 Period covered January 1941-April 1947_ ................. ........................... ................................... April 1947-July 1948................. ......................... ................................................. July 1948-November 1949 .................................................................................... November 1949-December 1950......................................... ........... .............. ...... December 1950-July 1952_______________ ______________ ______ _______ ___ July 1952-Deeember 1952...................................................................................... Employment cost Cost of materials Percent Percent 56 16 14 19 23 27 47 42 18 3 24 4 Even a cursory examination of the movements of the price of such an important steelmaking material as steel scrap would demonstrate the fallacious nature of any such claim. In the last few months of 1956, according to Steel magazine, steelmaking scrap rose consistently reaching a peak of $66.17 per ton in midDecember and then fell off to $59.83 in mid-January 1957. As compared with mid-January 1956, this was an increase of 24.1 percent at the peak and is still 2 T he index used as a measure o f m aterials costs is the BLS price index o f ‘‘all com m odities other than farm and food products” which the President’ s Council o f Econom ic Advisers refers to as “ industrial prices.” This index was referred to by a United States Steel Corp. spokesman in testim ony before the Tem porary National E conom ic Committee as a close indicator o f the movement o f prices o f the m aterials purchased by the corporation. ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT 299 12.2 percent above a year ago. Would anyone be so foolish as to claim that costs of labor in steel scrap procurement and preparation have risen by an amottnt even approaching this figure? Yet such myths as this pass for fact in the steel industry’s public relations. These scrap-price increases are simply the results of another industry, the steel-scrap industry, attempting to emulate the steel in dustry by increasing its prices as much as it thinks the market will bear. This is the stuff of which inflation— miscalled wage-price inflation— is made. An d now the need for funds for capacity expansion of the industry is advanced seriously as an important “reason” for higher steel prices. Certainly prices should be at a level sufficient to permit maintenance and replacement of existing facilities. But by some perversion of investment theory, it is no w argued that the public, the users of steel, should not only pay the steel companies a fair return on their investment but should also pay for expanded capacity through higher prices. The companies would thus avoid the traditional methods of raising capital, such as stock flotation and borrowing, and the stockholders would end up owning new and enlarged capacity without a red cent of additional invest ment on their part. This alleged “reason” for inflation in steel prices should be soundly condemned by all. W e cannot hope to stop inflation, whether it be in steel prices, scrap prices, auto prices, or the major items which make up the cost of living, until our major industries feel the glare of continuous publicity on their pricing actions. This committee and the Congress could make a great contribution by continuously investigating the facts concerning wages, prices, and profits and by focusing public opinion on unsupportable price increases. Only thus can w e learn whether erosive inflation can be prevented in our economy without more drastic steps. Chairman P a t m a n . We next have Mr. Bradford Smith, economist, United States Steel Corp. STATEMENT OF BRADFORD B. SMITH, ECONOMIST, UNITED STATES STEEL CORP. Mr. S m i t h . Mr. Chairman and gentlemen, it, of course, was not my understanding that this meeting was going to be devoted more or less exclusively to the industry from which I have employment. So I think it would be well at the outset to say that I am not here on this occasion either to expound or to defend the policies of the United States Steel Corp. I am here rather to be of such assistance to the committee as I may in analyzing the great majestic important trends which are occurring in our economy. I am much disturbed by the forces making for interminable inflation in our land. This concern arises out of the fact that following all of our previous great wars the war-inspired inflationary forces have subsided, after a year or two of readjustment, and given wTay to periods of relative stability. But that is not true this time as may be seen by a glance at the first chart. On the contrary, in the period since the close of World War II the underlying inflationary forces have in creased rather than decreased in power. They seem to be operating like a compound-interest curve, which, if not checked, will eventually carry inflation to astronomical heights. The contrast between this postwar period and previous postwar periods is prima facie evidence that something new has come to America—some change in the national attitudes, in the legislative and social frameworks within which we conduct our living in this land. Should this indeed be true, then I would suppose that few matters more urgently merit attention if our long-term economic healthiness is to be insured. My researches disclose that the massive, continuous surge of infla tion is most clearly manifest in industrial costs. For over 15 years nothing has stopped it, nor more than temporarily slowed it down. 300 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT The consequence to prices is a self-evident proposition; except as off set by increasing productivity, prices have got to go up to cover rising costs, least industry experience widespread bankruptcy. The connec tion between costs and prices is not, of course, an instantaneous oneto-one affair like closely intermeshed gears. Changing profit or loss margins, varying tax costs, shifting demand trends, and fluctuating levels of production interpose temporary cushions and compressions between costs and prices. But they do not alter the long-term arith metic, with which I presume this committee is primarily concerned. Underlying all industrial costs is wage cost. Up and down Amer ica’s production line, from extraction of raw materials to delivery of finished products, something over three-quarters of all costs are, di rectly or indirectly, employment costs. Thus if we have wage infla tion we cannot escape cost inflation since the first is the biggest part of the second. I f we have cost inflation beyond productivity increases we cannot escape rising prices, the latter being but the reflection of the former. May I say in passing that inflation can be accommodated only with in the framework of soft money policies and an expanding money sup ply. As a matter of fact the money supply has been multiplied 3% times since 1940. Since monetary restraint has become secondary to maintenance of full employment, and since the committee will deal with the monetary matter tomorrow, I omit further discussion of it in these brief comments. Our country has been caught up in a persistent and massive wage inflation. It shows, for example, in the records of United States Steel. In the second of the attached charts I show United States Steel’s employment cost per employee hour, on the basis 1940 equals 100. Since 1940 the employment cost has increased every year. The average rate of increase is 8.1 percent per annum compounded. This wage inflation is general, as may be noted in chart III, which again shows United States Steel’s employment costs and compares them with hourly earnings of wage employees for all manufacturing. The in crease in the latter is a little less than in the former largely because the Bureau of Labor Statistics does not include many fringe benefit costs. In the case of United States Steel these have risen from less than 10 cents an hour in 1940 to over 50 cents in 1956. The items are charted on a logarithmic vertical scale to disclose the dangerous compound interest type of trend in wage inflation. Anything increasing at 8 percent per annum doubles every 9 years. Since the basic wage inflation is general throughout industry it is quite natural that all of United States Steel’s other costs per em ployee hour should pursue the skyward path of its direct employment costs. And so they do, as shown by the other curve back on the second chart. From 1940 to 1956 total costs per employee hour have been multiplied by 3.8 which works out to an increase of 8.8 percent per annum compounded. With such persistent and large cost inflation, prices must obviously be pushed up. Fortunately the full impact of wage inflation on prices has been moderated by the provision of increasingly efficient tools of production. This may be observed in the fourth quarter chart in which the rise since 1940 in steel prices is compared with the rise in United States Steel’s employment costs per hour. You will note while employment costs per hour have been multiplied nearly 3 ^ ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 301 times, steel prices have been multiplied only 2% times. The steel price rise is the equivalent of 5.6 percent per annum compared with the employment cost increase of 8.1 percent. An annual average in crease in productive efficiency between 2 and 3 percent would account for the difference, although any such measurement must be surrounded with numerous reservations. For comparison, two other items appear on this fourth chart: The index of all-commodity prices at wholesale and United States Steel’s income as a percent of sales. The latter simply verifies that the price increase is not due to relative profit inflation, since over the period the percentage of profit margin has declined rather than risen. A similar observation is valid for the economy as a whole, as may be observed on page 8 of Economic Indicators, where it is shown that profits have not, since 1950, attained the levels reached in that year and more recently have been declining. The committee may be interested in the comparative price be havior. I start with i940 as the last year before the wartime distor tions came into the picture. There are three phases. From 1940 to 1946 wholesale prices—along with employment costs—increased over 50 percent, while steel prices did not increase at all until 1945 and by 1946 were only 12 percent above 1940. They were thus relatively deeply depressed and remained so for the next 5-year period up to 1951. During that period both steel and wholesale prices advanced in roughly parallel fashion. From 1951 on steel prices began to catch up with wholesale prices, the latter having experienced a plateau. They are now rising together again. It is interesting that the nonrise of steel prices in the 1940-46 period did not prevent wiiolesale prices from rising. Equally the readjustment rise in steel prices from 1951 to 1955 did not cause wholesale prices to rise. Steel industry critics, incidentally, are fond of picking a year in the middle or preadjustment period as a base for comparing that industry’s subsequent price and profit changes with those of other industries. This brief analysis illustrates four points I believe to be important for research and policy guidance: 1. It is unlikely that the key to the general inflation problem is to be found in the prices of any one or several industries; 2. The important key to the present inflation problem is to be found in the wage inflation, as the common denominator of all in dustries’ costs; 3. It follows that policy changes which leave the wage inflation untouched will prove futile; while 4. I f wage inflation is checked the present prospect of price infla tion will vanish. Thank you. Chairman P a t m a n . Thank you. Mr. George Hitchings, manager, economic analysis department, Ford Motor Co. STATEMENT OF GEORGE HITCHINGS, MANAGER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS DEPARTMENT, FORD MOTOR CO. Mr. Hitchings. The current rise in prices which generally started in mid-1955 is different from the type of inflation that occurred during and immediately after war periods. Those inflations involved a sharp 87624— 57-------20 302 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT and sustained increase in prices generated by money demand for goods and services substantially greater than the available supply at existing prices. These inflations were fed by a rapid expansion of the money supply, usually through Government deficit financing. Too rapid an expansion through private credit would, however, have the same effect. In the past 18 months, the only important areas in which money demand has exceed supply and pushed prices up have been in capital equipment industries and their suppliers. Wholesale prices of fin ished durable goods used by producers have risen 13 percent since mid-1955. These increases have been concentrated in metals, fabri cated metal products, machinery, and equipment. Prices of construc tion materials have also reflected heavy business construction demand. Prices of consumer goods have risen much less over the same period. At the wholesale level, prices of consumer goods in total increased only 2y2 percent after June 1955. Finished durable goods used by consumers were up about 6y2 percent, largely in the passenger car and household furniture segments. For consumer nondurable goods other than food, a moderate steady rise accumulated to 3 percent over the 18 months. Food prices continued to decline in the last half of 1955, but a subsequent increase in 1956 brought them back to their mid-1955 level. These changes in wholesale prices of consumer goods have been reflected in similar movements at retail. The consumer price index, which includes services as well as the types of consumer goods in the wholesale price index, has risen 3 percent since mid-1955. A decline in food prices in the last half of 1955 kept the rise in the overall index to very modest proportions during that period. In 1956, however, there has been a moderate rise in all segments of the index. Demand pressures in excess of supplies have not accounted for the rise in consumer prices. Rather, increasing costs of production are responsible for most of the rise in prices of consumer goods and services. An exception is the turn-around in the food component which has resulted in part from policies designed to bring about some recovery in depressed prices at the farm level. Most of the increase since 1948 in dollar income generated in the manufacturing segment of the economy has been in the form of higher payrolls and Government tax revenues. Corporate profits after taxes (adjusted to eliminate profits or losses from inventory price changes) have stayed at about the same total dollar amount since 194& In the first 9 months of 1956, these profits amounted to an annual rate of about $10 billion, compared with $82 billion for wages and salaries, including supplements to wages and salaries in the form of pensions, insurance, and accident compensation. This total of $82 billion of employee compensation represents a sharp growth from the $48.6 bil lion level in 1948—a growth of about 70 percent. Although part of this rise in total wages and salaries arose from increased employment, average annual earnings per full-time em ployee were up 48 percent from 1948 levels. Most of this rise in an nual earnings, in turn, stemmed from a 45 percent increase in average hourly earnings. I f nonwage fringe benefits were included, the rise would be still greater. ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT 303 Government tax revenues from corporate income generated in man ufacturing industries are much higher than in 1948. They now stand at about $12 billion, also some 70 percent above the 1948 level. Dur ing the upsurge after Korea, Government revenues from this source were temporarily higher because of the excess-profits tax. By contrast, corporate profits after taxes (adjusted for inventory profits and losses) are not significantly above 1948, 1949, and 1950 levels, despite the substantially higher dollar volume of sales and capital investment. The rate of return on investment for manufac turing corporations, therefore, has been reduced. Profits after taxes are the proper measure of income available to owners of the business. The stockholders, who are the owners of the business, have available as income only the amount left over after taxes. They, in turn, are taxed on this income just as are the em ployees on their income. Net profits distributed as dividends are taxed to the recipient. Undistributed profits invested in the business are taxed as capital gains when gains are realized. The proper com parison is between employees and stockholders, rather than with the corporate entity, which is merely the vehicle for producing income. Although it is desirable for employees to share in the increased in come available from the manufacturing operations, it is also necessary to obtain an adequate return on the capital investment because the in vestment makes possible most of the real gain in employee wages. Furthermore, the buyer of products must be offered a sufficiently attractive price to obtain maximum markets. Increase in the total pie available for distribution is the primary consideration of economic policy. To maintain a healthy economic growth there must be a proper distribution of income among em ployees, owners, and consumers. An attempt to garner the total in crease in productivity, or more, by either labor or capital results only in price inflation and/or shrinkage of the total market. In the period since mid-1955, there is evidence that average hourly earnings have outstripped productivity and led to increased costs of production. Such increased costs have resulted in higher prices of manufactured products. Return on investment in manufacturing has declined in this period despite continued high volume operations. In the second quarter of 1956, the rate of return was 12.6 percent after taxes, compared with 13 percent a year earlier and 14.8 percent on the average for 1947-50 (see table E-52 on p. 180 of the January 1957 Economic Report of the President). A further decline occurred in the third quarter, but the extent of decline was exaggerated by the steel strike and by model changeovers in the auto industry. Fourth quarter profits were more in line with rates earlier in the year. By contrast, average hourly earnings in manufacturing continued to rise in 1956, reaching a level in December that was nearly 10 per cent above mid-1955. This increase in wages cannot continue at Such a pace without further price increases and/or reduced markets. A l though increased hourly earnings make it possible for the recipients to pay the higher prices, those consumers who do not share in rising incomes are less able to buy. Furthermore, the purchasing power of existing savings is reduced. Increased costs also present problems in business financing (higher working capital requirements and higher expenditures for new plant 304 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT and equipment) as well as consumer financing of houses and durable oods. The monetary authorities are faced with the problem of easing ank-reserve positions to permit these higher expenditures or of maintaining such a tight rein that business activity declines. The key to prices in 1957 will be the extent to which payroll costs rise relative to physical production. Demand pressures in the capital goods segment of the economy will probably ease, as physical volumes level off or decline slightly. There will be adequate productive ca pacity to meet the probable levels of demand in nearly all major seg ments of the economy* Continued high levels of capital investment will be required, however, to provide for future growth in the economy and for the improved efficiency—or productivity, as it is often called— so necessary if increased income with price stability is to be achieved. (Mr. Hitchings later submitted the following:) f D istribution of national income in m anufacturing (1 94 8 - 5 6 ) [Millions of dollars] 1948 Total income. . . ______ ____ - - - _____________ . _ Memorandum: Inventory profits, corporations. . ___ ________ ____ Inventory profits, unincorporated _ __ ___ Number of full-time equivalent employees -----------------------Average annual earnings per full-time employment_________ 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 9 months annual rate, 1956 i 43,860 2, 264 5, 729 9,605 1,294 5 49,393 3,142 10, 905 9,293 1,579 -77 58,232 4,141 14,252 9,598 1,574 -63 62,918 4,431 11,687 8,911 1,330 41 69,773 4, 928 12,325 8,201 1,068 56 65, 948 5, 054 9,242 8,439 796 76 72,132 5, 709 12,518 10, 329 1,019 98 76,000 6,100 12,200 9,800 1,000 100 66,630 62, 757 74,235 87, 734 89,318 96,351 89, 555 101,805 105,100 1,440 36 15,285 3,040 -1,194 -56 14,183 3,092 3,082 149 14, 969 3,300 662 4 16,122 3,612 -640 -24 16,413 3,833 692 10 17, 231 4,049 311 11 16,024 4,116 1,325 37 16, 579 4,351 1,800 100 16,900 4,500 OF THE 1 Breakdown of total income partially estimated. Figures rounded to nearest $100,000,000. 2Includes insurance, pensions, and accident compensation. 3After excluding inventory profits or losses. A verage hours and earnings o f production w orkers in manufacturing ( 1948-56 ) ________ ______ _ _ Average weekly hours__ _ Average hourly earnings_____ ___ __________________ Average weekly earnings.__ __ ___ _ _____ _______ 39.2 $1.40 $54. 92 1950 40.5 $1.47 $59.33 1951 40.7 $1. 59 $64. 71 1952 40.7 $1. 67 $67.97 1953 40.5 $1.77 $71. 69 1954 39.7 $1.81 $71. 86 1955 40.7 $1.88 $76. 52 1956 40.5 $1.98 $80.13 305 40.1 $1.35 $54.14 1949 PRESIDENT 1948 REPORT 46,459 2,145 7,066 9,596 1,358 6 1950 ECONOMIC Wages and salaries------------------------ ------- -----------------------Supplements to wages and salaries 2_ ____ ________ Corporation income and excess profits tax_ ______ ______ .. Corporation profits after tax 3. _ __ _____ _____. .. ------Unincorporated income 3 __ .. _____ _ . - _ ___________ Net interest- ________ _ ______ _________ . 1949 306 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT Chairman P a t n a m . Mr, Nat Weinberg, Director, Research Depart ment, United Auto Workers. STATEMENT OF NAT WEINBERG, DIRECTOR, RESEARCH DEPARTMENT. UNITED AUTO WORKERS Mr. W e i n b e r g . Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, we are most happy to have the opportunity to appear before this com mittee on the subject of prices. We earnestly hope that following this discussion today the committee will proceed as quickly as possible with a thorough-going and searching investigation of wage-priceprofit relationships in leading corporations in certain industries that our union has repeatedly urged since July 1955. There is not time today to present all the evidence that cries aloud for such an investiga tion of the auto industry, for example. But permit me to cite a few of the pertinent facts. General Motors and Ford raised their prices in the fall of 1955, using the economic gains won by our members earlier in that year as their major excuse. The cost of those gains to the corporations came to about 20 cents an hour. During the first 9 months of 1955, before prices were raised—but after the gains of the workers had already been largely in effect for 4 months—General Motors profits before taxes came to $2.93 per hour for every hour worked in its plants by all its 400,000 U. S. factory workers, yielding a return on the stockholders’ investment equal on an annual basis to 78.9 percent. After taxes the rate of return was still a fabulous 36.5 percent. In Ford’s case, profits per hour were $3.06, and the rate of return on investment was 57.7 percent before taxes, and 26.1 percent after taxes. These after-tax profit rates were two to three times the 13 percent average for all U. S. manufacturing corporations during the same period which happened to be a period of generally high profits. Yet General Motors and Ford raised their prices and sought to put the blame for the increases on the gains won by their workers through collective bargaining. Again in 1956 they raised their prices, this time despite a depressed market and widespread unemployment among the industry’s workers. In the face of this kind of situation, labor and management alike are being exhorted to exercise restraint in their wage and price actions. Exhortation implies that both have been guilty of lack of restraint. We hope this committee will move vigorously to find out whether that is really so in order that the pressure of public opinion may be effec tively concentrated where the guilt lies, and the innocent protected against unjust condemnation. The determination of culpability is in any case the necessary first step toward connection of the situation. The very fact that exhortation is resorted to in order to restrain inflation points to the unique nature of current increases in the price level. They do not for the most part result from the blind and im personal operation of market forces. They do not, on the whole, result from abnormally high demand or high production pressing against capacity limits. In fact, recent increases in the physical volume of production have been considerably less than normal; and in industry after industry, prices have been raised in the face of diminishing sales and swollen inventories. Price increases under these circum ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT 307 stances are clearly not a reflection of the operation of the law of supply and demand. It can be shown also, and we hope this com mittee will very soon give us opportunity to show, that in the industries which have contributed significantly to our current inflation, price increases are not the result of cost increases that have squeezed profit margins to an unreasonably small size. What these price increases do reflect in our opinion is the absence of price competition, and the operation of an “ administered price” system. Under this system a few corporations furnishing “ price lead ership” to industries crucial to the national welfare hold the power to fix prices arbitrarily. They are not subject to the laws of the market place that inhibit the pricing practices of corporations in pricecompetitive industries. With respect to these corporations, therefore, the consumer and the Nation are without the protection that market forces afford in in dustries where price competition prevails. We are prepared to show that many corporations possessing the power to administer prices have abused that power. They have fixed their prices on the basis of what is considered financially desirable for the corporation, with out regard to what is desirable and necessary for the Nation as a whole, and for the health and stability of our economy. We hold strongly to the belief that the pressure of public opinion can minimize or at least reduce the extent of such abuse of pricing power. But the public can be mobilized to an effective expression of opinion only if it is equipped with the facts. General exhortation directed to all and sundry will not do the job. The specific and detailed facts of specific situations, leaving no room for doubt as to whether or not there has been abuse, can create a climate of public opinion which will induce self restraint on the part of those who would otherwise be tempted to abuse that power. We would like to make two proposals designed to equip the public with the necessary facts. Our union has always believed that economic decisions, particularly those affecting the general welfare, should be made on the basis of economic facts, rather than on the basis of eco nomic power. This holds whether the power involved be the power to shut down a plant and keep it shut down, or the powder to extort from consumers any price that a corporation may deem it desirable in its narrow interest to exact. For ourselves, we of the UAW are willing to be bound by the policy that demands for wage increases and other gains in administered price industries should be confined within the limits of ability to pay, with out price increases, of the efficient firm functioning under full em ployment conditions. This is no new principle for us. We first of fered to be bound by it during the General Motors strike of 1945-46 when more than 200,000 of our members struck 113 days for wage in creases without price increases. We offered during that strike to re duce our wage demand, justified though we were convinced it was, to whatever the amount—zero if need be—that could be paid by the cor poration without an increase in its prices. Implementation of this policy requires, of course, that the facts on ability to pay be available to us and to the public. Both must have all the information that is necessary to determine beyond a reasonable doubt the size of the economic package that could be granted without 308 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT reducing the profits of an efficient firm in a full-employment economy below a reasonable level. Obviously this cannot be a universal policy applicable to all industries. It would be improper, inequitable, and economically unsound to apply it in industries where existing wage levels are substandard. It is unnecessary to apply it in industries where prices are set by competition rather than by corporate fiat. Balancing the obligation we are ready to assume, we propose that a similar obligation be assumed by corporations in a position to ad minister prices. Specifically, we propose a statutory mechanism that would assure the public oi an adequate flow of essential factual information con cerning certain corporate price actions, without involving Government in the task of controlling prices. As we presently visualize it, legis lation directed toward this objective would require advance notice and public justification of price increases proposed to be put into effect by any corporation which accounts for more than a specified percentage—perhaps 20 or 25 percent—of the total sales of its industry. Such a corporation would give notice of intention to raise prices to a governmental agency created for that purpose. The agency would thereupon conduct public hearings at which the corporation would be required to present detailed justification based upon its records of the need for the proposed price increase. Its testimony would be subject to cross-examination and its pertinent records open for inspection both by the agency and by representatives of organizations or groups opposing the proposed price increase, including other corporations which purchase goods produced by the firm proposing to raise its prices. Following the hearing, the agency would promptly publish the con tentions of the parties, and the facts as it had determined them. The hearings having been concluded and the notice period having expired, the corporation involved would then be entirely free to raise the price if it so chose. But the public wrould have the means to determine for itself whether or not the price increase was justified. These proposals rest on the premise that an effective democracy must be an informed democracy. They impose no compulsion with respect to wage or price actions. They infringe no freedom. They are de signed solely to minimize the abuse of freedom through the unin hibited exercise of economic power. They are aimed at encouraging responsibility in the exercise of economic power by removing the veil of secrecy that now conceals facts of vital public interest, and thus shelters the irresponsible. We most earnestly urge that the members of this committee give these proposals their careful consideration. Mr. Chairman, I have submitted a longer statement to the staff, and I would like to ask that it be included in the record. Chairman P a t m a n . It will be included in the record. (The statement follows:) S ta te m e n t on P r ic e In c r e a s e s (By Nat Weinberg, director, research and engineering department) W e are most happy to have the opportunity to appear before this committee on the subject of prices. W e earnestly hope that this discussion today marks the beginning of the culmination of our efforts of ma n y months to bring about a thoroughgoing and searching investigation into wage-price-profit relationships in certain industries. In these industries, which are crucial to the welfare of ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 309 the economy as a whole, a few leading corporations hold the power to fix prices arbitrarily. They are not subject to the laws of the market place that inhibit other corporations and other industries in pricing their products. With respect to these corporations, the consumer and the Nation are therefore without the protection that market forces afford in industries where competition prevails. W e believe, and w e hope w e wTill be given the opportunity to prove, that major corporations which furnish price leadership in a number of industries have abused their power. W e believe that the force of public opinion can, to some degree at least, make up for the absence of the protections against such abuse that price competition provides where it exists. W e hope that this discussion today is the first step toward marshaling the force of public opinion to induce restraint on the part of those wh o are responsible for our current inflation. The members of the U A W have paid heavily in sacrifice for the right to be heard on prices. More than 200,000 of them walked the picket lines for 113 long days in 1945-46 in an effort to win ‘Svage increases without price in creases”— in an effort to prevent fulfillment of their legitimate demands from being used as an illegitimate excuse to inflict unjustifiable price increases on American consumers generally. Since then, our union has repeatedly sought to arouse the Nation to protect itself against excessive prices. Time and time again, w e have attempted to call public attention to unjustifiable and extortionate price increases by automobile manufacturers and by corporations in other industries. W e take pride in the belief that w e have played some part in bringing this group together today. In July 1955 our union’s international executive board called for a congressional investigation of wage-price-profit relationships, with particular emphasis on the auto and steel industries. At that time, the steel industry had already raised its prices for the 18th time during the postwar period. The signs were clear that the leading automobile producers were once again about to raise their prices. As w e expected, they did raise prices with the introduction of new models in the fall of 1955. Since then, further general price increases have been put into effect in both the steel and auto industries, and the steel industry has recently been adding increases on so-called extras and certain base prices to its general price increases of 1955 and 1956. W e urge that, following this general discussion today, preparations be made forthwith to begin a full-scale investigation of such industries as soon as is humanly possible. W e hope that such an investigation will be carefully planned to assure that specific and up-to-date facts about specific price increases will be laid bare. No witness, whether from labor or from management, should be permitted to sub stitute self-serving public relations declarations for facts and figures. Detailed and specific information should be required on prices, profits, wages, material costs, productivity, and similar matters. If adequate information is not produced voluntarily, this committee or some other appropriate congressional committee should be prepared to seek from Con gress the funds, the staff (including expert accountants) and the subpena power required to conduct a thorough examination of all pertinent books and records. The danger of inflation is too real and too important to permit any evasion of the responsibility that rests upon all of us to disclose all information which m a y be useful in developing a public policy to meet it effectively. In our considered opinion, a full public airing of the relevant facts concerning specific recent price increases can, by itself, do much to arrest the current in flationary spiral. It would certainly give food for thought to those wh o might be tempted in the future to increase prices without any justification other than the fact that they want greater profits and can exact them. This, in our opinion, is all the justification there is for the price increases that have impelled our repeated requests for an investigation. There is not time here to cite all the pertinent evidence. But permit m e to mention a few facts with reference to the price leaders in the auto industry. General Motors and Ford raised their prices in the fall of 1955, using the economic gains won by our members earlier that year as their major excuse. The cost of those gains to the corporations came to about 20 cents an hour. (The precise figure depends on the assumptions made in calculating the cost of certain of the gains.) During the first 9 months of 1955— before prices were raised but after the gains of the workers had already been largely in effect for 4 months— G M ’s profits before taxes came to $2.93 per hour for every hour worked in its plants by all its 400,000 United States factory workers; yielding a return 310 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT on the stockholders’investment equal, on an annual basis, to 78.9 percent. (After taxes the rate of return was still a fabulous 36.5 percent.) In Ford’s case, profits per hour were $3.06 and the rate of return on investment was 57.7 percent before taxes, and 26.1 percent after taxes. These after-tax profit rates were 2 to 3 times the 13.1 percent1 average for all United States manufacturing corporations during the same period, which happened to be a period of generally high profits. Yet G M and Ford raised their prices and sought to put the blame for the increases on the gains wo n by their workers through collective bargaining. In the fall of 1956, these same corporations increased their prices again when they introduced the new 1957 models. Once more, they darkly hinted that wage increases were the cause. Yet the only wage increases their workers had ob tained since the price increases of 1955 were the so-called annual-improvementfactor increase and cost-of-living wage adjustments. B y the industry’s ow n admission, the improvement factor provides no basis for price increases. In the words of Mr. Harry Anderson, former vice president of General Motors, it is “repaid in the form of increased production so that in effect you sometimes have a decrease in actual cost for a particular unit.” The cost-of-living wage adjustments similarly do not justify the blame for higher prices which the leading auto corporations seek to fasten upon their workers. Such wage adjustments are merely a reflection of price increases that have taken place before the wage adjustment is made. Ironically, in December 1956, autoworkers obtained a 2-cent per hour cost-of-living adjustment largely because of the higher price tags on the new 1957 car models, which had been introduced a month or two earlier. Our union has repeatedly made clear its position with respect to cost-of-living wage adjustments. W e would much prefer that no occasion should ever arise for cost-of-living wage increases. They come about through no action of the workers but simply because prices have been raised by others over w h o m the workers have no control. All too often, the price increases which bring about cost-of-living wage increases are put into effect arbitrarily by the same corpora tions which seek to blame wage increases for their higher prices. W e have emphasized repeatedly that the worker does not gain but actually loses when he receives a cost-of-living wage increase. At most, such adjustments protect him and his family against reductions in the buying power of his current wages. H e remains a victim of inflation because he loses out in the buying powrer of his savings, his insurance, and even of many other benefits wo n through collective bargaining such as pensions and weekly sickness and accident benefits. In the absence of cost-of-living wage adjustments, workers would sacrifice their families’ living standards so that others might reap inflationary profits;* and the consumer purchasing power base upon wThich economic stability ulti mately depends would be seriously undermined. Moreover, industrial conflict would be aggravated and embittered as workers found themselves engaged in repeated struggles merely to regain what the thief of inflation had taken out of the buying power of their wages. W e hear much advice these days to limit our wage demands to amounts com mensurate with increases in productivity. But surely those who offer this advice cannot in good conscience refer to money wages. They must mean real wages. For, if applied to money wages in the face of rising prices this advice would mean constant declines in the living standards of workers and their families or, at the very least, a constantly diminishing share for wTorkers in the increasing volume of goods and services that they produce. There is an abundance of evidence that employers find themselves compelled to raise wages to meet cost of living advances, although often not as promptly and fully as they should, even in the absence of unions. Thus, the responsibility for cost-of-living wage increases cannot be laid at the door of unions. They come about through the action of forces over which unions have no control— specifically, the prior price increasing actions of corporations. Therefore, if wage increases are to be compared to productivity increases for purposes of determining the influence of unions on the price level, the proper comparison is with real wages and not money wages. O n this basis, it is clear beyond all possibility of doubt that the blame for price increases cannot be pinned on labor. It can be shown that the real economic gains of workers in the post-wTar period, including fringe benefits as well as wage increases, have 1 F T C -SE C figures adjusted to show percentage return on net worth as o f beginning: of year fo r comparison with GM and Ford figures which are calculated on same basis. Before adjustment, the F T C -S E C quarterly figures average 12.7 percent fo r the year. ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT 311 not outpaced productivity, although it probably would have been desirable for them to do so. W e hope this committee will call upon the corporations that have been pri marily responsible for recent rising price trends to provide it with the basic data from which actual increases in the productivity of their workers can be computed. W e are confident that such computations will show that the real wages of their workers have lagged behind rather than exceeded their pro ductivity. W e reject, however, the notion that wage increases must never exceed the size of the productivity increment. This notion assumes implicitly that the exist ing relationship between wages and productivity is the proper one. It assumes, further, that workers in industries where productivity advances relatively slowly have no claim to a fair share in the increasing fruits of technological advance in the economy as a whole. Moreover, it would require that workers earning substandard wages abandon all hope of raising their families’ living standards to generally prevailing levels. Furthermore, w e believe it to be a dangerous notion from the standpoint of the long-term health and stability of the economy. The danger flows from the fact that the productivity of capital as well as* of labor is increasing. Thus, year by year, it takes less investment than previously to produce more goods with fewer workers. In consequence, the failure of wages to move ahead faster than productivity would lead to a situation of growing imbalance between a greatly augmented power to produce and an increasingly inadequate power to consume. These considerations of basic economic principles and long-term economic prospects, although definitely relevant, take us far away from the pressing current problem that has brought us together. In order to deal effectively with this problem w e must recognize its unique features. W e must recognize, spe cifically, that our current inflation does not, on the whole, result from abnormally high demand and high production rates pressing against capacity limits. In certain bottleneck areas of the economy, like the steel industry, capacity is a problem; but it is an artiflcally induced problem resulting from the policy of planned scarcity followed by the steel industry in order to maximize its prices and profits while minimizing its risks. Our union has had occasion, in other congressional hearings, to deal with this matter. It would be most instructive, incidentally, for this committee to examine the steel industry’s 1947 projections of future steel capacity needs in the light of shortages currently being experi enced despite capacity that far exceeds what the steel industry said w e would need by this time. The industry still follows a policy of planned scarcity; and that policy supports and reinforces its inflationary price policy. For the economy as a whole, however, the significant feature of the current inflation is that prices are being increased at a time and in industries where current rates of production are substantially below capacity. In fact, in some industries, notably oil, automobiles, and agricultural implements, prices have been raised at a time when sales were depressed and/or inventories were rising. Price increases under these circumstances are obviously not a reflection of the operation of the law of supply and demand. It can be shown also, and w e hope this committee will very soon give us opportunity to show, that in the industries that have contributed significantly to our current inflation, price increases are not the result of cost increases that have squeezed profit margins to an unreasonably small size. W h a t the price increases do reflect, in our opinion, is the existence of an administered price system which enables certain corporations to fix their prices on the basis of what is considered financially desirable for the corporation and without regard to the needs, the welfare, and the stability of the economy as a whole. The action of such corporations in raising prices in the face of adverse market conditions is of most direct concern to those of us in the trade union movement for it has grave effects on the employment opportunities of our members. This is evident from the warning given the auto industry by the president of the National Automobile Dealers Association before the increase in prices on 1957 models. This gentleman, Mr. Carl Fribley by name, said that higher price tags “could mean the difference between a 6y2- to 7-million-car year or a 5Vi- to 6million-car year.” Such a difference in sales would reflect itself in a difference of approximately 100,000 jobs in the automobile industry. There is evidence that the effects are already being felt. As of mid-December, 83,000 workers were unemployed in the Detroit area compared to 45,000 in the same month a year earlier. 87624 0 — 57-------21 312 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT The administered price system should also, in our opinion, occupy a central place in the attention of this committee. The Joint Economic Committee operates under a statute which has as its goal the achievement and maintenance of m a x i m u m employment. It is obvious, however, that full employment policy can be nullified and frustrated in practice by abuse of the power possessed by certain corporations to fix prices administratively. Such abuse results in the siphoning off into a relatively few corporate treasuries of purchasing power required to sustain demand in other areas of the economy. N o matter what m a y be done by Government and private groups to provide the economy with adequate purchasing power, abuses under the administered price system can make their efforts inade quate to sustain full employment. The existence of the administered price system in crucially important areas of the economy requires all of us to take a fresh look at the problem of inflation. The shibboleths of the free market, competition, supply and demand, no longer have any validity, if they ever did, for those sectors of the economy where prices are no w fixed by decisions of a few corporate executives rather than by the impersonal interplay of the forces of the market. With respect to these areas of the economy, w e must find ways to make up for the absence of the restraints imposed by competition. This, it seems to us, is one of the central economic problems of our time. W e do not pretend that we have found any final answers to these problems. W e do wish, however, to make two proposals which w e hope will receive the earnest consideration of this committee and of American citizens generally. One proposal calls for self-restraint by our union as an organization, although w e have not been guilty of exceeding the bounds of sound wage policy. The second proposal calls for self-restraint on the part of corporation possessing the power to administer prices. In both cases, the proposals would buttress selfrestraint with the force of public opinion. In both cases, also, the proposals would equip the public with the facts required to measure the degree to which selfrestraint had been exercised in conformity with the requirements of the general welfare. Our union has always believed that economic decisions, and particularly those affecting the general welfare, should be made on the basis of the economic facts rather than on the basis of economic power. This applies whether the power involved be the power to shut down a plant of a corporation and to keep it shut down, or the power to extort from the consumer any price that a corporation m a y deem it advisable in its narrow interest to impose. For ourselves, w e of the U A W are willing to be bound by the policy that demands for wage increases and other economic gains in administered price indus tries should be confined within the limits of the ability to pay, without price in creases, of the efficient firm functioning under full employment conditions. This is no new principle for us. W e first offered to be bound by it during the General Motors strike of 1945-46 when, as noted, more than 200,000 of our members struck 113 days for “wage increases without price increases.” W e offered during that strike to reduce our wage demand, justified though w e were convinced it was, to whatever the amount— zero if need be— that could be paid by the corporation without an increase in its prices. Implementation of this policy requires, of course, that the facts on ability to pay be available to us and to the public. Both must have all the information that is necessary to determine beyond a reasonable doubt the size of the economic package that could be granted without reducing the profits of an efficient firm in a full employment economy below a reasonable level. Obviously this cannot and should not be a universal policy applicable to all industries. It would be improper, inequitable, and economically unsound to apply it in industries where existing wage levels are substandard. In such industries, price increases m a y be necessary to bring wages up to prevailing levels. But such price increases can and should be offset, thus avoiding a rise in the general price level, by price reductions in industries with excessive profits and in others characterized by rapid technological advance. Similarly, this wage policy, designed for an administered price industry, is impracticable and unnecessary in industries where prices are set by competition rather than by corporate fiat. Balancing the obligation w e are ready to assume to be bound by the economic facts, w e propose that a similar obligation be assumed by corporations in a position to administer prices. Specifically, w e propose a statutory mechanism that would assure the public of an adequate flow of essential factual informa tion concerning certain corporate price actions without involving Government in the task of controlling prices. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 313 As we presently visualize it, legislation directed toward this objective would require advance notice and public justification of price increases proposed to be put into effect by any corporation which accounts for more than a specified percentage— perhaps 20 or 25 percent— of the total sales of its industry. Such a corporation would give notice of intention to raise prices to a governmental agency created for this purpose. The agency would thereupon conduct public hearings at which the corporation would be required to present detailed justifi cation, based upon its records, of the need for the proposed price increase. Its testimony would be subject to cross-examination and its pertinent records open for inspection both by the agency’s staff and by representatives of organiza tions or groups opposing the proposed price increase, including other corporations which purchase goods produced by the firm proposing to raise its prices. Following the hearing, the agency would promptly publish the contentions of the parties and the facts as it had determined them. The hearings having been concluded, and the notice period having expired, the corporation involved would then be entirely free to raise the price if it so chose. But the public would have the means to determine for itself whether or not the price increase was justified. These proposals rest on the premise that an effective democracy must be an informed democracy. They impose no compulsion with respect to wage or price actions. They infringe no freedom. They are designed solely to minimize the abuse of freedom through the uninhibited exercise of economic power. They are aimed at encouraging responsibility in the exercise of economic power by remov ing the veil of secrecy that now conceals facts of vital public interest and thus shelters the irresponsible. W e most earnestly urge that the members of this committee give these pro posals their most careful consideration. W e do not claim they are necessarily the best or the only answer to the problem of administered-price inflation. W e do hope that consideration of these proposals will yield implementing ideas, necessary modifications and, possibly, better alternatives. W e offer these ideas now as a modest contribution toward the development of workable means for the achievement of responsible economic self-restraint on the part of all groups in our population. Such restraint, w e believe, is an essential to the health of a democracy that resorts to compulsion with reluctance and only when lack of self-restraint has led to intolerable abuse. Chairman P a t m a n . Mr. Karl Fox, head, department of economics and sociology, Iowa State College. STATEMENT OF KARL FOX, HEAD, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND SOCIOLOGY, IOWA STATE COLLEGE Mr. Fox. Mr. Chairman, I am going to confine my remarks to things more or less directly related to agriculture. To w^hat extent have agricultural prices contributed to this recent rise in the general price level ? To what extent have price increases in other parts of the economy affected the welfare of farm people ? In recent years, United States agriculture has been subjected to a series of shocks and pressures that have caused farm product prices to move oppositely to prices of other goods and services. During the first few months of hostilities in Korea, prices of both farm and indus trial products rose sharply. Both sets of prices declined a little dur ing 1951-52, but after August 1952 farm prices fell rapidly while industrial prices leveled off and subsequently increased. Two factors sparked the initial drop in farm prices. A big in crease in cattle marketings dropped cattle prices more than a third between August 1952 and August 1953. At the same time our exports of farm products w^ere sharply re duced—wheat from 444 million bushels in 1951-52 to 296 million in 1952-53, and cottom from 5.5 million bales in 1951-52 to 3.0 million in 1952-53. Stocks of wheat and cotton began piling up rapidly under 314 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT the Government loan program. In 1953, big crops of wheat and cotton were produced on unrestricted acreages, swelling our carry over by more than 300 million bushels of wheat and 4 million bales of cotton. In 1954, marketing quotas were applied to wheat and cotton and acreages of these crops were reduced. But most of the acres taken out of wheat and cotton were planted to feed crops, which flooded over into the livestock economy of the Corn Belt and other regions. The resulting low prices and ample supplies of feed led to a rapid increase in livestock production and, among other things, to the ruinously low hog prices of late 1955 and early 1956. By December 1955 prices re ceived by farmers were down to bedrock, 24 percent lower than in August 1952 Prices paid by farmers fell only 3 percent, and the parity ratio fell from 102 down to 80. The decrease in prices paid was small comfort to farmers generally, as it resulted from lower prices for feed and cattle purchased by some farmers from other farmers. Retail prices of food also declined, though not nearly so much per centagewise as did prices at the farm level. The decline in food prices permitted a misleading stability in the general level of consumer prices. Thus, the Consumer Price Index stood at 114.3 (1947-49=100) in August 1952 and at 114.6 in February 1956; up only a fraction of 1 percent. But the food price component of this index declined from 116.6 to 108.8 between the 2 months; retail prices of other goods and services evidently increased by 3 or 4 percent. From February 1956 to November 1956, the retail food price index recovered about 4 points of its earlier decline. With food prices no longer falling, the increase in nonfarm prices was clearly revealed and the Consumer Price Index as a whole rose 3.2 points, about 3 percent, from February to November 1956. Prices received by farmers also arose about 3 percent between the 2 months, but a corresponding increase in prices paid kept the parity ratio at 81 in both months. Thus, changes in farm prices and incomes during the past 4 or 5 years have been deflationary and have been dominated by special prob lems peculiar to the agricultural sector. These problems result in part from Government policies and are in part amenable to correction by Government programs. With huge surpluses of wheat, cotton and corn available for sale at prices determined by the Government, the agricultural sector cannot play an active inflationary role in the economy during the next 2 or 3 years. However, a moderate rise in farm product prices could be induced if production of corn and other feed grains wrere cut below the level of consumption and export demands. Market prices of feed grains would drift upward from points well below applicable support prices to levels slightly above them; within a year or 2 prices of some live stock products would rise by a similar percentage until normal livestock-feed price relationships were restored. The effects upon farm people of changes in nonagricultural prices enter via marketing charges on the one hand and production expenses on the other. Farm prices for livestock and other perishable food products are equal to retail prices minus marketing charges. In creases in freight rates, container prices, and labor costs per unit of product handled may be regarded as driving a wedge between farmers and consumers. Such increases have indeed occurred. From 1952 ECONOMIC REPORT OF TH E PRESIDENT 315 (annual average) to October 1956 the retail cost of the “ food market basket” declined about 4 percent. But marketing changes increased 7 percent, and the farmer’s return declined 18 percent. The farmers’ share of the consumers’ food dollar decreased from 47 percent to 40 percent during this period. Prices received by farmers (times quantities sold) determine gross farm income. Net farm income equals this gross income minus pro duction expenditures. From 1952 to 1955 gross farm income fell nearly $4 billion. Production expenditures decreased about $1 billion, due to lower prices for purchased feed and livestock; expenditures for items of nonfarm origin remained about constant, while net farm in come fell $3 billion—over 20 percent. Gross farm income and pro duction expenditures in 1956 are both up slightly from 1955, and net farm income, including Soil Bank payments, is also up a little. Increases in prices of farm machinery and other items used in pro duction will reduce net farm income unless support prices, based upon the parity index, are increased proportionately. But this effect lags a year behind the increase in prices paid and applies directly to prod ucts accounting for less than half of gross farm income. The effect of higher price supports for corn on prices of livestock takes another year or more to materialize. Under current conditions, a general price inflation with no increase in the real incomes of consumers will tend to undermine the real net incomes of farm operators from farming. On the other hand, an increase in the real income of consumers tends to raise farm prices of livestock and other perishable food products by a somewhat larger percentage, with favorable effects on net farm in come and its purchasing power. Thus, farmers have a stake in the maintenance of high employment without price inflation if the two can be reconciled. Thank you. Chairman P a t m a n . Thank y o u , sir. Mr. Albert Rees, associate professor of economics at the University of Chicago. STATEMENT OF ALBERT REES, ASSOCIATE PROFESSOR OF ECONOMICS, UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO Mr. R e e s . Mr. Chairman, members of the committee, the rise in prices during 1956 should be viewed against the background of 3 preceding years of extraordinary price stability. The con sumer price index has risen slightly more than 3 percent in the past 4 years, during a period when employment has been high and growth has been rapid. This good record wTas not accidental. It was made possible by generally sound monetary and fiscal policies, in which the administration, the Congress, and the Federal Reserve System can take pride. Our commitments to maintain high employment means that there is always a potential danger of inflation. However, I doubt whether the price rise of the past year is the beginning of an immediate infla tionary movement. The stringency of present monetary policy and the surplus in the cash budget should be sufficient to check any substan tial further price rises. I f business expenditures for new plant and equipment were to fall from the unprecedented level they have now 316 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT reached, which could well happen, I should expect to see prices turn downward. The portions of the President’s state of the Union message dealing with inflation were disappointing to me, particularly so because I have admired the general economic policies of the Eisenhower ad ministration. An appeal to business and labor for price and wage restraint is no novelty; similar appeals were made by President Truman on sev eral occasions. We have learned that this method of fighting in flation encounters two difficulties. First, in most areas of a free economy, it won’t work. Many busi nessmen and union leaders will refuse to act against their own inter ests ; other who might be willing to do so will be dissuaded when they see rivals pursuing a more profitable course. It might be added that appeals for restraint are least effective where the economic system is most competitive. Second, and more important, such appeals, if heeded, can do much harm. In a moment I shall try to explain how this harm is done. The President said, “ Business in its pricing policies should avoid unnecessary price increases, especially at a time like the present when demand in so many areas presses hard on short supplies.” This suggests that price increases can only be justified by higher costs. But higher demand may itself be a justification for price increases. Higher prices direct goods where needs are greatest and insure that purchases are reduced most where needs are least. Buyers whose requirements are not urgent will postpone or reduce their demands or turn to substitute commodities. The alternative under voluntary price restraint is for sellers of scarce goods to allot them among eager buyers according to past patronage, or on the basis of friendship, or in exchange for favors. In other words, where you have a price that will not clear the market and where some form of nonprice rationing would be required to divide goods among buyers, I believe prices increases are justified even if there has been no change in costs. That does not mean, of course, that all price increases are justified. Such a system—that is, a system of nonprice rationing—discrimi nates against new and growing firms and against new and growing uses of materials at a time when innovation and growth are badly needed. Discussion of recent price rises in the press and by business leaders has usually been stated almost entirely in terms of costs and has neglected the role of demand. It is interesting to note that during 1956 the wholesale prices of durable finished producer goods rose 8.3 percent, while the wholesale prices of durable consumer goods rose only 3.8 percent. Changes in the costs of producing these two kinds of goods must have been very similar, but in 1956 the demand for producer goods increased rapidly. The particular cost whose role is most emphasized is wages, and wage increases are attributed largely to labor unions. Indeed, unions are often thought to be primarily responsible for inflation. As applied to the United States, this view is certainly too simple and probably substantially wrong. First, unions have had less influence on wages, even for their members, than is usually assumed. Since 1939 aver- ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 317 age hourly earnings in manufacturing have risen from 63 cents to $2.05, more than a threefold rise. Most of this rise is surely due to the increase in quantity of money, to rising productivity, and to the high level of demand for labor. I should be surprised if unions are responsible for as much as 10 percent of it, though the dramatic nature of the collective bargaining process often causes them to get credit for much more. Of course, unions have also made important and desirable noneconomic gains for their members, such as the estab lishment of machinery for handling grievances. Nor have unions necessarily contributed to inflation to the extent that they have raised the wages of their members. The state of the Union message said: W a g e increases that outrun productivity, however, are an inflationary factor. This is true in some circumstances, but it need not be true. Suppose that in a period of price stability wages rise more than pro ductivity in industries that are not experiencing any labor shortage. This creates a nasty dilemma for the Government. I f the monetary and fiscal authorities keep aggregate demand high enough to maintain employment in the affected industries, prices will rise. I f aggregate demand is restrained or reduced to keep prices stable, either wages in other industries will fall or, more likely, unemployment will increase. The essential point is that any government not controlled by labor unions can choose between the horns of this dilemma. I f it chooses to restrain demand, it reduces the extent to which the wage increase will be passed on to consumers in higher prices, and it creates a powerful check to further wage increases. While the choice between these unpleasant alternatives may some day confront us, I doubt whether it has confronted us as yet. Past price rises, in my opinion, have started wTith increases in demand. In particular, the price rises of 1956 seem to me to be much more closely related to heavy business investment than to collective bargaining. But regardless of the source of a rise in the general price level, reduc tions in the rate of growth of the money supply and surpluses in the Federal cash budget are the only sound weapons for combating it. I have not had time in this statement to touch on the role of produc tivity in determining particular wages. Since it has been mentioned very frequently here this morning, I might say that productivity in one particular industry should have anything at all to do with the determination of wages in that industry. I think the relationship is a much more general one. I f time permits I should like to come back tc that point later in the discussion. Chairman P a t m a n . Thank you. Members of the committee are limited as the panel is, so I shall be very brief, and then I shall yield to Senator Watkins. First, I am going to try something that we have done before, to get the attitude of the members of this fine panel on two questions. The first question is whether or not you see any signs of a buyer s strike or buyer’s resistance to higher prices. I f you see any sign of evidence of buyer’s resistance to higher prices would you mind indicat ing by an uplifting of hands ? Do you see any signs or any evidence? I see Mr. Keyserling, Mr. Brubaker, Mr. Weinberg, and Mr. Rees have their hands raised. 87624— 57-------21 318 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Mr. B r u b a k e r . I am personally on strike against the higher prices of cars. Chairman P a t m a n . That would be included. I had reference to any industry. As you know a large part of the capital expenditure for plant and equipment are obtained by higher prices through retained earnings— in fact, last year I think the evidence before this committee disclosed that 67 percent of the capital expenditures was obtained from retained earnings and depreciation. Testimony yesterday disclosed that this year it will probably be 70 percent, as prices are set higher in order to acquire expansion capital. Do you believe that could be one of the principal causes of inflationary danger that we will face in 1957 ? Mr. B r u b a k e r . I so noted in my statement, the part I did not get to present. Chairman P a t m a n . I do not believe that I will ask any more ques tions until the other members of the committee have had an oppor tunity to inquire. I shall now yield to Senator Watkins. Senator W a t k i n s . Mr. Chairman, I would like to say that so much was said in a few minutes, I am quite overwhelmed with the state ments and contradictory statements. I want to read it and analyze it all and I think I can contribute most at this time by listening. Chairman P a t m a n . Senator Sparkman, of Alabama. Senator S p a r k m a n . Mr. Chairman, perhaps it would be a matter of wisdom for me to follow the example set by Senator Watkins, but a great many questions are raised in my mind by the various, statements. Since the last statement is freshest on my mind, I think I will start off by asking a question about the price stability that we have had. I notice the statement that we have had remarkable price stability for the period of the last 3 years, and then have had a sharp rise during 1956Just for curiosity’s sake, I went back to the tables shown in the Consumer Price Index. I would like to ask this question: Is it not true that that stability really started back in the latter part of 1951 or the latter part of 1952, or you might even put it earlier than that? Did it not tie in almost exactly with the decline in farm prices? Mr. Rees. Senator, it is quite true that if you look at wholesale prices-----Senator S p a r k m a n . I am looking at consumer prices. Mr. Rees. There was some rise in consumer prices during the period you mention. Senator S p a r k m a n . I wonder if you would turn to page 23 of Economic Indicators and then look on page 25 at the table, Prices Received and Paid by Farmers. It seems to me that there is a re markable parallel if you look at the graphs and particularly if you look at the index numbers given before the graph in each case. I notice, for instance, that in 1951 all items stood at 111. That was just about the time that we were working under controls following the terrific price upsurge that resulted from the Korean War. I notice it stod at 111. In 1952 it stood at 113.5; in 1953, 114.5; in 1954, 114.8; in 1955, back to 114.5. The latter part of that year it started going up, 114.9, 115, and it ended back at 114.7. It maintained pretty close to that level until some time this year. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 319 The index on the farmers’ prices follows almost exactly the same pattern except in the inverse. Mr. Rees. Senator, it is true that the rise in the consumer price index during 1952 and 1951 was quite modest, and I think that is also a good record. I did not mean to disparge it in any way. Senator S p a r k m a n . I am not bringing up that question. I want to show that was when we were coming out of the war period because someone else has said that inflation usually results from war. But I wanted to see if my reasoning is correct that it was accom panied by a loss of prices to the farmer which, in my opinion, made the difference. Mr. Rees. This is certainly an important element in the whole price picture. My feeling here is that the Government’s overall monetary and fiscal policy—I am not speaking at the moment about its agricul tural policy—ought to be directed toward the stabilization of the general price level and toward high employment. In this general price level I include agricultural prices. I do not believe there is any way of using monetary and fiscal policy in such a way as to offset price declines in one particular sector of the economy. I might say that if agricultural prices had remained stable in that period, it is not clear to me that it necessarily follows that the general price level would have risen, because it is quite possible that in those circumstances the prices of industrial commodities would have risen less than they actually did. Senator S p a r k m a n . I wonder .if we may go one step further? Farm prices did start to rise in the summer of 1956. Is that not the same time that the general price index started up? Has not the level of farm prices pretty much followed the trend? I am agreeing with you that you cannot use the fiscal policy of the Government for one single segment of our economy, but on the other hand, I think it is just as important that we not hide our heads in the sand and think that because the farmers of the Nation have borne the burden over these years, we need not be concerned with the inflationary price increases which have occurred. I am not an economist, but it does not seem to me that we are getting anywhere if we assume we have had overall price stability without taking into consideration the fact that the farmers have pretty well had the burden of the maintenance of that stability. Mr. Rees. I think it would have been healthy if the price move ment during that period had been composed of greater stability within both the agricultural and the nonagricultural components, rather than offsetting movement. Given the surpluses of farm prod ucts that we have had, it seems to me the only natural and permanent way of achieving that would have been to move resources out of agriculture at a faster rate than we actually did. I think, though, that questions in this area should really be directed to Mr. Fox, because he knows a great deal more about that than I do. Senator S p a r k m a n . The reason I directed them to you is because I felt that you dealt with that subject in your paper. By the way, on this question of surpluses, if we go back to the time when this instability began we did not have farm surpluses, did we? Do you remember, at that time we had to borrow on cotton ? I would be glad for anyone to comment on this. May I go on to say we had an embargo on cotton. We could not ship cotton out of this 320 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT country, there was such a scarcity. When India wanted wheat, one of the great objections raised to it was the fact that we did not have enough wheat to spare, but India wanted to relieve her famine. It has not been so long. Mr. K eyserling. I want to make some comments on what Senator Sparkman has said, because I think his question promises to direct this inquiry to some things that are very pertinent. In the first place, it is true that between the middle of 1951 and the middle of 1953 or shortly thereafter, we had a faster rate of economic growth than we have now, fuller utilization of our resources, much fewer surpluses, and much less price inflation, which indicates the first very important point, that the price inflation of today is not the tradi tional situation generally of supply pressing against demand, but is rather the administered process of raising prices without justification or necessity. Second, I understood Senator Sparkman to make the point that we have to consider the allocation and use of our resources, as well as the price structure. I f I may say something for a minute about that, because I think it is central, the barrage of price and wage statistics that have been flung at us means nothing unless it is put in the framework of what our economy is really trying to do. Our economy is really trying to do only two things: Use its resources to produce to the maximum, and get that product used to serve our interests as a nation both overseas and at home. Prices and wages are merely the machinery through which we try to so allocate resources that we get maximum production and use it wisely. In order to test whether the price trends and wage trends are mov ing in a favorable or unfavorable direction, you have to set them against the pattern of what is happening to the real economy. What is happening to the real economy now is this, basically: Investment in plant and equipment has been moving relatively too fast as against consumption. I f you think this is my special statement, any business analyst will tell you that the real problem for the year ahead is that consumption is not growing fast enough. It has grown only 2 percent in real terms over the past year. As to the question of the buyers’ strike-----Senator Sparkman. May I interrupt right there ? Mr. K eyserling. Yes, sir. Senator Sparkman. Is my memory correct that within recent weeks 2 or 3 of our big industries have announced a cutback in their expansion ? Mr. K eyserling. Yes; that is correct. That is caused not by an inadequacy of profits or an inadequacy of funds. It is caused by they, themselves, beginning to sniff the air of an inadequacy of consumers. That is why they are cutting back. That is where the imbalance is. There was a question about a buyers' strike. Consumers are not on strike. Consumers do not have the money to buy enough to take up our expanding productive capacity. I f they were on a buyers’ strike, you would not have had the support of the inadequate level of consumer buying in the past year and a half by an utterly irrational credit boom. Consumers do not borrow more and more to buy with inadequate incomes if they are on strike. This is not a strike proposition. There is just not enough consumer income. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 321 The current trends in prices and wages, respectively, are rationing our resources contrary to our national needs. They are providing relatively too much funds for plant expansion, and relatively too little funds for consumption. From the equitable point-----Senator Sparkman . Would you say, relative to the amount which is available for the construction of homes for Americans at reasonable price ? Mr. K eyserling. That is also true. That brings us to the second point, that the utilization of our national economic policy, both the budgetary and hard money policy, is also rationing resources con trary to our primary needs as a nation. The hard money policy is not interfering with the investment boom. It is interfering with the construction of schools. The hard money policy is not interfering with big business. It is interfering with the marginal producer. The budgetary policy, to the extent that it has been anti-inflationary, has been anti-inflationary at an excessive cost in terms of basic needs. But it has also been inflationary in the short run, because it has built up bottlenecks. In other words, a policy that does not provide enough w^ater, a policy that does not provide enough roads, a policy that does not provide enough schools when the Russians are training skilled workers 4 or 5 times as fast as we are, is inflationary in the short run and deflationary in the long run. Senator Sparkman. Would you go one step further and say, a policy that is starving or threatening to starve small business? Mr. K eyserling. That is also true. I suggest, if I may humbly do so, that this committee look at the Employment Act of 1946 once again, which sets forth in one sentence a simple and adequate criterion of what economic policy is all about, to w it: What are our needed levels of employment, production, and purchasing power to meet our national needs? That, of course, involves the distribution and disposition of prod uct. I f we have enough resources to add 50 to the horsepower of automobiles every year, and say we do not have enough resources to out-pace the Russians, there is something wrong. I f we have enough-----Senator Sparkman. I hate to break in, but you and I together have used my share of the time. Chairman P atman . This is so interesting, I have been talking to Senator Sparkman about having an afternoon session. Mr. Kilburn ? Represenative K ilburn. This has been very instructive to me. I am a little puzzled, however, by the varying statements of Mr. Smith, Mr. Hitchings, Mr. Weinberg, and Mr. Brubaker. Did you all use the same set of figures ? Mr. W einberg. May I make a comment on that? In the case of Mr. Hitchings’ presentation, I think it is interesting and significant that he dealt very largely with information on the overall economy and stayed carefully away from information with respect to the Fora Motor Co. The thing we are concerned about is that our current inflation is not the result of uniform price movements and price policies through out the economy, but the price practices of a few corporations that happen to be located at strategic crossroads of the economy where they 322 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT can exert enormous economic influence. They exert that influence through the price mechanism. To take overall figures for the econ omy as a whole and to ignore the specific figures pertaining to those corporations serves to obscure the real source of our present price problems. In that connection, I would like to make one comment with respect to what the chairman of the committee has said. The\<shairman has referred to the fact that business has been raising capitjal through its excessive prices. I would like to stress the fact that there is no need for it to raise capital this way, nor is it the proper way to raise capital. The fact that there is no need is evident from page 135 of the Pres ident’s Economic Report. There you will find that since 1947 dividend payments have approximately doubled. Since 1950 they have in creased by one-third. I f corporations were starved for capital, they would not be paying out these dividends to stockholders. They would be retaining more of their earnings for investment. Then we come to the question of the propriety of this means of raising capital. Traditionally in economic theory it has been believed that the proper way to allocate capital resources as well as other resources was through competition—to go out into the competitive market for capital and sell stocks and bonds. But business does not do that today. Instead of raising capital tamong investors, it asks consumers to provide investment funds through excessive prices. However, the consumer gets no equity when he makes the investment. I would feel a little better about this policy, if with every item containing steel that I bought, I received a share of stock or a part of a share of stock in one of the steel corporations. This would make some sense. I f I am to supply the investment capi tal, I should get an equity. What we are concerned about is the fact that some corporations— not the whole economy, not small business, not the businesses in the competitive industries—but some corporations, controlling tremen dous shares of the total market for their industries are able, at will, to fix prices at a level that they think will best serve their own pur poses, regardless of what happens to the rest of the economy. That is why we have been urging repeatedly, since long before this inflation broke out, starting in July 1955, that a thorough investiga tion be made of the price practices of corporations that are in a posi tion to fix prices, and we hope that such an investigation will be forthcoming. Representative K ilburn. It is still not clear why you all use this same set of figures to come to so many different conclusions. Mr. B rubaker. May I comment on that % One of the central figures in Mr. Smith’s presentation was this com parison of United States Steel figures between 1940 and 1955, in which he pointed out that there had been an increase, according to his figures, in employee cost per hour during that period of 8.1 per cent per year. Very frankly, I hope there has been an increase in employee cost per hour during that period. It wrould be a tragic thing if this had not been, because we have had a tremendous increase in production by United States Steel during that period. We have had a tremen dous growth in output per man-hour. I f wages per man-hour did not go up during that period, it wrould simply mean that these poor ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 323 wage earners in steel would have less and less money with which to buy, with which to consume, as Mr. Keyserling has pointed out. I think to round out the picture that Mr. Smith has given you, we ought to look at United States Steel’s other figures from 1940 to 1955. I f you would look at them you would find that their sales have gone up from roughly $1 billion to more than $4 billion in that period. Their profits before taxes have gone up from $128 million to $736 million. Their net profits have gone up from $102 million to $370 million. Representative K ilburn. Wouldn’t their profits naturally follow sales? Mr. B rubaker. Yes, but they not only followed their sales but they went up by sixfold whereas the sales went up only by fourfold. Representative K ilburn. Are you talking about net profits on their investment ? Mr. B rubaker. This was profits before taxes. I have a figure on net profits on investment. Their net profits on investment in 1940 stood at the level of 71/£ percent. In 1955, at the end of this 15 years, their profit on investment was 14.3 percent, or almost twice as great. This is a picture not of inflation caused by increased employment costs. This is a question of inflation caused by an effort to increase their profit margin. The evidence is there. It is from their own figures. Let me give you two other figures to fill this in, wages and salaries as a percent of the corporation’s sales dollar in 1940 versus 1955. In 1940 wages and salaries were 43 percent of the corporation’s sales dollar. In 1955 it wTas only a little over 39 percent. In other words, we are losing ground within the corporation itself and within the industry in terms of the amount of sales dollar that goes to wages. Representative K ilburn. I don’t think that that in a way is a sound argument to me if the difference accounts for expense of techno logical improvements. Mr. B rubaker. But this is the total amount which they paid for all employment costs. They are saying that these costs have gone up and they imply that somehow this is bad. Representative K ilburn. I agree with you and with what the Presi dent says. Mr. Rees brought out that you ought to keep abreast of productivity. That is my next question to you and to Mr. Wein berg : I f the big companies do not raise their prices unduly for other reasons, do you think that the wages should increase only with productivity ? Mr. B rubaker. Y ou are asking me an “ iffy” question there. I think the answer in terms of our own union is a fairly simple one. It isn’t a question of what we think they should or should not do. The question is what has actually happened. I gave you a comparison in my formal statement as to what has actually happened. We are pictured in the press constantly as being a big union that can force wage increases that are out of relationship to productivity. Actually, if you go back and look at the figures since our union was founded, if you go back and take the figures from the base date used in the recent BLS productivity study, the rise in real productivity, the out put per man-hour in steel, has been 68.8 percent. The real straighttime earnings which our people have received have risen only 48.3 324 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT percent. I f you would add to that an allowance for the fringe bene fits which have also improved sharply during that period, you would still find that the growth in output per man-hour has been greater than the total increase in real wages and fringes This is very simple. Whether we wanted to or whether we didn’t, we have not been able to and we have not forced wages and fringe benefits up in our industry faster than productivity has gone up. Representative K ilburn. It seems to me that there you have an area of agreement while you folks disagree on your analysis of figures. Mr. B rubaker. I don’t think so. There ; >mething much more basic than the figures here. Mr. S mith . I think I know the figures of my company and the steel industry’s fairly well. All I would like to do at this point is to throw in a little facts. Rather than use those I will, if I may, use this same Bureau of Labor Statistics computation to which Mr. Bru baker has referred. The increase in output per man-hour, so-called productivity, as calculated by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, has averaged from 1939 to 1955, I believe their calculation was 2.8 percent per annum. This compares with the 8.1 percent increase in the cost per employee-hour. Chairman P atman . Mr. Bolling. Representative B olling. I would like to hear what Mr. Rees has to say on that question. Mr. R ees. Thank you, Mr. Bolling. Representative K ilburn. S o would I. Mr. R ees. I don’t want to comment on the figures of output per man-hour versus employment costs in the steel industry. I am not familiar with those figures for recent years. But I do want to say that I don’t think you can arrive at a sound wage policy by making that particular kind of comparison. To the extent that productivity has any bearing on wages, it has to be the productivity of the economy as a whole and cannot be the productivity of the particular industry. To illustrate it very simply, suppose you had an industry whose productivity was increasing by leaps and bounds because this was a rapidly growing industry and one employing a lot of new technology. Suppose we had applied these standards to the television industry starting in 1946. You would have choked off the growth of that in dustry. The workers in that industry are entitled to*some of the productivity gains but they surely are not entitled to all of them in that kind of situation. Something has to be passed on to the consumer in the form of lower prices. In addition, where you are getting heavy investment in an industry, output per man-hour is rather a bad measure of productivity. The measure you want, which is a hard one to find and much more difficult to compute and that is why we don’t use it very much, is output per unit of input, wherein that input you include not only labor input but also inputs of capital and other resources. We can turn that around. Suppose we applied this kind of standard to an industry which because of its nature is not subject to rapid technological progress. I am a teacher. It takes 1 teacher to teach 30 to 35 students. I assume it did 100 or 150 or 200 years ago. At least there is no measurable way of demonstrating that teachers’ productivity has gone up. I think you could say the same about Congressmen. They may be more productive now than they were at ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 325 the foundation of the Republic, but we certainly haven’t any statistics to prove it. Senator W atkins. Y ou might check on the number and kind of bills that we introduce. I think we have shown some progress. Mr. R ees. All I intend to do by this little joke is to show that if we want some of these industries to survive which are not subject to rapid technological progress, and we don’t want all their labor bid away by other kinds of employment, we have got to let the people who work in these industries share in the growth of our economy, and in doing that it means that we cannot give the people in the rapidly growing industries, either the workers or the owners, the full fruits of progress in those industries. That is why this discussion of the relation between wages and output per man-hour in the steel industry is likely to be misleading, because I don’t think either side can prove its case by reference to these figures. Representative B olling. I would like to get off on a slightly differ ent tack, if I might, and I know there are other people who would like to comment on this. I would like to ask Mr. Rees what criterion should be used in determining a rate of return on investment that con stitutes a reasonable level. Mr. R ees. This gets us back in terms of ability to pay as a criterion of wage increases. This is one that Mr. Weinberg has mentioned. I would disagree on that one, too, Mr. Bolling. I don’t believe that proper wage levels can be determined by ability to pay, and therefore if you are concerned about wage-price relationships I would not want to get into the kind of determination of a fair rate of return that one gets into, say, in setting public utility rates. Again, the obvious way of demonstrating this is to take the concern which is losing money. I f one of the automobile producers or any other company is losing money, unions will be very reluctant to say that that is a reason for a wage cut and quite rightly so because these workers are worth just as much, their services are just as valuable, their needs are just as great, whether the company is profitable or not. Perhaps I haven’t answered your question, but I don’t believe that it should be part of Government policy to determine a fair rate of return outside of the regulated industries. I surely would not want to say what a fair one is. It would have to be higher for risky industries than it is for regulated industries, which are by and large very safe industries in which to invest. Representative Bolling. In other words, you would not want even to say that you thought 20 percent on investment was a fair rate of return ? Mr. R ees. A s an overall rate of return for the whole economy it would certainly seem excessive, but if we have a particular industry where our needs for investment are very great and that industry is risky and the only way we can attract investment into that industry is to offer it 20 percent, I could conceive of circumstances in which I might regard that as fair. Representative B olling. There are representatives here from either side of two industries. For purposes of illustration, what wrould they say wrould be a fair rate of return in the automobile industry or the steel industry ? Mr. R ees. Mr. Bolling, I just don’t feel competent to answer that question, sir. I will have to decline to. 326 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Mr. H itchings. I would like an opportunity to comment since the auto industry has been mentioned specifically. Like Mr. Smith, I assumed that the present hearing was directed toward a broad inquiry into prices for the economy as a whole rather than a specific investiga tion of the auto industry or the steel industry or any other. Representative B olling. We are not attempting to do that. Let us be very clear. Mr. H itchings. I agree with Mr. Rees that profits and productivity of a particular company or industry should not be the controlling cri teria for establishing wage rates in that company or industry. Fur thermore, the facts for the auto industry do not support the extrava gant claims made as to increases in profits and productivity relative to wages. When periods of like unit volume are compared (and this is the only proper comparison for price-cost-profit relationships), dollar payrolls have advanced while profits have not. This is illustrated in a comparison for our own company of 1956 with 1954 and 1950, in each of which years unit volume amounted to about 2 million vehicles. The year 1956 is a proper base because it was neither exceptionally high nor low. Employee payrolls (including supplemental benefits) in 1956 were 13 percent above 1954 and 83 percent above 1950. Part of this total represented increased hourly and salaried man-hours, but the cost per hour worked by hourly employees was up 11 percent and 43 per cent over 1954 and 1950, respectively. By contrast, the profit position deteriorated. Total profits in 1956 were about the same as 1954 and slightly below the 1950 level. Since invested capital at the beginning of 1956 was 29 percent above 1954 and virtually double that of 1950, the return on investment declined sub stantially. Furthermore, the purchasing power of total profits was less than in 1954 and 1950 after adjustment for higher prices of goods and services purchased by the corporation and its stockholders. Such was not the case for employee compensation. Similarly, there are no facts to support the exaggerated claims of productivity increases. There are no adequate measures of comparable input and output for a company such as ours. A simple compari son of hourly worker man-hours per unit of finished output contains many flaws. It fails to include in input the other factors of pro duction and it also fails to distinguish changes in the type of output. Furthermore, changes in the ratio cannot be ascribed to the labor factor. To the extent that the simple ratio of hourly worker man-hours to vehicle output is used, however, it shows no improvement in 1956 over 1954 and some deterioration from 1950. Chairman P atman . Dr. Talle, would you like to ask some questions ? Representative T alle. Mr. Chairman, I will forego questions at the moment. Chairman P atman . Senator O’Mahoney ? Senator O’M ahoney . I came too late to add anything to this panel discussion, not knowing what has been said. Chairman P atman . We are back to Senator Sparkman. Senator Sparkman . I was just going to suggest to Senator O’Ma honey that he could question very well on the two papers presented here with somewhat conflicting views related to the steel industry. As ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 327 I recall, it was Senator O’Mahoney who conducted the study that we made back in about 1948 when there was a similar wage rise in steel followed by the still greater price rise in steel, and tried to determine the extent to which the price raise was justified by the wage rise. I am sure you remember that quite well. I may say, remembering the difficulty we had in reconciling such figures as have been given here by the two different sides, I can easily see the confusion which sometimes develops, but I believe that there was a pretty fair showing made in those hearings and certainly in things that have happened since then to lend some justification to the feeling that many of us have—and I have heard Senator O’Mahoney state it many times—that there is a rather large area of administered prices in some of the big industries. Senator O’M ahoney. There isn’t any doubt about that. Senator, and I would say offhand that price increases when administered by large companies are just like taxes imposed upon the people by Gov ernment for the support of the Government. The United States Steel Co. increases the price of steel, as I see it, for the purpose of getting what should be gotten from investment capital markets instead. This is the habit of many corporations now. Internal financing of big com panies is made possible by the huge profits which are kept undis tributed and are plowed back into the industry. Then whenever la bor seeks to have an increase in wages in order to create the market, speaking in terms of consumer economics, for all industries, the re sult is that the steel company has very frankly increased the price to the public to balance whatever increase in wage has been granted, in stead of taking it out of profits or of going to the market to borrow or seek the investment. I think there was a very great contrast be tween the financing of the American Telephone & Telegraph during the past year and the financing of United States Steel. American Telephone & Telegraph went into the money market to get the money by inducing new stockholders to put up the cash, capital investment for the expansion of plant. United States Steel sought to get the money for the expansion of plant not in the capital market but in the profit market by increasing its price. Senator Sparkman. Our chairman is going to have to leave in a short time. I wouid like to yield the balance of my time to him. Chairman P atman . Thank you, sir. I want to make just one ob servation, Senator O’Mahoney. Over the years I have noticed more and more of expansion capital is obtained from retained earnings and depreciation. To me that is an alarming trend. It is contrary to our private enterprise system, if I understand it correctly. I would like to be set right if I am wrong about it. Here is the way I understand it : It is all right for a concern that has the power to fix its own prices through administered pricing to charge a sufficient price to take care of wage costs, products and serv ices bought for use in the business, interest, all kinds of taxes, local, net profit, dividends, and even some surplus—but anything in excess of that amount seems to me should not be taken from the consumer in actual prices because it compels the consumer to make an involun tary investment in that concern for which he receives no return. Any returns go to the stockholders. 876 2 4 0 — 57--------22 328 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT In other words, if an automobile company adds $100 to the price of each car for expansion capital—and I suspect that is probably a fair amount to estimate, but I am not sure about it—that company takes that $100 away from the consumer and uses it for itself. That doesn’t seem to me to be exactly right. We find that in 1957, when $40 billion will be spent for plant and equipment, 70 percent of that money will come from retained earnings and depreciation and it is mostly the large firms who can use this method of financing. How can little fellows survive in the face of that competition ? Representative K ilburn. Mr. Chairman, don’t you think any pru dent company should have a backlog to take care of a few lean years? Chairman Patman . Surely. I said it was appropriate to set aside a reasonable amount for surplus for lean years, but this is not for lean years. This is for plant and equipment which is taking money away from the consumer and using it as investment capital. Senator Sparkman. We will announce at this time that there will be a meeting at 2 o’clock. Before you go, Mr. Chairman, I would like to say I have been intending to ask the panel to discuss the question which we have just been developing. I believe Mr. Weinberg sug gested it a while ago. There is this reservation: It is virtually im possible for small business, businesses wanting to borrow, we will say, under a million dollar, to utilize the securities market. So it seems to me that as long as we don’t have credit availability in our existing setup, there ought to be some plan by which they could obtain money. Dr. Talle, are you ready to ask some questions ? Representative T alle. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I will not have time to question. I must go to the floor because we meet at 12. I am sorry. Senator Sparkman. Senator Watkins. Senator W atkins . I want to ask Mr. Smith what he wished to say when he had his hand up a moment ago. Mr. Smith . Senator Watkins, I believe it is Mr. Hitchings who had his hand up. Mr. H itchings. Yes, I would like to comment on this matter of pricing to raise capital. The objective in pricing by business firms is to cover costs and provide a return on their investment. The ability to realize such a price depends, however, on demand for the firms’ products. Depreci ation of existing plant and equipment is a part of the cost of doing business which must be recovered in the sale of the product. In order to keep capital equipment intact, these depreciation allowances are quite properly reinvested in newTplant and equipment. The consumer is merely paying for the cost of facilities used in the production process just as he pays for the materials and labor used to produce the finished product. I f business firms are to expand and provide the necessary growth in jobs and in per capita standards of living, there must be sufficient profit remaining after costs are met to provide an incentive for in creased capital investment in the business. This capital investment can be accomplished either through withoholding a portion of the profits for reinvestment in the business or paying the full amount in dividends and raising the additional capital from external sources. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 329 There is nothing wrong with either method. It is solely a matter of the extent to which management and the stockholders prefer to retain earn ings directly for additional capital investment in the business. Price, coupled with the quantity of goods sold, determines the amount of income available to those who made the production pos sible—the employees who provided the labor, the lenders who provided borrowed money, and the owners who provided the capital. Pricing should be considered in relation to the adequacy of total receipts to cover these costs and provide sufficient profits after taxes to serve as an incentive for necessary expansion of the business. The extent to which income is spent or invested by the various recipients has no bearing on the validity of the prices. Senator O’M ahoney. May I interrupt you. What do you mean by management and stockholders preferring to retain earnings? Mr. H itchings. Management makes the recommendation to the stockholders. The stockholders are the ones who have the voting power. Senator O’M ahoney. But in many companies there are stock holders who have no voting power, particularly the Ford Company. Mr. B rubaker. A distant democracy in most of them, anyway. Mr. H itchings. In some companies that is correct. Senator O’M ahoney. Isn’t it a fact in the Ford Company that the management is retained by a minority of the stockholders, family and the management, the managerial group? Mr. H itchings. The public stock has voting rights, too. Senator O’M ahoney. Some, but there is nonvoting stock, is there not? Mr. H itchings. I would have to check with our people who are here. Senator O’M ahoney. It is a factor in this whole matter of price. Mr. H itchings. The Ford Foundation, I am informed, is the only one which holds any nonvoting stock. Any stock which has been offered to the public of course has voting rights. The original stock issued to the Ford Foundation, a nonprofit enterprise, is nonvoting stock. At that time there was no public stock, but when the Ford Foundation offered that stock publicly it was changed to voting stock. Mr. B rubaker. Could we hear from the steel industry on the same question that you asked ? Senator S parkman. Senator Watkins. Senator W atkins. I want to find out if there is anything illegal or immoral or uneconomic about getting some of the capital to run a business out of profits. Mr. H itchings. N o. Senator W atkins. There has been the intimation here that the consumer should not make any contribution. Mr. H itchings. I wasn’t making any moral judgment at all. All I was saying is that the pricing is not set on the basis of getting profits to plow back for new expansion. That is not the pricing procedure. The pricing procedure is to cover your costs, of which depreciation is one. The decision is made at the time of capital expansion program, which is over and above depreciation allowances, as to how that would be financed. I f it is financed in part, for example, out of not paying out all of the money in dividends, this is a perfectly proper procedure. 330 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Small companies have grown into big companies by the use of that procedure, as I believe Senator Sparkman himself pointed out. I am not taking any moral position as to whether the price should or should not cover capital expansion. All I am saying is that it is not taken into consideration in the pricing of business firms of which I am aware. Mr. B rubaker. May I give my answer to that question ? Senator W atkins. A s a matter of fact, the Ford Co. lias gi*own largely by turning profits back into investment. Mr. H itchings. That is correct. Senator W atkins. And that is true of nearly every firm that has made any great success in this country. Mr. H itchings. That is right. A small business grows into a larger business primarily through reinvestment of retained net profits. Senator W atkins. The gentleman from the steelworkers. I do not mean to neglect him. Mr. B rubaker. I would like to comment very briefly on this question. Mr. Rees earlier avoided answering a question from Congressman Bolling on what was a fair rate of return for steel and autos and so on, on the ground presumably that these are risk industries in which you have to have some kind of freedom to set profits wherever you need to set them or want to set them, and prices accordingly. Actu ally—and I am sure Senator O’Mahoney will remember, too—it was not so many years ago that the steel industry in testifying before him kept pointing out that steel was a prince and pauper industry, that it had such drastic ups and downs that they just had to be free to make a lot one year so they could make up for the years next time when they didn’t make anything. This has not been true for the last 15 years in this industry, and I don’t think there is any reason to expect it to be true. As a result, we have had a rate of return on net worth in the industry in that 15 years that has been more than 10 percent in most years. This is a good return, certainly, for an industry which is no longer a real risk industry in the sense that it might once have claimed it was. When you reach the point where there is no longer serious risk involved in your investment, it then does become, I think, frankly, immoral, Senator Watkins, for an industry to .say “We think we ought to raise the prices to everybody so that we can tap them for some investment funds,” and for the industry not to say that we will go to our stockholders who have an investment, that we will go to the profits that they have made as a return on their investment, to their dividends and even to the retained capital that might be a fair return on their investment and ask them for funds, but instead to say that we will go to the consumers who don’t own any of this and say “ You have got to contribute to this business, too.” The steel industry has been very blunt in the last several years now in saying “We are setting our prices higher than we think they need to be because we want to take money out of the consumer’s pocket for investment purposes, and not give him any stock for it.” I think that is immoral. Senator W atkins . The point I had in mind with respect to the ob taining of capital was sort of sidestepped, Mr. Smith, would you like to make any statement on whether in a free competitive enterprise ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 331 you have any right to use not only the profits but the increased profits in order to make a business grow. I thought that was the way the American enterprise system did grow. Mr. S mith . Senator Watkins, I think you have correctly portrayed the history of our great country. Throughout its entire span the tra ditional, customary, and accepted way for a company to grow and better serve the community, its employees, and itself is to plow back its earnings, so called. Money is miscible. You can’t tell which particular dollar received from the customer is going to go here or going to go there. But I think in order to get some proportions in here we should recall that the total dividends paid in this country are running along about a $12 billion annual rate, I believe, against the disposable income of $288 billion. I am rather personally grateful that instead of paying this money all out in dividends these various companies are making pro vision for the future by taking some of that money which might other wise be paid out in dividends and using it to improve the tools of production, to provide jobs in the process of it, to provide the working capital without which you cannot have those jobs. That is the way our country has grown. I think what Senator Sparkman said is very relevant. I don’t know how in the world so-called small business could ever grow if we developed in this country the notion that every bit of expansion had to come from going outside and borrowing or selling stock. Senator W atkins. I would like to get your response to another query which is in my mind since the gentleman from the steel union made his statement that there is not any risk to amount to anything in the steel business. I happen to live in a community where we have a steel industry. We are worried, I think rightly so, about this un usual demand caused by an artificial situation, planning for defense for our peace, security and liberty. What would happen to us with an expanded steel industry if we suddenly found some wTay to get nations to get along together and the demand for defense purposes became a thing of the past ? Mr. B rubaker. I will tell you where the risk is. Senator W atkins. Just a moment. I want to get the other gentle man’s view. You have stated that there is very little risk. Mr. S mith . I take it it is the hope of everyone in the land, certainly it is my hope, that the business ups and downs can be smoothed out. This is the beginning of 1957. Two and a half years ago the steel industry was down to an operating rate of 62 percent. The notion that the steel industry just automatically is going to go on forever is a notion which we like to play with and we dream about and hope for, but you are up against the hard realities of running a business which does experience ups and down. Senator W atkins. We would like to have a guaranty that the Geneva Steel Mills would continue operating. Mr. B rubaker. H ow much return did you make on your investment in 1954, Bradford ? Let’s get it on the table. Senator W atkins. Have you finished y o u r statement, Mr. Smith? Mr. S mith . I f you wish me to, I will answer Mr. Brubaker’s question. Senator W atkins. I have no objection but I really want to get the answers to mine. 332 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT Mr. Smith . The answer is very simple, that I don’t have time to compute a meaningless figure. Mr. B rubaker. I will tell you what it is if you want to know. Mr. S mith . Because the book values of properties which were pur chased 25 or more years ago are no proper basis for measuring whether or not an income today is adequate. I think that is something with which the committee members are quite thoroughly familiar. Mr. B rubaker. May I comment on that? Senator W atkins. With the Committee’s permission. I think I have used my 10 minutes. Senator Sparkman. We are on Senator O’Mahoney’s time now. Senator O’M ahoney. Mr. Smith, let me ask you, if you know, what proportion of the Government expenditures for defense go to United States Steel. Before you answer let me call your attention to a known fact. The proportion of Government expenditures for defense far exceeds any other expenditure of any kind. Any economic judgment which may be made in this time of war and preparation for wTar can not be based upon the normal facts of a peacetime economy because we do not have a peacetime economy. Now can you answer my question ? Mr. Smith . Senator, I didn’t expect that we were going to have such detailed questions of United States Steel when I came to this meeting. I thought it was a somewhat broader inquiry, so I don’t happen to have the exact figures with me. But I do recollect that the steel-industry direct shipments for defense purposes of late have been very, very small, something less than 10 percent. However, sir, that is not what you are getting at because undoubtedly there is a good deal of steel which indirectly goes to defense purposes—our customers, for example. Senator S parkman. I wonder if I might throw in a statistic there, as given by the Office of Defense Mobilization, that during 1955, 1.8 percent of the steel wTent into defense production. Senator O’M ahoney. That surprises me, frankly, because I thought it would be much greater. Senator S parkman. A very, very small percentage. I will say to Senator Watkins I believe there is a good healthy economy at Geneva. Senator W atkins . It hasn’t been very long ago that it was doubt ful whether we could get any buyer to go out there and take that plant and operate it. It wasn’t until Korea and the heavy demand for steel caused by the economy to sustain a wTar effort or a prospective war effort that wre had any assurance that the plant would be operated. Senator Sparkman. I may state an analogous situation which oc curred toward the end of World War II. Down in the Tennessee Valley we w^ere pretty much alarmed, wondering how in the world we would dispose of all of that power, but we have never had enough at any one time. Senator O’M ahoney. May I proceed ? Senator Sparkman. Please do. Senator O ’M ahoney. I am anxious to elicit such information as we can from these gentlemen. I like the idea—I initiated it, as a matter of fact—of getting the experts to come before the committee to debate with one another for the information of the committee. Mr. S mith . May I say that I remember that occasion. It was many years ago, and I wras present. ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 333 Senator O’M ahoney. Professor Backman, you indicated you want ed to say something. Mr. B a c k m a n . Thank you, Senator. The chairman suggested that there was something contrary to the private-enterprise system in the internal financing of business, and I think several members of the panel have already effectively scotched that idea. The fact remains that most of these figures which are used on rate of return by industry, whether it is all manufacturing or steel or autos or railroads or any other industry, are completely meaningless. They are completely meaningless because they relate an inflated volume of earnings and usually an over-inflated volume of earnings in terms of what they really are to a much deflated base of net worth. I mean simply this: I f you have a plant which cost you $10 million 20 years ago and today that plant would cost you $40 million to replace, you are relating today s earnings to what is left of that $10 million, but more important, when it comes to your earnings all-----Senator O ’M ahoney. Who would want to replace a 20-year-old mill at the stage of technological progress which we now