The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
/ REPORT " B S K T } SENATE \No. 2500 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY 1951-57 REPORT STUDY PREPARED BY ASHER ACHINSTEIN LEGISLATIVE REFERENCE SERVICE LIBRARY OF CONGRESS TOGETHER WITH COMMENTS OF STAFF OF FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND CURRENCY OCTOBER 10, 1958.—Ordered to be printed Under authority of the order of the Senate of August 24, 1958 UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 20006 WASHINGTON ; 1968 COMMITTEE ON B A N K I N G A N D CURRENCY J. W. FULBRIGHT, Arkansas, Chairman A. WILLIS ROBERTSON, Virginia HOMER E. CAPEHART, Indiana JOHN J. SPARKMAN, Alabama JOHN W. BRICKER, Ohio J. ALLEN FREAR, JR., Delaware WALLACE F. BENNETT, Utah PAUL H. DOUGLAS, Illinois PRESOOTT S. BUSH, Connecticut A. S. MIKE MONRONEY, Oklahoma J. GLENN BEALL, Maryland JOSEPH S. CLARK, Pennsylvania FREDERICK G. PAYNE, Maine WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin CLIFFORD P. CASE, New Jersey J. H. YINGLING, Chief Clerk ROBEBT A. WALLACE, Staff Director n CONTENTS Page Statement of chairman Summary Chapter I. The period of transition, 1951-52: Monetary policy and debt management The accord Flexible monetary policy and rising interest rates The money supply Economic developments Revival of the discount mechanism Economic and financial developments in second half of 1952 Federal Reserve credit policy Chapter II. Federal Reserve policies in 1953-54: Appraisals of the business situation, first half of 1953 Money and bank credit, first half of 1953 The objective of a free market The policy of bills—only Debt management policy: The Treasury's 3^s The midyear shift in Federal Reserve policy The 1953-54 business recession The policy of credit ease Bank loans and investments Chapter III. Federal Reserve policy, 1955-57: The key importance of 1955 in recent economic and financial developments The stock market and margin requirements Credit expansion in 1955 Policy directives of the Open Market Committee Policy decisions as viewed in retrospect by the Federal Reserve The discount rate as a tool of monetary restraint The discount rate and consumer credit The shift in Federal Reserve attitude toward consumer credit controls. Monetary policy and the growth of financial intermediaries The tight-money policy and its critics, 1956 to mid-1957 Deliberations of the Open Market Committee in 1957 The mistaken credit policies after mid-1957 Some concluding observations Appendix: Member bank reserves, reserve bank credit, and related items, 1950-57 Comments of staff of Federal Reserve Board: Letter of transmittal Comments v vii 1 3 6 9 11 13 14 15 19 22 26 27 28 . 29 30 34 38 41 43 44 47 52 55 58 61 64 65 67 72 74 77 81 83 I N D E X OF TABLES Table 1. Indexes of industrial production, wholesale and consumer prices, 1950-52 2. Bond yields and interest rates, 1950-52 3. Estimated ownership of Federal obligations, 1950-57 4. Deposits and currency, 1950-52 5. Loans and investments of all commercial banks, 1950-52 6. Gross national product, seasonally adjusted at annual rates, 1950-52 7. Disposition of disposable personal income, 1950-52 8. Installment credit, 1950-52 9. Open-market transactions in United States Government securities, July 1, 1951-September 30, 1952 10. Member bank reserves and related items, 1950-52 11. Member bank excess reserves, borrowings, and free reserves, 1950-52 ni 3 5 8 9 10 12 13 14 15 16 17 IV CONTENTS Table 12. Annual rate of turnover of demand deposits, 1950-52 13. Indexes of industrial production, wholesale and consumer prices, 1953-54 14. Gross transactions in Government securities by the Federal Open Market Committee, January-December 1953 15. Bond yields and interest rates, 1953-54 16. Gross national product, seasonally adjusted at annual rates, 1953-54 17. Disposition of disposable personal income, 1953-54 18. Installment credit, 1953-54 19. Member bank reserves and related items, 1953-54 20. Member bank excess reserves, borrowings, and free reserves, 1953-54 21. Deposits and currency, 1953-54 22. Loans and investments of all commercial banks, 1953-54 23. Loans and investments of all commercial banks, 1950-57 24. Mortgage debt outstanding, by type of property and of financing, 1950-57 25. Annual rate of turnover of demand deposits, 1953-54 26. Indexes of industrial production, wholesale and consumer prices, 1955-57 27. Gross national product, seasonally adjusted at annual rates, 1955-57 28. Disposition of disposable personal income, 1955-57 29. Loans and investments of all commercial banks, 1955-57 30. Deposits and currency, 1955-57 31. Annual rate of turnover of demand deposits, 1955-57 32. Member bank reserves and related items, 1955-57 33. Member bank excess reserves, borrowings, and free reserves, 1955-57 34. Bond yields and interest rates, 1955-57 35. Installment credit, 1955-57 Appendix: Member bank reserves, Reserve bank credit, and related items, 1950-57 Page 18 20 23 25 30 31 32 32 33 34 35 37 39 40 41 42 43 45 46 47 50 51 57 59 77 STATEMENT OF THE CHAIRMAN The Federal Reserve Board is an agency directly responsible to the Congress. Its action or lack of action with respect to the flow of credit may affect the stability and growth of the economy. Congress must therefore be concerned with how the Board uses its monetary tools and the adequacy of these tools for stabilization purposes. The Treasury-Federal Reserve accord of 1951 restored the independence of the Federal Reserve from the Treasury, an independence which the record shows could not have been achieved without energetic support in Congress. Since that time monetary policy has increasingly been in the forefront of discussion in newspapers and periodicals, in academic circles, and in Congress. The views expressed have ranged from general endorsement of Federal Reserve policies to fundamental skepticism which regards monetary tools as weak reeds on which to lean in the promotion of economic stabilization. In view of such basic differences and the likelihood that Congress will be considering a number of measures relating to monetary policy and economic stabilization, I considered it important to review Federal Reserve policies since the accord. Recent events have shown that the economy is still subject to sizable fluctuations in aggregate economic activity, and inflationary as well as deflationary developments are ever present phenomena. I felt it desirable to have an independent analysis of Federal Reserve policies from 1951 through 1957 which would throw light on the adequacy and the use of the tools employed by the Federal Reserve Board. Any review of Federal Reserve policies is, of course, bound to be controversial. Were it to be prepared by the Board itself, one would expect it to consist mainly of explanation and justification of past actions. I preferred to have the study prepared by an economist uncommitted to an official or a doctrinaire viewpoint but who, nevertheless, possessed professional qualifications of a high order. For this reason, I requested that the services of Dr. Asher Achinstein, senior specialist in the Legislative Reference Service of the Library of Congress, be made available to prepare this report. He was assisted by Mrs. Elizabeth M. Boswell. Dr. Achinstein is an acknowledged expert in business cycles and has demonstrated his scholarship, objectivity, and independence in dealing with the problems of economic policy. He is the author of Introduction to Business Cycles, a standard textbook on economic fluctuations. He was associated in 1953 and 1954 with Dr. Arthur F. Burns, Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers, in the preparation of the first two Economic Reports of President Eisenhower, and has served as economic consultant to the Senate Banking and Currency Committee. While the committee and the individual members take no position on the report, it nevertheless deserves the careful attention not only v VI STATEMENT OF THE CHAIRMAN of the Congress but of all citizens concerned with the vital issues of monetary policy. Not the least of its contributions is that it focuses attention on problems requiring further research and study. Dr. Achinstein's study was submitted to the staff of the Federal Reserve Board for comments and many of these were incorporated. In view of the fact that all of their suggestions were not accepted, the Board's staff was invited to prepare a statement to be published along with the report. J. W . FULBRIGHT. SUMMARY This report examines Federal Reserve policies in terms of the fluctuations in aggregate economic activity from 1951 through 1957. The following statements from the Douglas Subcommittee Report of 1950 on Monetary, Credit, and Fiscal Policies, quoted at the very outset of the study, indicate two of the underlying basic premises for this review. (1) We recommend that an appropriate, flexible, and vigorous monetary policy, employed in coordination with fiscal and other policies, should be one of the principal methods used to achieve the purposes of the Employment Act. (2) The essential characteristic of a monetary policy that will promote general economic stability is its timely flexibility. To combat deflation and promote recovery, the monetary authorities must liberally provide the banking system with enhanced lending power, thereby tending to lower interest rates and increase the availability of credit. To retard and stop inflation they must restrict the lending power of banks, thereby tending to raise interest rates and to limit the availability of credit for private and Government spending. And these actions must be taken promptly if they are to be most effective. A corollary to these basic propositions is that appropriateness and timeliness of monetary actions must be judged in the light of the economic developments unfolding during the period. Not all economic changes warrant monetary actions of a contracyclical character. Nor is the test of successful application of the principle of timely flexibility the complete elimination of fluctuations in general business activity. What may be expected from the monetary authorities is a reasonably good diagnosis of the current changes taking place in the economy and such use of their tools as to minimize economic instability. To be sure, they are not omniscient and are bound to make mistakes in appraisals of current developments and in the use of their instrumentalities. One of the virtues of monetary policy, as compared to fiscal and debt-management policy, is that the monetary authorities are usually in a better position to minimize errors of diagnosis or of action by more speedily steering a different course to meet changing conditions. Whether monetary management actually exhibits the desirable degree of flexibility is another matter. When the Treasury-Federal Reserve accord was reached on March 4, 1951, it was hailed as an important development marking the end of a decade during which monetary policy had been subordinated to debt-management policy. The outbreak of the Korean war in June 1950 had touched off strong inflationary pressures and it had become increasingly evident that credit expansion would continue to feed the upward price spiral, so long as the Federal Reserve System purchased large quantities of Government securities at pegged prices. It was in the light of these developments that the Treasury finally agreed to an TO VIII SUMMARY arrangement giving monetary policy a coordinate role with debtmanagement policy. The significance of the accord lies in the fact that it paved the way for the Federal Reserve to exercise greater freedom in the use of its major instruments of credit policy for promoting economic stability. So long as the rigid support of the Government security market continued, open-market operations, the discount rate, and reserve requirements—the three principal methods for regulating the volume of bank credit and the money supply—could not be employed effectively. The accord took place at a time when inflationary developments had about reached their greatest intensity. Wholesale commodity prices, which had risen by 16 percent during the first 9 months after the Korean war, reached their peak in March 1951, and began to edge downward more or less continuously until the end of 1952. The extent to which the accord was of strategic importance in weakening inflationary pressures after March 1951 is a debatable question. Federal Reserve officials are inclined to attribute an especially powerful role to the accord in curbing inflationary pressures; others emphasize instead the importance of the change in business conditions, particularly the cessation of the abnormally heavy forward buying by consumers and business firms when the anticipated war shortages did not develop. There were also additional anti-inflation influences in 1951—perhaps of lesser importance—such as direct controls over prices and wages by the Federal Government, and selective controls over real-estate credit, consumer credit, and credit for the security markets. It was not until at least a year after the accord that the discount mechanism began to be reactivated as a major supplement to openmarket operations as a tool for monetary control. This change coincided more or less with the acceleration in the pace of business activity and the intensification of the demand for bank credit toward mid-1952. As a result of the increasing pressure on bank reserves, bank borrowing at Federal Reserve banks rose from about $300 million in March 1952 to a record level of $1.6 billion by the end of the year. The revival of the use of the discount window by member banks gave promise that the monetary authorities would henceforth be in a stronger position than they had been for about two decades to exercise restraint on credit expansion. It was thought that they could count on the traditional reluctance of the banks to borrow from the Federal Reserve, on administrative regulations discouraging continuous borrowing to replenish reserves, and on making borrowing more expensive through raising the Federal Reserve discount rate. It was also about the time of the accord that the view began to be influential among Federal Reserve officials that a policy of monetary restraint which results in even small changes in interest rates would curb bankcredit expansion. With a substantial part of the portfolios of banking and financial institutions consisting of Government securities, obese institutions were thought to be sensitive to small rises Li interest rates and to the capital losses involved in disposing of Government securities in order to switch into private loans. The first half of 1953 is an especially instructive period, since it brings to focus some of the major problems that continue to confront SUMMARY IX monetary management in its attempt to promote economic stability. The first relates to appraisal of the current business situation; the second to the influence of Treasury debt-management policy on monetary actions; and the third to the actual use made of the available instruments of credit control. It was also in this period that the Open Market Committee arrived at significant decisions with respect to its most important tool of monetary policy, namely, open-market operations. During almost the whole of the first 6 months of 1953 the monetary authorities based their credit policy on the assumption of continuation of business expansion and the intensification of inflationary pressures. There were others who pointed out early in the spring of 1953 that the Federal Reserve Board's preoccupation with inflation resulted in its minimizing unfavorable developments indicative of an impending downward readjustment in business activity. With more or less the same statistical and other pertinent data available to competent and trained observers, such differences in appraisal of the current economic situation must be largely interpretative and analytical in character. However, psychological and other influences enter into these judgments. During this as well as in other periods of buoyancy in the economy at more or less peak levels, there is a general tendency for optimistic appraisals and the ignoring of imbalances that are building up and which are likely to result in deflationary developments. Another influence that appeared to have resulted in overemphasis on the continuation of inflationary pressures was the decision of the Treasury early in the spring of 1953 to launch a program of refunding the debt into longer maturities. At the same time, the Federal Reserve Board was expounding a philosophy of the "free securities market" with open-market operations confined to the short-term securities and no intervention in the long-term sectors. These views of the Treasury and Federal Reserve brought forth criticism by economists and others that a free-market philosophy represented a degree of passivity on the part of the Federal Reserve which was likely to weaken credit policy as a tool for stabilization. Within the Federal Reserve System, Mr. Sproul, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, opposed the "bills only" doctrine of the Open Market Committee, contending that it placed monetary management in a straitjacket. By mid-1953 the Federal Reserve was moving vigorously to reverse the course of monetary policy from one of credit restraint to credit ease. This shift was initially made in response to a critical situation that had been permitted to develop in the financial markets rather than, as is sometimes asserted, to the expectation that the economy was about to slip into a business recession. Nevertheless, extensive midyear open-market purchases and lowering of reserve requirements created a favorable financial environment for meeting the problems of economic readjustment in the period immediately ahead. The earlier restrictive monetary policy may have had some influence in the slackening of activity, but this in no way compares with the major importance in the 1953-54 business recession of the downward readjustment of business inventories and the cutback in defense contracts. The liquidation of inventories occurred because production and sales had fallen out of balance, especially in the consumer durable X SUMMARY goods sector, and because of curtailment of the defense program. These developments were independent of the tight-money policy. Federal Reserve policy contributed substantially to moderating the recession and supporting economic recovery. All three major instrumentalities were employed after mid-1953. There was a further increase in open-market purchases in the last half of the year, the discount rate was lowered from 2 to 1% percent in February 1954 and to 1 y2 percent in April, and reserve requirements were reduced once more around mid-1954. The policy of active ease made credit more available and lowered its cost considerably. With ample reserves and greater liquidity banks sought out new business more aggressively and greatly expanded their investment portfolios. The chief beneficiaries of the easy-money policy were the construction industry—especially housing, commercial and public works construction—and the stock market, with credit for trading in 1954 showing the greatest increase during any of the postwar years. Monetary policy would not have been so influential in recovery if the level of consumer spending had not remained so high, if the "automatic stabilizers" had not come into play, and if additional antirecession measures had not been undertaken promptly by the Federal Government. For understanding the 1955-57 business expansion and the role played by the monetary factor, it is necessary to concentrate on 1955, when the expansion assumed its most rapid rate of increase and the volume of credit rose at a record rate. No single year so illuminates the shortcomings of monetary policy when the principle of appropriate and timely flexibility is violated. It also focuses attention on some of the limitations inherent in the existing tools of monetary control. Between the third quarter of 1954 and the first quarter of 1955 the gross national product advanced at an annual rate of over $22 billion; about two-thirds of the increase was due to the sharp expansion in outlays for consumer durable goods, continued advances in purchases of new homes, and a shift from liquidation to accumulation in business inventories. The speedy economic recovery, which received its main impetus from these sectors, was accompanied by a substantial rise in credit and by a considerable easing in financial terms, especially longer maturities and lower downpayments on mortgage and installment credit. In the second quarter of the year, installment credit outstanding expanded by nearly $2 billion, a record rate in so short a period. The mortgage debt on 1- to 4-family homes increased by $6.5 billion during the first 6 months of the year. The upsurge in consumer expenditures for durable goods and housing was a major stimulus to the acceleration of business investment in plant and equipment during the latter half of 1955. In all of these developments the commercial banks played a powerful role through a $12 billion expansion of loans in 1955. The first restrictive credit move by the Federal Reserve Board was the raising of margin requirements from 50 to 60 percent in January 1955. Since stock prices and stock-market credit had each risen by about 50 percent since September 1953, and speculative activity was increasing during the latter half of 1954, the 10-point rise in margin requirements could hardly succeed in checking the flow of credit to the market. In April, a month after the widely followed stock market hearings of the Senate Banking and Currency Committee were completed, margin requirements were raised from 60 to 70 percent. It SUMMARY XI was only after this action was taken that the rate of increase in stockmarket credit began to slacken considerably. The record of the meeting of the Open Market Committee at the beginning of March 1955 shows that it was concerned that relaxation of terms for the rapidly expanding volume of consumer and mortgage credit represented a potential threat to stability. At the beginning of May, and even more so by the end of June, it noted that overall economic activity was reaching boom proportions with the likelihood of prices moving upward and that business, financial, and consumer confidence was extraordinarily high. It was therefore surprising, even in financial circles, that the Reserve banks waited until mid-April and early May to raise the discount rate from to 1% percent. The Federal Reserve waited another 4 months before it made a similar feeble attempt at monetary restraint when it raised the discount rate to 2 percent in August. While open-market operations were conducted during the months of March through June so as not to increase bank reserves, it would seem to have been more appropriate, in view of the swelling demands for credit, if there had been direct intervention by the System to reduce bank reserves. Federal Reserve officials have recently admitted that they should have moved faster and more vigorously in 1955. One reason for the failure to do so given by the presidents of the Reserve banks was that the economic data available in the first half of 1955 understated the speed of the recovery. This explanation for the inadequacy of monetary policy leaves much to be desired. If the monetary authorities failed to act more vigorously, it was much more a matter of judgment and interpretation than limitations inherent in the data. The Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, in accounting for the tardiness and lack of vigor of the restrictive actions taken in the upswing, has acknowledged an important element ignored by the bank presidents, namely, the human factor of hesitancy to exercise curbs that might check the pace of business expansion. Additional explanations for the inadequacy of monetary policy in 1955 may be found in the theory of credit control that seemed to be influential among officials of the Federal Reserve System as well as in the limitations of general monetary controls. From the degree of pressure exerted in 1955 it would appear that the monetary authorities were still under the influence of the view propounded around the time of the accord that small increases in interest rates inhibit bank disposal of Government securities, thereby curbing bank-credit expansion. This theory received little support from actual financial developments in 1955 and the first half of 1956. Throughout this period interest rates were moving upward; the discount rate was raised 6 times from April 1955 to August 1956—from IK to 3 percent. In order to meet demands of their customers the banks disposed of more than $12 billion of Government securities in 1955 and up to mid-1956. It was not until the latter period that considerations of bank liquidity caused the shifting out of Government securities to cease. The Federal Reserve appeared to underestimate considerably the lag between the adoption of its policy of monetary restraint and the time when it could take effect. The ineffectiveness of monetary policy was particularly evident in the case of consumer durable goods purchases. The rise in interest rates neither inhibited users nor lenders of installment credit. The XII SUMMARY Federal Reserve had no authority to exercise selective controls over downpayments and maturities with which to check excessive expansion of consumer credit. It had such powers under temporary authority during 1941-47, 1948-49, and in 1950-52. Nor did it request the Congress for authority to regulate consumer credit at any time since the expiration of regulation W in mid-1952. Despite the evidence that the rapid expansion of consumer credit in 1955, with its accompanying secondary impacts on capital investment, contributed to subsequent inflationary developments, the Federal Reserve Board arrived at the conclusion, on the basis of a six-volume study published in the spring of 1957, that authority for regulating installment credit was inadvisable and that the use of general controls was adequate to deal with unstabilizing credit developments. This is in contrast to the views of the Board expressed in a more comprehensive statement submitted to the Patman committee 5 years earlier, that consumer credit is relatively unresponsive to general credit instruments and for this reason selective regulation provides a helpful supplement to general monetary controls. An additional factor reducing the effectiveness of Federal Reserve policy which has been stressed in recent years is the growth of financial intermediaries, such as life-insurance companies, building and loan associations, savings banks, investment companies, and pension funds. In 1955 life-insurance companies, savings and loan associations, and mutual savings banks acquired over two-thirds of the more than $16 billion increase in the non-farm-mortgage debt. Accordingly, some students of monetary policy have argued for selective control over housing credit as well as over installment credit. The monetary authorities had a difficult course to steer with respect to credit policy in 1956. Once they had failed to adopt stronger measures in 1955, they were in the proverbial position of holding a bear by the tail during the following year and a half. On the one hand, there was the risk that a more liberal policy with respect to the availability of bank reserves might accelerate price rises, especially in "bottleneck" sectors of the economy. On the other hand, if the policy became much more restrictive, there was the danger of initiating a downward spiral in business activity since certain of the key sectors which had ushered in the boom had been showing considerable weakness for some time. Nevertheless, with the economy continuing to operate near capacity levels—despite some uncertainties about its general direction—and with prices1 and wage rates moving upward, 11 the Open Market Committee felt t J I T relax in its efforts at restricting Open-market operations were so conducted that the security holdings of the System had increased by only $160 million during 1956. The money supply grew at the rate of only 1 percent as compared to a 2.8 percent rise in 1955. However, the rate of turnover of demand deposits in centers outside of New York City increased 8 percent in 1956. One may justifiably view with favor the determination of the Federal Reserve not to relax restraints in 1956 and in the first half of 1957, but there is much less justification for regarding favorably the policies pursued through the summer and fall of 1957. In public statements by Federal Reserve officials, in testimony at congressional hearings, and through policy decisions such as raising the discount SUMMARY XIII rate one-half of 1 percentage point, i. e., to 3% percent in August, the monetary authorities appeared to show little concern about the increasing signs that the boom might end in the not-too-distant future. In the fall and almost up to mid-November, when the discount rate was lowered from 3% to 3 percent, giving public notice that the Federal Reserve regarded the immediate problem ahead as not inflation but business contraction, presidents of the Reserve banks and members of the Board of Governors of the System were making speeches that inflation was still the No. 1 economic problem and it would be a great mistake to relax credit restraint. In the light of the vehemence and the frequency with which Federal Reserve officials publicly stressed during the first 10 months of 1957 the necessity for continuing monetary restraint, it comes as a surprise to read the record of the 1957 meetings of the Open Market Committee. During almost all of the 18 meetings held throughout the year there appeared to be an absence of that confidence in the business outlook and in the continuation of inflationary pressures which was manifested in public statements by top spokesmen for the System. The contrast between the record of the deliberations of the Open Market Committee and the public statements and actions of the Federal Reserve requires explanation. Similarly, the relatively sharp rise in the discount rate in August, when business expansion was grinding to a halt, is also in need of a more satisfactory explanation than has been thus far advanced by the monetary authorities. It is safe to predict that long after the events of 1957 have passed, economists will still seek the answer to these two questions. In explaining the August 1957 rise in the discount rate, the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board recently stated that the change was necessary for technical reasons, but what he appeared to ignore was the fact that the sharp hike in the rate was widely interpreted as indicating that the monetary authorities regarded the intensification of inflationary pressures and the need for continuation of monetary restraint as the immediate issue facing the country. That a change in the discount rate is regarded as a signal to the public of a shift in Federal Reserve policy was expressly stated by the Board of Governors of the System when it lowered the rate in November. If it was a public signal in November, it must also have been one in August. If the inadequacies of the Federal Reserve in 1955 may justifiably be said to have encouraged subsequent inflationary developments, the miscalculations in the summer and fall of 1957 may be said to have contributed to the sharpest business decline in the postwar period. The misunderstanding with respect to the unusually sharp rise in the discount rate in August, and the fact that meetings of the Open Market Committee are publicly reported as late as a year after they have taken place, call for exploration of improved methods for providing the public with a clearer understanding of Federal Reserve policy changes through prompt publication of explanatory statements. The 1955-57 boom, followed by the sharpest recession in the postwar period, and the current signs of resumption of expansion with the probable renewal of inflationary pressures, all emphasize the necessity of a fundamental reexamination of our financial system with a view to increasing the effectiveness of monetary policy in a stabilization program. 8 5 T H CONGRESS ) M Session J SENATE J REPORT 1 No. 2500 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY 1951-57 OCTOBER 10, 1 9 5 8 . — O r d e r e d t o b e p r i n t e d under a u t h o r i t y of t h e order of t h e S e n a t e of A u g u s t 24, 1958 Mr. FULBRIGHT, from the Committee on Banking and Currency, submitted the following REPORT CHAPTER I. THE PERIOD OF T R A N S I T I O N , M O N E T A R Y POLICY A N D D E B T 1951-52 MANAGEMENT When the Treasury-Federal Reserve accord was reached on March 4, 1951, it was hailed as an important development marking the end of a decade during which monetary policy had been subordinated to debt management policy. Freed from the necessity of supporting the Government security market at fixed or pegged prices, the monetary authorities would henceforth be in a position to use more effectively the tools of credit policy for promoting economic stability. There had been mounting criticism for several years prior to the accord on the extent to which debt management considerations by the Treasury continued to dominate Federal Reserve monetary policies. These views were thoroughly aired during the hearings of the Douglas Subcommittee on Monetary, Credit, and Fiscal Policies which opened in September 1949, and in the collection of statements submitted to the subcommittee by Government officials, bankers, economists, and others, published in November 1949. There followed in January 1950 the subcommittee's report which recommended that "an appropriate, flexible, and vigorous monetary policy, employed in coordination with fiscal and other policies, should be one of the principal 1methods used to achieve the purposes of the Employment Act." It went on to state: Timely flexibility toward easy credit at some times and credit restriction at other times is an essential characteristic of a monetary policy that will promote economic stability rather than instability. The vigorous use of a restrictive 1 Monetary, Credit, and Fiscal Policies: Report of the Subcommittee on Monetary, Credit, and Fiscal Policies, Joint Committee on the Economic Report, 81st Cong., 2d sess., 1950, S. Doc. No. 129, p.l. 1 2 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY monetary policy as an anti-inflation measure has been inhibited since the war by considerations relating to holding down the yields and supporting the prices of United States Government securities. As a long-run matter, we favor interest rates as low as they can be without inducing inflation, for low interest rates stimulate capital investment. But we believe that the advantages of avoiding inflation are so great and that a restrictive monetary policy can contribute so much to this end that the freedom of the Federal Reserve to restrict credit and raise interest rates for general stabilization purposes should be restored even if the cost should prove to be a significant increase in service charges on the Federal debt and a greater inconvenience to the Treasury in its sale of securities for new financing and refunding purposes.2 The subcommittee rejected, for the reasons given below, the notion held by some groups that for stabilization purposes "little or no reliance should be placed on monetary policy and that we should rely exclusively on other measures, such as fiscal policy (1) It is highly doubtful that fiscal policy would be powerful enough to maintain stability in the face of strong destabilizing forces even if monetary policy were neutral, and a conflicting monetary policy could lessen still further the effectiveness of fiscal policy. (2) Monetary policy is strong precisely where fiscal policy is weakest; it is capable of being highly flexible. It can be altered with changes in economic conditions on a monthly, daily, or even hourly basis. (3) It is a familiar instrument of control and thoroughly consistent with the maintenance of our democratic government and our competitive free-enterprise system. It is certainly much to be preferred over a harness of direct controls. (4) Our monetary history gives little indication as to how effectively we can expect appropriate and vigorous monetary policies to promote stability, for we have never really tried them.3 The report stressed that, to be effective, monetary management must be characterized by timely, vigorous, and flexible actions: The essential characteristic of a monetary policy that will promote general economic stability is its timely flexibility. To combat deflation and promote recovery, the monetary authorities must liberally provide the banking system with enhanced lending power, thereby tending to lower interest rates and increase the availability of credit. To retard and stop inflation they must restrict the lending power of banks, thereby tending to raise interest rates and to limit the availability of credit for private and Government spending. And these actions must be taken promptly if they are to be most effective.4 a Ibid., p. 2. s Ibid., p. 18. < Ibid., p. 19. 16 F E D E R A L RESERVE TABLE 1 . — I n d e x e s of industrial Month 1950—Januar y February March April May... June. July August September... October. November. December-.. 1951—Januar y February March April May June POLICY A N D production, wholesale [1947-49=100] Industrial pro-1 duction Wholesale prices Consumer prices 100 99 102 106 97.7 98.3 98.5 98.5 99.6 100.2 103.0 105.2 107.1 107.7 109.3 100.6 100.4 100.7 100.8 101.3 101.8 102.9 103.7 104.4 105.0 105.5 106.9 108.6 109.9 110.3 110.4 110.9 110 112 115 120 120 121 120 122 122 122 122 122 122 121 112.1 115.0 116.5 116.5 116.3 115.9 115.1 ECONOMIC 110.8 STABILITY and consumer Month 1951—July. August. September-. October November.. . December. 1952—Januar y February March AprilMay June. July AugustSeptember... October November... December... Ind ustrial pro-1 duction 119 118 118 118 119 119 121 121 121 120 119 118 115 123 129 130 133 133 prices, 1950-52 Whole- Consumer sale prices prices 114.2 113.7 113.4 113.7 113.6 113.5 113.0 112.5 112.3 111.8 111.6 111.2 111.8 112.2 111.8 111.1 110.7 109.6 110.9 110.9 111.6 112.1 112.8 113.1 113.1 112.4 112.4 112.9 113.0 113.4 114.1 114.3 114.1 114.2 114.3 114.1 i Seasonally adjusted. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and U. S. Department of Labor. Fourteen months elapsed between the publication of the Douglas committee report and the accord. During this period, the outbreak of the Korean war in June 1950 touched off strong inflationary pressures. The abnormally heavy buying by consumers and business firms in anticipation of possible future shortages resulted in a sharp increase in prices. Between June 1950 and March 1951, wholesale commodity prices rose by about 16 percent. During these 9 months, the Federal Reserve System increased its holdings of Government securities by over $4 billion, thus increasing bank reserves which facilitated the unusual expansion of bank loans by nearly $10 billion. Public hearings and committee reports helped to focus attention on the desirability of greater Federal Reserve independence. But it was not until developments after the Korean war made it especially evident that credit expansion would continue to feed the upward price spiral, so long as the Federal Reserve System purchased large quantities of Government securities at pegged prices, that the Treasury finally agreed to an arrangement giving monetary policy a coordinate role with debt management policy. THE ACCORD The Treasury and the Federal Reserve System announced on March 4, 1951, that they had—• reached full accord with respect to debt-management and monetary policies to be pursued in furthering their common purpose to assure the successful financing of the Government's requirements and, at the same time, to minimize the monetization of the public debt. In accordance with this agreement, holders of the 2% percent restricted bonds of 1967-72 in the amount of $19.7 billion were to be given the opportunity to exchange them for a nonmarketable 2%percent 29-year bond, convertible at the option of the holder into a 1^-percent 5-year marketable Treasury note. This was designed to encourage the holding of long-term bonds and thus curb debt monetization. H. Kept. 2500, 85-2 2 4 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY The most important phase of the agreement directed toward minimizing the monetization of the debt was that the Reserve System would immediately discontinue purchases of Government securities at pegged prices at the option of the market. It was agreed, however, that a limited volume of open-market purchases would be made while the long-term bonds were being exchanged. This meant that disposal by banks and other investors of such securities would be governed by the demand in the market without Federal Reserve open-market support. In response to market forces, short-term interest rates were expected to fluctuate around the Federal Reserve discount rate which, except for unforeseen developments, would remain at 1% percent for the rest of the year. Under these circumstances, the Federal Reserve expected to influence the availability of credit because individual member banks would have to come to the discount window and borrow at the discount rate to maintain or increase their reserves. Finally, it was agreed that there would be more frequent conferences between the Treasury and Federal Reserve officials and staff to work more closely on a joint program of Government financing as well as in the maintenance of orderly markets for Government securities. The significance of the accord lies in the fact that it paved the way for the Federal Reserve to exercise greater freedom in the use of its major instruments of credit policy for promoting economic stability. So long as the rigid support of the Government security market continued, open-market operations, the discount rate, and reserve requirements—the three principal methods for regulating the volume of bank credit and the money supply—could not be employed effectively. They could only operate effectively in an inflationary period if they were free to restrict the availability of bank reserves. But the initiative in changing member bank reserves when the Government security market is pegged rested largely with the holders of these securities. In a period of a great rise in the demand for credit, commercial banks and nonbank investors, a large part of whose assets were in the form of Government securities at low yields, found it more attractive to dispose of substantial amounts of these securities and place their funds in higher-earning loans. From the end of June 1950 to the end of February 1951, commercial banks sold United States Government securities in the amount of $6.7 billion, insurance companies $1.1 billion, and mutual savings banks nearly $1 billion. The Federal Reserve banks purchased about $4 billion. During the 8-month period, member bank reserves increased by over $3 billion despite a loss in gold of nearly $2.5 billion. About $2 billion of member bank reserves were absorbed by the Federal Reserve increasing requirements in January and February 1951 by 2 percentage points on demand deposits and 1 percentage point on time deposits. TABLE 2 . — B o n d yields and interest rates, 1950-52 [Percent per annum] U. S. Government securities Period 1950—January.__ FebruaryMarch April May June July August September. October. __ November. December. 1951—January _.. FebruaryMarch April May June July August September. October. November. December . 1953—January... FebruaryMarch April May. June July August September. October-.. November. December . 1 2 3-month Treasury bills 1.090 1.125 1.138 1.159 1.166 1.174 1.172 1.211 1.315 1.329 1.364 1.367 1.387 1.391 1.422 1.520 1. 578 1.499 1.593 1.644 1.646 1.608 1.608 1. 731 1.688 1.574 1.658 1.623 1.710 1.700 1.824 1.876 1.786 1.783 1.862 2.126 9 to 12 month issues 1 1.12 1.15 1.16 1.17 1.18 1.23 1.23 1.26 1.33 1.40 1.47 1.46 1.47 1.60 1.79 1.89 1.85 1.79 1.74 1.70 1.71 1.74 1.68 1.77 1.75 1.70 1.69 1.60 1.66 1.74 1.89 1.94 1.95 1.84 1.89 2.03 Taxable bonds (long term) 2 2.20 2.24 2.27 2.30 2.31 2.33 2.34 2.33 2.36 2.38 2.38 2.39 2.39 2.40 2.47 2.56 2.63 2.65 2.63 2. 57 2.56 2. 61 2.66 2.70 2.74 2.71 2.70 2.64 2.57 2. 61 2.61 2.70 2. 71 2.74 2.71 2. 75 Includes certificates of indebtedness and selected note and bond issues. 2H percent bonds, 15 years and over prior to April 1952 and 12 years and over beginning April 1952. Corporate bonds (Moody's) Aaa 2. 57 2.58 2.58 2.60 2.61 2.62 2.65 2.61 2.64 2. 67 2.67 2.67 2.66 2.66 2.78 2.87 2.88 2.94 2.94 2.88 2.84 2.89 2.96 3.01 2.98 2.93 2.96 2.93 2.93 2.94 2.95 2.94 2.95 3.01 2.98 2. 97 Baa 3.24 3.24 3.24 3.23 3.25 3.28 3.32 3.23 3.21 3.22 3.22 3.20 3.17 3.16 3.22 3.34 3.40 3.49 3.53 3. 51 3.46 3.50 3.56 3. 61 3.59 3.53 3. 51 3.50 3.49 3.50 3.50 3. 51 3.52 3.54 3.53 3. 51 Common stock yields, 200 stocks (Moody's) 6.28 6.24 6.16 5.98 5.79 6.17 6.17 6.39 6.22 6.49 6.80 6. 57 6.32 6.27 6.40 6.18 6.35 6. 55 6.20 5.86 5.91 6.02 5.78 5. 55 5.53 5.73 5.49 5.77 5. 65 5. 45 5.39 5.46 5.56 5.56 5.28 5.13 HighAverage Prime grade rate on municipal short-term commerbonds bank loans cial paper, 4 to 6 (Standard to business, months & Poor's) selected cities 2.08 2.06 2.07 2.08 2.07 2.09 2.09 1.90 1.88 1.82 1.79 1. 77 1.62 1. 61 1.87 2.05 2.09 2.22 2.18 2.04 2.05 2.08 2.07 2.10 2.10 2.04 2.07 2.01 2.05 2.10 2.12 2.22 2.33 2.42 2.40 2.40 2.60 2.68 2.63 2.84 3.02 3.07 3.06 3.27 3.45 3. 51 3.49 3. 51 1.31 1.31 1.31 1.31 1.31 1.31 1.31 1.42 1.65 1.72 1.69 1. 72 1.86 1.96 2.04 2.11 2.16 2.31 2.31 2.26 2.19 2.22 2.25 2.30 2.38 2.38 2.38 2.35 2.31 2. 31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 Federal Reserve bank discount rate 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 3 1.75 1.75 1. 75 1. 75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 1. 75 1. 75 1.75 1. 75 1. 75 1. 75 1. 75 3 Effective Aug. 21, 1950. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Treasury Department, Moody's Investors Service, and Standard and Poor's Corp. H § S >3 F* S3 M GO H S3J < ^ O4 t i—i O H £ fet O o O o CO w HH F •H H H Oi 6 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY F L E X I B L E M O N E T A R Y POLICY A N D R I S I N G I N T E R E S T RATES As was expected, abandonment of the rigid support policy resulted in an increase in bond yields and in interest rates. The yields on Federal securities rose moderately from April 1951 to mid-1952—a rise that was much less than was anticipated in some quarters. During this period yields on long-term bonds ranged from 2.56 to 2.61, 90-day bills from 1.52 to 1.70, and Aaa corporate bonds from 2.87 to 2.94. Could a rise of interest rates of these magnitudes have any significant effect on the expansion of bank credit? The monetary authorities who argued for a more flexible credit policy maintained that even moderate increases in interest rates would serve to curtail the volume of bank credit. This view is explained at length in statements prepared by the Federal Reserve for the Patman Subcommittee on General Credit Control and Debt Management.5 According to this theory, the monetary authorities can limit bank reserves by selling Government securities or by limiting the amount of securities purchased and permitting their prices to adjust to investor demands in the market. A rise in yield occurs in either case. The increasing yield checks the tendency of banks and other financial institutions who are inclined to sell Government securities from switching to such other investments as business loans or mortgages. They are reluctant to sell Government securities because of the capital loss involved. Moreover, institutional rigidities which keep rates on other assets from rising while the yield on Government securities increases make the holding of Governments relatively more attractive. Then too, in an unpegged market, banks and financial institutions become more cautious in disposing of Federal securities because of the increasing uncertainty about future security prices and yields. As a result of these reactions by lending institutions, there is a reduction in the volume of credit extended to borrowers, even though the latter may not be disposed to lessen their demand for funds because of increasing interest rates. In short, according to this theory, a more flexible of credit monetary policy can succeed in limiting the availability even without an appreciable rise in interest rates.6 To what extent did developments in the money market after the accord support this viewpoint? In the first place, it is essential to establish whether the sale of Government securities by lending institutions was curtailed. Secondly, even if this occurred, did the change take place because the price of Governments fell below par, i. e., the rise in interest rates, or because of other factors that influenced the demand and supply of credit? Examination of data on changes in Government security holdings since the accord does not indicate uniformity of reaction to rising interest rates by lending institutions. For example, from mid-1951 to mid-1952, insurance companies and mutual savings banks continued to dispose of large amounts of Government securities while 5 Monetary Policy and Management of the Public Debt: Replies to questions and other material for the use of the Subcommittee on General Credit Control and Debt Management, Joint Committee on the Economic Report, 82d Cong., 2d sess., 1952, S. Doc. No. 123, pt. I, p. 368 ff. and especially pp. 371-373 and 380-383. • The view that under modern conditions even small changes in interest rates can have a considerable restrictive influence on bank loans has been expounded by Robert V. Roosa, now vice president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. His article, Interest Rates and the Central Bank, has become the standard reference for the exposition of this viewpoint. See Money, Trade, and Economic Growth, in honor of John Henry Williams, pp. 270-295. The Macmillan Co., New York, 1951. 7 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY commercial banks increased their holdings of short-term securities substantially. It would seem that supporters of the view that a more restrictive monetary policy, accompanied by a moderate increase in interest rates and culminating in a lessening of the availability of credit, cannot obtain comfort from the fact that institutional holders of long-term Government securities, such as insurance companies and savings banks, did not stop sales from their portfolios. However, they can point out that the rate of disposal of Governments by these institutions did definitely slacken after the accord, a change that was presumably influenced by the fact that sales had to be made at market and not at pegged rates. TABLE 3.—Estimated ownership of Federal obligations, 1950-57 00 [Par values 1 in billions of dollars] End of month 1950—June December. 1951—June December. 1952—June December. 1953—Jun e December. 1954—June December. 1955—June December. 196fr-June December. 1957—June December. Total Federal securities outstanding 2 U. S. Government investment accounts 257.4 256.7 255.3 259.5 259.2 267.4 266.1 275.2 271.3 278.8 274.4 280.8 272.8 276.7 270.6 275.0 37.8 39.2 41.0 42.3 44.3 45.9 47.6 48.3 49.3 49.6 50.5 51.7 53.5 54.0 55.6 55.2 Held by banks Total 83.9 82.6 81.4 85.4 84.0 88.1 83.6 89.6 88.7 94.1 87.1 86.8 80.8 84.2 78.9 83.2 Commercial banks8 65.6 61.8 58.4 61.6 61.1 63.4 58.8 63.7 63.6 69.2 63.5 62.0 57.1 59.3 55.8 58.9 Held by private nonbank investors Federal Reserve banks 18.3 20.8 23.0 23.8 22.9 24.7 24.7 25.9 25.0 24.9 23.6 24.8 23.8 24.9 23.0 1 United States savings bonds, series A-F and J, are included at current redemption value. 2 Securities issued or guaranteed by the U. S. Government, excluding guaranteed securities held by the Treasury. 3 Consists of commercial banks, trust companies, and stock savings banks in United States and in Territories and island possessions. * Includes partnerships and personal trust accounts. Nonprofit institutions and corporate pension trust funds are included under "Miscellaneous investors." Total 135.6 134.9 132.9 131.8 130.8 133.4 135.0 137.3 133.3 135.1 136.7 142.3 138.5 138.5 136.2 136.6 5 6 Individuals4 Insurance companies 67.4 66.3 65.4 64.6 64.8 65.1 66.0 64.8 64.8 63.6 65.4 65.6 67.5 67.1 67.4 19.8 18.7 17.1 16.5 15.7 16.1 16.0 15.8 15.3 15.0 14.8 14.3 13.3 12.8 12.3 12.0 Mutual savings banks 11.6 10.9 10.2 9.8 9.6 9.5 9.5 9.2 9.1 8.8 8.7 8.5 8.4 8.0 7.9 7.6 Corporations 5 18.4 19.7 20.1 20.7 18.8 19.9 18.7 21.6 16.6 19.2 18.7 23.3 17.4 18.6 15.7 16.9 State and Miscellalocal govneous ernments • investors7 8.7 8.8 9.4 9.6 10.4 11.1 12.0 12.7 13.9 14.4 14.7 15.1 15.7 16.1 16.9 17.0 9.7 10.5 10.7 10.6 11.6 11.7 12.8 13.2 13.7 13.9 14.4 15.6 16.3 16.1 16.1 16.5 Exclusive of banks and insurance companies. Consists of trust, sinking, and investment funds of State and local governments and their agencies, and Territories and island possessions. 7 Includes savings and loan associations, nonprofit institutions, corporate pension trust funds, dealers and brokers, and investments of foreign balances and international accounts in this country. Source: Treasury Department, 3 O H W S> F w H GO W W <J a o H Q § o § I FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND T H E MONEY ECONOMIC STABILITY 9 SUPPLY The rise in interest rates did not appear to have any deterrent effect on the money supply. The volume of money, measured by demand deposits and currency outside banks, which had risen by $3.2 billion from June 1950 to March 1951, increased by $5.8 billion in the comparable period of 1951-52. The increase in money supply took place despite a slackening in the expansion of bank loans. Total bank loans which had risen by $10 billion during the 9 months prior to the accord increased by less than one-third in the 9 months ending March 1952, due largely to the slackening in business, real estate, and consumer loans. Two factors were mainly responsible for the change in the relationship between bank loans and the money supply. In the earlier period the expansion of bank loans was accompanied by a very substantial drop in the holdings of Government securities by the banking system and by a sizable outflow of gold from the country; in the later period the rise in bank loans was accompanied by an increase in bank holdings of Government securities and by an inflow of gold into the country. TABLE 4 . — D e p o s i t s and currency, [Billions of dollars] 1950-52 Deposits and currency Demand deposits and currency End of period Total i Total 1950—January. February March April May June July August September October November December 1951—January February... March April May June July August September October November December 1952—January February March AprilMay June July August September October November December __ 169.7 168.2 167.1 168.4 169.2 170.0 170.2 171.0 171.6 172.8 173.9 176.9 175.2 174.2 172.5 173.3 173.7 174.7 175.8 177.0 177.9 181.6 182.7 186.0 185.2 183.4 182.9 183.8 184.4 184.9 185.8 186.2 187.4 190.2 191.6 194.8 110.9 109.2 107.8 108.9 109.7 110.2 110.9 111.9 112.5 113.8 115.2 117.7 116.2 115.2 113.4 114.1 114.4 114.7 115.8 116.7 117.4 120.7 122.1 124.5 123.5 121.3 120.5 121.0 121.3 121.2 121.9 122.1 123.0 125.3 126.8 129.0 Demand deposits adjusteda Currency outside banks 86.4 84.5 83.2 84.3 85.0 85.0 86.5 87.4 88.0 89.2 90.3 92.3 91.6 90.6 89.0 89.5 89.5 89.0 90.7 91.4 92.0 95.0 96.3 98.2 97.9 95.7 94.8 95.1 95.3 94.8 95.7 95.8 96.4 98.6 99.4 101.5 24.5 24.7 24.6 24.6 24.7 25.2 24.4 24.5 24.5 24.6 24.9 25.4 24.6 24.6 24.4 24.6 24.9 25.8 25.1 25.3 25.4 25.7 25.8 26.3 25.6 25.6 25.7 25.9 26.0 26.5 26.2 26.3 26.6 26.7 27.4 27.5 Time deposits 3 58.7 59.0 59.3 59.5 59.5 59.7 59.4 59.1 59.0 59.0 58.7 59.2 59.0 59.0 59.1 59.2 59.3 59.9 60.0 60.3 60.5 60.9 60.6 61.5 61.7 62.0 62.4 62.7 63.0 63.7 63.8 64.1 64.5 64.9 64.8 65.8 12 Includes holdings of State and local governments, but excludes U. S. Government deposits. Includes demand deposits, other than interbank and U. S. Government, less cash items in process of collection. 3 Includes deposits in commercial banks, mutual savings banks, and Postal Savings System, but excludes interbank deposits. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 10 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY Total member bank reserves had increased by $3.1 billion from June 1950 to March 1951, but the raising of reserve requirements in January 1951 resulted in only $1.1 billion increase in the reserves available for credit expansion by March 1951. In the year ending March 1952 the reserves available for credit expansion had increased by $1.3 billion. The difference between the two periods was that prior to March 1951, very large Federal Reserve purchases of Government securities more than offset a substantial outflow of gold to increase bank reserves, while during the year ending March 1952 Reserve bank holdings of Government securities showed little net change with additional reserves being supplied by a gold inflow. TABLE 5 . — L o a n s and investments of all commercial banks, 1950-52 1 [Billions of dollars] End of period3 1960—January February March April May June July August September October November December-1951—January February March April May June July August September October November December1952—January February March April May June July August September October November December Total loans and investments 121.2 120.6 120.3 120.3 121.2 121.8 122.3 123.3 123.6 124.5 125.4 126.7 125.1 125.0 125.7 125.4 125.1 126.0 126.1 127.0 128.6 130.5 131.9 132.6 132.8 132.2 132.5 132.3 133.1 134.4 136.8 136.6 137.1 139.4 141.7 141.6 Loans Total« 42.9 43.1 43.7 43.8 44.1 44.8 46.0 47.3 48.9 49.9 51.5 52.2 52.7 53.5 54.4 54.4 54.5 54.8 54.6 55.2 56.0 56.8 57.3 57.7 57.5 57.6 57.8 58.2 58.5 59.2 59.7 60.2 61.2 62.4 63.4 64.2 Investments Business 4 17.2 17.2 17.1 16.8 16.7 16.9 17.3 18.3 19.4 20.0 21.1 21.9 22.3 23.1 23.7 23.6 23.5 23.7 23.4 23.9 24.5 25.0 25.3 25.9 25.6 25.6 25.8 25.2 24.9 25.3 25.1 25.5 26.2 26.9 27.5 27.9 Total 78.3 77.5 76.6 76.5 77.1 77.0 76.4 76.0 74.6 74.6 73.8 74.4 72.4 71.5 71.4 71.1 70.6 71.2 71.5 71.8 72.6 73.8 74.6 74.9 75.3 74.7 74.7 74.2 74.5 75.2 77.0 76.4 75.9 77.1 78.3 77.5 U.S. Government obligations 68.0 67.1 65.8 65.5 66.1 65.8 65.0 64.2 62.5 62.5 61.7 62.0 60.0 59.1 58.8 58.5 58.1 58.5 58.7 59.1 59.7 60.9 61.6 61.5 62.0 61.3 61.1 60.5 60.7 61.2 62.9 62.0 61.6 62.9 64.1 63.3 Other securities 10.3 10.4 10.8 11.0 11.0 11.2 11.4 11.8 12.1 12.1 12.1 12.4 12.4 12.4 12.6 12.6 12.5 12.7 12.8 12.7 12.9 12.9 13.0 13.3 13.3 13.4 13.6 13.7 13.8 14.0 14.1 14.4 14.3 14.2 14.2 14.1 1 Excludes mutual savings banks. ' June and December figures are for call dates. Other monthly data are for the last Wednesday of the month. 3 Data are shown net. Includes commercial and industrial loans, agricultural loans, loans on securities, real estate loans, loans to banks, and "other loans," some of which represent consumer credit. * Data are shown gross, i. e., before deduction of valuation reserves. For months other than June and December data are estimated on the basis of reported data for all insured commercial banks and for weekly reporting member banks. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. In considering monetary policy after the accord, it is necessary, of course, to refer to the underlying business conditions that were influencing the demand for funds as well as the factors influencing their supply. The accord took place at a time when inflationary develop- 11 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY ments had about reached their greatest intensity. Few would deny that continuous support purchases of Government securities at pegged prices had made the Federal Reserve System an "engine of inflation" during the 9 months after the outbreak of the Korean war. But the extent to which the removal of continuous support purchases of Government securities was of strategic importance in the weakening of inflationary pressures after March 1951 is a debatable question. There are those who emphasize the importance of the change in business conditions, particularly the cessation of the abnormally heavy forward buying by consumers and business firms when the anticipated shortages did not develop. To be sure, they grant that the shift in monetary policy exerted some anti-inflation influence in 1951, as was the case also with direct controls over prices and wages by the Federal Government, and of the selective controls over7 real state credit, consumer credit, and credit for security markets. ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTS That inflationary pressures had lessened after March 1951 is evident from the indexes of industrial production and of wholesale prices. The former which had climbed from 112 in June 1950 to 122 by December continued at the same level through May 1951, dropped to 118 by August and more or less remained at this level for the rest of the year. The latter rose from 100.2 in June 1950 to 116.5 in March 1951, declined to 113.7 in August, stabilized at this level for the remainder of the year, and continued to drift downward in 1952. The gross national product which rose from an annual rate of $274.4 billion in the second quarter of 1950 to $317.8 billion in the first quarter of 1951—an increase of 15.8 percent—reached $341 billion in the first quarter of 1952—-an increase of only 7.3 percent during the year. In the earlier period the pronounced increase in GNP was due primarily to the sharp rise in consumer expenditures and in business inventories; in the later period defense expenditures showed a very marked rise while the rate of accumulation of business inventories fell off sharply and consumer spending at first declined and then moved upward gradually. The relative influence of the various sectors of the economy on the changes in the pace of total national output before and after the accord can be seen from the figures for the major components of GNP from quarter to quarter. 7 In support of their position that the accord played a more powerful role in curbing inflationary pressures than their critics have been prepared to grant, Federal Reserve officials have argued that the mere fact of ceasing to support long-term Governments had the effect of shrinking considerably the liquidity of the economy. As was expected, this decrease in the general liquidity resulted in the banks enlarging their holdings of short-term United States securities and of nonbank institutional holders greatly decreasing the rate of their disposals of long-term Government securities. For the same reason, there was an increase in the demand for cash balances—as the rise in the money supply after the accord appeared to indicate. The critics, on the other hand, who question the substantial influence ot the accord in curbing inflation, cite in support of their view the fact that bank loans continued to grow, insurance companies and savings banks continued to dispose of Government securities in favor of other assets, and the expansion of currency and deposits was more rapid after the change in policy than before. For the latter view, see Charles R. Whittlesey, Old and New Ideas on Reserve Requirements, Journal of Finance, May 1953, pp. 193-194; also James Tobin, Monetary Policy and the Management of the Public Debt: The Patman Inquiry, Review of Economics and Statistics, May 1953, p. 124. For an interpretation of the period which indicates that general market conditions were chiefly responsible for the downward movement of wholesale prices since early in 1951, see Bert G. Hickman, The Korean War and United States Economic Activity, 1950-52, Occasional Paper 49, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., 1955. 12 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY TABLE 6.—Gross national product, seasonally adjusted at annual rates, 1950-52 [Billions of dollars] 1951 1950 I II III IV I II 1952 III IV I II III IV Gross n a t i o n a l product 265.8 274.4 293.2 304.3 317.8 326.4 333.8 338.1 341.0 341.3 347.0 358.6 Personal consumption expenditures Durable goods Nondurable goods Services 185.7 189.9 204.4 200.1 211.5 205.5 208.8 213.4 214.6 217.7 219.6 227.2 26.8 27.9 35.5 31.2 33.0 28.0 28.5 28.4 27.7 29.1 27.5 32.1 96.2 97.7 103.3 102.0 110.2 108.1 109.5 112.7 113.3 113.9 115.9 117.2 62.6 64.3 65.7 66.9 68.3 69.4 70.8 72.3 73.6 74.7 76.2 77.9 Gross private domestic investment New construction Residential nonfarm Other Producers' durable equipment Change in business inventories: total Nonfarm only Net foreign investment. Government purchases of goods and servicesFederal National security. Other,.. Less Government sales.. State and local 39.8 21.6 46.9 23.6 51.1 25.6 61.4 25.3 56.9 25.7 61.6 25.0 56.3 24.5 51.0 24.5 52.2 25.2 45.6 25.4 49.1 25.4 52.6 26.1 12.2 9.4 13.8 9.8 15.4 10.3 14.4 10.9 14.1 11.6 12.5 12.5 11.8 12.7 12.1 12.4 12.4 12.8 12.7 12.7 12.8 12.6 13.4 12.7 15.7 18.4 20.6 21.1 20.7 21.3 21.6 21.5 21.9 22.4 19.4 21.2 2.5 2.2 4.9 4.2 4.9 3.8 15.0 13.8 10.5 9.3 15.2 14.0 10.2 9.1 4.9 3.8 5.1 - 2 . 2 4.0 - 3 . 3 4.3 3.4 5.3 4.7 - . 9 -2.3 -3.0 -2.7 -2.3 -.6 1.9 1.9 2.0 41.2 21.9 17.0 5.2 39.9 20.6 17.1 3.8 40.6 20.8 17.8 3.2 45.5 25.2 22.2 3.3 51.6 30.8 27.6 3.5 59.9 38.4 34.8 3.9 66.8 44.9 41.1 4.4 71.8 49.7 45.3 4.9 72.2 49.6 45.3 4.7 77.1 54.0 49.0 5.4 80.0 56.7 50.0 7.0 80.7 57.0 51.3 6.0 .3 19.3 .2 19.3 .2 19.8 .3 20.3 .3 20.9 .3 21.6 .6 21.9 .5 22.1 .4 22.5 .4 23.1 .3 23.2 .3 23.7 .9 - 1 . 7 - 1 . 9 Source: Department of Commerce. One of the immediate effects of the outbreak of the Korean war was the marked rise in consumer expenditures and the sizable drop in personal savings. From the second to the third quarter of 1950 personal consumption expenditures increased at an annual rate of $14.5 billion, or 7.1 percent. More than one-half of the increase was in consumer durable goods. This pronounced rise was followed by a sharp increase in business inventories in the last 3 months of the year, a change from an annual rate of $4.9 billion in the third to $15 billion in the fourth quarter. In the first quarter of 1951 consumer expenditures increased by $11.4 billion over the final quarter of 1950. During the next 3 months they dropped by $6 billion with most of the decline in expenditures for consumer durables. Spending for consumer durables continued at the sharply reduced second quarter level through the first 3 months of 1952. Investment in business inventories which reached a record annual rate of $15.2 billion in the second quarter of 1951 dropped to $4.9 billion in the fourth and to minus $2.2 billion by the second quarter of 1952.8 Residential nonfarm construction expenditures which had reached an annual rate of $15.4 billion in the third quarter of 1950 dropped to a rate of $11.8 billion a year later. 8 Federal Reserve officials stress the view that the accord played a major role in changing the climate of expectations in the money market and in general market conditions. The flight of "hot money" from the dollar before the accord, and reflected in gold exports, was followed by the cessation of the flight of gold after the accord. Moreover, it was an important factor in changing inflationary psychology with a consequent shift in consumer expenditures and business inventories. 13 F E D E R A L RESERVE POLICY A N D TABLE 7 . — D i s p o s i t i o n of disposable ECONOMIC personal income, STABILITY 1950-52 [Seasonally adjusted quarterly totals at annual rates] [Billions of dollars] Period 1950—1st quarter 2d quarter 3d quarter 4th quarter 1951—1st quarter 2d quarter 3d quarter 4th quarter 1952—1st quarter 2d quarter 3d quarter 4th quarter Disposable personal income Personal consumption expenditures 200.9 201.7 210.2 217.7 219.8 226.4 229.5 233.8 232.1 235.6 241.1 245.6 Personal saving 185.7 189.9 204.4 200.1 211.5 205.5 208.8 213.4 214.6 217.7 219.6 227.2 15.2 11.8 5.8 17.6 8.3 20.9 20.7 20.4 17.5 17.9 21.5 18.4 Saving as percent of disposable personal J income 7.6 5.9 2.8 8.1 3.8 9.2 9.0 8.8 7.5 7.6 9.0 7.4 Source: Department of Commerce. Thus, while outlays for consumer durable goods and housing together with inventory investment were major stimuli in the inflationary developments during the second half of 1950 and in early 1951, by mid-1951 these sectors were a restraining influence upon inflationary pressures. At the same time that these contractive forces were operating, defense outlays had stepped up sharply. National security expenditures which were at an annual rate of $22.2 billion in the final quarter of 1950 more than doubled by the final quarter of 1951. Most of the rise in gross national product during this period originated from this source. REVIVAL OF THE DISCOUNT MECHANISM If we must largely attribute the subsidence of inflationary pressures during the first year after the accord to the reduction in spending by consumers for durable goods and to the downward adjustment of business inventories, this does not signify that the more flexible credit policy was not a salutary development. While there are differences of opinion as to how much of an anti-inflationary influence the monetary authorities actually were or could be after March 1951, it can hardly be questioned that with the turning away from the rigid support of Government security prices the way was paved for openmarket operations and the discount mechanism to become more effective complementary tools of monetary policy. It was not until a year after the accord that it had become apparent that the member banks were resorting increasingly to borrowing at the Federal Reserve banks in order to obtain additional reserves for supporting credit expansion. The discount mechanism had fallen more or less into disuse for two decades and could not be reactivated until a flexible open-market policy had been restored. When the monetary authorities deem it desirable to exercise restraint on credit expansion, less reserves are made available to the banks through restrictive open-market operations. In order to obtain additional reserves to meet temporary deficiencies in their legal reserves, the jnember banks turn to the discount window of the Federal Reserve banks. 14 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY An expanding volume of discounts enables the Federal Reserve System to exercise greater control over bank credit expansion. The banks are said to be traditionally reluctant to borrow from the Federal Reserve banks and are also subject to administrative regulations that discourage continuous borrowing. Moreover, replenishing of reserves through the discount window may be made more expensive through the raising of the Federal Reserve discount rate. As a result of these pressures, member banks readjust their loans and investments to meet their obligations to repay promptly. In other words, the discount mechanism acts as a brake in bank credit expansion, and serves as a major supplement9 to open-market policy as a tool for promoting economic stability. TABLE 8 . — I n s t a l l m e n t credit, 1950-52 [Millions of dollars] End of month Total outstanding 1950—January. February.. March April May_ June July August September. October... November. December. 1951—January.. _ February.. March April May June July August September. October. _. November. December. 1952—January.._ February.. March April May June July August September. October. _ . November. December. 11,599 11,669 11,888 12,136 12,534 13,030 13.578 14,045 14,452 14, 570 14,492 14,703 14,564 14,409 14,382 14,321 14,376 14,437 14,369 14,622 14, 766 14,826 14,946 15,294 15,121 15,030 15,032 15,234 15, 834 16, 588 17,044 17,329 17,669 18,216 18.579 19,403 Automobile paper Other consumer goods paper 1 4,613 4,717 4,868 5,024 5,220 5, 504 5,825 6,032 6,191 6,212 6,133 6,074 5,984 5,910 5,875 5,873 5,932 5,996 5,992 6,108 6,157 6,095 b, 048 5,972 5,881 5,848 5,824 5,916 6,249 6,662 6,878 6,946 7,055 7,293 7,504 7,733 3,671 3,643 3,690 3,760 3,887 4,004 4,159 4,349 4,546 4,611 4,588 4, 799 4,727 4,639 4, 591 4,502 4,445 4,393 4,289 4,354 4,389 4, 178 4, 572 4,880 4, 776 4,683 4,647 4, 667 4,812 5,001 5,133 5,252 5,400 5,626 5,712 6,174 Repair and moderniza-2 tion loans 887 872 872 897 922 945 971 996 1,014 1,021 1,016 1,001 988 987 989 1,002 1,003 1,012 1,029 1,045 1,064 1,082 1,0! 1,074 1,073 1,071 1,091 1,132 1,174 1,216 1,254 1,297 1,345 1,374 1,385 1 Represents all consumer installment credit extended for the purpose of purchasing automobiles and other consumer goods, whether held by retail outlets orfinancialinstitutions. Includes credit on purchases bya individuals of automobiles or other consumer goods that may be used in part for business. Represents repair and modernization loans held by financial institutions; holdings of retail outlets are included in other consumer goods paper. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. ECONOMIC AND F I N A N C I A L DEVELOPMENTS IN SECOND HALF OF 1952 Toward mid-1952, there was a quickening in the pace of business activity with accompanying increase in the demand for credit. The index of industrial production rose from 119 in May to 133 in December, except in June and July during the steel strike. The gross 9 For the most recent Federal Reserve statement on the role of the discount mechanism in monetary policy, see the Forty-fourth Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 1957, pp. 7-18. 15 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY national product rose at an annual rate of $17.3 billion, or 5.1 percent from the second to the final quarter of 1952. Virtually all of the increase arose from the expansion of business inventories and from consumer spending. The rise in consumer spending was facilitated by the rapid expansion of installment credit, especially after the lifting of consumer credit controls. In addition, there was the discontinuance around the middle of the year of direct regulation of real estate credit and of the voluntary credit-restraint program. Defense spending considerably slackened its rate of expansion after the second quarter of the year. The leveling off of defense expenditures in the last half of the year and the substantial growth of production in the civilian sector were accompanied by a decline in wholesale prices and by consumer price stability. Total loans of all commercial banks increased by $5 billion from June to December 1952 with most of the expansion in consumer and business loans. Total bank investments rose by over $2 billion with practically all of the acquisition in United States Government securities. Despite the greater increase in bank credit in the last half of 1952 as compared to the corresponding period of 1951, the rise in the money supply (adjusted demand deposits and currency in circulation) was about $2 billion less in the second half of 1952 than in the last half of 1951. FEDERAL RESERVE CREDIT POLICY With the intensification of the demand for bank credit as business activity accelerated and with a large increase in the demand for funds by the Treasury to finance a Government deficit, there WSLS increasing pressure on bank reserves. In the absence of offsetting open-market operations, the member banks turned increasingly to discounting at the Reserve banks to replenish their reserves. In March 1952 discounts and advances of the Federal Reserve System averaged $314 million; in June the monthly average rose to $585 million; during the next 4 months it was around $1 billion; and in December it reached $1.6 billion. TABLE 9.—Open-market transactions in TJ. S. Government securities}l Sept. 80, 1952 July 1, 1951- [Millions of dollars] During periods of refunding2 Total Other than periods of refunding Class of security Maturing issues (rights) _ _ Other securities maturing: Within 91 days 91 days to 14 months 14 months to 5 years 5 years to 10 years Over 10 years Total 3,059 1, 568 594 1 3 23 5,248 Sales Purchases Sales Purchases Sales 2,206 2,277 3,059 541 341 372 1,154 too Purchases 1,834 1,123 5 4,488 6 3,947 3 1,529 1,301 2 2,959 1 Excludes repurchase agreements with dealers and brokers and purchases and sales of special certificates from and to Treasury. 3 Commitments from date of announcement to closing of books, plus all transactions in new securities on a when-issued basis. Source: United States Monetary Policy: Recent Thinking and Experience: Hearings, Subcommittee on Economic Stabilization of the Joint Committee on the Economic Report, 83d Cong., 2d sess., 1954, p. 265. 16 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC TABLE 1 0 . — M e m b e r bank reserves and related STABILITY items,1950-52 [Averages of daily figures, millions of dollars] Period 1950—January. . . February— March April. May June. July August September. October... November. December. 1951—January... February. . March April May. June July August September. October... November. December. 1952—January. FebruaryMarch April May June July August September. October. _. November. December. Federal Reserve credit 18,649 18,310 18,242 18,136 18,005 18,325 18.703 18,877 19,610 20,044 20,159 21,606 21,839 23,286 23.663 23,983 23,686 23,913 24.285 24,264 24.664 24,982 24.785 25,446 24,444 23,826 23,890 23,726 23.704 24,144 24.786 24,824 25,055 25,681 26,172 27,299 Gold stock 24,420 24,346 24,311 24,247 24,236 24,231 24,192 23,927 23,560 23,366 23,157 22,879 22,523 22,249 21,909 21,806 21, 757 21,755 21,757 21,790 21,906 22,104 22,298 22,483 22,824 23,039 23,278 23,293 23,297 23,308 23,348 23,346 23,343 23,340 23,338 23,276 Currency in circulation 27,220 27.008 27,043 27,062 27,022 27,026 27,117 27.009 27,154 27,233 27,380 27,806 27,304 27,145 27,171 27,179 27,324 27,548 27,859 27,951 28,213 28,387 28,612 29,139 28,637 28,406 28,437 28,459 28,557 28,843 29,028 29,088 29,343 29,555 29,904 30,494 Total reserves 16,520 16,146 16,081 15,898 15,941 16,194 16,253 16,273 16,602 16,731 16, 742 17,391 18,088 18,907 19,207 19,324 18,892 19.309 19,229 19,174 19,396 19,868 19,794 20.310 20,469 19,995 20,207 19,777 19, 767 20,140 20,535 20,306 20,514 20,611 20,744 21,180 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. From June to December the required reserves needed to support the increase in bank deposits amounted to $1 billion, and about $1.6 billion of reserve funds were needed to offset the outflow of currency in circulation. The additional reserves were supplied as follows: About $1 billion originated from borrowing from the Federal Reserve, $1.3 billion from outright purchases of Government securities by the Open Market Committee, and about $400 million through the acquisition of securities under repurchase agreements.10 The Federal Reserve did not change its preaccord directive "to maintain orderly conditions" in the Government securities market until March 1953 when the present wording "to correct disorderly conditions" was approved. In the interval it underwrote Treasury refunding operations through open-market purchases of the maturing issues for which an exchange was being offered and at times of the new security on a when-issued basis. During the period between July 1, 1951, and September 30, 1952, the Treasury entered the market 9 different times to refund about $49 billion of maturing securities. During these 15 months, purchases of the Open Market Committee amounted to $5.2 billion and were concentrated almost wholly in short-term securities, i. e., issues less than 14 months. About three-fourths of the total purchases were made during periods of refunding and only one-fourth were made between refunding periods. The $3.9 billion of support purchases during refunding 10 See appendix, p. 78. 17 F E D E R A L R E S E R V E POLICY A N D ECONOMIC TABLE 1 1 . — M e m b e r bank excess reserves, borrowings, STABILITY and free reserves, 1950-52 [Averages of daily figures, millions of dollars] Borrowings at Federal Reserve banks Period 1950—Januar y February March. April May June July August September. __ October November... December. 1951—Januar y February March April May June 737 783 694 704 767 746 647 765 842 731 1,027 825 627 713 833 590 35 123 128 101 80 68 123 164 96 67 145 142 212 330 242 161 438 170 Free reserves 901 614 655 593 624 699 623 483 669 775 586 885 613 297 471 672 152 664 Period 1951—July August SeptemberOctober November. December. 1952—January. __ February.. March April May. June. July August September. October November. December. Excess reserves 756 704 721 915 729 695 885 650 628 709 609 649 778 648 657 723 Borrowings at Federal Reserve banks 194 292 338 95 340 657 210 365 307 367 563 579 1,077 1,032 683 1,048 1,532 1,593 Free reserves 562 412 723 330 578 283 65 130 -468 -383 95 -400 -875 -870 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. periods were offset at the same time by $1.5 billion of sales of other securities in the portfolios of the Reserve banks. Nearly $3 billion of sales by the Open Market Committee were made between periods of refunding in order to withdraw funds supplied during support operations. However, since total purchases for the 15-month period amounted to $5.2 billion and total sales were nearly $4.5 billion, this meant that offsetting sales fell short of purchases by $700 million. This additional Federal Reserve credit occurred during the sizable August and September 1952 Treasury refunding operations when a large part of the substantial increase in open-market purchases was not offset by sales transactions. The decision not to withdraw funds supplied in support of the August and September 1952 refundings reflected the tightening situation in the money market, a condition that was becoming more apparent since the spring of 1952. The increasing pressure on member bank reserves is evident from an examination of table 11 showing the member bank reserve balances and the amount of rediscounting at the Federal Reserve banks. Particularly significant for indicating stringency of credit conditions is the difference between excess reserves (i. e., total reserves less legal required reserves) and member bank borrowings at the Federal Reserve banks. This difference is known as free reserves. There was a downward trend in free reserves since the spring of 1952, becoming negative in the latter half of the year. In November and December free reserves were minus $900 million. Tightness in the money market was reflected in the rise in the yields of securities, particularly the Treasury bill rate. The monthly average of Treasury 3-month bills rose from 1.57 in February 1952 to 2.12 in December. The last half of the year the bill rate was above the 1% percent discount rate of the Federal Reserve. When the bill rate is above the discount rate, there is some encouragement for banks to borrow from the Federal Reserve banks rather than to dispose of bills, but it was not until January 1953 that the Federal 18 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY Reserve banks attempted to bring the discount rate more nearly in line with short-term market rates by raising the discount rate to 2 percent. Another factor in the growth of member bank borrowing was the excess-profits tax which made it profitable for potentially affected banks to borrow during this period. As table 11 shows, total member bank borrowing and net borrowed reserves grew rapidly. They would have grown even more rapidly, however, had it not been for purchases of the Open Market Committee. TABLE 1 2 . — A n n u a l rate of turnover of demand its, 1950-52 1 [Ratio of debits to deposits] Period 1950—Januar y February March April May June July August September... October November. __ December. __ 1951—Januar y February March.. April May June New York City 29.0 29.0 30.1 28.4 30.0 31.6 29.0 34.5 32.8 30.6 32.3 36.1 32.5 30.1 35.1 32.5 31.0 33.7 1 3 6 other centers2 338 other reporting centers 20.9 20.9 23.5 22.0 21.7 23.2 21.5 16.3 15.8 22.2 23.5 23.0 24.0 25.2 24.7 23.5 26.4 25.6 24.2 24.0 16.0 15.7 16.2 17.0 17.1 17.1 18.4 18.3 19.1 19.2 19.0 18.3 18.5 18.5 18.3 18.4 Period 1951—Jul y August SeptemberOctober NovemberDecember _ 1952—January _ __ February.. March April May June July August September. October NovemberDecember. New York City 31.1 27.6 30.6 31.2 32.1 35.9 31.2 32.3 33.6 34.0 32.8 37.4 34.4 29.6 35.4 36.4 34.1 41.8 6 other 338 other centers3 reporting centers 23.3 22.1 23.6 23.1 24.4 24.3 23.0 23.4 25.7 24.6 22.8 24.9 24.0 20.8 24.3 25.0 24.1 26.9 18.0 17.3 18.3 18.4 19.6 19.0 18.3 18.5 18.2 17.8 17.9 18.8 18.1 17.0 18.9 18.7 19.3 19.8 Does not include interbank and U. S. Government deposits and is given without seasonal adjustment. Boston, Philadelphia, Chicago, Detroit, San Francisco, Los Angeles. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. CHAPTER I I . FEDERAL RESERVE POLICIES IN 1953-54 The first half of 1953 is an especially interesting period to the student of monetary policy. It posed a series of issues to the Federal Reserve Board and the Open Market Committee which have been discussed ever since not only in the academic literature but by the Congress itself, particularly at committee hearings where monetary and fiscal problems affecting economic stability are under consideration. On some of these questions there have been sharp differences of opinion within the Federal Reserve System, in the Congress, and among economists. Some of the issues are quite technical and on the surface appear to be concerned only with the operating techniques of what has come to be the most important tool of monetary policy, namely, open-market operations. But they cannot be readily dismissed on the grounds that the issues involve only considerations of the technical operations of the System's open-market account. They raise important questions of credit policy which have a significant bearing on the objective of promoting the stability and growth of the economy through the use of the powers of the Federal Reserve System. The issues referred to in the preceding paragraph all came to the fore at the March 1953 meeting of the Open Market Committee and are reported in the record of its policy actions in the Federal Reserve Board's Annual Report for 1953. The first of the policy decisions was concerned with the longstanding directive to the Executive Committee to continue, as it had done since August 1951, to operate "with a view to exercising restraint upon inflationary developments." The second, involving a change from previous directives, provided that the Executive Committee should arrange for transactions in the System open-market account with a view "to correcting a disorderly situation in the Government securities market/' rather than as previously, "to maintaining orderly conditions in the Government securities market." The third action instructed the Executive Committee that "operations for the System account should be confined to the short end of the market (not including correction of disorderly markets)." In practice, this meant confining operations to Treasury bills. The System account was also to refrain from support purchases in the market during periods of Treasury refinancing. A P P R A I S A L S OF T H E B U S I N E S S S I T U A T I O N , F I R S T H A L F OF 1953 Let us first consider the early March directive which instructed the Executive Committee to continue to operate "with a view to exercising restraint upon inflationary developments." The assumption that the economy was likely to be dominated by inflationary developments explains in large measure the controversies about Federal Reserve policy and Treasury debt management policy that flared up in the Congress and in the financial and business community during the first half of 1953. Particularly important for the purposes of this 19 H. Rept. 2500, 85-2 3 FEDERAL 20 RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY report is that the controversies bring to the fore certain limitations in the use of the tools of monetary policy (and fiscal and debt management policy) for promoting economic stability. As we shall see in the next chapter, these limitations are not only apparent in a review of the first half of 1953; they become even more apparent in the review of later Federal Reserve actions. The limitations referred to relate to the difficulties involved in appraisals of changes in the business situation, currently and for the near future. As the Open Market Committee saw it, economic activity which had been expanding at a rapid rate in the second half of 1952 was continuing to expand further in the early months of 1953. Industrial production, the gross national product, and business inventories were increasing, and unemployment was exceptionally low. At the same time the demand for capital and credit continued strong, especially mortgage and consumer credit, despite the raising of the discount rate from 1% percent to 2 percent around the middle of January. There were some observers who did not anticipate continuation of inflationary pressures. Typical of those who were critical of the Open Market Committee's concern with further inflationary developments was Mr. Marriner Eccles, former Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, who argued that the signs pointed rather to deflationary developments. The wholesale and consumer price levels had stabilized. It was also pointed out that the production of automobiles and other consumer durable goods and the construction of housing were reaching a point of saturation in relation to demand, and that Government expenditures were scheduled to reach a peak and start declining during the year.1 These appraisals of current developments were publicly expressed at the same time that spokesmen for the Federal Reserve and the Treasury were publicly stressing the predominance of inflationary pressures calling for monetary and debt management policies of an anti-inflationary character. TABLE 1 3 . — I n d e x e s of industrial production, 1958-54 wholesale and consumer prices, [1947-49=100] Month Industrial production 1 Wholesale prices 134 134 135 136 137 136 137 136 133 132 129 109.9 109.6 110.0 109.4 109.8 109.5 110.9 110.6 111.0 110.2 109.8 110.1 1953—January February March April May June July August September—. October November. _. December. 126 Consumer prices 113.9 113.4 113.6 113.7 114.0 114.5 114.7 115.0 115.2 115.4 115.0 114.9 Month 1954—January February March April May June July — August September-. October November... December. Industrial production 1 Wholesale prices 125 125 123 123 125 124 123 123 124 126 128 130 110.9 110.5 110.5 111.0 110.9 110.0 110.4 110.5 110.0 109.7 110.0 109.5 i Seasonally adjusted. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and U. S. Department of Labor, i Washington Post, April 15, 1953. Consumer prices 115.2 115.0 114.8 114.6 115.0 115.1 115.2 115.0 114.7 114.5 114.6 114.3 21 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY To be sure, at any given time, analysts of business conditions differ in their appraisals of current economic developments. In view of the fact that more or less the same statistical and other pertinent data are available to competent and trained observers, such differences must be largely interpretative and analytical in character. Since even in periods of general high and expanding levels of activity there are sectors of the economy that are contracting rather than expanding, there are bound to be differences in judgment as to the relative influence of the diverse movements that are taking place. Unfortunately, psychological and other biases enter into these judgments, especially during periods of prosperity, which result in minimizing the unfavorable influences that appear on the business horizon and the neglect of which may result in faulty policy decisions. Fortunately, however, one of the virtues of monetary policy, as compared to fiscal and debt management policy, is its greater flexibility. The monetary authorities are generally in a better position to minimize errors of diagnosis by more speedily steering a different course to meet changing conditions. As we shall see, this was the case in 1953; it may have been less so in 1957. Let us examine some of the statisticaFseries which measure the behavior of the economy during this period. The index of industrial production, which rose from 115 in July 1952 to 133 in November and December, climbed to 137 in May 1953. This would appear to indicate that the rate of expansion in production was slackening in the earlier part of 1953. The gross national product, which increased at an annual rate of $11*6 billion between the third and fourth quarters of 1952, rose by $5.9 billion in the first quarter of 1953, and by an annual rate of $4.3 billion in the second quarter. To some observers at the time, the slackening in the rate of economic activity, as indicated by such broad-gaged measures as the index of industrial production and the gross national product, meant that the economy was approaching the peak in the expansion phase of the business cycle and would soon turn down. To others, especially the monetary authorities, whose daily activities in the area of credit indicated continuing strong pressures for additional funds, the slackening in the rate of economic expansion—even if it could be so gaged at the time—might only be temporary, to be followed by a further upward surge of activity in the months ahead. Officials of the Federal Reserve have pointed out that business inventories were rising at the time, and they interpreted this rise as an indication of the intensification of inflationary pressures. However, a rise in inventories could also signify that production and sales were growing out of balance, a condition that could culminate in readjustments of a deflationary character. Toward midyear, when inflation was still the dominant theme, it was becoming more apparent that such readjustment was in process. When one turns from general measures of business activity and examines the behavior of specific areas, there were a number of signs early in 1953 which indicated impending change in a downward direction. It is sufficient to cite only a few of such indicators. Industrial stock prices, which in the past have manifested a definite tendency to lead at cyclical turning points of business activity, moved downward during each of the first 6 months of 1953. Orders for manufacturers' durable goods and the average length of the manufacturing workweek started to decline in the spring. The rise in retail sales 22 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY was halted in February, while business inventories continued to expand through the summer. It is precisely at the time when aggregate measures of business conditions indicate increasing buoyancy in the economy at more or less peak levels that there is intensification of concern about inflationary pressures. It is at such times also that there is a tendency to ignore imbalances that have been building up in certain sectors for a number of months but which only become visible later on in the general measures of business activity. With retail sales sluggish since the early months of 1953, while inventories were piling up, a downward adjustment in the economy rather than a further upward push was the more likely prospect. MONEY AND BANK CREDIT, FIRST HALF OF 1953 Turning from the industrial sector, where production was at peak levels while key individual sectors were manifesting signs of weakness, to the financial sector, let us examine briefly the changes in the money supply and some of the major influences affecting bank reserves. Demand deposits and currency, which usually move downward during the first half of the year and rise substantially in the second half, declined more sharply in the first 6 months of 1953 than in the corresponding periods of 1950-52. The relatively greater decline in the money supply largely reflected a shrinkage in bank holdings of Government securities in the amount of $4.2 billion during the first half of 1953. The commercial banks not only sold Government securities to meet the large demands for credit; they also continued to rely heavily on borrowing from the Federal Reserve banks. In January their discounts and advances were nearly $1.4 billion and in April they were close to $1.2 billion. There is little doubt that the reserve positions of the banks were under pressure. This pressure was exerted by foreign gold withdrawals starting in December and by restrictive Federal Reserve openmarket operations. The latter may be seen from table 14 showing open-market transactions for 1953. Jn the first part of the year there were no outright purchases of Government securities and over $200 million of sales. There was also substantial reselling of securities which had been purchased in December under repurchase agreements with dealers in short-term Government securities. As a result of these operations, there was a net reduction in Federal Reserve holdings of Government securities and to that extent an absorption of member bank reserves. Free reserves, i. e., excess member bank reserves less borrowings by member banks, were minus at least $600 million in each of the first 4 months of 1953. The pressures on credit resulted in a general firming of interest rates to mid-April and a sharp advance to early June. Between January and June, the monthly averages of Treasury bill rates rose from 2.04 percent to 2.23 percent, prime commercial paper from 2.31 percent to 2.75 percent, and long-term Governments from 2% to 3% percent. TABLE 14.—Gross transactions in Government securities by the Federal Open Market Committee, January-December 1953 [In millions of dollars] Market transactions (gross) Net change in Federal Reserve holdings Outright transactions 1 Total Purchases Purchases January— February, _ March April May_ June July August September . October November. December. . -753.4 -68.3 -69.2 +74.0 +366. 3 +499. 8 +217. 5 +99.5 +171. 5 +113 0 2-252. 5 +820 4 Total. +1, 218. 6 1 2 Purchases 2,801. 6 477.5 414 1 384.0 138.0 144.9 646.4 57.0 1,102.0 1,981. 3 75.5 225.0 687.1 245 5 25.0 263 7 113.0 165.0 375.0 2 520.0 50.0 478.2 242.9 119.0 476 0 555.4 196.7 110.0 219.4 554.2 57.0 684.5 2, 426. 6 8, 294.7 7,076.1 2,174. 8 890.4 6,119. 9 478 2 242.9 119 0 551.5 780 4 883 8 355.5 244.4 817.9 170.0 849.5 Includes runoff of Treasury bills at maturity. Includes 2^-percent notes of December 1953, redeemed with gold certificates. Repurchase agreements with dealers 1, 231. 6 311.2 188.2 145.7 35.3 46.2 75.5 17.7 Sales Special certificates purchased Exchange of directly from maturing Treasury certificates, (largest notes, and amount outbonds standing in month) 350.1 3,886. 9 270.5 1,085. 9 275 9 142 0 402 0 414.1 384.0 138.0 144.9 628.7 57.0 582 0 1,931. 2 1,172.0 6,185. 7 1, 505 0 281.3 1,152 8 503.0 710.9 1,398. 2 702.7 591.0 7,978 4 17,825. 8 Source: Hearings on January 1954 Economic Report of the President, Joint Committee on the Economic Report, 83d Cong., 2d sess., February 1954, p. 133. H t* H W >1 tr w M U1 fel W <J H Hd O1 tr i—i o > o tei o o o ZP > W i—i F i—i h3 H to CO 24 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY Around mid-February the Federal Reserve Board reduced margin requirements on stock market credit2 from 75 to 50 percent. In explaining its action the Board stated: The margin requirements had been increased from 50 to 75 percent in January 1951 as a preventive measure and as a supplement to the steps previously taken in the credit and monetary area to lessen inflationary pressures. By February 1953 inflationary pressures had moderated and, with the margin requirements fixed at 75 percent, there had been no substantial increase in the total amount of credit in use in the stock market. Accordingly, the Board concluded that margin requirements of 50 percent would be adequate to prevent the excessive use of credit for the purchasing and carrying of securities and that a reduction to that level would be in harmony with the System's overall credit and monetary policy under current conditions. To be sure, inflationary pressures in early 1953 were certainly not as strong as in early 1951, but they were apparently regarded as sufficiently strong for the System to raise the discount rate in January 1953 and to restrict bank reserves through open-market operations. Consequently, critics pointed out at the time that the Board's action in lowering margin requirements was inconsistent with its concern about "inflationary developments" and with its restrictive general monetary policy. 2 Fortieth Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1953, p. 83. TABLE 1 5 . — B o n d yields and interest rates, 1953-54 [Percent per annum] U. S. Government securities Period 1953-^-January _ _. February.. March April May June July August September October November. December. 1954—January. _. February.. March April May June July August September. October.... November. December. 1 2 3-month Treasury bills 2.042 2.018 2.082 2.177 2.200 2.231 2.101 2.088 1.876 1.402 1.427 1. 630 1.214 .984 1.053 1.011 .782 .650 .710 .892 1.007 .987 .948 1.174 9-to-12month Taxable bonds 10 to 20 years2 1.97 1.97 2. 04 2.27 2.41 2.46 2.36 2.33 2.17 1. 72 1.53 1. 61 1.33 1.01 1.02 .90 .76 .76 .65 .64 .89 1.03 .94 1.10 Corporate bonds (Moody's) 2.80 2.83 2.89 2.97 3.09 3.09 2.99 3.00 2.97 2.83 2.85 2. 79 2.67 2.58 2.50" 2.45 2.52 2.53 2.45 2.46 2.50 2.52 2.55 2.57 3.26 3.29 3.25 3.22 3.19 3. 06 3.04 2.96 2.90 2.85 2. 73 2. 70 2. 72 2.70 2.62 2.60 2.64 2. 65 2.68 2.68 Includes certificates of indebtedness and selected note and bond issues. 2^> percent bonds, 15 years and over prior to April 1952 and 12 years and over beginning April 1952 3 3H percent bonds of 1978-83, 1st issued May 1, 1953. 4 Effective Jan. 16, 1953. Aaa Baa 20 years and over 3 3.02 3.07 3.12 3.23 3.34 3.40 3.28 3.24 3.29 3.16 3.11 3.13 3.06 2. 95 2. 86 2.85 2.88 2.90 2. 89 2. 87 ?. 89 2.87 2.89 2.90 3. 51 3.53 3. 57 3. 65 3. 78 3.86 3. 86 3. 85 3.88 3. 82 3. 76 3.74 3. 71 3. 61 3. 51 3.47 3.47 3.49 3.50 3. 49 3.47 3.46 3.45 3.45 Average Common High-grade Prime rate on stock municipal short-term commeryields, bonds bank loans cial paper, 200 stocks, (Standard to business, 4 to 6 (Moody's) & Poor's) selected months cities 5.15 5. 22 5.34 5.49 5. 51 5.58 5.46 5. 75 5. 73 5. 59 5.53 5. 55 5.33 5.32 5.14 4.94 4.88 4.82 4.61 4. 75 4.46 4. 57 4. 39 4.20 2.47 2.54 2.61 2.63 2. 73 2.99 2.99 2.88 2. 88 2. 72 3.54 3. 73 3^74 2.62 2.59 2.50 2.39 2.38 2. 47 2.49 2.48 2.31 2.23 2.29 2.32 2.29 2.33 3. 76 3.72 3. 56 3. 55 2.31 2.31 2.36 2.44 2. 67 2. 75 2. 75 2. 75 2.74 2. 55 2.31 2.25 2.11 2.00 2.00 1.76 1.58 1.56 1.45 1.33 1.31 1.31 1.31 1.31 <2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 s 1. 75 1.75 6 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 s Effective Feb. 5, 1954. 6 Effective Apr. 16, 1954. Sources: Board of Governors of Federal Reserve System, Treasury Department, Moody's Investor Service, and Standard and Poor's Corp. § K| to Oi 26 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY THE OBJECTIVE OF A FREE MARKET One cannot fully understand monetary and debt management policy as well as conditions in the money market during the first half of 1953 without consideration of the March directives of the Open Market Committee other than that of "exercising restraint on inflationary developments." Since these directives, mentioned at the beginning of this chapter, have also played an important role in Federal Reserve3 policy ever since, it is essential that we examine them more closely. The change in the directive to the Executive Committee from "maintenance of orderly conditions" to that of "correction of disorderly conditions in the Government securities market" was designed to make more explicit the commitment of Federal Reserve policy to a philosophy of a "free securities market." It was intended to reassure dealers and professional buyers and sellers of Government securities that the forces of supply and demand would determine the prices and yields of Government securities and that in such a market they would not be subject to the hazards of unpredictable intervention by the Open Market Committee. The Federal Reserve would confine its operations to releasing and absorbing reserve funds in order to effectuate its general credit policies. Only in extreme circumstances would the Open Market Committee step in to correct a market that was clearly disorderly. To reinforce the goal of a "free market" there were the additional directives: (1) Open-market operations would be confined to the short end of the market; (2) support of the market during periods of Treasury refinancing would be discontinued; (3) the policy of the Committee was not to support any pattern of prices and yields in the market. The view that yields on Government securities should be determined by a free money market was vigorously expounded in speeches in the spring of 1953 by the Chairman of the Board of Governors and by the Secretary of the Treasury. This view was regarded with much less enthusiasm by a number of critics, among whom were distinguished economists.4 They pointed out that the Federal Reserve System came into existence precisely because the country had learned from the bitter experience of the past that it was dangerous to the stability 3 These directives which were adopted at the March meeting of the Open Market Committee are based on recommendations of an ad hoc subcommittee appointed in 1951 to study methods of improving the effectiveness of open market operations. The full text of the report of the ad hoc subcommittee on the Government securities market, which was submitted to the Open Market Committee in November 1952, was first made public 2 years later in United States Monetary Policy: Recent Thinking and Experience: Hearings before the Subcommittee on Economic Stabilization, Joint Committee on the Economic Report, 83d Cong., 2d sess., 1954, pp. 257-307. 4 Among the critics of the "free market philosophy" was Prof. Lester V. Chandler of Princeton University: * * High officials in the Treasury Department have at times suggested that interest rates should be determined by the market forces of demand and supply, and the Chairman of the Board of Governors made a memorable speech describing the transition to 'free markets,' which was to include a 'free money market.' This was, in my opinion, an unfortunate choice of words. * * * But to allow the total supply of money and loans, and the price of loans, to be determined by private demand and private supply would negate the very idea of central banking. Central banks exist because we are not willing to allow the total supply of money and credit, and the cost of credit, to be determined by the unregulated forces of private supply and demand. The basic function of a central bank is to regulate the total supply of money and credit and the terms on which they are made available. It should be clear that the Federal Reserve can make its maximum contribution to economic stability and growth only by recognizing its continuous responsibility for money market conditions, and by taking whatever positive actions that may appear conducive to the attainment of its objectives. * * * A successful policy of economic stabilization cannot be a passive policy * * * (United States Monetary Policy: Recent Thinking and Experience, cited in footnote 3; pp. 45-46). For this and the next section see Alvin H. Hansen, The American Economy, McGraw-Hill, 1957, ch. 4. Also Paul A. Samuelson, Recent American Monetary Controversy, The Three Banks Review, March 1956; also Deane Carson, Recent Open Market Committee Policy and Techniques, Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 1955; and C. R. Whittlesey, Monetary Policy and Economic Change, Review of Economics and Statistics, February 1957. 27 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY of the economy to permit the unregulated forces of supply and demand to determine the total volume of credit and its cost. Strict adherence to the "free-market" philosophy, instead of making open-market operations more effective, represented a degree of passivity on the part of the Federal Reserve which was likely to weaken credit policy as a tool for stabilization. It was incompatible with economic developments in recent decades in which so high a proportion of total indebtedness had come to be represented by Government debt. According to the critics, there are periods when it is highly desirable in the interests of promoting economic stability and growth that the monetary authorities take an active role in influencing the course of interest rates. This may be accomplished at times through regulating the volume of bank reserves; at other times it may be necessary to operate directly in the long-term sector of the Government security market. According to its proponents, the free market promotes "market depth, breadth, and resiliency." In such a market dealers are active in buying and selling not only as brokers for institutional investors but also for their own account. In operating in the latter capacity, they rely heavily on the use of borrowed funds. To such dealers a very small change in bond prices and yields may make all the difference between a profitable and an unprofitable transaction. They may be prepared to take risks in a free market. But when it is subject to uncertainties originating from Open Market Committee intervention, dealers are reluctant to take trading positions that involve sizable amounts of borrowed funds. THE POLICY OF BILLS-ONLY If the free market is to provide depth, breadth, and resiliency, then, according to the Committee, it is desirable that open-market operations be confined to short-term securities, and there should be no intervention in the intermediate and long-term sectors. The Government securities market has "depth" when there are orders to buy and sell above and below the current market price; it has "breadth" when orders are large in volume and come from widely divergent investor groups; it has "resiliency" when there are small fluctuations in price due to speedy investor reactions to small changes in market conditions. These conditions are more nearly fulfilled in the market for Treasury bills and when dealers are assured that the Open Market Committee will limit its operations to this sector. When the Committee enters the short end of the market with a view either to increasing or decreasing bank reserves, it has relatively the smallest effect on price changes and on the asset value of investor portfolios. On the other hand, if it were to operate directly in the long-term bond market, dealers would find the risks of sharp fluctuations in bond prices much too great. Mr. Allan Sproul, President of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and Vice Chairman of the Open Market Committee, agreed with his colleagues that the Committee should avoid continuously intervening in the market to influence the structure of interest rates and thus permit the free market to govern. But he strongly opposed adoption of the "bills only" approach to open-market operations. While voting for the March 4 directive to substitute for the "maintenance of orderly conditions" the clause "correction of disorderly 28 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY situations in the market," he thought the emphasis should be on the "avoidance of disorderly situations rather than their correction after they happened." 6 * * * One of the virtues of credit control is supposed to be its ability to take prompt action to head off financial disturbances which might otherwise have harmful repercussions throughout the economy. If open-market operations in longer term Government securities can be used to this end, I would use them rather than wait until a disorderly situation or a crisis has developed, and only then depart from operations solely in Treasury bills * * *.6 Mr. Sproul contended that to confine open-market operations to the short end of the market was to place monetary management in a straitjacket; that there were circumstances when credit policy would be more effective if it operated directly in the long-term sector. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York questioned the view that it is fear of Federal Reserve intervention that produces uncertainty and therefore thin markets. * * * Clearly it is the appraisals of the outlook for interest rates and security prices by dealers and investors, much more than any fear (or hope) of intervention by the System in the market for particular securities, that determine the "depth, breadth, and resiliency" of the market at any given time. Fear of adverse trends, or uncertainty as to what the trend is likely to be, is the predominant reason for thin markets, rather than apprehensions concerning System inter-7 vention in particular sectors to limit price movements * * *. Mr. Sproul questioned the majority view that operations in very short-term securities are transmitted speedily to the longer sectors of the market through arbitrage transactions by dealers. For example, in a period of business recession when monetary authorities pursue a policy of credit ease by increasing bank reserves through purchase of Treasury bills, their yields may go down substantially, while longterm rates may not be lowered much or soon enough to stimulate business investment. If there were direct intervention in the longer sector of the market, Federal Reserve credit policy would be more effective in achieving its objective of promoting economic stability. DEBT MANAGEMENT POLICY: T H E TREASURY'S At the same time that the Federal Reserve was stressing the importance of the free market with noninterference by the System, the Treasury was even more emphatically expounding the virtues of a free market for Government securities and of a debt management policy that aimed at refunding the debt into longer maturities. It was maintained that stretching out the debt through issuance of long-term bonds was essential to curb inflationary pressures. Moreover, borrowing from nonbank investors rather than from commercial banks did not result in an increase in the money supply during a period when it was considered important to reduce spending. 8 United States Monetary Policy: Recent Thinking and Experience, cited in footnote 3; p. 225. • Ibid, p. 225. * Ibid., p. 310. 29 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY Early in April 1953, the Treasury announced the offering of $1 billion of 30-year bonds at 3% percent. Although the issue was heavily oversubscribed, these bonds quickly declined below par even before the May 1 issue date. About the same time banks increased their prime commercial loan rate from 3 percent to 3% percent. The yields on municipal, State, and corporate bonds also advanced sharply. In early May, maximum interest rates on FHA-insured and VAguaranteed mortgages were increased from 4% and 4 percent respectively, to 4K percent. The 3% percent bond issue brought forth considerable criticism in the Congress and in the editorial pages of influential financial papers and weeklies. Criticism was directed not only at the Treasury for its decision to launch its program of stretching out the debt at this time and for the excessive rate of interest fixed for the issue, but it was also directed at the Federal Reserve for continuing its policy of monetary restraint. The tight monetary policy was being overdone with the consequence that prices of seasoned Government and industrial bonds were slumping badly and interest rates were climbing rapidly along a wide front. Moreover, it had become apparent that the Treasury would have to borrow in much greater amounts because of the sizable budget deficit that was expected in the latter half of the year. Tension in the money market in May increased further when the Treasury offered 1-year 2%-percent certificates in exchange for $5 billion 1%-percent maturing certificates and for $700 million of 2-percent bonds. Greater apprehension on the part of lenders as to the future of interest rates and fear that the Federal Reserve would continue its restrictive credit policy increased investor reluctance to commit funds at existing rates. On June 1-2, the Government securities market became demoralized, as evidenced by the fact that there were practically no bids for United States Treasury securities. Only a few days earlier it had also become clear that reception of the new 2%s was disappointing. T H E MIDYEAR S H I F T IN FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY In the second week of May, the System began to take some cognizance of the growing tensions in the money market by supplying reserves to member banks through a moderate amount of open-market purchases. But the release of Federal Reserve credit in May was inadequate to meet a situation in which there were large private demands for credit, in part the result of the fear that funds would be difficult to obtain later on and would command higher interest rates, and increasing demands for funds by the Government. With the demoralization of the bond market and the tensions in the financial markets generally at the beginning of June, the Federal Reserve began to move much more vigorously to ease the financial situation. It greatly stepped up purchases of Treasury bills. Between early May and early July the System increased its holdings of United States Government securities by $1.2 billion. And even more aggressive acrossthe-board action was taken when the Federal Reserve Board announced on June 24 a reduction of reserve requirements on demand deposits from 24 to 22 percent in central Reserve city banks, from 20 to 19 percent in Reserve city banks, and from 14 to 13 percent in country banks, The release of reserves in May and June through open-market 30 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY operations was accompanied by a sharp decline in borrowings at Federal Reserve banks, so that the amount of discounting in June was down to one-third the average for the first 4 months of the year. Free reserves which were minus at least $600 million in these months became plus $364 million in June. TABLE 1 6 . — G r o s s national product seasonally adjusted at annual rates, 1953-54 [Billions of dollars} 1953 I II 1954 III IV I II III IV Gross national product 364.5 368.8 367.1 361.0 360.0 358.9 362.0 370.8 Personal consumption expenditures Durable goods Nondurable goods Ser vices 230.9 33.2 118.1 79.6 233.3 33.4 118.6 81.2 234.1 33.6 117.8 82.8 232.3 31.2 117.4 83.7 233.7 31.2 117.9 84.6 236.5 32.2 118.8 85.5 238.7 32.3 119.6 86.9 243.2 33.9 121.0 88.3 52.0 26.9 13.7 13.2 22.5 2.5 3.0 52.9 27.8 14.0 13.8 22.0 3.1 4.0 51.1 27.7 13.8 14.0 22.6 .7 1.5 45.2 27.9 13.7 14.2 21.9 -4.6 -4.3 46.6 27.8 13.7 14.1 21.4 -2.6 -2.8 47.2 28.9 14.7 14.2 20.9 -2.7 -3.2 48.8 30.2 15.8 14.4 20.7 -2.1 -2.8 52.3 31.6 17.0 14.6 19.9 .8 .2 - -2.1 -2.6 -2.0 -1.4 -1.0 -.4 -.9 .7 85.2 60.9 53.0 8.3 .4 24.3 83.8 58.9 51.3 8.0 .4 24.9 84.9 59.2 49.8 9.7 .3 25.7 80.8 54.2 46.6 8.0 .4 26.5 75.5 48.3 43.1 5.6 .4 27.3 75.5 47.3 41.9 5.8 .4 28.2 74.6 45.9 40.6 5.6 .3 28.7 Gross private domestic investment New construction Residential nonfarm Other Producers' durable equipment Change in business inventories: total Nonfarm only Net foreign investment Government purchases of goods and services _ Federal National security Other Less Government sales State and local 83.7 59.2 52.1 7.6 .5 24.4 Source: Department of Commerce. The May shift in Federal Reserve policy from credit restraint to credit ease was not due primarily, as is sometimes asserted, to the expectation by the monetary authorities that the economy was about to slip into a business recession which it was deemed desirable to counteract. The measures designed to ease credit were initially undertaken rather in response to a critical situation that had been permitted to develop in the financial markets—a situation that was frequently described at the time as reaching nearly panic proportions. As a result of the Federal Reserve moving vigorously in June to reverse the course of monetary policy, the rise of interest rates came more or less to an abrupt halt and the strained condition in the credit markets quickly eased. T H E 1953-54 BUSINESS RECESSION Apart from the question as to whether the extensive open-market purchases and the lowering of reserve requirements in June were the result of Federal Reserve prevision of a change in business conditions, there can be little doubt that these actions created a favorable financial environment for meeting the problems of economic readjustment in the period immediately ahead. For it was only a matter of weeks after the system moved aggressively to ease credit conditions that the general level of business activity began to move downward. The index of industrial production dropped from a peak of 137 in July to 123 in March 1954 and more or less remained at this level through 31 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY August. The gross national product declined from an annual rate of $368.8 billion in the second quarter of 1953 to $360 billion in the first quarter of 1954. TABLE 1 7 . — D i s p o s i t i o n of disposable personal income, 1953-54 [Seasonally adjusted quarterly totals at annual rates] [Billions of dollars] Period 1953--1st quarter 2d quarter 3d quarter 4th quarter 1954--1st quarter 2d quarter 3d quarter 4th quarter Disposable personal income 250.0 252.8 253.8 253.8 254.6 254.8 j 256.8 260.9 , Personal consumption expenditures 230,9 233.3 234.1 232.3 233.7 236.5 238. 7 243.2 Personal saving 19.0 19.6 19.7 21.6 21.0 18.3 18.0 17.7 Saving as percent of disposable personal income 7.6 7.8 7.8 8.5 8.2 7.1 7.0 6.8 Source: Department of Commerce. How much of an influence did the restrictive monetary policy and the tight money market have in bringing on the recession? There is little doubt that in the spring months builders found it more difficult to secure funds for construction, and it was also the case that the peak of housing starts was reached in April and moved downward during the remainder of the year. There was also some evidence of postponement of other capital ventures because of unfavorable credit conditions. To some extent, then, the tight money policy was an influence contributing to a slackening in economic activity but its effect in no way compares with the impact of two other factors that were of major importance in the business recession. The first, and initial factor, was business inventory adjustments, and the second was the cutback in defense contracts. Businessmen were adding to their inventories at an annual rate of $3.1 billion in the second quarter of 1953, and at the very moderate rate of $®.7 billion in the third quarter; by the fourth quarter of the year they were reducing their inventories at a rate of $4.6 billion. National security expenditures, which were at an annual rate of $53 billion in the second quarter—the peak of such expenditures since the beginning of the Korean war—dropped to $49.8 billion in the fourth quarter and moved downward throughout 1954 to a rate of $40.6 billion in the last quarter of the year. The tight money policy can hardly be said to have contributed to the reduction either of investment in inventories or of defense expenditures. The liquidation of inventories occurred because production and sales had fallen out of balance, especially in the consumer durable goods sector, and because of curtailment of the defense program. 32 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY TABLE 1 8 . — I n s t a l l m e n t credit, 1953-54 [Millions of dollars] End of month Total outstanding Automobile paper 1 Other consumer goods paper 1 Repair and moderniza-a tion loans 7,899 8,093 8,397 8,693 8,996 9,241 9,514 9,677 9,772 9,875 9,898 9,835 9,650 9,497 9,403 9,416 9,459 9,604 9,722 9,769 9,781 9,768 9,720 9,809 6,145 6,070 6,100 6,124 6,200 6,287 6,337 6,369 6,379 6,422 6,485 6,779 6,622 6,490 6,331 6,296 6,256 6,261 6,234 6,214 6,218 6,280 6,377 6,751 1.380 1.381 1,392 1,412 1,441 1,472 1,500 1,524 1,557 1,585 1.609 1.610 1.595 1,581 1,571 1,575 1,594 1.596 1,604 1.615 1,622 1,628 1,626 19,586 19,720 20,150 20,551 21,016 21,467 21,887 22,146 22,317 22,503 22,654 23,005 22,638 22,365 22,160 22,207 22,268 22,501 22,658 22,740 22,803 22,881 22,983 23,568 1953—January February.. March April May June July August September. October.. _ November. December. 1954—January... February— March April May June July August September, October... November. December. 1.616 Personal loans 4,162 4,176 4,261 4,322 7,629 7,565 7,371 7,402 7,466 7,588 7,618 8,238 7,688 7,283 7,152 7,402 7.633 7,699 7.634 7,587 7,676 7,834 8,000 8,724 i Represents all consumer installment credit extended for the purpose of purchasing automobiles and other consumer goods, whether held by retail outlets or financial institutions. Includes credit on purchases by individuals of automobiles or other consumer goods that may be used in part for business. 3 Represents repair and modernization loans held by financial institutions; holdings of retail outlets are included in other consumer goods paper. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. From the second to the fourth quarter of 1953, consumer expenditures for durable goods declined by $2.2 billion and for nondurables $1.2 billion, while expenditures for services rose by $2.5 billion. During the same period, personal saving as a percent of disposable TABLE 19.—Member bank reserves and related items, 1953-54 [Averages of daily figures, millions of dollars] Period 1953—January... February., March April May June July August September. October-.. November. December. 1954—January. __ FebruaryMarch April May. June July August September. October... November. December. Federal reserve credit Gold stock 23.101 22,797 22,606 22,562 22, 557 22, 514 22,366 22,226 22,176 22.102 22,057 22,028 22,015 21,957 21,963 21,966 21,971 21,927 21,926 21,871 21,809 21,787 21,724 21,711 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Currency in circulation 29,920 29,718 29,752 29,782 29,870 30,012 30,165 30,167 30,328 30,366 30,555 30,968 30,282 29,903 29,800 29,755 29,773 29,856 29,968 29,896 29,991 30,078 30,287 30,749 Total 20,958 20,520 20,416 20,007 19,897 20,287 19,653 19,526 19,552 19,536 19,718 19,920 20,179 19,557 19,573 19,392 19,533 19,670 19,164 18,478 18,403 18,893 19,207 19,279 Required reserves 20,251 19,882 19,828 19.472 19,306 19,499 18,882 18,834 18,784 19,034 19,227 19,243 18,925 18,881 18.627 18,817 18,813 18,329 17,638 17.628 18,173 18,393 18,576 33 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY income rose from 7.8 to 8.5 percent. In the first quarter of 1954 consumer expenditures for commodities continued at the reduced level of the previous quarter, while national security expenditures dropped by more than $3 billion. By March 1954 the index of industrial production declined 10 percent from its July 1953 peak and nearly 6 percent of the civilian labor force was unemployed in March as compared with 3 percent a year earlier. Despite these and other deflationary pressures which have been known to exert a cumulative downward push on the economy, the gross national product reached its low in the second quarter, advanced moderately in the third, and rose sharply in the last quarter of the year. TABLE 2 0 . — M e m b e r bank excess reserves, borrowings, and free reserves, 1953-54 [Averages of daily figures, millions of dollars] Period 1953—January February March. April May June July August September October... November December 1954—January February March April May June July August September October November December Excess reserves — 707 638 588 535 591 787 784 643 718 752 684 693 936 632 692 765 716 858 836 839 775 720 814 704 Borrowings at Federal Reserve banks 1,347 1,310 1,202 1,166 944 423 418 650 468 363 487 441 100 293 189 139 155 146 66 115 67 82 164 246 Free reserves -640 -672 -614 -631 -353 364 366 -7 250 389 197 252 836 339 503 626 561 712 770 724 708 638 650 458 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. There were various influences originating in the private and the governmental sectors of the economy that contributed to the relative mildness of the 1953-54 business recession. In the private sector there were such favorable factors as the maintenance of consumer spending at a high level. After dropping at the annual rate of nearly $2 billion in the fourth quarter of 1953, personal consumption expenditures rose at an annual rate of $1.4 billion in the first quarter of 1954, $3 billion in each of the next 2 quarters, and $4.5 billion in the last quarter. Personal saving, which was at its highest in the last 3 months of 1953 and in the first 3 months of 1954, dropped substantially during the remainder of the year with a fourth-quarter level that was $4 billion less than the peak reached a year earlier. Another factor in the private economy that exerted a stabilizing influence and hastened business recovery was the pace of residential construction which stepped up with each succeeding quarter of 1954. Both the reduction of the personal income tax that became effective in January 1954 and the decision of consumers to maintain a lower rate of saving contributed to the rise in consumer expenditures. Apart from the offsetting effect of the "automatic stabilizers," such as unemployment insurance 34 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY and the decline in taxpayments, there was also the favorable influence of the rise in State and local government expenditures all through the period of contraction. In addition to these and other factors of a contracyclical nature that might have been listed, there was the significant contribution of the monetary factor. Let us now turn to the role which credit policy played during this period. TABLE 2 1 . — D e p o s i t s and currency, 1958-54 [Billions of dollars] Deposits and currency Demand deposits and currency End of period Total i 1953—January February March April May June July August September October November December 1954—January February March. April May June. ___ July August September. October November December _ 193.3 191.6 191.0 192.2 192.1 192.6 193.0 193.4 194.3 197.3 197.4 200.9 199.8 197.4 195.2 197.3 198.0 198.5 200.4 200.3 202.5 204.7 205.8 209.7 Total Demand deposits adjusted 2 Currency outside banks 100.5 98.3 97.4 98.0 97.5 96.9 97.4 97.5 97.7 100.3 100.2 102.5 102.3 99.6 96.7 98.6 98.7 98.1 100.0 99.4 101.2 103.1 104.0 106.6 26.8 26.9 26.9 27.0 27.0 27.4 27.2 27.3 27.5 27.4 27.9 28.1 26.9 26.9 26.9 26.7 26.8 27.1 26.8 26.9 26.9 26.9 27.5 27.9 127.3 125. 2 124.3 125.0 124.5 124.3 124.6 124.8 125. 2 127.7 128.1 130. 5 129.2 126. 5 123.6 125. 3 125. 5 125.2 126. 8 126.3 128.1 130.0 131.5 134.4 Time deposits3 66.1 66.4 66.8 67.2 67.6 68.3 68.4 68.7 69.1 69.6 69.3 70.4 70.6 71.0 71.7 72.0 72.5 73.3 73.7 74.0 74.4 74.8 74.3 75.3 1 Includes holdings of State and local governments, but excludes U. S. Government deposits. 2 Includes demand deposits, other than interbank and U. S. Government, less cash items in process of collection. 3 Includes deposits in commercial banks, mutual savings banks, and Postal Savings System, but excludes interbank deposits. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. T H E P O L I C Y OF C R E D I T EASE We have seen that the Federal Reserve authorities shifted from a policy of restraint to credit ease shortly before the general business contraction had begun and that this change was not initiated as an antirecession move.8 Nevertheless, in increasing their holdings of Government securities by $1 billion between May and July and then lowering reserve requirements in July, commercial banks entered the recession without the fears of uncertainty about Federal Reserve policy that seemed to be created by official pronouncements of a noninterventionist philosophy of the free market. The actions taken by the Federal Reserve also had the immediate tangible effect of greatly reducing member bank borrowing so that by January 1954 all mem8 The 1953 Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System records only 2 meetings of the Open Market Committee during the first half of the year, March 4-5 and June 11. It was at the June meeting that the credit policy directive was changed from "exercising restraint upon inflationary developments" to "avoiding deflationary tendencies without encouraging a renewal of inflationary developments." 35 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY ber bank indebtedness at the Reserve banks was virtually eliminated— a condition that continued during most of the year. This was accompanied by a sharp decline in interest rates until at least mid-1954. TABLE 2 2 . — L o a n s and investments of all commercial banks, 1953-54 [Billions of dollars] End of period * Total loans and investments 1953—January February March April.. May June,. July August September.. October November--December 1954—January February March April May June July August September October November December 140.8 140.1 140.0 138.5 138.1 138.0 143.2 143.1 143.0 144.0 145.5 145.7 145.3 144.9 142.8 144.1 145.7 146.4 147.3 149.5 150.6 154.0 155.7 155.9 Investments Loans Total 2 63.9 64.1 65.2 65.3 65.4 65.0 65.6 66.0 66.3 67.1 67.3 67.6 66.5 66.9 67.1 66.8 67.1 67.3 67.3 66.5 67.3 67.7 69.5 70.6 Business loans 3 27.5 27.4 27.9 27.8 27.6 27.4 27.5 27.7 27.9 27.9 27.8 27.2 26.6 26.4 26.7 26 2 26.0 26.1 25.8 25.8 26.1 26.2 26.6 26.9 Total 77.0 76.0 74.8 73.3 72.7 72.9 77.5 77.1 76.7 76.8 78.3 78.1 78.9 78.0 75.8 77.3 78.6 79.0 80.0 83.0 83.3 86.3 86.3 85.3 U. S. Government obligations4 62.8 61.9 60.5 58.9 58.3 58.6 63.2 62.6 62.2 62.3 63.7 63.4 64.2 63.0 60.7 62.1 63.3 63.5 64.3 67.3 67.3 70.2 70.1 69.0 Other securities 14.2 14.1 14.3 14.4 14.4 14.3 14.3 14.5 14.5 14.5 14.6 14.7 14.7 15.0 15.1 15.2 15.3 15.5 15.7 15.7 16.0 16.1 16.2 16.3 1 June and December figures are for call dates. Other data are for the last Wednesday of the month. 2 Data are shown net, i. e., after deduction of valuation reserves. Includes commercial and industrial, agricultural, security, real estate, bank, consumer, and other loans. 3 Data are shown gross of valuation reserves. For months other than June and December data are estimated on the basis of reported data for all insured commercial banks and for weekly reporting member banks. 4 Figures are based on book values and relate only to banks within the continental United States. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. In pursuing a policy of active ease after mid-1953, all three major instrumentalities of Federal Reserve credit policy were employed to facilitate economic recovery—open-market operations, the discount rate and reserve requirements. Between July and December 1953, there was an additional increase of nearly $700 million in Federal Reserve holdings of Government securities. At the beginning of February 1954 the discount rate was lowered from 2 percent to 1% percent and in April-May the rate was lowered to 1% percent. In June-July, reserve requirements against demand deposits were reduced 2 percentage points at central Reserve cities; in July, 1 percentage point at Reserve city "banks and a similar reduction in August at country banks; there was also a reduction in June of 1 percentage point on time deposits at member banks. These reductions released approximately $1.6 billion of reserves. Since member banks were supplied with more reserves than were needed at the time, the freed reserves were offset in part by a reduction in Federal Reserve holdings of Government securities of about $1 billion during the next 2 months. However, for the remainder of the year, open-market purchases of nearly $1 billion provided the banks with additional reserves for credit and monetary expansion. The progressive easing of the reserve position of member H. Kept. 2i500, 85-2 4 36 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY banks is evidenced by the fact that their free reserves averaged $279 million in the fourth quarter of 1953, $559 million in the first quarter of 1954, $633 million in the second and $734 million in the third quarter. The policy of active ease resulted in a marked decline in interest rates. The average rate on Treasury bills dropped from a peak of 2.23 percent in June 1953 to a low of 0.65 percent in June 1954. The rate on prime commercial paper fell from its peak of 2.75 percent in 1953 to 1.33 percent in August 1954 and remained at this level for the rest of the year. In contrast to these sharp declines was the sluggish movement of the average rate on short-term bank loans to business firms. Customer loan rates moved fiom a peak of 3.76 percent in December 1953 to 3.60 percent in June 1954 and to 3.55 percent at the end of the year. TABLE 2 3 . — L o a n s and investments of all commercial banks, 1950-57 [Millions of dollars] Call date Total loans and investments (excluding interbank) Dec. 30, 1949. June 30, 1950. Dee. 31,1950. June 30, 1951. Dec. 31,1951. June 30, 1952. Dec. 31, 1952. June 30,1953. Dec. 31, 1953. June 30, 1954. Dec. 31,1954. June 30,1955. Dec. 31, 1955. June 30, 1956. Dec. 31, 1956. June 6, 1957.. Dec. 31, 1957. 120,099 121,665 126,585 125,890 132,461 134,284 141,467 137,802 145, 525 146,208 155,676 154,846 160,307 159,344 164,471 163, 514 169,346 Total loans (excluding interbank) 42,867 44, 694 52,159 54,666 57,597 59,080 64,006 64,870 67,431 67,162 70,379 74,765 82,027 86,223 89,650 90,027 93,177 Business 17,060 16,947 21,927 23,651 25,879 25,312 27,870 27,418 27,204 26,120 26,867 28,872 33,245 36, 111 38,720 39,020 40,526 Agriculture 3,051 2,896 2,905 3,122 3,408 3, 651 3,919 3, 675 4,965 5,143 5,200 4,391 4,475 4,254 4,161 4,077 4,066 Loans 1 Investments Securities U. S. Government securities 2,637 2,804 2,859 2,644 2,561 3,078 3,163 2,793 3,563 3,718 4,454 4,471 5,037 4,433 4,281 3,908 4,221 1 Figures for various loan items are shown gross (i. e., before deduction of valuation reserves); they do not add to the total. Total loans are shown net. Real estate 11,542 12,412 13, 541 14,144 14,580 15,019 15, 713 16,231 16,694 17,227 18,418 19,779 20,809 21,787 22,509 22,530 23,110 Consumer 5,777 6,613 7,374 7,425 7,455 8,256 9,368 10, 597 10,897 10,760 10,892 12,129 13,236 14,168 14, 550 15,100 15,809 All other 3,357 3,613 4,228 4,395 4,528 4,616 4,877 5,096 5,068 5,185 5,619 6,247 6,492 6,819 6,990 6,630 7,219 Total 77,232 76,972 74,426 71,224 74,863 75,204 77,461 72,932 78,094 79,046 85,297 80,081 78,280 73,122 74,821 73,487 76,169 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 67,005 65,751 62,027 58, 521 61,524 61,178 63,318 58,644 63,426 63,508 68,981 63,271 61,592 56,620 58,552 56,642 58,239 Other securities H © H S3 > t* 10,227 11,221 12,399 12,703 13,339 14,026 14,143 14,287 14,668 15,538 16,316 16,809 16,688 16,502 16,629 16,845 17,930 W H W H W <J O E o £ O W o § c 1 0 i—i § Kj 00 38 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY In the long-term sector of the market, the yield on the 3^-percent Treasury bond issued May 1, 1953, dropped to 2.6 percent in August 1954. High-grade municipal bonds moved downward from 2.99 percent in June 1953 to a low of 2.23 percent in August 1954, and Moody's Aaa corporate bonds declined from 3.40 percent in June 1953 to a low of 2.85 percent in May 1954. Apparently, in this period at least, proponents of the view that Federal Reserve credit policy should concentrate on the short-term sector of the market and that its influence would soon be felt in the long-term sector can point to the decline of yields on long-term securities in the 1953-54 period as supporting their position. It should be noted, however, that from high to low, the percentage decline of yields in the long-term sector was generally less than half the decline in the short-term sector. Relatively smaller fluctuations of yields in long-term as compared to short-term markets has characterized other periods when interest rates moved downward during business contractions. BANK LOANS AND INVESTMENTS Both the decline in business activity and the more ample bank reserves resulting from the easier Federal Reserve credit policy caused commercial banks to turn to the purchase of Government securities. In the last 6 months of 1953 they acquired $4.8 billion, in contrast to the sale of $4.7 billion in the first half of the year when they were under pressure to meet credit demands. Their holdings of Government securities changed little in the first half of 1954 but during the last half increased by $5.5 billion. The United States Government obligations of over $10 billion acquired since mid-1953 were partly from purchases of new Treasury securities and partly from nonbank holders. Thus, these acquisitions by the commercial banks provided funds to other financial institutions facilitating their expansion of loans for investment activity. This was especially the case with mortgage credit for housing, an area that contributed substantially to the mildness of the 1953-54 recession. Moreover, the absorption by commercial banks of Federal securities, especially during the second half of 1954, resulted in a sharp rise in demand deposits. Another category of commercial bank investment which was a stimulus to recovery was the $2 billion increase in the holdings of "other securities/' mainly State and local, between mid-1953 and the end of 1954. The long-term borrowing by State and local governments was largely for construction of highways, schools, and other community facilities. Total commercial bank loans in the second half of 1953 increased less than in any corresponding 6-month period since 1950. During the next 9 months they remained lower than at the end of 1953, but in the last quarter of 1954 they expanded by over $3 billion. Two categories of loans showed a marked rise in 1954 and played a significant role in investment activity; namely, loans on real estate and for purchasing and carrying securities to brokers and dealers and to others. FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND TABLE 24.—Mortgage debt outstanding, ECONOMIC STABILITY by type of property and of financing, 39 1950-57 [Billions of dollars] Nonfarm properties Period All properties 1- to 4-family houses Government underwritten Total Total 1950—March June September December. _ 1951—March June September _ . December. _ 1952—March June SeptemberDecember. _ 1953—March June September. _ December - _ 1954—March June.. September.. December. _ 1955—March June September. _ December-. 1956—March June September. _ December. _ 1957—March i June 1 September 1 December - 72.8 75.0 77.8 79.9 82.3 84.1 86.4 88.9 91.1 93.4 96.1 98.7 101.3 103.1 106.2 109.7 113.8 117.2 121.8 126.1 130.0 133.6 137.6 141.4 144.8 147.2 150.2 153.4 156.3 66.7 69.1 71.6 73.6 75.6 77.4 79.5 81.8 84.0 86.0 88.6 91.1 93.6 95.3 98.2 101.6 105.5 108.8 113.2 117.2 120.9 124.2 128.0 131.6 134.9 137.1 129.9 143.0 145.8 39.0 41.0 43.3 45.2 46.9 48.7 50.4 51.9 53.3 55.1 57.0 58 7 60.3 62.4 64.3 66.1 67.6 69.9 72.6 75.7 78.5 82.2 85.5 88.2 90.8 93.7 96.6 99.1 101.1 103.3 105.6 107.6 Total 15.6 16.5 17.6 18.9 20.0 21.0 22.0 22.9 23.5 24.0 24.7 25.4 26.1 26.7 27. 5 28.1 28.8 29.7 30.7 32.1 33.5 35.3 37.0 38.9 40.2 41.3 42.4 43.9 45.1 45.9 46.5 47.2 FHA insured VA guaranteed 7.3 7.6 8.2 8.6 8.9 9.2 9.5 9.7 9.9 10.1 10.4 10.8 11.1 11.4 11.7 12.0 12.2 12.4 12.6 12.8 13.2 13.5 13.9 14.3 14.7 15.0 15.2 15.5 15.7 15.9 16.1 16.5 8.3 8.9 9.4 10.3 11.1 11.8 12.5 13.2 13.6 13.9 14.3 14.6 15.0 15.3 15.8 16.1 16.6 17.3 18.1 19.3 20.3 21.8 23.1 24.6 25.5 26.3 27.3 28.4 29.4 30.0 30.4 30.7 Multifamily and commerConvencial proptional erties 23.4 24.5 25.7 26.3 26.9 27.7 28.4 29.0 29.7 30.8 31.7 33.1 34.2 35.7 36.8 38.0 38.8 40.2 41.9 43.6 45.0 46.9 48.5 49.3 50.6 52.4 54.1 55.1 55.9 57.4 59.1 60.4 21.6 22.2 23.0 23.3 23.9 24.1 24.4 24.9 25.3 25.7 26.2 26.7 27.5 27.7 28.4 29.0 29.8 30.3 31.0 31.8 32.7 33.4 34.3 35.1 35.8 36.1 36.6 37.4 38.2 Farm properties 6.1 6.0 6.2 6.3 6.7 6.7 7.0 7.1 7.1 7.3 7.5 7.6 7.8 7.8 8.0 8.1 8.3 8.4 8.7 8.8 9.1 9.4 9.6 9.8 9.9 10.1 10.3 10.4 10.5 1 Preliminary. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Heal estate loans rose by $1.7 billion, more than one-half the rise of total bank loans in 1954. This was in response to the expansion in housing construction which started its upward climb in the fall of 1953 and accelerated its pace during the following year. There is little doubt that the easy money policy was a major factor in the 1954 housing boom. Both the greater availability of credit and the more liberal financing terms on FHA and VA mortgages spurred builders to increase the volume of home building. From September 1953 to December 1954 the total mortgage debt outstanding on nonfarm 1- to 4-family houses increased by $11.4 billion—a rise that was made possible by the adequacy of funds for mortgage investment by insurance companies, mutual savings banks, savings and loan associations, as well as by commercial banks. The second largest 1954 increase in bank loans—nearly $1 billion— was for the purchase and carrying of securities. The expansion in the volume of stock market credit accompanied as well as stimulated increased stock market activity. Common stock prices began to rise in September 1953 and continued their uninterrupted upward course until January 1955—an increase of 50 percent with the most rapid 40 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY rise in the later months of 1954. The ample supply of bank credit spilled over into the stock market so that credit for trading showed the greatest increase during any of the postwar years. The buoyancy of the stock market, even while business activity was moving downward, was regarded by the investing public as indicating that the business recession would be mild ana of short duration. TABLE 2 5 . — A n n u a l rate of turnover of demand its,1 1953-54 [Ratio of debits to deposits] Period 1953—January February March April May June July... August September. __ October November. . . December-.. New York City 34.3 35.1 37.1 35.4 35.6 38.9 36.0 32.2 40.2 35.8 38.4 43.1 6 other 338 other centers3 reporting centers 23.9 24.4 28.7 26.7 26.2 26.5 25.7 23.6 25.9 23.9 26.4 26.8 18.4 18.9 19.4 18.4 18.8 19.2 19.2 17.8 19.3 18.4 20.2 19.7 Period 1954—January... February.. March April May June JulyAugust September. October November. December _ New York City 42.7 42.7 44.6 41.3 41.9 44.2 41.6 40.0 40.4 39.3 42.2 48.1 6 other 338 other centers* reporting centers 24.1 25.5 29.2 27.6 25.5 26.8 24.9 24.8 25.3 23.6 26.3 28.1 18.6 19.2 19.7 18.8 18.8 19.7 18.8 18.5 19.4 18.6 20.7 21.0 1 2 Does not include interbank and U. S. Government deposits and is given without seasonal adjustment. Boston, Philadelphia, Chicago, Detroit, San Francisco, Los Angeles. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Our review of economic and financial developments since mid-1953 indicates that Federal Reserve credit policy contributed substantially to moderating the recession and supporting economic recovery. The shift to a policy of active ease played an important part in making credit more available and in lowering its cost. With more ample reserves and greater liquidity banks sought out new business more aggressively and greatly expanded their investment portfolios. The chief beneficiary was the construction industry—especially housing, commercial and public works construction. Toward the end of 1954 even credit for the consumer durable goods industry, which had declined during the first half of 1954, began to move up sharply. Monetary policy would not have been so powerful an influence in recovery if the level of consumer spending had not remained so high and if other antirecession measures had not been undertaken promptly by the Federal Government. It has been said that monetary policy was too liberal in this period and created difficult problems after the business upswing in the fall of 1954 gathered much greater momentum in the following year. This and related questions concerning the role of monetary policy in economic stabilization are discussed in the next chapter. CHAPTER THE III. KEY IMPORTANCE FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY, 1955-57 O F 1955 I N R E C E N T E C O N O M I C A N D DEVELOPMENTS FINANCIAL For understanding the character of the business expansion from the fall of 1954 to the summer of 1957 and of the role of monetary policy in these developments, no single year is so illuminating as 1955. It was in this year that the expansion assumed its most rapid rate of increase and the amount of private indebtedness rose at a record rate. The acceleration in the pace of production and in the volume of credit posed a series of problems for the monetary authorities that are central in any consideration of the role of monetary policy in economic stabilization. The rapidity of the expansion in economic activity in 1955 is indicated by the index of industrial production which moved from a low of 123 in August 1954, to 130 in December and advanced to 144 by December 1955. Only during 1 month of 1956 and 1 month of 1957 did the index generally exceed the December 1955 level by 2 points. The gross national product increased by nearly $35 billion in 1955, $22 billion in 1956, and $15 billion in the first 9 months of 1957. TABLE 2 6 . — I n d e x e s of industrial production, wholesale and consumer prices, 1955-57 Industrial production 1 Wholesale prices Consumer prices 136 143 144 146 146 147 146 146 145 143 143 144 144 145 144 141 139 135 114.0 114.7 115.5 115.6 115.9 116.3 116.9 117.0 116.9 117.2 117.1 117.4 118.2 118.4 118.0 117.8 118.1 118.5 [1947-49=100] Month 1955—Januar y February March April. May June July August September... October November. December... 1956—Januar y February March April.-. May June Industrial production! Wholesale prices 132 133 135 136 138 139 139 140 142 143 143 144 143 143 141 143 141 141 110.1 110.4 110.0 110.5 109.9 110.3 110.5 110.9 111.7 111.6 111.2 111.3 111.9 112.4 112.8 113.6 114.4 114.2 Consumer prices 114.3 114.3 114.3 114.2 114.2 114.4 114.7 114.5 114.9 114.9 115.0 114.7 114.6 114.6 114.7 114.9 115.4 116.2 Month 1956—July August September. October November. December. 1957—Januar y February. _ March April May June July August September. October NovemberDecember. 117.0 116.8 117.1 117.7 117.8 118.0 118.2 118.7 118.9 119.3 119.6 120.2 120.8 121.0 121.1 121.1 121.6 121.6 1 Seasonally adjusted. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and U. S. Department of Labor. The main impetus to the speedy pace of the economic recovery after the summer of 1954 came from residential construction and automobile production. Between the third quarter of 1954 and the first quarter of 1955 disposable personal income rose at an annual rate of $7 billion, while consumption expenditures increased at the rate of $10.7 billion. Personal saving as a percent of disposable income fell 41 42 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY from 7.0 to 5.5 percent. During this 6-month period consumer expenditures for durable goods rose by $5.9 billion. Expenditures on nonfarm residential construction, which began to rise in the second quarter of 1954, advanced to a level that was $4.2 billion higher by the second quarter of 1955. Thus, the consumer played a powerful role in the speed of business recovery. The liberality of credit terms and the rise in the volume of credit for the purchase of homes and automobiles were also powerful influences in the economic expansion. The mortgage debt on 1- to 4-family houses, which had risen by $9.6 billion in 1954, increased by $12.5 billion in 1955. Consumer installment credit rose by about $5.5 billion during 1955. TABLE 2 7 . — G r o s s national product, seasonally adjusted at annual rates, 1955-57 [Billions of dollars] 1955 I II 1956 III IV I II III 1957 IV I II III IV Gross national product 384.3 393.0 403.4 408.9 410.8 414. 9 420.5 430. 5 436.3 441.2 445.6 438.9 Personal consumption expenditures 249.4 254.3 260.9 263.3 265.2 267.2 269.7 275.4 279.8 282.5 288.3 Durable goods 38.2 39.1 41.4 39.8 38.7 37.8 37.5 39.5 40.2 39.5 40.4 Nondurable goods 121.2 123.7 126.1 128.1 129.6 130.9 131.6 133.4 135.5 137.1 140.5 Services 90.0 91.6 93.4 95.3 96.9 98.6 100.6 102.5 104.1 105.9 107.4 287.2 39.6 138.8 108.7 Gross private domestic investment 58.8 New construction 33.9 Residential nonfarm 18.5 Other 15.4 Producers' durable equipment 20.5 Change in business inventories: total 4.4 Nonfarm only 3.8 63.1 34.9 65.4 35.4 67.6 35.4 68.0 35.2 67.7 35.8 68.1 35.8 68.8 36.2 65.9 36.1 67.0 36.1 66.7 36.6 61.5 37.1 18.9 16.0 18.9 16.5 18.4 17.0 17.8 17.4 17.7 18.1 17.6 18.3 17.7 18.4 17.2 18.9 16.5 19.6 16.9 19.7 17.6 19.6 22.1 24.4 25.4 25.9 26.6 27.3 28.2 28.7 28.1 28.0 26.7 6.1 5.7 5.7 5.5 6.7 6.7 6.9 7.4 5.4 6.2 4.9 5.3 4.4 4.6 1.1 .6 2.9 2.0 2.2 1.3 -2.3 -3.1 -.8 .1 -.5 -.5 1.3 2.0 2.8 4.2 4.2 3.6 1.9 76.5 47.0 41.9 5.5 76.4 46.2 41.1 5.6 77.0 46.5 41.0 5.8 78.5 47.5 41.2 6.8 78.1 46.1 41.2 5.4 78.7 46.0 41.4 5.0 80.8 47.4 43.0 4.7 83.4 49.1 44.5 5.0 86.4 50.5 45.8 5.1 87.5 51.5 47.4 4.5 87.0 50.9 46.9 4.5 88.3 50.5 46.0 5.0 .4 29.5 .4 30.2 .4 30.5 .4 31.0 .4 32.0 .4 32.7 .4 33.4 .4 34.4 .4 35.9 .4 36.0 .5 36.1 5 37.8 Net foreign investment. _. - . 5 Government purchases of goods and services Federal National security. Other Less Government sales State and local Source: Department of Commerce. The continuous business upswing in 1955 was associated with an increasing accumulation of inventories, from an annual rate of less than $1 billion in the last 3 months of 1954 to $6.7 billion in the last 3 months of 1955. Another major stimulus to the 1955 expansion was the rise of business investment in plant and equipment, beginning in the second quarter and accelerating in the latter half of the year. To a considerable extent the sharp rise in business investment was induced by the upsurge in consumer demand for durable goods and housing. The marked expansion of business activity in 1955 was accompanied by very little rise either in the index of wholesale prices or the index of consumer prices. While industrial prices in wholesale markets rose 3K percent in the second half of 1955, this rise was largely offset by the decline in farm prices. If the increasing exuberance of the 43 F E D E R A L RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY economy since the fall of 1954 was not reflected in the general level of commodity prices at wholesale or retail during 1955, it was registered in the acceleration in the rise of common stock prices in the last 3 months of 1954—a rise that had been continuing for a year. Stock prices climbed upward with a few interruptions all through 1955, although at a slower pace than in the preceding year. TABLE 2 8 . — D i s p o s i t i o n of disposable personal income, 1955-57 [Seasonally adjusted quarterly totals at annual rates] [Billions of dollars] Disposable personal income Period 1955—1st quarter 2d quarter 3d quarter 4th quarter 1958—1st quarter 2d quarter 3d quarter 4th quarter 1957—1st quarter. 2d quarter 3d quarter 4th quarter __ __ _ __ _ ___ Personal consumption expenditures 263.8 272.0 277.7 283.0 283.1 288.8 292.1 297.2 300.0 305.7 308.7 306.8 249.4 254.3 260.9 263.3 265.2 267.2 269.7 275.4 279.8 282.5 288.3 287.2 Personal saving 14.4 17.8 16.8 19.8 17.9 21.6 22.4 21.7 20.3 23.2 20.4 19.6 Saving as percent of disposable personal income 5.4 6.6 6.0 7.0 6.3 7.4 7.7 7.3 6.8 7.6 6.6 6.4 Source: Department of Commerce. T H E STOCK M A R K E T AND MARGIN REQUIREMENTS We have seen in the previous chapter that the monetary authorities pursued a liberal credit policy which encouraged banks to lend more freely. One sector that took advantage of the increasing credit opportunities was the stock market. During 1954 bank credit extended to brokers and dealers increased by nearly $1 billion. Loans on margin accounts by brokers and dealers to their customers increased by about the same amount, with the greatest rise taking place in the second half of the year. The first restrictive credit move by the Federal Reserve Board was the raising of margin requirements from 50 to 60 percent at the beginning of January 1955. As measured by Standard & Poor's index of 500 stocks, their average price rose by more than 50 percent between September 1953 and January 1955. In addition to about a 50-percent rise in stock-market credit, there was increasing evidence of speculative activity in the market during the latter half of 1954. It was these developments which led the Federal Reserve Board to act on January 4, as well as the Senate Banking and Currency Committee to decide on January 14 upon a study of the stock market. Past experience has shown that continuously rising stock prices generate an optimistic psychology that is transmitted to other areas than the stock market, resulting in widespread overconfidence and to excesses that can jeopardize economic stability. The Banking Committee's public hearings were held during the first 3 weeks in March and were widely reported in the daily press. Practically every one of the 21 prominent witnesses who testified expressed some concern about 1 or more of the speculative tendencies that had appeared in the stock 44 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY market. On the basis of its hearings, the Committee "was of the view that conditions in January warranted more vigorous action to curb stock-market credit by the Federal Reserve Board" than the 10-point rise in margin requirements.1 It is also significant to note that the Committee pointed out that the liberality of credit in other areas than the stock market might be a potential threat to economic stability: 2 * * * A number of witnesses stressed the dangers in overextension of credit in the mortgage market and the possibility that the recent rate of housing construction may not be sustainable for very long. Likewise, concern was expressed about the high level of consumer credit and the ability of the automobile industry to maintain current levels of production during the second half of the year * * * On April 23, 1 month after the close of the Senate Banking Committee's hearings, the Federal Reserve Board raised margin requirements from 60 to 70 percent.3 After the second action was taken, the rate of increase in stock-market credit declined substantially. CREDIT EXPANSION IN 1955 Between the third quarter of 1954 and the first quarter of 1955 the gross national product advanced at an annual rate of $22.3 billion; about two-thirds of the increase was due to the sharp expansion in outlays for consumer durable goods, continued advances in purchase of new homes, and a shift from liquidation to accumulation in business inventories. The speedy economic recovery which received its major impetus from these sectors was accompanied by a substantial rise in credit and by a considerable easing in financial terms, especially longer maturities and lower downpayments on installment and mortgage credit. Business loans of commercial banks which usually decline in the first half of the year increased by $2 billion in the first 6 months of 1955. In the second quarter of the year, installment credit outstanding expanded by nearly $2 billion, a record increase in so short a period. The mortgage debt outstanding on 1- to 4-family homes increased by $6.5 billion during the first 6 months of 1955 as compared to $3.8 billion in the corresponding period of 1954. 1 Stock Market Study: Report together with the individual views and minority views of the Committee on Banking and Currency, Senate, 84th Cong.. 1st .sess., May 26, 1955, p. 7. 2 Ibid., p. 13. » It is of interest to note that when Mr. Martin, Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, testified on March 14,1955, at the hearings on the stock-market study he was questioned at considerable length about the adequacy of the January change in margin requirements by Mr. Fulbright, chairman of the Senate Banking and Currency Committee. ML>EFTAL R E S E R V E POLICY A N D TABLE 29.—Loans and investments ECONOMIC STABILITY of all commercial banks, 45 1955-57 [Billions of dollars] Total loans and investments End of period 1 1955—January February March April May June July August. September October 8 November December 1956—January February March April May June July August September October November December 1957—January February March April May June. July___ August September. October. November December - 156.3 154.8 153.5 155.5 155.6 155.3 157.0 156.7 157.3 158.9 159.4 160.9 159.4 158.4 159.9 160.1 159.7 160.0 159.6 161.0 162.0 162.5 164.0 165.1 162.8 162.5 162.9 165.1 165.1 165.6 165.4 165.9 166.3 167.9 167.3 > 170.1 Loans Total 2 70.6 71.2 72.3 72.9 73.9 75.2 76.6 77.3 78.4 79.2 81.4 82.6 82.0 82.5 84.7 85.3 86.0 86.9 87.1 87.5 88.5 88.8 89.5 90.3 88.9 89.3 90.6 91.0 91.2 93.3 92.3 92.8 93.4 93.0 92.9 93.9 Investments Business 3 26.6 26.8 27.4 27.6 28.0 28.9 29.1 29.9 30.5 31.1 32.3 33.2 32.7 32.9 34.5 34.8 34.8 36.1 35.8 36.4 37.0 37.2 37.8 38.7 37.6 37.8 39.0 39.0 38.9 40.5 39.6 39.9 40.3 39.7 39.6 40.5 Total 85.7 83.6 81.2 82.6 81.7 80.1 80.4 79.4 78.9 79.7 78.0 78.3 77.4 75.8 75.2 74.8 73.7 73.1 72.5 73.6 73.6 73.8 74.5 74.8 73.9 73.1 72.2 74.2 73.9 72.3 73.1 73.1 73.0 74.9 74.3 76.2 U. S. Government obligations4 69.0 66.8 64.2 65.6 65.0 63.3 63.7 62.5 62.0 62.9 61.4 61.6 60.9 59.2 58.6 58.2 57.3 56.6 56.2 57.2 57.0 57.5 58.2 58.6 57.7 56.8 55.7 57.5 57.1 55.5 56.3 56.2 55.9 57.3 56.9 58.2 Other securities 16.7 16.8 17.0 17.0 16.7 16.8 16.7 16.9 16.9 16.8 16.6 16.7 16.5 16.6 16.6 16.6 16.4 16.5 16.3 16.4 16.6 16.3 16.3 16.3 16.2 16.3 16.5 16.7 16.8 16.8 16.8 16.9 17.1 17.6 17.4 17.9 1 June and December 1956, and December 1957, figures are for call dates. Other data (including those for2 June 1957) are for the last Wednesday of the month. Data are shown net, i. e., after deducting valuation reserves. Includes commercial and industrial, agricultural, security, real estate, bank, consumer, and other loans. 3 Data are shown gross of valuation reserves. For months other than June and December data are estimated on the basis of reported data for all insured commercial banks and for weekly reporting member banks. *8 Figures are based on book values and relate only to banks within the continental United States. For October 1955 certain loan items are available on 2 bases because of a reclassification resulting from reporting errors. The business loans figure shown above is after reclassification. The figure before reclassification is $30.8 billion. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Commercial banks played a powerful role in the speedy economic recovery in the first half of 1955 through their expansion of credit for housing and consumer durables. Bank loans increased by $4% billion— a record for the January-June period since World War II. During these 6 months, there was an increase of $1.3 billion in real-estate loans, $1.2 billion in consumer loans, and $2 billion in business loans of which a substantial part was for sales finance companies.4 In order to meet the increasing demands for loans, the banks reduced their holdings of United States Government securities by $5.7 billion in the first half of the year. There was also some rise in bank borrowing from the Federal Reserve banks—an increase from a monthly average of $160 million in the last quarter of 1954 to an average of about $400 million in the first half of 1955. * See table 23, p. 37. 46 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY TABLE 3 0 . — D e p o s i t s and currency, 1955-57 [Billions of dollars] Deposits and currency Demand deposits and currency End of period Total i Total 1955—January February March April May June July.. August September October November December 1956—January February March April May June July August September October November December 1957—January February March April... __ . May June July August September October November December . . . 209.2 206.9 205.3 207.4 206.7 207.7 208.1 208.6 209.7 211.3 212.2 216.6 214.4 211.6 210.8 212.4 211.2 213.6 213.3 212.8 214.1 216.6 217.2 222.0 219.9 218.0 217.2 219.6 218.4 219.7 221.0 220.0 220.9 223.0 223.3 227.7 133.8 131.3 129.1 131.2 130.1 130.6 131.0 131.2 132.1 133.4 134.8 138.2 136.0 132.8 131.6 133.1 131.6 133.0 132.6 132.0 132.8 135.1 136.3 139.7 136.9 134.4 132.6 134.7 132.7 133.4 134.4 132.9 133.3 135.0 135.7 138.6 Demand deposits adjusted2 107.0 104.5 102.4 104.5 103.3 103.2 103.9 103.9 104.9 106.1 106.9 109.9 108.9 105.6 104.4 106.1 104.2 104.7 105.2 104.5 105.4 107.4 108.3 111.4 109.5 107.0 105.2 107.3 104.8 105.6 106.6 105.1 105.5 107.2 107.2 110.3 Currency outside banks 26.8 26.8 26.7 26.7 26.8 27.3 27.1 27.4 27.2 27.3 27.9 28.3 27.1 27.2 27.2 27.0 27.4 28.3 27.4 27.5 27.4 27.7 28.0 28.3 27.4 27.4 27.4 27.4 27.9 27.8 27.8 27.8 27.8 27.8 28.5 28.3 Time deposits 3 75.4 75.7 76.2 76.2 76.5 77.1 77.1 77.4 77.7 77.9 77.4 78.4 78.4 78.8 79.3 79.3 79.6 80.6 80.7 80.9 81.3 81.5 80.9 82.2 82.9 83.6 84.6 84.9 85.7 86.4 86.7 87.1 87.7 88.1 87.6 89.1 1 2 Includes holdings of State and local governments, but excludes U. S. Government deposits. Includes demand deposits, other than interbank and U. S. Government, less cash items in process of collection. 3 Includes deposits in commercial banks, mutual savings banks, and Postal Savings System, but excludes interbank deposits. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. In the second half of the year, bank loans increased by $7.4 billion with three-fifths of the advance occurring in the category of business loans. The rise in consumer loans was the same as in the first part of the year, and real estate loans advanced at a somewhat slower pace than during the first 6 months. As a result of the pressure for funds, bank borrowing at the Federal Reserve banks during the last quarter of the year averaged $900 million.5 A $12 billion increase in bank loans in 1955 was offset by the sale of Government securities in the amount of $7.4 billion. Commercial bank sales of United States Government obligations were absorbed by nonfinancial corporations, pension and trust funds, State and local govern5 It is of some interest to note that the amount of borrowing during the latter part of 1955 and right through 1957 did not reach the level of the earlier 1952-53 period of tight credit. Part of the explanation lies in the fact that in recent years the banks turned increasingly to the Federal funds market for adjusting their reserves. More intensive use was made of existing reserves since banks with a deficiency of reserve balances borrowed from those with excess reserves. Another explanation is that Federal Reserve borrowing in 1952-53 could be included with other borrowed capital in calculating a bank's excess profits tax liability. In June 1953 the excess profits tax expired. 47 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY ments, and individual investors. Largely because of the contrary movement of bank loans and investments, there was a rise in demand deposits of only $3.4 billion. Although the money supply increased moderately during 1955, the velocity of circulation rose substantially. Demand deposits and currency outside banks increased at the rate of 2.8 percent as compared to a 3 percent rise in 1954. However, the average annual rate of turnover of demand deposits outside New York City increased by nearly 7 percent between 1954 and 1955. TABLE 3 1 . — A n n u a l rate of turnover of demand deposits, 1955-57 1 [Ratio of debits to deposits] Period 1955—January February March. April May June July August September___ October November. __ December.. _ 1956—January. __ February March April May June New York 42.0 41.9 41.7 37.3 42.7 44.7 40.7 38.2 43.5 44.7 45.4 51.3 45.7 41.1 47.2 45.4 46.0 47.0 6 other centers 2 25.4 26.4 30.2 27.1 28.4 28.3 26.6 25.9 27.4 26.5 29.0 28.1 29.5 27.5 29.7 30.1 28.7 28.9 337 other reporting centers 3 19.6 19.6 20.0 19.2 20.6 20.8 20.4 19.9 21.1 20.3 22.0 21.6 21.7 21.0 20.8 21.5 21.7 21.6 Period 1956—July August. ___ September. __ October November. __ December 1957—January. _ _ February March April.. May June... July August.. __ September.. _ October November. _. December New York 45.9 44.4 44.8 45.2 48.3 51.8 48.3 48.9 48.7 46.9 47.1 51.4 49.5 44.7 52.2 49.9 51.2 58.9 6 other 337 other centers 2 reporting centers 3 22.4 21.3 22.0 22.1 23.6 23.3 22.9 23.0 22.5 22.4 23.2 23.1 23.6 22.1 24.1 22.7 23.5 24.7 29.6 27.4 27.4 28.4 31.0 29.9 30.0 30.2 32.0 30.3 30.5 30.4 30.6 28.5 31.4 29.6 30.5 32.2 1 Does not include interbank and U. S. Government deposits and is given without seasonal adjustment. 2 Boston, Philadelphia, Chicago, Detroit, San Francisco, Los Angeles. 3 Before April 1955, 338 other reporting centers. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. The increase in the demand for funds and the growing pressure on bank reserve positions was reflected in the rise of interest rates. The yield on Treasury bills, which averaged 0.65 percent in June 1954 and rose to 1.17 percent by December, advanced to 2.6 percent in December 1955. The rate on 4-to-6 months' prime commercial paper rose sharply during 1955, from 1.47 percent in January to 3 percent in December. Long-term rates in 1955 advanced much less than shortterm rates. Between December 1954 and December 1955, yields on Government 10- to 20-year taxable bonds rose from 2.57 percent to 2.88 percent, and Moody's Aaa corporate bonds advanced from 2.90 percent to 3.15 percent. POLICY DIRECTIVES OF T H E OPEN MARKET COMMITTEE 6 In view of the pace of economic and credit expansion during 1955, let us see how the Open Market Committee regarded the changing situation and how it dealt with it. On January 11 it revised its directive to the Executive Committee from "maintaining a condition of ease in the money market" to "maintaining conditions in the/money market that would encourage recovery and avoid the development of unsustainable expansion." However, the change in directive "did not 6 The policy actions of the Open Market Committee referred to in this section are recorded in the Fortysecond Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1955, pp. 89-111. 48 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY call for pursuit at this stage of a program of credit restraint or of firmness in the money market." At its meeting of March 2, the Committee noted "that expansive forces had continued generally strong, both domestically and abroad," but concluded that the "situation did not appear to call for a generally restrictive credit policy." It is interesting to note that the record of this meeting states that— concern was indicated with respect to the relaxation of terms for, and the volume of expansion in, mortgage and consumer credit, and there were some fears that in a few industries, including building, activity was reaching levels that could not be sustained. In the light of this recognition of the potential dangers arising from the two sectors of the economy that played so significant a part in the rate of economic expansion during the rest of the year, one may be puzzled at the Committee's conclusion that "further measures toward restraint should be deferred until the effects of the shift in operations that had taken place since the beginning of the year were more apparent." The credit restraint referred to was the reduction in January and February of Federal Reserve holdings of United States Government securities by $1.3 billion. But this reduction was primarily for the purpose of absorbing reserve funds that normally become available to commercial banks by the seasonal return of currency from circulation and by the seasonal decline in deposits. The sale of Government securities by the Federal Reserve banks may have been larger than usual in recognition of the increasing demand for bank credit. But the amount of such sale in excess of the seasonally "normal" was small and could exert—as it was intended to do—only a very moderate influence in tightening bank reserves. It was not until its meeting of May 10 that the Open Market Committee revised its January directive by deleting the words "encourage recovery." Since "recovery now was an accomplished fact," the credit policy was to aim at "maintaining conditions in the money market that would avoid the development of unsustainable expansion." Among the various developments in the economy, it noted that the gross national product had risen substantially since its 1954 low and had exceeded its mid-1953 peak; a number of industries were operating at or close to capacity; business, financial, and consumer confidence was extraordinarily high; there had been no seasonal contraction in business loans, and the rapid expansion of real estate and consumer loans had continued. In its meeting of June 22, the Committee referred to new record levels in economic activity, but expressed some concern that the high level of production and employment had been supported by rapid expansion in consumer and mortgage credit on easy terms and that there was the likelihood of prices moving upward. There appeared to be little leeway for further increases in production, and it was doubtful that productivity could be increased rapidly enough to counteract cost-price influences. In view of the fact that the monetary authorities recognized around the beginning of May, and even more so by the end of June, that overall economic activity was reaching boom proportions, it was surprising even in financial circles that the Reserve banks waited until mid-April 49 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY and early May to raise the discount rate from l){ to 1% percent.7 The new 1% rate was below the discount rate at the beginning of 1953, and it was not until early in August that the 2 percent rate established in January 1953 was reached. Since the gross national product in the second quarter of 1955 was about $28 billion above the first quarter of 1953, an increase of about 8 percent, one could hardly accuse the Federal8 Reserve of having moved vigorously in its restrictive credit policy. Moreover, after the initial reduction in Government security holdings of the System open-market account in the first 2 months, open-market operations were so conducted as to produce no net change in Reserve bank holdings during the months of March through June. To be sure, failure to provide reserves through open-market operations may be regarded as a restrictive action. But in view of the swelling demands for credit, direct intervention of the System to reduce bank reserves would appear to have been more appropriate. Apparently, the Open Market Committee counted on the stronger credit demands to drive the commercial banks to the discount windows of the Federal Reserve banks for their additional reserves. With the traditional reluctance of the banks to augment their indebtedness to the Federal Reserve and the rise in the discount rate in April, credit would be more costly and less available and thus undue credit expansion would be discouraged. However, the banks did not rush to borrow in any great amount from the Federal Reserve during the first half of the year. Between December 1954 and June 1955, bank borrowings from the Federal Reserve increased by less than $200 million. They relied on the disposal of their substantial holdings of Government securities, which they had accumulated under the influence of the easy money policy of 1953-54, to obtain funds to take care of the heavy demands for private credit. As we have seen, $5.7 billion of United States Government obligations were sold or redeemed during the first half of the year by all commercial banks. i The following quotation from the First National City Bank Monthly Letter of May 1955, p. 53, is of interest: "* * * In light of the resurging strength of business, the only surprise was that the Federal Reserve had waited so long to act. As far back as January possibilities of a rate advance became a common topic of discussion. As it was, the Federal Reserve authorities limited their actions at that time to raising stock margin requirements and paring down idle loan funds among the banks while the Treasury reentered the long term market with an issue of 40-year 3-percent bonds. At the end of February, after the Treasury bond issue had been placed, talk of imminent action on discount rate spread about the financial community. The authorities contented themselves with suspending open market operations, permitting the business rise to carry forward on its established momentum, and letting the related credit demands absorb slack of excess reserves and compel banks to come in as borrowers from the Federal Reserve at the discount rate." s As financial editor Edward H. Collins of the New York Times noted in his column of August It, 1955: "There is at least a budding tendency to ask today * * * whether the Reserve, recalling the severe criticism towliich it was subjected (in 1953), isn't, consciously or unconsciously, proceeding somewhat overcautiously in this, its second bout with incipient inflation." 50 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC TABLE 32.—Member bank reserves and related items, STABILITY 1955-57 [Averages of daily figures, millions of dollars] Period 1955—January February March... April May June July August September October November December 1956—January February March April May June July August September October November December 1957—January February March April May June July August September October November December Federal Reserve credit 25,449 25,021 24,989 25,070 24,924 24,958 25,497 25,450 25, 525 25, 792 26,089 26,853 25,879 25,183 25, 517 25,411 25,237 25, 516 25, 599 25,357 25, 737 25,698 26,097 27,156 25,905 24, 912 24, 968 25,411 25,041 25,189 25,466 25,166 25,489 25,326 25,373 26,186 Gold stock 21,714 21,715 21,718 21,680 21,673 21,676 21,680 21, 682 21, 682 21, 685 21, 687 •21,689 21,692 21,694 21,711 21,735 21,768 21, 795 21,826 21,855 21,880 21,906 21,910 21, 942 21,989 22,279 22,305 22,313 22,358 22,621 22,625 22,626 22,627 22,660 22, 743 22,769 Currency in circulation 30,110 29, 784 29, 790 29,807 29,861 30,050 30,284 30, 289 30, 420 30, 532 30, 791 31,265 30,620 30,214 30,256 30,245 30,322 30, 536 30,751 30,650 30,803 30,864 31,198 31, 775 31,040 30, 595 30, 568 30,614 30,645 30,902 31,116 31,035 31,143 31,109 31,335 31,932 Total reserves 19,114 18,819 18,635 18,800 18, 746 18, 715 18,825 18, 728 18, 711 18,870 18, 902 19,240 19,138 18, 709 18,924 18,847 18, 735 18,933 18,836 18, 783 19,024 18,939 19,169 19, 535 19,295 18,816 18,884 19,087 18,827 18,982 19,129 18,834 18,956 19,040 18,958 19,420 Required reserves 18,432 18,195 18,050 18,210 18,166 18,146 18,205 18,152 18,148 18,345 18,378 18, 646 18, 586 18,177 18,340 18,320 18,268 18,359 18,237 18,224 18,446 18,419 18, 579 18,883 18, 773 18,302 18,366 18, 580 18,362 18,485 18, 595 18,300 18,434 18, 573 18,447 18,843 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. At its meeting of August 2, the Open Market Committee changed its directive from "maintaining conditions in the money market that would avoid the development of unsustainable expansion" to "restraining inflationary developments in the interest of sustainable economic growth." A few days later the Federal Reserve increased the discount rate from 1% to 2 percent. Recent statements by top officials of the Federal Reserve with respect to the monetary policies pursued in 1954 and 1955 make it desirable to quote at length from the record of the August 2 meeting of the Open Market Committee indicating the basis for their decision to change their directive "to restraining inflationary developments": The shift to a policy of restraining inflationary developments resulted from the Committee's review of the economic situation and its conclusion that the supply of money and credit was a more stimulating force at the time than was desirable in the interest of sustainable economic growth. Information that had become available for June and July indicated that industrial production had increased to a new high level, with fairly general advances in durable and nondurable goods lines as well as in minerals. Unfilled orders had continued to rise. In addition, a renewed upsurge of consumer buying appeared to be developing. Buying of FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D TABLE 3 3 . — M e m b e r bank excess reserves, ECONOMIC borrowings, STABILITY and free reserves, 51 1955-57 [Averages of daily figures, millions of dollars] Period 1955—January February. March April May June July August September October November December, 1956—January. February March April May... June July August September October November December. 1957—January. February March April May June July August September October November December, Excess reserves ___ ... . .. - .. - - 682 625 585 590 580 569 619 577 564 524 525 594 552 533 585 527 467 575 599 559 579 520 590 651 523 514 518 506 465 496 534 534 522 467 512 577 Borrowings at Federal Reserve banks Free reserves 313 354 463 495 368 401 527 ; 765 849 884 1,016 839 807 799 993 1,060 971 769 738 898 792 715 744 688 407 640 834 1,011 909 1,005 917 1,005 988 811 804 710 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. automobiles in July continued at record levels, and sales of appliances and other goods at department stores showed remarkable gains from the preceding month and a year ago. This upsurge in consumer demand reflected a further marked rise in consumer installment credit and an increased willingness of consumers to draw on liquid asset accumulations. It also suggested consumer expectations of higher prices later on. Numerous industries appeared to be producing at near capacity, and overall productivity gains had virtually disappeared in recent months. The situation was one in which a given percentage in output called for about an equal percentage gain in man-hours, and in which too easy access to bank credit was likely to result in increased prices rather than in increased production. There had been a substantial and contraseasonal rise in bank loans during the first half of the year, and in July all banking reports confirmed a continuing strong demand for bank credit. The Committee believed that, with increased costs pushing upward on industrial prices, the general price level might well move upward with accompanying speculative increases in inventories. It also took into account discussions relating to a probable increase in the discount rate at the Federal H. Rept. 2500, 8 5 - 2 5 369 271 122 95 212 168 92 -188 —285 -360 -491 -245 -255 -266 -408 -533 -504 -194 -139 -339 -213 -195 -154 -37 117 -126 -316 —505 -444 -508 -383 -471 -467 -344 -293 -133 52 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY Reserve banks early in August, based on observations of economic and financial developments in the respective Federal Reserve districts, and it agreed that the wording of its directive should be changed, as indicated above, to show that increased monetary restraint on credit expansion was now clearly appropriate.9 In view of the Committee's current and more or less similar appraisals since early May of the pace in economic activity, waiting 4 months before changing the discount rate and then raising it by only one-fourth of 1 percent was rather a feeble attempt at restrictive monetary action. By September there was greater realization within the Federal Reserve System that a larger increase was justified and the rate was advanced from 2 to 2% percent. P O L I C Y D E C I S I O N S AS V I E W E D I N R E T R O S P E C T BY T H E F E D E R A L R E S E R V E Officials of the System have recently admitted that they should have moved more vigorously, as the following 10 statement by the presidents of the Federal Reserve banks indicates: There is some question, however, whether the policy of ease was carried too far in 1954, when a combination of openmarket operations and reductions in discount rates and reserve requirements pushed available reserves of member banks to high levels and short-term interest rates to exceedingly low levels. As noted above, commercial banks utilized a large portion of the available reserves to purchase Government and other securities. While this action cushioned the recession and provided a basis for recovery by promoting growth in the money supply, it also contributed to the growth of liquidity in the banking system. Consequently, when policy was shifted toward restraint in 1955, and gradually became more restrictive through 1955 and in 1956, commercial banks were in a position to meet demands of consumer and business borrowers by liquidating Governments and extending loan credit. There also is some question whether the System moved fast enough in exercising restraint in the early and intermediate stages of the boom. Granted that a somewhat less easy policy in 1954 would have reduced commercial bank purchases of securities at that time, even the excessive liquidity existing at the beginning of 1955 might have been absorbed more quickly, and credit expansion thereby restrained further, had policy been tightened faster in 1955 * * * [Italic supplied.] One reason given by the presidents of the Reserve banks for^not moving more vigorously was that the economic data available in the first half of 1955 understated the speed of the recovery:11 * * * The recovery from the recession of 1953-54 moved much faster than was generally expected; there were still doubts in early 1955 that the recovery was firmly established, 9 Forty-second 10 Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1955, p. 102. Investigation of the Financial Condition of the United States: Joint and supplemental comments of the presidents of the Federal Reserve banks in response to the questionnaire of the Committee on Finance, U. S. Senate, 85th Cong., 2d sess., ch. 1, April 1958, p. 44. " Ibid., p. 45. 53 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY and there was considerable apprehension that a move toward tighter credit at a faster pace might halt the recovery short of its full potential. Much of the economic data available currently in the first two quarters of 1955 seriously understated the extent of the recovery up to that time. It was only later, when revisions of statistics became available, that the rapidity of the upturn became apparent. Moreover, it should be recalled that, at various times during the boom period, forces emerged that seemed to indicate a leveling off in business activity, or even an imminent decline. It is only through hindsight that the need for a more restrictive policy in the early stages of the boom seems clear. Unfortunately, the Reserve Board presidents failed to indicate which of the many statistical series employed by their research departments in analyzing current business conditions misled them because they "seriously understated" the magnitude of the recovery. To be sure, there are limitations in currently published data that purport to reflect monthly and weekly changes in business conditions, and there is little doubt that Government officials would be greatly aided in arriving at sounder policy decisions if they were supplied with improved and more currently available statistical information. There were undoubtedly some statistical series, such as the quarterly estimates of the gross national product, that were revised upward after mid-1955, but understatement of these series during the first half of the year is hardly a justification for the implication that because of it monetary policy moved too slowly. There was an abundance of statistical information to indicate that the economy was moving upward at a rapid pace during the first 6 months of 1955, and that certain sectors were developing at a rate that could threaten economic stability. Apparently, the Open Market Committee was convinced by this evidence, since at the beginning of May it dropped the phrase "economic recovery" and its credit policy directive concentrated on "avoiding unsustainable expansion." By the summer of 1955, it was concerned with restraining inflationary developments. If the monetary authorities failed to act more vigorously, it was much more a matter of judgment and interpretation of the economic data than of the limitations inherent in the data. We must look in other directions for an explanation of the inadequacy of monetary policy in 1955. In this connection the following quotations from the testimony of Mr. Martin, Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, before the Senate Finance Committee in August 1957, is of special interest: 12 Senator M A R T I N . I would now like to ask you some questions about the present, current inflation. When did this current inflation begin? Mr. M A R T I N . Well, I cannot state it precisely, Senator. It is pretty difficult to say that it began at any precise point. I think those of us in the System—and mind you, the System is not a one-man operation, for we have many varying views—I think we began to get worried about the current aspect of inflation in the middle of 1955. * * * Let me go back just a little bit if I may. In the inventory recession of 1953-54, we pursued a policy, and I think we were quite 18 Investigation of the Financial Condition of the United States: Hearings before the Committee on Finance, U. S. Senate, 85th Cong., 1st sess., pt. 3, 1957, pp. 1304-1305. 54 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY correct in our policy, in the early stages, of adjusting promptly, to make the inventory adjustments as orderly as possible, by easing money. By the end of 1953 and the early part of 1954,1 personally think that we were overdoing it a bit. We were using the phrase "active ease." One thing you find out about this is that while your weapons may be more effective in inducing restraint than they are in galvanizing the economy, nevertheless it is more difficult to get people to recognize the need for action when it comes to restraint. And I think in retrospect that one of the errors we made was that, in 1954, when the adjustments that were being made by the market were culminating and the base was being laid for the recovery that we had, we got a little bit enthusiastic about increasing the money supply, and we lowered our discount rate in February 1954 from 2 to 1% percent; and then we lowered it again to 1% percent in April of that year. * * * The trouble in 1955, the place where I began to get concerned, was when it took us from April of 1954 until April of 1955 to move back from IK to 1% percent in the discount rate—a whole year—because the constant discussion in the System was, "Well, better not take a step, you had better not do anything to slow things down." You see, everybody likes expansion. Then we went up to 1%. We later moved up successively during 1955 in four notches. * * * Senator M A R T I N . D O you feel you acted soon enough, and do you feel those actions were strong enough to stave off inflationary pressures then present? Mr. M A R T I N . N O ; I do not think we did. But there are differences of opinion on that within the System. I would think we would have been more effective if we had acted a little bit quicker and a Utile bit sharper in our movements * * *. [Italic supplied.] Mr. Martin and the Federal Reserve bank presidents are in agreement that the System overdid the policy of credit ease in 1954, thus making it more difficult later for the monetary authorities to control credit expansion. However, the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, in accounting for the tardiness and lack of vigor of the restrictive actions taken in the upswing, stressed an important element ignored by the bank presidents. This is the human factor of hesitancy to exercise curbs w^hen business expansion is underway. There is little doubt that the record of the past, as well as of the more recent period in monetary history, furnishes plenty of illustrations of the monetary authorities yielding to the weakness referred to by Mr. Martin. Since proper timing is of the essence of effective monetary policy, this limitation cannot be ignored in any evaluation of tools for promoting economic stability. The tardiness and lack of vigor shown in 1955, however, was more than a matter of hesitancy by those responsible for decisions with respect to general credit policy to exercise restraints that might check the pace of business expansion. Part of the explanation may be found 55 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY in the theory of credit control that seemed to be influential among officials of the Federal Reserve System, as well as in the limitations of the tools that were actually employed. T H E D I S C O U N T R A T E AS A TOOL OF M O N E T A R Y RESTRAINT All through the 1955-57 period, the discount rate was a major weapon employed by the Federal Reserve to limit bank credit expansion. The use of the discount mechanism is based on the view that member banks are traditionally reluctant to borrow funds from the Reserve banks or to remain in debt to them for any length of time. For the discount mechanism to act as a brake on credit expansion, it must be preceded by restrictive Federal Reserve open market operations that will put pressure on the reserves of the banks. From the degree of pressure exerted in 1955 it would seem that Federal Reserve officials were still under the influence of the theory propounded around the time of the accord that small changes in interest rates could have a significant influence on the decisions of lenders to curtail the expansion of private credit.13 Since a substantial part of the portfolios of banking and financial institutions has come to consist of Government securities, these institutions are sensitive to small rises in interest rates and to the capital losses involved in disposing of Government securities in order to switch into private loans. This is a comfortable theory for those who have the responsibility for decisions with respect toflexiblemonetary policy. If one could be fairly successful in curbing excessive credit expansion without much of an increase in interest rates, one could avoid the unpopularity associated with such diverse criticisms as high interest rates result in sizable increases in interest payments by the Treasury on the large public debt, cause disturbances in the capital market through sharp fluctuations in capital values, enrich the banks through increased earnings, and have an adverse discriminatory effect on small businesses, homebuilders, and municipalities. Unfortunately, the view that a policy of monetary restraint which results in small rises in interest rates curbs credit through locking in securities of financial institutions received little support from the developments in 1955 and the first half of 1956. The banks disposed of $5.7 billions of United States Government obligations during the first half of 1955, nearly $2 billion during the second half, and an additional $5 billion by the summer of 1956. Throughout this period interest rates were moving upward, and the rise was accompanied by the sale of more than $12 billion of both shortterm and long-term securities in order for the banks to meet their credit demands. The discount rate was increased 6 times between April 1955 and August 1956—from 1% percent to 3 percent. Bank loans increased $4.5 billion in the first 6 months of 1955, $7.4 billion in the second half of the year, and nearly $5 billion in the first 6 months of 1956. Why did the view that small increases in the interest rate inhibit bank disposal of Government securities, thereby curbing bank credit expansion, not find support in the financial developments of 1955?14 13 See Chapter I, p. 6. " The theory might have had a more realistic basis if there had been effective consumer and mortgage credit controls in the first half of 1955. H. Rept. 2500, 85-2 6 56 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY One answer given by some critics of the theory is that it is based on a mistaken interpretation of the behavior of lending institutions during a period of rapidly increasing demand for loan funds. The anticipation of a rise in interest rates, instead of checking the disposal of securities because of fear of capital losses, acts for a considerable time to hasten such disposals. Even before the April change in the discount rate the banks sharply reduced their holdings of Government securities—a reduction of nearly $5 billion between January and March. They had been expecting a rise in the rate for some months, as was indicated on page 49. Such expectation increases the incentive to dump securities at a time when capital losses are minimal, and there appear to be ever-widening opportunities for profitable lending. The banks sold another $3 billion between April, the month of the first hike in the discount rate, and August, the month of the second hike. Since their portfolios contained large quantities of short-term United States Government securities, the banks were prepared to take the relatively small losses from the sale of these securities and switch into more profitable areas such as mortgages, installment credit, and industrial and commercial loans. This was largely the case in 1955; later the banks sold mainly longer term Government securities on which they incurred heavier losses. After a time, to be sure, rising interest rates did have a noticeable influence in checking disposals. But it was not until mid-1956 that bank holdings of United States Government obligations stabilized and more or less continued at this level with relatively minor fluctuations through 1957. If for no other reason, a point is reached where considerations of bank liquidity cause the shifting out of Government securities to cease. In short, the Federal Reserve appeared to considerably underestimate the lag between the adoption of a policy of monetary restraint and the time when the policy takes effect. U. S. Government securities Period 3-month Treasury bills 1955—January... February.. March April May June July August September. October.... November. December. 1916—January February.. March April May June July August September. October November. December. 1957—January February.. March April., May June July August September. October November. December. 1.257 1.177 1.335 1.620 1.491 1.432 1.622 1.876 2.086 2.259 2.225 2.564 2.456 2.372 2.310 2.613 2.650 2.527 2.334 2.606 2.850 2.961 3.000 3.230 3.210 3.165 3.140 3.113 3.042 3.316 3.165 3.404 3. 578 3. 591 3.337 3.102 9- to 12month Taxable bonds 10 to 20 years * 1.36 1.41 1.49 1.71 1.72 1.71 1.88 2.12 2.14 2.19 2.28 2.56 2.50 2.38 2.43 2.83 2.83 2.69 2.62 3.01 3.17 3.07 3.15 3.33 3.17 3.23 3.35 3.41 3.37 3.55 3. 71 3.93 4.02 3.94 3.52 3.09 2.66 2. 72 2.72 2.77 2.76 2. 77 2.88 2.91 2.88 2.82 2. 85 2.88 2.86 2.82 2.90 3.05 2.94 2.89 2.97 3.15 3.19 3.18 3.30 3.43 3.33 3.20 3.25 3.30 3.39 3.61 3.63 3.63 3.72 3.84 3. 61 3.28 20 years and over 8 2.77 2.92 2.92 2.92 2.91 2.91 2.96 3.02 3.00 2.96 2.96 2.97 2.94 2.93 2.98 3.10 3.05 3.19 3.25 3.24 3.30 3.36 3.34 3.26 3.27 3.35 3.42 3.54 3.58 3.64 3. 61 3.63 3.50 3.33 »Includes certificates of indebtedness and selected note and bond issues. / Percent bonds, 15 years and over prior to April 1952 and 12 years and over beginning April 1952. 3 3H percent bonds of 1978-83,1st issued May 1, 1953. Sources: Board of Governors of Federal Reserve System, Treasury Department, Moody's Investor Service, and Standard and Poor's Corp. Corporate bonds (Moody's) Aaa 2.93 2.99 3.02 3.01 3.04 3.05 3.06 3.11 3.13 3.10 3.10 3.15 3.11 3.08 3.10 3.24 3.28 3.27 3.28 3.43 3.56 3.59 3.69 3.75 3. 77 3.67 3.66 3.67 3.74 3.91 3.99 4.10 4.12 4.10 4.08 3.81 Baa 3.45 3.47 3.48 3.49 3.50 3.51 3. 52 3.56 3.59 3.59 3.58 3.62 3.60 3.58 3.60 3.68 3.73 3. 75 3.80 3.93 4.07 4.17 4.24 4.37 4.49 4.47 4.47 4.44 4. 52 4.63 4.73 4.82 4.93 4.99 5.09 5.03 Average Common High-grade rate on stock municipal short-term yields, 200 bonds bank stocks (Standard loans to (Moody's) <fc Poor's) business, selected cities 4.22 4.21 4.21 4.12 4.14 3.87 3. 78 3.91 3.93 4.12 4.09 4.06 4.21 4.09 3.86 3.87 4.13 4.01 3.87 4.02 4.24 4.23 4.25 4.13 4.31 4.44 4.35 4.16 4.05 4.05 4.01 4. 21 4.50 4.68 4.58 4. 77 2.39 2.42 2.45 2.43 2.41 2.48 2.62 2.67 2.63 2. 56 2. 55 2. 71 2.64 2.58 2.69 2.88 2.86 2. 75 2.78 2.94 3.07 3.14 3.38 3.44 3.40 3.26 .3.32 3.33 3.52 3. 75 3.75 3. 91 3.90 3.79 3.76 3.47 3.54 3.56 3.77 3.93 3.93 4.14 4.35 4.38 4.38 4.40 4.83 4.85 Prime commercial paper, 4 to 6 months 1.47 1.68 1.69 1.90 2.00 2.00 2.11 2.33 2.54 2.70 2.81 2.99 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.14 3.27 3.38 3.27 3.28 3.50 3.63 3.63 3.63 3.63 3.63 3.63 3.63 3.63 3.79 3.88 3.98 4.00 4.10 4.07 3.81 Federal Reserve bank discount rate 1.50 1.50 1.50 *1.75 1.75 1.75 1.75 •2.00 •2.25 2.25 r 2.50 2.50 2.50 2.50 2.50 •2. 75 2.75 2.75 2.75 •3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.50 3.50 3.50 » 3.00 3.00 EFFECTIVE DATES «Apr. 15. 5 Aug. 5. « Sept. 9. ' Nov. 18. « Apr. 13. • Aug. 24. « W > W M U1 H W <1 tei hj O i—i o H « W Q O O Q W £ w Kj w Aug. 23. » Nov. 15. Oi 58 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC T H E D I S C O U N T R A T E AND C O N S U M E R STABILITY CREDIT The ineffectiveness of monetary policy in checking credit expansion was particularly evident in the case of consumer durable goods purchases, which played so important a role in the 1955 boom. The rise in interest rates neither inhibited the users nor the lenders of installment credit. The recent studies of installment credit prepared under the auspices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System indicate that users of consumer credit appear to be much more concerned with the amount of the downpayment and the maturity of the loan than with the interest rate.15 They are frequently unaware of the actual financial rate they are being charged. The important consideration seems to be the amount of the monthly payments to be made. Under increasingly liberal financial arrangements, especially the lengthening of maturities, there was little change in the size of monthly payments during 1955. Lending institutions were also not deterred by the interest rate from greatly expanding the volume of installment credit. Well over half of the $5.4 billion increase in installment credit during 1955 was supplied directly and indirectly by commercial banks. They were reluctant to curtail so profitable a source of earnings as consumer credit loans. They had become the largest supplier of installment credit so that by the end of 1955 they held 37 percent of the total outstanding installment loans. About 32 percent was held by sales finance companies with 4 of these companies doing three-fifths of the business. These large companies had little difficulty in obtaining funds either through borrowing from the banks at lower interest rates than were paid by all other bank borrowers, or direct placement of their commercial paper with nonfinance companies and large institutional investors, or through sale of their long-term notes and debentures. 15 Consumer Instalment Credit: A study by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 6 vols. 1957. Pt. I: Growth and Import, 2 vols. Pt. II: Conference on Regulation, prepared under the auspices of the National Bureau of Economic Research, 2 vols. Pt. Ill: Views on Regulation, 1 vol. Pt. IV: Financing New Car Purchases, a national survey for 1954-55,1 vol. 59 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY TABLE 3 5 . — I n s t a l l m e n t credit, 1955-57 [Millions of dollars] End of month 1955—January. __ February.. March April May June July August September. October... November. December. 1956—January. __ FebruaryMarch April May June July August September. October... November. December. 1957—January. __ FebruaryMarch April May June July August September. October... November. December. Total outstanding 23,512 23,604 24,046 24, 591 25,204 25,969 26, 509 27,154 27, 653 27,913 28,211 28,958 28,849 28,896 29,101 29,424 29, 779 30,114 30,366 30, 743 30,841 30,985 31,240 31,827 31,568 31,488 31.524 31,786 32,158 32,608 32,968 33,303 33,415 33, 504 33, 596 34,105 Automobile paper 1 9,861 10,028 10,410 10, 796 11,254 11, 794 12,235 12, 718 13,075 13,246 13,327 13,472 13, 488 13, 582 13, 750 13,898 14,065 14,261 14,389 14, 539 14, 547 14,498 14, 469 14,459 14,410 14,432 14,528 14,691 14,883 15,127 15,329 15,490 15,556 15, 579 15,542 15,496 Other conRepair and sumer goods modernipaper 1 zation loans 2 6,668 6, 563 6, 554 6,596 6,665 6, 770 6,810 6,888 6,962 7,029 7,176 7,634 7, 517 7,429 7,376 7,434 7, 578 7, 554 7, 590 7,697 7,733 7,872 8,066 8, 510 8,305 8,160 8,043 8,017 8,081 8,165 8,189 8,229 8,228 8,236 8,300 8,687 1, 574 1, 552 1, 533 1,538 1, 552 1, 572 1, 585 1, 612 1,639 1,664 1,678 1,689 1,662 1, 656 1,662 1,680 1,718 1,748 1, 768 1,799 1,832 1,865 1,890 1,895 1,872 1,859 1,856 1,862 1,886 1,905 1,921 1,954 1,969 1,988 1,996 1,984 i Represents all consumer installment credit extended for the purpose of purchasing automobiles and other consumer goods, whether held by retail outlets or financial institutions. Includes credit on purchases by2 individuals of automobiles or other consumer goods that may be used in part for business. * Represents repair and modernization loans held by financial institutions; holdings of retail outlets are included in other consumer goods paper. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. We have seen that concern was expressed about consumer credit expansion during almost every one of the 1955 meetings of the Open Market Committee. But the Federal Reserve had no authority to exercise selective controls over downpayments and maturities with which to curb excessive expansion of consumer credit. It had such powers under temporary authority during 1941-47, 1948-49, and in 1950-52. Nor did it request the Congress for authority to regulate consumer credit at any time since the expiration of regulation W in mid-1952. The January 1956 Economic Report of the President had pointed out that installment credit accentuates swings in consumer durable goods purchases, "thereby exposing the rest of the economy to the hazard of widened fluctuations." 16 The report appeared to regard favorably standby controls over installment credit as a supplementary stabilization device and recommended study of the problem:17 * * * Experience during the recent past suggests that the authority to set, if and as circumstances may require, mini16 Economic 17 Report of the President, January 1956, p. 94. Ibid., p. 94. 60 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY mum downpayments and maximum maturities on installment credit for the purchase of consumer durables would be a useful adjunct to other stabilizing measures. Its availability as a standby measure, to be used only when the economic situation demands it and under proper administrative safeguards, would increase the Government's ability to fulfill its responsibilities under the Employment Act. Although present conditions do not call for the use of such authority to regulate the terms of installment credit, this is a gpod time for the Congress and the executive branch to study the problem. * * * About the time of the release of the President's report, Mr. Martin, Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, was appearing before the Senate Banking Committee which was concerned with his nomination for a full term of 14 years. During 2 days of hearings he was questioned at length about the monetary policies pursued by the Federal Reserve during the preceding year and on the influence of the Treasury on the Board's actions. Mr. Fulbright, chairman of the committee, closed the hearings by reading a statement on consumer credit which indicated his readiness to schedule hearings on the question of18granting standby authority. The statement in part read as follows: I have been greatly concerned about the tremendous growth of consumer credit for some time now. During the stock-market hearings last year, I and other members of this committee called attention to the potential dangers in the marked rise of installment credit. The President's economic report states that in the second quarter of 1955 consumer installment debt expanded by nearly $2 billion, the largest on record over so brief a period. While members of the Committee on Banking and Currency cautioned the public on the dangers of excessive credit in this area, as well as in the stock market, the administration's concern seems belated. * * * If the administration wants standby authority over consumer credit, I shall be glad to schedule hearings on their proposal. The staff of the committee has been gathering data and opinions on this subject for some time. Generally, I prefer indirect credit regulations to direct controls, but the indirect methods did not stop an unhealthy increase in consumer credit last year. Whether this was because general credit instrumentalities were not effectively employed or whether they were simply inadequate, I am not prepared right now to say. If consumer credit controls had been in existence in 1955, prospects for consumer durable goods this year might well be brighter. It now appears that a great part of the boom of 1955 was borrowed from the future, in the form of great increases in private debt for consumer durables. In any event, however, we should not permit a recurrence of excessive borrowing which can only result in violent fluctuations in so important an industry as automobiles. 18 Nomination of William McChesney Martin, Jr.: Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Cur* rency, U. S. Senate, 84th Cong., 2d sess., January 20 and 27,1956, pp. 68-69. 61 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY Insofar as the 1955 prosperity was based on an unusually rapid expansion of consumer debt, there is a real question whether the high level of activity was not achieved at the expense of substantially lower levels of production in 1956. T H E SHIFT IN FEDERAL RESERVE ATTITUDE TOWARD CONSUMER CREDIT CONTROLS In mid-February 1956 the President, through the Council of Economic Advisers, requested the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System to undertake "a broad study of the role of consumer installment credit in a growing economy, including arguments for and against renewal in some form of governmental authority to regulate credit, in this field." This 6-volume, 2,000-page study, which was published by the Board in the spring of 1957, contains a vast mass of factual and analytical materials pertaining to consumer installment credit, and widely varying viewpoints are represented on the question of regulation of consumer credit. On May 24, 1957, the Board of Governors, after studying these reports, transmitted a two-page statement to the chairmen of the Senate and House Banking and Currency Committees, the Joint Economic Committee, and the Council of Economic Advisers,19 giving its views on the regulation of consumer installment credit. The principal conclusion of the Board of Governors was that— a special peacetime authority to regulate consumer installment credit is not now advisable. The Board feels that the broad public interest is better served if potentially unstabilizing credit developments are restrained by the use of general monetary measures and the application of sound public and private fiscal policies.™ [Italic supplied.] It is of interest to record the third, fourth, sixth, and eighth findings of the Board: 21 (3) Though of recognizable importance as a factor of instability, fluctuations in consumer installment credit have been generally within limits that could be tolerated in a rapidly growing and dynamic economy. (4) A possible exception to the third finding occurred during the 1954-56 upswing in economic activity. The rapid expansion of consumer installment credit in 1955, with its accompanying secondary impacts on capital investment, contributed to the emergence of inflationary pressures. This expansion, however, combined with real estate mortgage and other types of credit expansion in producing this sequence of developments. (6) Liberalization of installment credit terms and standards from mid-1954 through 1955, which was particularly marked in connection with the purchase of new automobiles, contributed to the further widening of the practice of installment buying and borrowing and to the very great expansion in installment credit outstanding that occurred. Some of the » Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1957, pp. 647-648. »Ibid., p. 648. «Ibid., p. 648. 62 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY forces making for this rapid widening of the market for consumer credit were temporary. Also, this drastic liberalization of credit terms and standards exposed consumer lenders to increased risks. On both counts, the forces making for credit liberalization in that period were to an extent transient and self-limiting. (8) Under peacetime conditions, special regulation of consumer installment credit would inevitably present problems of compliance to the financing and business firms subject to it, and of administration and enforcement to the agency of Government responsible for the regulation. It is important to note that the Board of Governors had expressed itself with much greater vigor on the contribution of consumer credit to economic instability 5 years earlier in a more comprehensive statement on the subject submitted for the Patman committee report.22 The Board had also regarded selective regulation of this area as a helpful supplement to general monetary controls. Let us quote from the earlier Federal Reserve statement: Expansion in consumer credit adds directly to the growth of bank credit and by this means to the money supply. A substantial part of the consumer credit outstanding is financed either directly or indirectly by bank loans. In addition to the consumer loans made directly by banks, a large part of the funds of sales finance and personal loan companies is obtained from bank sources, and a great many retail establishments finance their receivables partly through borrowing at banks. Thus, a substantial part of every dollar of additional consumer credit ordinarily stems from bank credit expansion and represents a direct addition to the total number of dollars competing for an existing supply of goods and services. To the extent that nonbank lenders sell Government securities to finance an expansion of their consumer credit balances, this also affects the money supply directly or indirectly. Of equal importance from the standpoint of monetary stability is the fact that the operations of bank and nonbank lenders in this credit area influence the activity or turnover of money. An expansion of consumer credit, accordingly, affects both the money supply and its circulation.23 The general role of consumer installment credit in economic fluctuations can be described briefly as follows: When incomes rise in the upswing of the cycle, demand for and extensions of installment credit increase, with the result that the expenditures of people increase more rapidly than their income. When incomes shrink in the downswing of the economic cycle, demand for and extension of credit decreases and outstanding installment balances contract. In order to pay off debt, people are forced to cut back their expenditures more than if they had not incurred debts in the upswing. This 32 Monetary Policy and the Management of the Public Debt: Their Role in Achieving Price Stability and High-Level Employment: Replies to questions and other material for the use of the Subcommittee on General Credit Control and Debt Management, Joint Committee on the Economic Report, 82d Cong.. 2d sess., 1952, pt. I, pp. 410-418. 23 Ibid., pp. 411-412. 63 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY expansion and contraction of consumer debt * * * is a significant factor in fluctuations in bank credit and the money supply. The generalization to which this description leads is that fluctuations in installment credit accentuate cyclical swings in consumer expenditure and hence in economic activity. This cause and effect role of consumer credit in economic fluctuations is in many respects similar, of course, to that of other credit, producer credit included, but, as pointed out later, continued expansion of consumer credit in periods of strong inflationary boom has a significance somewhat different from that of producer credit. * * * 24 Consumer credit functions at a point in the economy and in a manner that tends to make it relatively unresponsive to the effects of general credit instruments. For this reason selection of this credit area for regulation provides a helpful supplement to the general measures * * * 25 [Italic supplied.] Thus, the unregulated expansion of consumer credit adds to general inflationary pressures and might actually require a more aggressive use of general credit instruments than would otherwise be necessary. That is to say, in the absence of selective regulation of consumer credit, other means of credit restraint might have to be exercised more restrictively in order to bring about sufficient restraint on the overall expansion of private credit. This emphasizes the desirability of being able to use selective credit measures to complement, but not to substitute for, overall or general credit measures, the extent of such use depending on prevailing economic circumstances. One of the primary justifications for the selective regulation of consumer credit is that it helps to avoid too strong effects on segments of the economy that are more sensitive to general credit actions.26 It should be noted that there was at least one top official of the Federal Reserve System who spoke out vigorously in 1955 for giving the System authority over installment credit. Mr. Allan Sproul, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, in an important address before a joint meeting of the American Finance Association and the American Economic Association in December 1955, declared:27 * * * I know that there are those who believe that selective credit controls are a dangerous step on the road to general overall planning, and I have no desire to become a fellow traveler on that road. But I do believe that there is a temptation to abuse consumer credit in boom times, that it 2* Op. cit., pp. 411-413. « Op. cit., p. 413. 26 Op. cit., p. 414. 27 Allan Sproul, Reflections of a Central Banker, Journal of Finance, March 1956, p. 12. This address also challenged economists to take the lead in assisting monetary authorities to reexamine the basic problems in the field of central banking. He stressed the necessity of independent analysis of these problems by persons not connected in any official capacity with the System. His remarks in this connection were as follows: "We have excellent research staffs in the Federal Reserve System: able economists and statisticians and devoted students of money and banking problems. But their work needs more cross-fertilization and critical analysis by thoughtful and disciplined minds outside the System who can apply their talents to this special field without the bias of an organizational viewpoint. Not enough work has been done, I would say, on the monetary problems of a mixed Government-private economy, on the functioning and form of a fractional reserve banking system in such an economy, on the growing importance of other financial institutions, which crisscross both the fields of commercial banking and investment banking, and on the performance and characteristics of our money and capital markets. These are subjects which are becoming critical in the development of central banking * * *" (pp. 13-14). 64 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY can thus become a serious source of instability in our economy, and that we would not jeopardize our general freedom from direct controls by giving the Federal Reserve System permanent authority to regulate consumer credit. * * * MONETARY POLICY AND THE GROWTH OF FINANCIAL INTERMEDIARIES We have seen that the ineffectiveness of monetary policy resulted in part from a reluctance to move vigorously to restrict credit when business confidence was high and activity was rapidly expanding. Apart from the limitation of this human factor, the nature of the boom was such that areas which were making the greatest demands on credit in 1955—housing and consumer durables—were those that were not particularly sensitive to the restrictive tools actually employed by the Federal Reserve. There is an additional limitation on monetary policy which has been stressed in recent years, namely, the greatly changed institutional and financial environment in which the banking system operates. In particular, what is referred to is the vastly increased importance of the role played by financial intermediaries, such as life insurance companies, building and loan associations, savings banks, investment companies, and pension funds, in the field of credit. Since World War II the increase in the assets of nonbank financial intermediaries was at least three times that of commercial banks. The acceleration in the flow of savings to nonbank financial institutions raises many problems with respect to the functioning of our capital markets. Here we are concerned, however, only with the contention that the growth of these institutions has rendered monetary policy less effective in restricting credit during the recent boom. Life insurance companies, savings and loan associations, and mutual savings banks invested heavily in mortgages in 1955. During the year these 3 groups acquired over two-thirds of the more than $16 billion increase in the nonfarm mortgage debt. Life insurance companies and savings banks not only financed mortgages through savings that were channeled to them, but also obtained additional funds for such loans by borrowing heavily from the commercial banks. Under "warehousing" arrangements they either sold mortgages to the banks which they agreed to buy back or they obtained forward commitments from the banks in order to make good on their own forward commitments to lend. Savings and loan associations expanded their mortgage activity by greatly increasing their borrowing from the Federal home-loan banks. From one point of view, it would seem that the growth of financial intermediaries should have made the capital markets more sensitive to a restrictive monetary policy. These institutions hold a considerable proportion of the public debt. Since their portfolios contain the longer term Government securities they should be especially sensitive to capital losses arising from increasing interest rates. Critics of general monetary controls, however, have argued that the financial intermediaries have reduced the effectiveness of Federal Reserve policy. Their spectacular growth has signified greater efficiency in assembling idle funds and putting them to work. In a period when monetary policy seeks to restrict the money supply, these institutions 65 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY increase the velocity of monetary circulation by increasing the proportion of the money supply that is actively spent at the expense of the portion that is held idle. By selling their Government securities to nonbank investors they take— up idle balances which they transfer to active spenders by making mortgage or other loans or by buying newly issued corporate securities. In this case idle balances become active, passing through financial institutions in the process, and velocity is increased.28 The critics have argued that the monetary authorities have placed excessive emphasis on the money supply and on the volume of bank reserves and have 29not given sufficient attention to the change in the velocity of money. In the minds of some students of Federal Reserve policy, the growth of financial institutions raises the question whether, in the interest of promoting economic stability, it is not desirable to supplement general monetary controls with selective control over housing credit as well as over installment credit.30 T H E T I G H T M O N E Y P O L I C Y A N D I T S CRITICS, 1956 T O MID-1957 Once the monetary authorities failed to adopt stronger measures in 1955, they were in the proverbial position during the following year and a half of holding a bear by the tail. The great increase of consumer and mortgage credit which stimulated the production of nearly 8 million cars and the construction of more than 1.3 million homes in 1955 sparked the expansion of plant and equipment expenditures. These expenditures rose 7 percent in 1955, and in 1956 they advanced to record levels with a 22-percent rise over the preceding year. The increasing pressure on resources and manpower culminated in an upward movement of wholesale industrial prices starting in mid-1955. By the end of 1956 these prices rose 8 percent. During the year the index of industrial production, however, hovered more or less around the advanced level reached in December 1955. Despite a 16-percent decline in housing starts and more than a 20-percent drop in production of automobiles in 1956, the sharp rise in plant and equipment expenditures was a major factor in the continuation of the high level of business activity. The rate of economic expansion slackened with about one-half of the advance in the gross national product accounted for by higher prices. The monetary authorities had a difficult course to steer with respect to credit policy in 1956. On the one hand, there was the risk that a more liberal policy with respect to the availability of bank reserves might accelerate price rises, especially in "bottleneck" sectors of the economy. In these sectors production could not readily advance, or if output were expanded it would be at substantially higher costs. On the other hand, if the policy became much more restrictive, there was the danger of initiating a downward spiral in business activity since certain of the key sectors which had ushered in the boom had been showing considerable weakness for some time. 38 Warren L. Smith, On the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy, American Economic Review, September 1956, p. 602. a ® Ibid., pp. 600-604. On the influence of the growth offinancialintermediaries see also: Arthur F. Burns, Prosperity Without Inflation, Fordham Universty Press, 1957, ch. 3. M See Irwin Miller, Monetary Policy in a Changing World, Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1956, p. 3411; Alvin H. Hansen, The American Economy, McGraw-Hill, 1957, ch. 3. 66 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY The Open Market Committee directives during 1956 reflected the uncertainties resulting from the mixed trends of the various sectors of the economy. From late January to late March, the credit policy directive read that transactions in the System open market account were to be with a view "to restraining inflationary developments in the interest of sustainable economic growth" but should also take "into account any deflationary tendencies in the economy." This supplementary clause "gave consideration to the view that the domestic economy after a year and a half of expansion might be nearing31 a cyclical peak and that a reaction might be in prospect before long." At the end of March, however, the clause to take into account deflationary tendencies was deleted, since the balance of evidence was believed32 to indicate a further advance in the economy. The record stated: * * * Among the general factors leading to this conclusion were the much greater than expected plans of business concerns in all major lines for plant and equipment expenditures, the widespread optimism of consumers as to the economic outlook and their own financial position and income prospects, and evidence of an exceptionally heavy demand for bank credit in the current month. The committee also noted that common stock prices had risen sharply further. Growing pressures for increases in prices and wages were evident, and there was danger that if supported by further credit expansion pressures would engender an inflationary spiral. * * * Consideration was also given to possible action by the Federal Reserve to increase the discount rate to "prevent undue credit expansion for financing capital outlays through the banking system." 33 In April the Board of Governors raised the discount rate from 2% percent to 2% percent in 10 of the Reserve banks and to 3 percent for the 2 others. By the end of May, however, the directive once more added the additional clause of taking into account deflationary tendencies as well as pursuing a policy of restraining inflationary developments. This directive was continued until early in August. In this month the Board of Governors raised the discount rate from 2% to 3 percent. For the remainder of the year the directives called for restraining inflationary developments in the interest of sustainable economic growth. During the last month, there was a supplementary clause that "recognition should be given to additional pressures in the money, credit, and capital markets resulting from seasonal factors and international conditions." 34 With the economy continuing to operate near capacity levels— despite some uncertainties about its general direction during the first part of the year—and with prices and wage rates moving upward, the Open Market Committee felt that as a general policy it could not relax in its efforts at restricting the availability of bank reserves. Despite mounting criticism of the "tight money policy"—what with interest rates advancing in all sectors of the money and capital markets 31 Forty-third Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1956, p. 20. 32 Ibid., p. 26. 33 Op. cit., p. 27. Op. cit., p. 43. 67 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY and especially long-term rates because of the increased business demand for investment funds—the determination of the Federal Reserve to resist pressures for relaxation during 1956 and the first half of 1957 was applauded in many quarters. Open market operations were so conducted that the security holdings of the System had increased by only $160 million during 1956. The money supply had risen by $1.5 billion, representing a rate of increase of only 1 percent, as compared to a 2.8 percent rise in 1955. However, the rate of turnover of demand deposits in centers outside of New York City increased 8 percent in 1956. To be sure, there was also increasing criticism that while business firms were able to obtain funds for capital expansion from the banks and through the security markets—over 70 percent of the $7.6 billion increase in bank loans in 1956 was in the category of business loans— residential builders, small business firms, and State and local governments were adversely affected by the restrictive monetary policy. Other critics pointed out that neither open-market operations nor further rises in the discount rate accomplished the objective of the restrictive credit policy since plant and equipment expenditures—the major influence in the intensification of inflationary pressures—were not inhibited from continuing their rapid rise throughout 1956. During the year more than four-fifths of corporate outlays for plant and equipment was derived from depreciation and amortization allowances and retained profits. Toward the first of these criticisms, officials of the Federal Reserve took the position that in a free economy the market was35the regulator of the flow of credit and not the monetary authorities. With respect to the second criticism, the Federal Reserve recognized that liberal depreciation and amortization provisions in the tax law and large corporate earnings contributed to the capital boom, but it was pointed out that were it not for its restrictive policy, capital expenditures would have been greater and inflationary pressures in other areas would have been intensified.36 In support of this position they cited the large volume of scheduled offerings in the capital market that were canceled or postponed. DELIBERATIONS OF T H E OPEN MARKET COMMITTEE IN 1957 One may justifiably view with favor the determination of the monetary authorities not to relax restraints in 1956 and in the first half of 1957, but there is much less justification for regarding favorably the policies pursued through the summer and fall of 1957. As critics have pointed out, in holding onto a policy of restraint too long, the Federal Reserve may have contributed to accelerating the pace of the downswing in business activity. The monetary authorities had become so preoccupied with the increase in inflationary pressures since mid1955 that they ignored the cumulative evidence which pointed to the likelihood of the boom ending in the not-too-distant future. At least so it seemed from the public statements by Federal Reserve officials, their testimony at congressional hearings, and policy decisions such as raising the discount rate one-half percentage point, i. e., to 3% percent, in August. At his appearance before the Senate Finance 35 Hearings on January 1957 Economic Report of the President, Joint Economic Committee, U. S. Congress, 85th Cong., 1st sess., 1957, p. 591. a0 Investigation of the Financial Condition of the United States: Hearings before the Committee on Finanee, U. S. Senate, 85th Cong., 1st sess., pt. 3, August 1957, p. 1399. 68 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY Committee during that month, the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board stated that credit restraint is "required at present, for clearly the most critical economic problem now facing the country is that of inflation." 37 In the fall and almost up to mid-November, when the discount rate was lowered from 3% to 3 percent giving public notice that the Federal Reserve regarded the immediate problem ahead as not inflation but business contraction, presidents of the Reserve banks and members of the Board of Governors of^the System were making speeches that inflation was still the No.f lfeconomic|problem and it would be a great mistake to relax credit restraint. In the light of the vehemence and the frequency with which Federal Reserve officials publicly stressed during the first 10 months of 1957 the necessity for continuing monetary restraint, it comes as a surprise to read the record of the 1957 meetings of the Open Market Committee published in the annual report of the Board of Governors and released in April 1958. During almost all of the 18 meetings held throughout the year there appeared to be an absence of that confidence in the continuation of the upward movement of business activity and in the intensification of inflationary pressures which was manifested in public statements by top spokesmen for the System. Even as early as January the record indicates: 38 There were * * * developments that suggested that the economy might be losing some of its upward momentum. While these data were not sufficient to support a forecast of a downward turn as a clear, nearby prospect, they suggested that the economy might be entering a period of sidewise movement. For example, a tendency for total capital expenditures to level off was evidenced by recent figures for factory construction contracts, new machine tool orders, and freight car orders, together with scattered announcements of postponements of plant construction projects. There were cross currents in the area of prices with higher costs showing up in increased prices for finished goods, both at wholesale and at retail, in contrast with a softening trend in prices of a number of primary products. Business loans at all reporting member banks after a fourth quarter rise of $1.6 billion declined by more than $700 million in the 3 weeks to midJanuary, a postwar record decline for the period that compared with a drop of $355 million a year earlier. A rapid decline in security loans had also occurred and about threefourths of the total rise in loans during the fourth quarter of 1956 had been wiped out. * * * In February it was noted that there was some easing of inflationary pressures. It was too early to tell, however, whether this was but a temporary lull, the beginning of a downturn, or the attainment of high-level stability. During the first 2 months of the year there was no change in the credit policy directive that open-market operations were to be conducted with a view— 37 Investigation of the Financial Condition of the United States: Hearings before the Committee on Finance, U. S. Senate, 85th Cong., 1st sess., pt. 3, August 1957. p. 1262. 38 Forty-fourth Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1957, p. 37. 69 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY to restraining inflationary developments in the interest of sustainable economic growth, while recognizing unsettled conditions in the money, credit, and capital markets and in the international situation. At the beginning of March, the wording was changed. While calling for a continuation of restraint on inflationary developments, the directive took recognition of "uncertainty in the business outlook, the financial markets, and the international situation." This change in wording * * * was not an indication of a shift in direction of policy but was designed to emphasize the factor of uncertainty in the current business outlook. The general direction of policy continued to be one of restraining inflationary developments. In its review of conditions, the committee found evidence of the slowing down of expansionary forces in many sectors of the private economy but no indication that a pronounced downturn had begun. Rather, there were many underlying forces tending to hold activity at a high level. * * * 39 While it was apparent that a sidewise movement was taking place in the economy, there was uncertainty as to which way the economy would go. In any event, however, since the economy's upward momentum had definitely slackened and since the rise in finished goods prices seemed likely to level off in the near future, it was not believed appropriate that overt action be taken toward increasing credit restraint, although maintenance of about the degree of restraint that had existed for some time seemed to be called for. * * * 40 The March policy directive of the Open Market Committee was renewed without change at each of its subsequent meetings until the revision of November 12. Around mid-year and during the month of August when the discount rate was raised from 3 to 3% percent, the Open Market Committee continued to note that business activity manifested a sidewise movement and that divergent trends in various sectors "provided no clue as to the direction and intensity of the next major change in economic activity." 41 The increase of one-half percentage point in discount rates "was regarded as primarily a technical move made at a time when market interest rates were considerably above discount rates".42 The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, at its August 8 meeting approving the relatively large hike in the discount rate, also noted the general sidewise movement of the economy but stressed the upward trend of prices and wages and the 43 vigorous demand for credit which was pushing interest rates upward: * * * With the upward movement of interest rates, the discount rate of the Federal Reserve banks, which had stood at 3 percent since the fall of 1956, fell further behind the rate structure generally. The disparity became even more pronounced in early August when the commercial banks inIbid., Ibid., «Ibid., «Ibid., «Ibid., p. 42. p. 43. p. 49. p. 50. p. 68. 70 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY creased from 4 to 4% percent the rate charged on loans to prime business borrowers. The increase in the Federal Reserve bank discount rates, which brought them into better alinement with money market rates, raised the cost to member banks of operating on borrowed reserves and thus diminished incentive on the part of the member banks to borrow from the Reserve banks. At the September 10 meeting, the Open Market Committee found no material change in business activity for the past several months. It was noted that bank credit had expanded less rapidly in the previous 5 weeks than in other recent years and some slackening in money turnover had appeared. On October 1 the Committee took note of the fact that— an increasing number of business observers were suggesting that the major expansive forces had been spent, that pressure of inflationary forces was in process of lessening and even of dispersing, and that the prospective movement in activity was a decline. Business sentiment * * * appeared to be developing into a psychology of gloom in some places and was much more cautious about prospects than for some months * * * On the other hand, the reports to the Committee at this meeting did not present a picture of a settling or declining economy. There was considerable feeling that while inflationary clouds might be breaking up, it would be44 premature to conclude that they had been scattered. * * * On October 22, 3 weeks before the Federal Reserve had signaled a definite shift in its position through the reduction of the discount rate from 3% to 3 percent, the Open Market Committee still appeared uncertain as to how the economy would 45 * * * breakout from the sidewise movement that had been characteristic of business for some months. In a searching reexamination of the economic situation, the Committee found that the latest quarterly and monthly figures showed continuation through the third quarter of 1957 of many features prevailing earlier in the year, with production steady at a high level, price movements in wholesale markets mixed with the average up, and consumer prices generally continuing upward. September industrial production was at 144, down a point from August but within the narrow 143 to 146 range prevailing so far this year. The economy as a whole showed basic strength, but there was uncertainty as to what combination of demands would prevent recession in activity, or, on the other hand, make for an advance in total output and employment from present levels. In analyzing the implications of recent business and credit developments for monetary and fiscal policy, it appeared that there had been short-run abatement in inflationary pressures, and questions were raised about potential declines in important sectors of activity. Business sentiment had turned more pessimistic than the current indicator picture, and attitudes of common stock investors appeared to reflect «Ibid., pp. 51-52. «Ibid., pp. 53-54. 71 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY a growing disbelief in the extension of inflationary trends. Business loan expansion was continuing to run behind the preceding year. As a result of the increasing uncertainty as to the business situation * * * the environment for monetary policy was beginning to look quite different from the boom conditions that initially justified the current restrictive policy. * * * The Committee concluded, after reviewing the data, that there was no immediate occasion to reverse its policy of restraint in credit expansion or to make a change in the policy directive. While it was clear that the Committee at this juncture did not wish to make any move which would signal a change in policy, it wished to supply seasonal needs reasonably freely. It did not wish to increase restraint from what it had been. There was some feeling that the Committee should actually diminish restraint a little, but more of the members believed that the Committee should resolve doubts on the side of ease. Thus, in renewing the directive without change, the Committee agreed that although general policy was not to be changed appreciably, it should tend on the easier side from where it had been in recent weeks. On November 12 the Open Market Committee decided "that action should now be taken to recognize the change in the general economic situation away from the sidewise movement that had prevailed during most of 1957." It had46finally become convinced that a business recession was underway: * * * there was no longer much doubt that at least a mild downturn in business activity was underway, and there was widespread belief that it would probably continue well into 1958. The major question seemed to be not whether a further business decline would occur, but for how long and in what degree. In terms of credit policy, the question presented was how far the Committee should go at this time in recognizing the change in the economic situation and outlook, and by what means. * * * Its policy directive was changed from that of restraining inflationary developments to "fostering sustainable growth in the economy without inflation, by moderating the pressures on bank reserves." Two days after this revision, the Board of Governors of the System approved the reduction of the discount rate to 3 percent, with one member (Mr. Robertson) dissenting on the ground that the "economic situation did not call for an overt act that could be interpreted as a drastic move toward monetary ease."47 In mid-December the Open Market Committee revised its credit policy directive to provide that openmarket operations were to be conducted with a view "to cushioning adjustments and mitigating recessionary tendencies in the economy."48 The economic and financial data presented at this meeting confirmed rather clearly the developing recession that had been indicated by reports at earlier meetings at which the Committee acted to moderate the pressures on bank re«Ibid., p. 56. «Ibid,, p. 70. «Ibid., p. 61. H. Kept. 2500, 85-2 7 72 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY A N D ECONOMIC STABILITY serves. The recession was still of moderate intensity, and inasmuch as the Committee actions taken since midNovember to lessen pressures on reserves, together with the reduction in Reserve bank discount rates, had signaled an effective change in policy toward less severe credit restraint, it did not appear to the Committee that additional major actions were necessary at the moment. The change at this meeting in wording of the Committee's policy directive was adopted with the understanding that reserves would continue to be made somewhat more available, but the particular reason for this change was to recognize that the economy had encountered a recession and that the Federal Open Market Committee's policies were being molded accordingly. * * * T H E MISTAKEN CREDIT POLICIES AFTER MID-1957 In defending the tight monetary policies of 1956 and 1957 before congressional committees, Government officials frequently quoted in support of their actions from the 1950 report of the Douglas Subcommittee on Monetary, Credit, and Fiscal Policies. But they generally failed to refer to those sections of the report which stressed that to be effective, monetary management must be characterized by timely, vigorous, and flexible actions. We have seen that officials of the Federal Reserve System stated in retrospect that they fell short of satisfying these criteria in 1955. Although they have not yet admitted to shortcomings in the application of these criteria in the second half of 1957, it is not unlikely that, after allowance of a longer period for hindsight, the violation in the summer of 1957 of the principle of timely flexibility in monetary policy will also be admitted. If mistakes in 1955 may justifiably be said to have encouraged subsequent inflationary developments, the errors in 1957 may be said to have contributed to the sharpest business decline in the postwar period. The successful application of the principle of timely flexibility depends on a reasonably good diagnosis of the current changes that are taking place in the economy. The monetary authorities are, of course, not omniscient, and are bound to make mistakes. They are not only engaged in practicing the difficult art of prevision but, unlike many other forecasters, they have the responsibility for making decisions with respect to the flow of credit, based on their judgments of the prospective business situation, which can seriously affect the entire economy. Recognizing both the limitations arising from the uncertainties attached to prompt discernment of economic changes and from a definite inclination on the part of the monetary authorities to unduly delay in taking the necessary steps, there are those who look with a dim view on the potentialities of monetary policy for promoting economic stability. Some skeptics advocate the use of impersonal devices which would signal both the need and time for action, thus minimizing errors originating in human psychology. Others place major reliance on the stabilizing power of different tools, such as fiscal policy.49 Those, however, who regard monetary policy as an essential tool, among a variety of measures required in a stabilization « John K. Galbraith, The Affluent Society, chs. 16 and 17, Houghton-Mifflin, 1958; testimony of Seymour E. Harris, Investigation of the Financial Condition of the United States: Hearings before the Committee on Finance, U. S. Senate, 85th Cong., 2d sess., April 1958, pt. 6, p. 1992 £f. 73 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY program, need not entertain illusions that human limitations can be overcome by the adoption of mechanical formulas, either in forecasting or in decision making. There are no mechanical substitutes for diagnoses based on the fullest use of the available evidence—often conflicting in character—nor can the necessity for the exercise of the age-old virtues of sound judgment, wisdom, and courage be eliminated from decisions for action. As a consequence, the process of identifying past errors and ascertaining the source of the miscalculations must be an ever-continuous one if we are to make progress in learning how to cope more effectively with the problems of economic instability. The contrast between the record of the deliberations of the Open Market Committee, which stressed the sidewise movement of the economy during most of the year, and which expressed considerable uncertainty as to the business outlook, and the public statements and actions of the Federal Reserve, which emphasized that the central problem during the first 10 months was inflation, requires explanation. Similarly, the relatively sharp rise in the discount rate in August when business expansion was grinding to a halt is also in need of a more satisfactory explanation than has thus far been advanced by the monetary authorities. It is safe to predict that, long after the events of 1957 have passed, economists will seek the answer to these two questions. If in the eyes of the Federal Reserve officials, inflation was the No. 1 problem, it would appear that, in part, it was because the main focus of their attention was on the continuous rise of consumer prices and interest rates. Insufficient attention was given to the fact that the underlying forces which were responsible for the boom and for inflationary pressures were fast becoming contractive influences—if due recognition were given to the time-lags that are operative in these sectors of the economy. This is not a matter of hindsight since there was cumulative evidence that the sidewise movement was more likely to tilt downward rather than upward. The index of industrial production had reached its peak in December 1956 at 147, slipped to 144 in April and May, and remained at 145 from June to August. New orders of manufacturers had been declining ever since the beginning of the year and unfilled orders dropped $6 billion between January and August. The average weekly hours of work in manufacturing was moving downward from 41 hours in December 1956 to 39.7 in July and employment in manufacturing industries was drifting downward in the same period. The index of spot prices of raw materials dropped steadily from 100.4 in December 1956 to 92.1, or a decline of 8 percent in 7 months. Corporate profits had been declining since the fourth quarter of 1956; exports were dropping since March of 1957; and Government contracts were being cut back by midyear. Above all, a number of the before-mentioned indicators and other signs pointed to the tapering off of the boom in the capital goods industries—a boom that had been a major influence in the inflationary pressures of 1956 and early 1957. In view of a rate of expansion of physical plant capacity, especially by manufacturing industries, that was much higher than that of output or sales since the beginning of 1956, this disparity could not continue indefinitely. In the words of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, "the pace of current and planned business investment in capital equipment and in. inventory had already reached such proportions, by 1956, that an eventual 74 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY slowing down for consolidation and reassessment could be considered inevitable." 50 To be sure, there was 51uncertainty as to "the timing and dimensions of such a slackening." But in view of the fact that heavy commitments for capital outlays were made 1 to IK years earlier and that downward revision of investment programs was becoming increasingly evident by mid-1957, the fact that current capital outlays were at peak levels did not signify that a sharp decline in such expectations was not a near prospect. In the light of these developments, the August rise in the discount rate remains inexplicable. When pressed on this point, the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board insisted that the change was "necessary for technical reasons." 52 But what Mr. Martin appeared to ignore was the fact that a sharp hike in the rate was also widely interpreted as indicating that the monetary authorities regarded the intensification of inflationary pressures and the need for continuation of monetary restraint as the immediate issues facing the country. That a change in the discount rate is regarded as a signal to the public of a shift in Federal Reserve policy was expressly stated by the Board of Governors of the System when it lowered the rate in November.53 If it was a54 public signal in November, it must also have been one in August. SOME C O N C L U D I N G OBSERVATIONS The sharp contrast between the deliberations of the Open Market Committee as revealed in the 1957 Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and the public interpretations of their actions, as well as the misunderstandings with respect to the meaning and significance of the August hike in the discount rate, raise the question of the necessity for the secrecy surrounding the decisions of our monetary authorities. This question was raised by Senator Fulbright, Chairman of the Senate Banking and Currency Committee, during the course of interrogating Mr. Martin at the stock market hearings in March 1955. The chairman of the committee asked whether the Board of Governors gives any explanation for its actions when it announces changes in margin requirements. Mr. Martin replied that "Our actions should speak louder than our words. In this particular field, as in most central bank moves, it is by action rather than by announcement and statement that we get our results." 55 Mr. Fulbright then pointed out that failure to furnish an explanation for their moves results in misunderstanding of Federal Reserve policies.56 If the absence of a forthright statement of policy changes resulted in faulty interpretations of Federal Reserve decisions 60 Annual Report, 1957, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, p. 7. «Ibid., p. 7. 82 Federal Reserve Monetary Policies: Hearings before a subcommittee of the Committee on Banking and Currency, U. S. Senate, 85th Cong., 2d sess., February 1958, pp. 24r-25. Senator Douglas' interrogation of Mr. Martin on the necessity for raising the discount rate at the very time when the economy had begun to slip is contained on pp. 20-28. 83 Forty-fourth Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1957, p. 70. The sign-aspect of the discount rate is also indicated in the following quotation from the 1957 Report of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, p. 12: "By mid-November, it was decided to give all sections of the84 economy an unmistakable sign that the direction of credit policy had changed." It is interesting to note that tnere were differences within the System on the advisability of the August rise in the discount rate. "As was to be expected, when the underlying forces of the boom were beginning to wear out, there were differences of view, even within the central bank, over the need for this final overt step in the long sweep of the System's restrictive policy." Annual Report, 1957, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, p. 11. 88 Stock Market Study: Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency, U. S. Senate, 84th Cong., 1st sess., March 1955, p. 571. ««Ibid., p. 572t 75 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY with respect to margin requirements at the beginning of 1955, there were more serious misunderstandings of the more general monetary controls that were exercised after mid-1957. The problem of providing the public with a clearer understanding of Federal Reserve policy changes through prompt publication of explanatory statements is of sufficient importance to warrant serious exploration in the near future. There are other matters of an informational character relating to monetary policy that need strengthening. There have been numerous complaints recently by Federal Reserve officials concerning the adequacy of the statistical tools employed in arriving at policy decisions. The shortcomings of existing data and the need for additional and more timely statistical information essential for the appraisal of changing business conditions have been stressed in recent years by the Joint Economic Committee of57the Congress and by the President's Council of Economic Advisers. Progress toward filling the gaps in our knowledge of the operations of our economy through improvement of the Federal statistical programs depends upon more liberal appropriations for economic statistics. But this does not mean that even with their present resources Government agencies cannot initiate beneficial changes in their statistical programs.58 Our review of the financial and economic developments between 1950 and 1957 has discussed the successes and the inadequacies of monetary policy in promoting economic stability. The shortcomings have been of two kinds: (1) The actual use that was made of the available tools for monetary control; and (2) the limitations inherent in the existing tools. The recent boom followed by the sharpest recession in the postwar period has emphasized once more the necessity of a fundamental reexamination of our financial system with a view to increasing the effectiveness of monetary policy in a stabilization program. The setting up of a National Commission on Money and Credit for a period of 3 years under the auspices of the Committee for Economic Development should result in valuable information and analyses. But the committees of the Congress must continue to inquire into the operations of the Federal Reserve System in the more immediate context of the problems that face the country as the economy moves from expansion to contraction and to resumption of expansion with the probable renewal of inflationary pressures. In the light of the latter eventuality it is well to keep in mind the limitations revealed in the present report with respect to our existing monetary controls and the necessity for considering in the near future methods for strengthening our credit instrumentalities for the promotion of economic growth and stability. ®7 Economic Statistics: Hearings before the Subcommittee on Economic Statistics of the Joint Committee on the Economic Report, 83d Cong., 2d sess., July 1954, 363 pages; Economic Report of the President, January 1958, pp. 91-96. 58 In the field of banking and monetary statistics, for example, it is essential to have easily available compilations of monthly data going back over extended periods of time. The latest extensive compilation in this area published by the Federal Reserve Board in 1943 was Banking and Monetary Statistics, statistics f banking, monetary, and other financial developments, November 1943, 979 pages. APPENDIX MEMBER BANK RESERVES, RESERVE BANK CREDIT, AND R E L A T E D ITEMS, 1950-57 [Averages of daily figures, millions of dollars] Reserve bank credit outstanding U. S. Government securities Period Total 1950—January, February March.. April. .. May June July.... August. September... October NovemberDecember 1951—January. February March.. April... May June July..., August. September October November... December See footnotes at end Bought outright 18,082 18,082 17,705 17,705 17,682 17,682 17,608 17, 571 17,486 17, 486 17,800 17,800 18,129 18,129 18, 328 18,291 18, 946 18,931 19,365 19,364 19,381 19,373 20,345 20,336 20,682 20,699 21,733 21, 703 22,316 22, 333 22,975 22, 970 22,438 22, 395 22,783 22, 797 22,996 23,059 23,035 23,123 23,259 23,171 23,834 23,826 23,364 23,364 23,409 23,310 of table, p. 79 DisHeld counts under and repuradchase vances agreement 37 37 15 1 8 9 17 30 17 5 43 14 63 88 88 8 99 101 178 170 140 116 84 140 172 96 67 145 142 213 330 242 162 438 170 194 292 338 131 343 657 Float 464 425 386 385 400 437 431 375 565 611 631 1,117 924 1,219 1,084 842 806 940 1,026 843 1,062 1,012 1,074 1,375 Total 18,649 18,310 18.242 18,136 18.005 18,325 18,703 18,876 19, 610 20,044 20,159 21, 606 21,839 23,286 23, 663 23,983 23,686 23, 913 24,285 24,263 24, 664 24,982 24 785 25,446 Gold stock 24,420 24,346 24, 311 24,247 24,236 24,231 24,192 23,927 23, 560 23,366 23,157 22,879 22,523 22, 249 21,909 21,806 21, 757 21, 755 21, 757 21,790 21,906 22,104 22,298 22,483 TreasTreasury cur- Currency ury rency in circu- cash holdoutlation ings standing 4.597 4.598 4.600 4.601 4.602 4.605 4.606 4,609 4,613 4,618 4,622 4,629 4,635 4,637 4.639 4.640 4,643 4,647 4,656 4,666 4,674 4,682 4,688 4,701 27,220 27.008 27,043 27,062 27,022 27,026 27,117 27.009 27,154 27,233 27,380 27,806 27,304 27,145 27,171 27,179 27,324 27, 548 27,859 27,951 28,213 28,387 28,612 29,139 1,314 1,310 1, 307 1,313 1.302 1,299 1,305 1, 307 1.303 1,305 1,290 1,290 1,297 1.290 1,289 1,292 1.291 1,286 1,291 1,288 1,284 1,283 1,286 1,280 Deposits, other than member bank reserves, with Federal Reserve banks Nonmember 1 Treasury 472 585 638 695 563 512 549 668 749 590 450 615 368 842 603 632 640 280 405 483 576 451 436 271 Member bank reserves Other Federal Reserve accounts Total Required Foreign Other 1,420 1, 478 1,331 1,250 1,299 1,372 1,481 1,404 1,235 1,367 1,331 1,273 1,199 1,255 1,212 1,252 1,243 1,162 1,158 1,104 1,055 977 867 719 728 752 764 717 759 796 752 740 803 746 739 742 734 730 750 696 731 756 719 721 802 776 796 16,520 16,146 16,081 15,898 15,941 16,194 16,253 16,273 16,602 16, 731 16,742 17,391 18,088 18, 907 19,207 19,324 18,892 19, 309 19,229 19,174 19,396 19,868 19,794 20,310 15, 585 15, 409 15,298 15,204 15, 237 15,426 15,507 15,626 15,837 15,889 16,009 16,364 17,263 18,279 18,494 18,491 18,302 18, 475 18,473 18,470 18, 675 18,952 19,065 19,484 Member bank reserves, reserve bank credit, and related items, 1950-57—Continued oo [Averages of daily figures, millions of dollars] Reserve bank credit outstanding U. S. Government securities Period Total -January February March April May June July August September... October November. . . December... -January February March April May June July August SeptemberOctober. November. __ December. -January February March April May June July August September—. 23,206 22,552 22,634 22,448 22,308 22, 617 22, 798 23,027 23,471 23,657 23,638 24.400 24,202 23,918 23,892 23,861 23,973 24,748 24,955 25,000 25,168 25,344 25,172 25,639 25,263 24,770 24,633 24,635 24,689 24,998 24, 771 23,989 23,941 Bought outright 23,195 22,552 22,626 22,448 22,308 22,505 22, 617 22,983 23,433 23,644 23, 527 23,876 24,011 23,875 23,878 23,806 23,881 24,729 24,943 24,974 25,097 25,341 25,078 25,218 25,149 24,729 24,620 24,632 24,680 24,960 24, 761 23,930 23,928 DisHeld counts and under repuradchase vances agreement 11 8 112 181 44 38 13 111 524 191 43 14 55 92 19 12 26 71 3 94 421 114 41 13 3 9 38 10 59 13 200 365 314 365 573 585 1,092 1,059 723 1,093 1, 577 1, 633 1,372 1,336 1,220 1,184 955 433 428 658 468 367 494 448 118 308 205 151 172 166 104 210 170 Float 1,034 904 937 908 818 936 890 734 856 927 954 1,262 1,008 822 909 843 750 776 737 660 771 800 744 1,018 861 667 712 696 640 710 695 654 725 Total 24,444 23,826 23,890 23, 726 23,704 24,144 24, 786 24,824 25,055 25,681 26,172 27,299 26, 586 26,080 26,025 25,892 25,682 25,960 26,123 26,322 26,410 26,514 26,413 27,107 26,243 25, 746 25, 553 25,483 25,503 25,876 25,571 24,855 24,838 Gold stock 22,824 23,039 23,278 23,293 23,297 23,308 23,348 23,346 23,343 23,340 23,338 23,276 23,101 22, 797 22,606 22, 562 22, 557 22, 514 22,366 22,226 22,176 22,102 22,057 22,028 22,015 21,957 21,963 21,966 21,971 21,927 21,926 21,871 21,809 Deposits, other than member bank reTreasserves, with Federal Other ury Reserve banks TreasFederal cur- Currency ury Reserve rency in circu- cash Nonmember 1 outlation holdacings standcounts ing Treasury Foreign Other 4,709 4,719 4,728 4,737 4,740 4,751 4,756 4,765 4,778 4,788 4,796 4,806 4,814 4,821 4,825 4,832 4,843 4,851 4,853 4,860 4,867 4,873 4,878 4,885 4,891 4,904 4,920 4,941 4,954 4,956 4,959 4,960 4,967 28,637 28,406 28,437 28,459 28, 557 28,843 29,028 29,088 29,343 29, 555 29, 904 30,494 29,920 29, 718 29, 752 29,782 29,869 30,011 30,165 30,167 30,328 30,366 30,555 30,967 30,282 29,903 29,800 29,755 29,773 29,856 29,968 29,896 29,991 1,281 1,294 1,283 1,278 1,281 1,282 1,270 1,276 1,275 1,276 1,278 1,271 1,280 1,299 1,296 1,281 1,279 1,273 1,264 1,273 1, 273 1,274 915 767 778 811 813 825 830 815 810 806 796 109 352 333 549 553 328 306 501 326 550 591 569 552 500 244 395 356 52 545 656 537 557 497 602 201 568 490 584 486 602 498 591 541 J37 601 681 785 766 688 689 745 611 526 530 563 552 566 537 548 538 463 434 466 453 470 494 481 531 553 632 536 522 799 845 875 i£8 242 279 259 231 253 297 290 405 336 378 397 350 203 239 376 354 406 424 390 422 429 352 427 412 321 409 464 431 744 738 790 818 745 767 791 720 721 876 803 832 775 800 841 861 779 933 939 861 871 889 805 908 834 870 913 926 864 941 973 916 929 Member bank reserves Total 20,470 19,995 20,207 19,777 19,767 20,140 20, 535 20,306 20, 514 20,611 20, 744 21,180 20,958 20,520 20,416 20,007 19,897 20,287 19,653 19, 526 19, 552 19, 536 19, 718 19,920 20,179 19,557 19,573 19,392 19,533 19,670 19,164 18,478 18,403 Required Excess 19,537 19,300 19,322 19,127 19,139 19,431 19,926 19,657 19, 736 19,963 20,087 20,457 20,251 19,882 19,828 19,472 19,306 19,499 18,869 18,882 18,834 18,784 19,035 19,227 19,243 18,925 18,881 18,627 18,817 18,813 18,329 17,638 17,628 933 695 885 650 628 709 609 649 778 648 657 723 707 638 588 535 591 788 784 644 718 752 683 693 936 632 692 765 716 857 835 840 775 October November--December 1955—Januar y February March April May June July August September. October—. November- - _ December 1956—Januar y February March April May June July August September. October November.._ December 1957—Januar y February March April May June July August September... October November. __ December 24,485 24,661 24,917 24, 200 23,838 23,619 23,632 23, 666 23,598 23,967 23,886 23, 709 23,951 23,997 24,602 23,897 23,401 23,522 23,410 23,322 23, 522 23,580 23,530 23, 728 23.781 24,024 24,765 24,092 23, 111 23,061 23,239 23,041 22, 989 23,351 23,146 23, 325 23, 348 23,417 23, 982 24,472 24,654 24,888 24,182 23,787 23,604 23,604 23,617 23, 596 23,925 23,870 23, 668 23,881 23, 963 24,318 23,824 23,375 23,449 23,393 23,262 23,486 23, 573 23,488 23,695 23,742 23,951 24,498 24,056 23, 083 22, 997 23,121 22,996 22,917 23,198 23,129 23, 302 23,252 23,276 23, 615 13 7 29 18 51 15 28 49 2 42 16 41 70 34 284 73 254 345 407 444 473 566 585 445 465 576 803 872 895 1,018 840 26 73 17 60 36 7 42 33 39 73 267 36 118 45 72 153 17 23 96 141 367 1,060 971 770 738 898 792 715 745 706 432 665 859 1,036 931 1.009 917 1.010 994 818 810 716 720 769 992 805 710 804 838 798 878 940 746 1,055 1,389 1,152 965 987 925 928 1,206 1,263 910 1,198 1,182 1,300 1,633 1,343 1,106 1,024 1,110 1,046 1,170 1,175 989 1,147 1,143 1,126 1,443 25,459 25,776 26,317 25.449 25,021 24,91" 25,070 24,924 24,958 25,497 25.450 25, 525 25, 792 26,089 26.853 25,879 25,183 25,517 25,411 25,237 25,516 25,599 25,357 25, 737 25,698 26,097 27,156 25, 905 24,912 24,9" 25,411 25,041 25,189 25,466 25,166 25,489 25,326 25,373 26,186 i Nonmember deposits, January 1950-June 1952, represent total of foreign and other. 4,973 4,979 4,982 4,985 4,990 4,996 4,997 4,999 5,001 5,003 5,004 5,006 5,008 5,008 5,008 5,008 5,011 5,013 5,018 5,028 5,033 5,032 5,038 5,043 5,048 5,056 5,064 5,067 5,071 5,081 5,090 5,098 5,106 5,108 5,115 5,121 5,129 5,137 5,144 30,077 30,287 30,749 30,110 29,784 29, 790 29,807 29,861 30,050 30,284 30,289 30,420 30,532 30, 791 31,265 30,620 30,214 30,256 30,245 30,322 30,536 30, 751 30,650 30,803 30,864 31,198 31,775 31,040 30, 595 30, 568 30, 614 30, 645 30, 902 31,116 31,035 31,143 31,109 31,335 31, 932 797 800 805 819 826 823 816 818 825 801 801 797 781 778 777 787 796 783 783 785 778 771 774 772 776 774 772 794 817 812 803 792 782 769 764 763 780 793 768 610 492 443 341 477 690 501 421 329 461 569 540 509 538 434 356 480 532 545 556 485 521 504 523 487 456 463 335 336 423 429 521 490 480 490 547 495 464 385 455 416 439 477 420 363 370 389 412 423 431 386 390 394 459 404 364 349 338 331 315 300 318 356 337 308 372 323 335 316 348 361 393 377 349 378 338 322 345 444 393 365 383 473 442 481 432 345 423 398 392 403 444 394 354 351 350 338 322 304 280 275 237 299 313 247 276 294 216 339 276 290 279 273 271 258 337 186 944 883 929 903 927 960 973 928 959 962 918 968 1,000 937 983 921 973 1,048 1,067 982 991 999 946 946 950 845 998 896 1, 071 1,135 1,195 1,075 1,077 1,048 1,163 1,180 1, 097 1,044 1,063 18,893 19,207 19, 279 19,114 18,819 18,635 18,800 18, 746 18,715 18,824 18,728 18, 711 18,870 18,902 19,240 19,138 18, 709 18,924 18,847 18, 735 18,933 18, 836 18,783 19,024 18,939 19,169 19,535 19, 295 18,816 18,884 19, 087 18, 827 18,982 19,129 18,834 18, 956 19,040 18, 958 19,420 18,173 18,393 18, 576 18,432 18,195 18,050 18,210 18,166 18,146 18,205 18,152 18,148 18,345 18,378 18,646 18,586 18,177 18,340 18,320 18,268 18,359 18,237 18,224 18,446 18,419 18,579 18,883 18, 773 18,302 18,366 18, 580 18, 362 18,485 18,595 18,300 18,434 18, 573 18,447 18,843 720 814 703 682 624 585 590 580 569 619 576 563 525 524 594 552 532 584 527 467 574 599 559 578 520 590 652 522 514 518 507 465 497 534 534 522 467 512 577 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. £ KJ CO COMMENTS OF STAFF OF FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL B O A R D OF G O V E R N O R S OF T H E F E D E R A L R E S E R V E S Y S T E M , Washington, September 15, 1958. Hon. J. W . FULBRIGHT, Chairman, Senate Committee on Banking and Currency, United States Senate, Washington 25, D. C. D E A R S E N A T O R F U L B R I G H T : Thank you for your letter of August 2 6 inviting comments by the Board's staff on the revised draft of the paper, enclosed with your letter, prepared by Dr. Asher Achinstein of the staff of the Legislative Reference Service of the Library of Congress under the heading, "Federal Reserve Policy and Economic Stability, 1951-57." Because we ourselves are continually studying and reviewing System experience to search out the lessons it may hold in guidance for the future, the Board and its staff welcome efforts by others to review System policies and actions critically in development of standards for a more perfect execution of monetary responsibilities. As the attached comments by our staff indicate, however, it is disappointing that this paper, while fully explicit as to the personal evaluation of the author, fails to state what monetary actions may or may not be expected to accomplish in economic stabilization or to set forth any standards for measuring the performance of monetary policy. This omission deprives the reader of a basis for judging either the validity or objectivity of the author's conclusions. The Board will appreciate having the attached comments published in the printed report along with this letter. Sincerely yours, WM. M c C . MARTIN, J r . 81 C O M M E N T S BY T H E S T A F F OF T H E B O A R D OF G O V E R N O R S O F T H E F E D E R A L R E S E R V E S Y S T E M ON T H E R E P O R T " F E D E R A L R E S E R V E P O L I C Y AND E C O N O M I C STABILITY, 1 9 5 1 - 5 7 / ' BY D R . ASHER A C H I N S T E I N OF T H E L E G I S L A T I V E R E F E R E N C E S E R V I C E O F T H E L I B R A R Y OF C O N G R E S S The report has been reviewed with care in recognition that critical evaluation may help toward perfecting the application of monetary policy. From this point of view, the paper suffers from three major defects. First, its economic analysis envisages a more drastic recession in 1958 than actually developed. The author's views were formulated before it was generally realized that the 1957-58 recession had come to an end. Hence, the paper reflects, both explicitly and implicitly, the general foreboding of early last spring that the recession of 1957-58 would be long and severe. The same forebodings were prevalent during the downturn phases of the recessions of 1948-49 and 1953-54. Happily, in all three cases forebodings proved wrong. For the third time in the postwar period, recessionary tendencies in this country have proved to be short-lived adjustments and have been followed by renewed and vigorous expansion. Much of this paper—and particularly the discussion of 1957— would now need revision. For example, from a reading of this document anyone would be surprised to learn that, even before it had been published, the recession of 1957-58 was regarded as among the shortest and mildest (in terms of total man-hours of work lost in the economy as a whole) in American history. Surely, this fact is relevant to any judgment on the precautionary policies pursued by the Federal Reserve System in 1957. There is, and has been, practically no informed opinion among economists that fluctuations in business activity can be entirely eliminated from a free market economy. Accordingly, it is out of focus to concentrate, as does the author, on the fact that fluctuations occurred. The ideal, and aspiration, has been that instability be minimized. The question for objective appraisal is whether or not Federal Reserve policies since 1951 have tended to mitigate or to accentuate economic instability. This question, moreover, must be considered in relation to the actual situation when monetary actions were taken, including any concurrent actions of a stabilizing or destabilizing nature by other Government agencies. Thus considered, a judicious view would surely be that without the monetary actions taken by the Federal Reserve since 1951 the booms would have been more exuberant and the recessions more severe. Second, the author attempts to evaluate the effectiveness of monetary policies without adequate recognition of the principles and guides on the basis of which these policies have been determined, or presentation of an alternative set of standards. As a result, the paper has serious limitations for a reader seeking a balanced appraisal of the effects of Federal Reserve policy. What, for example, should be the 83 84 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY relation of monetary actions to stability or instability in the economy? Also, are Federal Reserve actions the sole factor for stability on the side of public responsibility, or is economic stability also affected by taxing and spending policies, by agricultural policies, and by other public policies such as those that govern the terms and conditions in the insurance and guaranty of home mortgages? If other public policies also influence economic stability, is it not incumbent upon the author to state concretely and definitely his concept of the relative role of monetary policy in the years discussed and to analyze the extent to which monetary policy was aided or vitiated by other public actions? Third, the paper fails to deal adequately with the most persistently grave threat to economic stability during the postwar period—inflation. At some points, it ignores inflation as a problem, and at others it plays down the problem. For example, the paper evaluates Federal Reserve policy actions in 1956-57 as though the economy were not in the grip of an active wage-price spiral. It ignores the growing tendency throughout the economy after mid-1956 to hedge against inflation by incorporating in longer term contracts escalator clauses for higher wage and other costs, and the consequent speeding up of the wage-price spiral. It also ignores the growing tendency on the part of business management in this period to anticipate future construction needs in an effort to avoid expected future increases in construction costs, and the effects of these anticipatory decisions on construction costs and surplus plant capacity. As a result the paper gives inadequate recognition to the effect of the developing inflationary psychosis on the prices of fixedinterest securities, and on the level of long-term interest rates. Expectations of renewed inflation are at least as widespread today as they were in the early summer of 1957. They constitute the major current threat to the continued progress of our recovery. Investors are being urged on all sides to shift their holdings to common stocks as hedges against inflation. This is illustrated by the growth and formation of investment trusts and by the decisions on the part of private pension trusts to increase the proportion of common stocks to bonds held in their portfolios. The sale of bonds—which constitutes the only means for raising market funds to finance public expenditures, State and municipal as well as Federal, and a principal means of financing industrial growth—is being seriously handicapped. Today, prices of common stocks have risen to a point where their average yields are below the yields of senior bonds of the same corporations and at approximately the same level as average yields on United States Government securities. Additional points which may be helpful in reading the paper are: (1) In its criticism of monetary actions through open market and discount operations, no account is taken of the complications caused by Treasury debt management problems and the relation of Treasury refinancing and financing operations to the timing of monetary actions. (2) Unfavorable comments on the use of available instruments for monetary policy are frequently accompanied by favorable comments on the possible revival of regulation of mortgage credit and of consumer credit, the authority for which, as supplementary instruments of credit control, has been discontinued by the Congress. And yet the paper offers no analysis of the problems or limitations of the latter type of instrument. 85 FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND ECONOMIC STABILITY (3) In his detailed comments on restrictive Federal Reserve policy in 1952-53, 1955, and 1957, the author appears to favor a sledgehammer approach of sharper and more rapid actions on the basis of forecasts presumed to be accurate. Perhaps preoccupation with the sledge-hammer approach in applying monetary actions accounts for the author's surprise that the Federal Open Market Committee through the first three quarters of 1957 was weighing meticulously all aspects of the current economic situation in order to detect promptly any evidences of downturn. The Federal Open Market Committee's record was entirely consistent, of course, with the System's public posture of monetary restraint during the period in view of the evidence that the economy was in the grips of a demand-pull cost-push inflation and of the danger that speculative excesses would lead to serious liquidation and severe economic recession. (4) The paper suggests some avenues of inquiry that afford promise, as for example when it takes up in critical vein what it terms certain limitations in the use of the tools of monetary policy, and fiscal and debt management policy, for promoting economic stability. However, the inquiry does not go beyond recognizing that the fallibility in foreseeing the future that attends all forms of human endeavor extends to monetary policy. Indeed, the author makes the point that monetary policy has unusual virtues, at least in comparison with fiscal policy and debt management policy, in that its flexibility enables the monetary authorities to minimize errors of diagnosis by more speedily steering a different course to meet changing conditions. o