View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Interview with James Bullard
Conducted by Karen Branding, David Wheelock
July 26, 2023
Branding:

Today is Wednesday, July 26, 2023. And we're with President Jim Bullard, who on July
13th announced his upcoming departure from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis to
become inaugural dean of the Mitchell E. Daniels, Jr. School of Business at Purdue
University on August 15th, 2023.
Mean�me, President Bullard sat down with us today to have a discussion about his
experiences as President of the St Louis Fed for the past 15 years and his overall 33-year
tenure at the bank.
Let's start with introduc�ons. My name is Karen Branding. I'm the Senior Vice President
of External Engagement and Corporate Communica�ons and the Bank's corporate
secretary. Dave.

[00:00:44]
Wheelock:

I'm David Wheelock. I'm an economist and Senior Vice President and senior policy
adviser in the office of the President of the Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis.

[00:00:53]
Branding:

Jim.

[00:00:54]
Bullard:

I'm Jim Bullard. Up un�l recently, I was president and CEO of the Federal Reserve Bank of
St Louis. Now I'm depar�ng.

[00:01:03]
Branding:

Well, let's get started. Okay. By way of background, Jim, tell us about how you came to
join the St Louis Fed, your posi�on at that �me and how your role has evolved over your
33-year career at the Bank?

[00:01:18]

Page 1 of 20

Bullard:

Uh, I came to the Bank from Indiana University, where I got my Ph.D. There's an annual
job market for PhDs. I had many interviews at that job market, over 30, as I recall, some
of them elsewhere in the Federal Reserve. But the St Louis Fed made me the best offer,
and so I came and joined the staff here as a staff economist. So, it was a good place to
work at that �me, and s�ll is, but it had a good combina�on of plenty of �me to do
research but also a policy angle to it. So that appealed to me as a budding Ph.D.
researcher.

[00:02:09]
Branding:

Mm hmm. Well, now, let's fast forward a bit. When you became president in early 2008,
the Federal Reserve was just beginning to grapple with the financial crisis. The Federal
Reserve responded with a variety of new programs, as well as a vigorous monetary
policy response that set the stage for a long recovery. Can you tell us about your
experience as a member of the Federal Open Market Commitee, the FOMC, at the �me,
and what the Fed learned from that episode?

[00:02:38]
Bullard:

Yeah, I became president of the Bank in April 2008, and I would refer listeners to this to
a slide deck that I have called the Notorious Summer of 2008, because it was a key
moment in U.S. macroeconomic history.
But I'll give you just a gist of what was going on at that �me as I joined. I think one thing
to keep in mind is that I'd been on the research staff for 18 years before I became
President, and I was also FOMC Class I, which is sort of the top level as far as monetary
policy is concerned.
And so, I was I had access to the key monetary policy documents and discussion all the
way through the 1990s and up un�l 2000–and up un�l the present, really. So, when I
came in in 2008 as President, the crisis had already been going on for some �me. The
crisis really started in August, in earnest, in August of 2007, and to be specific, August
9th and 10th of 2007.
That's the point where the Fed really went into emergency mode as far as the global
financial crisis was concerned. That's the those are the days where the major banks of
the world started to distrust each other. And that is the hallmark of that par�cular crisis.
So, the Fed had taken ac�ons in the fall of 2007, and especially in the winter of
2007/2008, when interest rates were lowered drama�cally.
And by the �me you got to the spring of 2008, you know, you were already nine months
or so, eight months into the crisis, there was a Bear Stearns event right around that
�me. And I was named president shortly a�er that. I actually had a call with then Chair
Ben Bernanke at the �me. So, the way this works is it's all very quiet when, you know,
Page 2 of 20

you're going through the search process and, you know, it's announced at 10:00 and
then at 10:30, the chair gives you a call.
And I knew Ben Bernanke from the academic world and from �mes that we had dinner
together and done other things. And so, I was expec�ng him to say that, “Hey, welcome
to the Fed, glad you're joining the team,” you know. But instead, he told me all about the
Bear Stearns deal and the mezzanine notes and the special arrangements that have been
made. So, I think I've always told that story because I think it reflects the intensity of the
�mes and the intensity of the crisis that, you know, Bear Stearns was such a major play.
[00:06:00]
Now, basically, the Fed intervened in that one. And I've since been saying that the
problem with the global financial crisis was that the Bear Stearns interven�on was prety
successful. And it gave a sense of complacency that that could be repeated if one of the
other investment banks had significant problems.
That turned out to be an inaccurate view. But that was the view that was held during the
notorious summer of 2008, that if Lehman was going to have trouble, that you'd be able
to play the same trick again. You'd be able to get a marriage partner for Lehman, and
then you'd be able to escape serious problems because that's what happened in the
Bear Stearns case.
Also, I think in the summer of 2008, it was possible to argue that the U.S. was not in
recession. The real �me data said that the U.S. economy was not in recession at that
�me. There was not nega�ve GDP growth. And it was also possible to say that because
the crisis had been going on for a year and we had taken lots of ac�on, that it was
possible that we'd skate through and avoid recession. That was a typical thing that was
being said in early August of 2008, which was one year anniversary of the crisis itself.
That all came unraveled. I think the reason that became unraveled was because in the
mean�me, during that year, oil prices had doubled all the way up to $145 a barrel. And
that slowed down the economy in other ways. And then that slowdown made the
financial crisis much, much worse. You got the failures of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac,
and then later Lehman did have further difficul�es and collapsed. And then you found
out about AIG on top of that. And so, then the risk of recession was really on at that
point.
But I think that the ini�al thinking right around that �me was that in the summer and in,
let's say, early August 2008, was the idea that the Fed had taken lots of ac�on, that the
crisis had been going on for a year, firms had had �me to adjust, and if something
further did happen, you could play the Bear Stearns card again.
And most of that came unraveled in the fall—all of that came unraveled in the fall of
2008. So, then the crisis was really on and the recession is usually dated to December

Page 3 of 20

2007. But if you look at it, it was far more serious when you got to the third quarter and
fourth quarter of 2008 and beyond that.
So, it was a difficult �me, obviously, for the FOMC and a fascina�ng �me to get bap�zed
as incoming president.

[00:09:09]
Branding:

Well, just a follow up ques�on to that. Do you think that that experience in the Fed's
response to it, did it help the Fed in some ways prepare for what it had to go through
with COVID and the pandemic?

[00:09:22]
Bullard:

COVID is a different shock. It was, you know, I think one thing to stress is that the global
financial crisis originated on Wall Street and reverberated around the world, whereas
COVID was nature driving health problems all across the world. And so, it was a very
different and more out—it's a shock origina�ng outside the financial system, I suppose,
at the heart of the financial system.
So, in some ways it's the polar opposite of what happened during the Global Financial
Crisis. However, we did pull out many of the same ideas from the Global Financial Crisis
response playbook to respond to the pandemic. And I think one of the best things that
happened was that those ac�ons forestalled a financial crisis that could have occurred in
March and April of 2020, but did not occur.
The measures of financial stress during March and April of 2020 rivaled those of 2008.
So, as far as the amount of stress in the financial system, is almost as bad or just as bad
in March and April of 2020 as it was in 2008. But, because of all these rapid ac�ons that
were taken jointly with the U.S. Treasury, we were able to forestall a financial crisis that
could have occurred on top of the pandemic. And that was one of the great success
stories about the pandemic.
One of the things that we did locally here during the pandemic era is we provided lots
and lots of analysis right around in March and April of 2020, some of the best analysis I
think that existed at that �me about the effects of the pandemic on the economy.
We had an analysis that was the predic�on about what would happen in sort of the
May-June �meframe. So, you had March and April of 2020, and you basically had people
predic�ng that the Great Depression was upon us. But what actually happened was that
May and June were quite strong and one of the manifesta�ons of that was that the
May—let's see, April, March, April, May, yeah—the May jobs report was going to come
out in June, the first week of June of 2020.

Page 4 of 20

And Wall Street thought that it would be -10 million. So, ridiculously large job loss that
they were predic�ng. We had an analysis here that said it would be plus a couple of
million. So, we actually didn't know what to make of it when I first saw that. But as it
turned out, that was accurate. So, Wall Street was totally wrong.
So, this is a miss of like, you know, epic propor�ons, biblical propor�ons. As far as a miss
on that par�cular jobs report. We got that. Our analysis here got that exactly right. And
so that was a big success story. I remember si�ng—of course, you couldn't talk to
anybody, you're all remote during the pandemic—but I remember si�ng on my porch
and reading that, and then I sent email to all the researchers in the whole Federal
Reserve System and said, “Hey, maybe you beter pick up this analysis and take a look at
it.”
So, that was—I would say I just put that anecdote in there as an illustra�on that, you
know, we do a lot of very serious basic research that's headed for journals and stuff, but
we also turn around and do great and �mely research about current policy issues.

[00:13:35]
Branding:

Thanks, Jim. One other thing before I turn it over to Dave is, you know, throughout your
�me as President, you made transparency and public outreach priori�es for your
communica�on strategy interna�onally, domes�cally and across our seven state Federal
Reserve district.
So, talk more about the importance that you put on communica�ons and the role it
plays for the monetary policymaker.

[00:13:58]
Bullard:

Yeah, we've done a lot of outreach. We've had a very careful, carefully designed
outreach strategy, especially for the district, but also na�onally and interna�onally. You
know, former Chair Bernanke once quipped that monetary policy is 98% talk and 2%
ac�on, and he's very right about that. That sounds crazy if you're not involved in it. But
that comes from the idea that most of what's going on is a shaping of expecta�ons
about future policy.
And it's those expecta�ons about future policy that feed back to actual decision making
today by businesses and households. So, in some ways, a lot of monetary policy is
actually this guidance about how are we going to play this going forward. Of course, you
have uncertain�es abound and all kinds of things are happening in the macroeconomy
at any point in �me. So, this requires a con�nuous nurturing and a con�nuous process to
keep the expecta�ons consistent with what's happening in the economy.

Page 5 of 20

So, I think it's been a great development, and I credit former Chair Bernanke in
unleashing the transparency revolu�on for the Federal Reserve and changing the
a�tude from the Volcker-Greenspan Era. And Greenspan did do some things in the in
the realm of transparency, but Bernanke did a lot more.
And you’ve set up now a system where FOMC and other central bank policymaking
commitees are very ac�ve in constantly communica�ng their current posi�on and their
expected future posi�on as part of the normal course of how to conduct monetary
policy. I also think the FOMC, being the most powerful commitee in global finance and
being a member of that commitee, it's incumbent that you talk to people both on Main
Street in your local jurisdic�on, also to people na�onally, understand na�onal trends and
businesses, some of which might not be in your par�cular district or your par�cular area,
but also interna�onally.
The Fed is very important all across the globe, and I think it's important to, at least at
�mes, be in other loca�ons around the world so that you can get a sense of what's going
on in Asia, what's going on in Europe, and even other parts of the world that are up and
coming, such as the Middle East, La�n America, Africa and elsewhere.
So, you know, it's when you're outside the country, you just can't realize how important
the FOMC is for everybody all around the world.

[00:17:05]
Branding:

You know, just to follow up on that, you know, I would say that you were out front on the
transparency revolu�on in the Fed. You know, the nature of your communica�ons in
2008 was probably a bit untradi�onal or nontradi�onal for Fed policymakers back then.
For example, you know, you talk to media frequently and in giving public presenta�ons
on your policy views, you moved away from the Fed's typical approach of a prepared
long speech in favor of PowerPoint presenta�ons. So, explain how that approach helped
facilitate your broader strategy in terms of transparency in communica�ons.

[00:17:43]
Bullard:

Well, I think in an interview or a fireside chat, you can talk more conversa�onally with
people. And if you have enough confidence in in your posi�ons and in your views, then I
think you can get them across in those kinds of se�ngs, in those kinds of formats.
I liked using the PowerPoint presenta�on partly because a picture is worth a thousand
words. I think that's one aspect of it. But also, you can summarize the presenta�on in a
few bullet points at the beginning and the end, and those are o�en the things that will
get picked up in the media as the summary statement. But you've designed the
summary statements, so that you get the thing picked up in the right way. If you write a
Page 6 of 20

long speech, it's harder to predict. It's harder for reporters, I think, to know what exactly
you want to say here, because you're summarizing so much informa�on in a verbose
way.
So, I think also a part of our brand is to provide background and detail and data. And,
you know, by using other formats, more lengthier formats, we did Wharton Radio and
other things, you know, hour-long format. So, these are places where you can talk in
more detail about maybe tangen�al issues or more minor issues with respect to
monetary policy, instead of just talking about the absolute headline, you know, what's
infla�on today or what's the interest rate going to do today.
So, you know, macroeconomics is a complicated subject; you're talking about tens of
trillions of dollars globally every single day. Many hundreds of trillions probably in assets
being traded every day. So, you can't summarize all that in just, you know, a few words.
So, you have to have some more expansive formats in order to be able to talk about
things in more detail.

[00:19:54]
Wheelock:

So, Jim, let me pursue this this line about communica�on. So, you are recognized as a
par�cularly influen�al member of the FOMC. So, in your experience, what’s the best way
to influence the FOMC? Is it primarily through speeches and interviews or more through
your statements at the actual FOMC mee�ngs?

[00:20:15]
Bullard:

Yeah, I think I guess I have a two-prong answer to this.
One part is to recognize and admit that U.S. monetary policy is being debated 365 days a
year, 24 hours a day through global media. And most of the par�cipants in this debate
are actually not the people on the commitee, but the people in financial markets. They
have posi�ons that they're arguing for, and they have books of business that they're
arguing for.
So, I love them and a lot of them are former Fed people. But on the other hand, they're
not the actual policy makers and they should not by themselves be shaping actual
monetary policy decisions. So, I think, in order to have a successful policy, you have to
have ways to talk from the policymakers’ perspec�ve about the monetary policy debate
and what the policy is trying to accomplish, not necessarily what the private sector
would like to accomplish.
And so, this sets up a 24-hour-a-day, a global debate going on, which I love, I love the
debate. And this is, this is how it works. But I think you should just admit that from the
beginning that that's what's going on and that's how it works.
Page 7 of 20

So, you have to par�cipate in that. I think it's great to have a big commitee because you
can have many people have various events at various �mes. A lot of those events are
scheduled way ahead of �me. But on a given day they can say, “Well, I thought the jobs
report was, you know, it was a litle weaker than I expected” or “I thought—I've changed
my view slightly. And now I think, you know, rate should go up a litle bit more.” That's
part of the daily kind of adjustment in monetary policy.
And I think it's great to have a big commitee. It's too much for the chair. The chair has,
does a great job but has certain junctures where the chair can do the communica�on on
behalf of the en�re commitee. But individual members can give their own views in
various formats and various places as you go through the year.
The other part of this is that the mee�ng itself—which is a great thing, a great
checkpoint—but the mee�ng is just one day out of these 365 days. And so, and it's a big
formal mee�ng. And so, you can't really expect the chair to allow, you know, a kind of
wild conversa�on. And we're not sure how the mee�ng is going to come out. It all has to
be prety much set by the �me you get to the mee�ng. It’s too big a group and too
heavy of consequences to have that not be lined up ahead of �me. So, that means that
when you actually get to the mee�ng, what you're going to do on that par�cular day is
usually prety clear and most of the debates about, I think, is about the future moves in
policy, not at that par�cular mee�ng, but in the subsequent mee�ngs to that.
So, it is a good checkpoint. It is a good place to hear everyone's views and it's good for
everyone to sort of look at the same data on the same day and make sure they're all on
the same—that they understand everyone else's posi�ons at that point in �me, and
especially the chair's posi�on. But I don't think you can really have expecta�ons that
you're going to come into the mee�ng thinking it's going to go one way and then it's
going to go quite a different way.
[00:23:53]
The commitee does get into trouble some�mes when there's a lot of financial market
vola�lity, right as you're trying to go into the mee�ng. That some�mes upsets the plans
for the mee�ng and can lead to a bit of chaos. I can think of two instances in par�cular
that I some�mes cite.
One is August 2011 where—you can check the transcript—Chair Bernanke came in at
the beginning of the mee�ng, said, “We're going to have to do something different than
what I previously thought.” People were taken by surprise. It was a hot debate. He got
three dissents on the day, and it was unclear whether that was really a good policy
choice or not. We spent a long �me unraveling that par�cular policy choice over the
next 18 months.
Another one was the June 2013 ‘taper tantrum’ mee�ng; I think that one also was a bit
chao�c. The transcript is out about that. Again, you had unclear direc�on coming from
financial markets and or even the chair as you came into that mee�ng and kind of split
Page 8 of 20

commitee and didn't go well. Over the summer real interest rates went up by 100 basis
points and it caused tremendous disloca�on around the world. I dissented on that one. I
thought it was a good dissent on the day, that we should have had a sharper policy
there. We were downgrading our outlook for the economy and for infla�on, but we
nevertheless said that we were going to have a more hawkish policy, basically on that
day. So, I didn't think it was a good one, and I dissented on that one.
So, there are cases where the commitee does make adjustments more on the fly, but
it's not basically it's probably not best prac�ce. Some�mes you get you get forced into it.
We also had just one other dimension is the Sunday March 15th mee�ng in 2020. You
know, the commitee was already planning to meet two days later, but because of the
pandemic, you know, things were moving so quickly that, no, we had to move it up to an
all-day mee�ng on Sunday and try to announce before close of business, before Asian
markets opened on Sunday, that the commitee had lowered the policy rate all the way
to, 100 basis points on the day, all the way to zero.
And so, the commitee did agree with that. But it does show that you can move quickly if
necessary. And the commitee is willing, and Jay was willing to respond to developments
in a �mely manner. And that one was probably the fastest moving of all.

[00:26:42]
Wheelock:

I've got a couple more ques�ons about the actual mee�ng itself and how you approach
the mee�ng.
So, I o�en remember hearing you say that the purpose of your remarks at an FOMC
mee�ng is not so much about today's policy, but about se�ng up future policy or
influencing the debate about the future mee�ngs. Is that a fair characteriza�on, and
what were you trying to accomplish with your statements at FOMC mee�ngs?

[00:27:07]
Bullard:

Yeah, I think last I was just saying the mee�ng itself, it's very formal.
It's not at �mes it's been a litle bit more open and other �mes a litle bit more sedate, I
would say. But it is a moment where you get to hear everyone's statements and
posi�ons, kind of see where everybody's at. If you're following this all the �me, you can
detect subtle�es and changes in people's posi�ons and how they interpret various
pieces of data that have come in in recent days or during the intermee�ng period.
And so, it is useful, but it's not really a point where you can change the decision on that
par�cular day. But I think you can have tremendous influence on monetary policy by
leading the discussion over the 365-day mee�ng that's occurring all year long, and
especially if—on certain occasions, I do think that the commitee gets out of line with
Page 9 of 20

reality and you start to get too much groupthink going in a certain direc�on and that's a
good moment for individual members to call that out and to make the case that maybe
we should be doing something a litle bit different.
I also think that the big commitee is extremely helpful in the sense that you have
presidents who are not inside the Beltway or in New York City. They can play the role of
muses in the sense that they can introduce poten�al policies that might be beneficial in
the future but might not be ini�ally considered to be, you know, that useful on the day.
So, I think that, the example I liked—I think I did some of this—but the example I like to
give is my colleague Charlie Evans, who had the idea about thresholds, and we should
during the twenty-teens, he was sugges�ng that we should not raise the policy rate un�l
certain condi�ons were met with respect to unemployment or infla�on.
And when he first gave those speeches, he was the only one that was talking about that.
And he developed that posi�on. About six months later, those started to show up in
policy alterna�ves. About six months a�er that, they actually got adopted as actual
policy. So that was a case where you had Evans playing the role of muse saying, “Well,
here's a way that we could make our policy more state con�ngent.” And ini�ally, you
know, no one, I didn't even know what he was talking about. But then a�er a while that
actually became policy. So that shows you how if the chair can't do that, the chair can't
just muse about “well, hey, maybe we could do this, maybe we could do that,” because
the chair has too big a microphone and it would be too jarring to introduce that kind of
idea suddenly.
So, the role was to socialize the idea and then shepherd it through to a policy outcome.
So, I did some things that were like that, but that's a clear example of the role I think
that the presidents can play.

[00:30:29]
Wheelock:

So, you men�oned a minute ago about dissen�ng at a couple of mee�ngs, and I'm
interested in your view about policy dissents and whether there's a strategic role in
dissents. You know, as you know, some members of the commitee dissented serially,
several �mes in a row, whereas other members never dissent.

[00:30:48]
Bullard:

Yeah.

[00:30:49]

Page 10 of 20

Wheelock:

I think by my count, you dissented four �mes. I could get the number wrong. But. Well,
you know, what's the strategy? What's the threshold there? And is there a reason to
dissent other than just… [Talking over each other].

[00:31:00]
Bullard:

Yeah, I mean, I respect my colleagues, but generally speaking, I think the idea that, you
know, monetary policy took a wrong turn, you know, three years ago and therefore
we're totally on the wrong track, and, you know, should be doing something totally
different—without ar�cula�ng that more, more clearly, I don't think it's that effec�ve to
say that we're just totally on the wrong planet, as far as monetary policy. I think it's far
more effec�ve—I would recommend for anybody coming on of the commitee in the
future that if you want to dissent, you should dissent for a good reason on that
par�cular decision on that par�cular day and say, “this is not what you should be doing
on this day.” And then you're ready to come back at the next mee�ng and say, well, the
commitee could make the right decision at the next mee�ng, and you're ready to work
with your colleagues there. So, I think, you know, it could be that you'd have mul�ple
dissents in a row. But I think it’s probably most effec�ve to just have this idea about, you
know, on this day, I didn't think that the policy choice was the right one.
Now, I was going to say something else about this which is now slipping my mind. Oh, I
was going to say that the idea of dissen�ng also is losing value, and probably isn't that
informa�ve because people give their own views and their own speeches in between
the mee�ngs. So, if you come out of the mee�ng and you're kind of lukewarm on a
par�cular decision, then that's going to come out in the speech that you give. And does
it really mater if you actually dissented at the mee�ng or even if you were actually
vo�ng at the mee�ng? You know, you could say, and I have done it where I said, “well, if
it had been up to me, I wouldn't have done it that way. I would have done it this other
way.” And so, since everyone's giving their views all the �me, which is part of the
transparency juggernaut unleashed by Bernanke. What does it really mater, you know, if
you formally dissented or not? How important is that really? You also had the specter of
Kevin Warsh going along with a decision at one point and then coming out with an op ed
the next day saying he actually opposed the decision.
So, I think it's great. It's a very collegial organiza�on. And I do think it's great that the
organiza�on rallies around the chair. The chair does a great job of trying to split
differences between people on the commitee. But since you have all the views of
everyone on the commitee, if they're communica�ng regularly, observers can assess for
themselves. Here's where the commitee's at; here's the arguments that the different
people are making. And they can assess for themselves about what that means for the
future direc�on of monetary policy.

[00:34:13]
Page 11 of 20

Branding:

Jim, at the �me of your re�rement announcement, you were the longest si�ng Reserve
Bank president and FOMC par�cipant, 15 years, and you’ve been at the Fed for more
than 30. During that �me, a lot of the history that you’ve covered so far, including being
part of the centennial commemora�ons, and I think about that �me, at least that I’ve
been here throughout your presidency, you’ve kept Fed history and the Bank’s legacy in
front of us.
The Bank has a reputa�on as a historic leader on monetary policy. So, I’d like to hear
more. How do you see the St Louis Fed’s role historically and did your percep�ons about
that role change at all during your presidency?

[00:34:57]
Bullard:

I see the St Louis Fed as part of the world's leading central bank, but it's an iconic part of
the world's leading central bank. It has a great tradi�on of suppor�ng economic
research. This was the first Bank to sort of get serious about academic style research
inside the central bank. That model was later copied, especially in Minneapolis, but now
all around the Federal Reserve System. You've got very powerful research groups in
Chicago and San Francisco and elsewhere around the system. So, what was once
innova�ve and unusual became commonplace throughout the system and not only in
the in the U.S., but now around the world, as has become standard in central banks to
have very good research teams that sort of straddle the academic literature and the
literature that you would read in the economic journals, and also the day-to-day policy
issues that central banks face. So, it's iconic in that sense.
And also, our emphasis on data, data collec�on and the power of understanding the
facts is something that was unusual in, let's say, in 1958 when Homer Jones originally
came here, but became more and more commonplace over �me. And now is epitomized
by our FRED and friends database that’s free for all users around the world.
And I think there's s�ll blue sky ahead for that, that could expand even further, and we
could do even more in that dimension. But, you know, to open up the Wall Street Journal
every day and say, you know, look at a chart and it says St Louis Fed. I think that that
shows that we're the people that are dedicated central bankers who, we know the
history, we know the nity grity, we know all arguments, we know all the data. We're
sort of at the center of the ac�on, not that there aren't other great players. There
certainly are across the country, across the Fed, across academia and around the world.
But we're sort of, you know, the leader for the system, I think on sort of understanding
central banking in a scien�fic sense and trying to get to beter policy through that
channel.
So, there are certainly other iconic places in central banking. The Bank of England comes
to mind, a 350-year history, and others. But I think we can rival many places around the
world, and I think that's part of what makes it a great place to work.
Page 12 of 20

[00:38:09]
Branding:

Well, you talk about FRED, and that brings up the topic of innova�on. And during your
�me as the CEO of the Bank. One of your priori�es was to encourage innova�on at all
level levels of the Bank. You created an innova�on ini�a�ve, and you created the
President’s award for innova�on. You know, why do you see innova�on as important for
the Bank?

[00:38:31]
Bullard:

So, you're working for a public ins�tu�on that does not have a botom line.
And in business, it’s that botom line that usually spurs the innova�on. Sales are down,
you beter figure out a way to get sales up or else you're going to have to lay people off
or shrink your business. And we don't have that. So, I think it's incumbent upon the
management of the Bank to create incen�ves to innovate, even in an environment
where you don't have that profit mo�ve or that botom line.
So, that's what the President's Awards were about. I think another aspect of it is that
we're part of a federal system. We're just one part of that system. We want to find a role
to play within that system that makes sense for the St Louis Fed, but also provides great
service back to the central bank as a whole.
I think we’ve found many ways to do that. We've created many brands during my tenure,
and I like this idea of branded things. They might be a small group, might be four people,
might be ten people, but you're doing something for the system as a whole that isn't
ge�ng done elsewhere and is important to the system as a whole.
And I think that's the kind of innova�on that we've been looking for. And we again, we
have many of these across the system. Of course, the Treasury func�on has grown
drama�cally. It was at one �me four people. It's now over 500 people. So just shows you
the kind of exponen�al growth we've had there. But that's not the only one that has
grown over �me. And I think we've got many smaller businesses that will prove to be
even more important going forward. And we'll set the St. Louis Fed up for a great
performance over the next couple of decades.

[00:40:29]
Branding:

Jim, you talked a few minutes ago about the COVID pandemic and how it changed many
things. So especially I'm thinking how people work and how the economy works.
What were some of the biggest impacts of the pandemic that you had to deal with as
CEO of the Bank?

Page 13 of 20

[00:40:47]
Bullard:

Yeah, the pandemic was, you know, unan�cipated and a very special situa�on. I think
the unprecedented nature of the health threat and trying to somehow get, come to
grips about how to handle the health aspect of it, but s�ll get our work done. I think the
Bank did a great job partly because we had a great Bank culture going into the pandemic
and we knew each other going into the pandemic, that we were able to do much of our
work during the first phases of the pandemic knowing each other. But the pandemic
also, you know, we had built, we spent a lot of �me on Bank culture. A lot of that was
sort of personal interac�on and making sure that we knew each other and interacted a
lot. I think gradually the pandemic eroded that and we're just now trying to earn that
back and win that back. I think, you know, we hired hundreds of people during the
pandemic. They came in as virtual workers and weren't used to the pre-pandemic
culture that won best workplace awards in 2016 and in 2018, I guess. And so now we
have to think about how to rebuild that culture. I think we're doing that. But it's been a
long process.
It's not just us. It's all of corporate America that is struggling with these issues. We're not
against technology. We certainly love remote technology, and we try to be very
innova�ve in that dimension and use it effec�vely. But we also want a great high
performing organiza�on that has great in-person interac�on.

[00:42:39]
Wheelock:

Jim, I'd like to loop you back to monetary policy and the FOMC. So, at the FOMC,
there've been a number of big changes over your 15 years as President. Now we have
the chair giving press conferences a�er every mee�ng; there was the introduc�on of the
summary of economic projec�ons or SEP; the publica�on of a statement on long run
goals and monetary policy strategy, among other innova�ons. Which ones stand out as
par�cularly important in your mind and influen�al for monetary policy going forward?

[00:43:09]
Bullard:

Yeah, I would say that I was a big advocate of the chair giving press conferences. I
thought we should meet an interna�onal standard on that; we were one of the later
holdouts there. That it has happened now. So, the chair does give a press conference at
every mee�ng. I think, again, that's part of the transparency ini�a�ve unleashed by
Chair Bernanke.
But I think the biggest innova�on was the se�ng of infla�on target in 2012, I chaired a
small group of presidents in the first half of 2011, and at that point, Chair Bernanke
wanted to get an infla�on target but didn't really have a mechanism for how to do it. We
Page 14 of 20

started to talk, and the group spanned the dovish spectrum and the hawkish spectrum
of the commitee, but the whole group was in favor of trying to get an infla�on target in
place. That led to a provisional statement, which eventually became the statement of
long-run goals for the commitee in January of 2012. So, we ini�ally got support from all
the presidents, took it to the Board of Governors, eventually got the support of the
Governors as well. So that was the—
So, I think that the 2012 statement, it says a lot of things, but the main thing it says is
that the U.S. will have an infla�on target of 2%. That meets an interna�onal standard.
Other central banks all around the world had done this sooner. We were laggard on this.
There's no reason we shouldn't have done it even sooner. But this was a mechanism for
actually ge�ng this in place and realizing Ben Bernanke's goal of naming an infla�on for
the U.S.
I think that served us well, both during the period when infla�on was consistently
running below the 2% target. It forced the commitee to ask and answer ques�ons about
why are you allowing infla�on to be below target for such a long period of �me? Why
aren't you doing more to get infla�on to move toward target? And aren't you at risk of
becoming Japan? Japan has missed its infla�on target for about a quarter of a century
depending on how you measure it. So, you know, with kind of a ques�onable
consequences for the Japanese economy.
So on the other hand, when infla�on did take off post-pandemic and in 2021, the 2%
infla�on target again gave us an anchor to hold on to and to refer to repeatedly and the
commitee has certainly been completely united, as far as I know, on this subject, and
has repeatedly said, well, you know, we have an infla�on target, it is a credible infla�on
target, and we intend to get back to that.
And it's that credibility itself that will help us get infla�on back to 2%. As I'm talking
today, at least headline infla�on, which at one point I guess was over 9% on an annual
basis, now down to about 3% on an annual basis. So, if you look at just the headline
number anyway, it seems to have been very successful.
There are other aspects of that debate that are going on now. But if you just look at that
graph, it certainly looks like the 2% infla�on target has helped us enormously as we've
tried to navigate the post-pandemic world.

[00:47:11]
Wheelock:

So, let me throw you a curve ball and ask a follow up ques�on. Are there any changes
you'd like to see the FOMC make that it hasn't made? What would improve the process?

[00:47:21]

Page 15 of 20

Bullard:

Yeah, I think the main thing here is the summary of economic projec�ons which was put
in place rather quickly, I thought, and with maybe not enough, the a�tude at the �me
was, “Oh, we'll try this out and then we can modify it going forward,” but once it got in
place, it proved very hard to modify and you s�ll have a situa�on where it's unclear if
the summary of economic projec�ons can be changed in any meaningful way because of
many factors around it.
So, you know, the various pieces of the summary are not linked together. So, you're not
sure which unemployment forecast is supposed to go with which infla�on forecast or
which interest rate forecast. It's you know, you've got this chart about dots. These are,
the �ming is off. The �ming is on an annual basis. So that as you go through the year, the
�meline gets shorter for the current year.
You've got this problem that the September SEP is basically predic�ng what's going to
happen at the November and December mee�ngs, which is very weird. You're basically
plo�ng out exactly what you're going to do without knowing what the date is going to
be over that period. That has goten us into trouble a few �mes when the data doesn't
cooperate or doesn't go in the right direc�on compared to what people were thinking in
September. So, I think that's something that would require a lot of effort. Different
people have looked at it and kind of stayed away from trying to change it. And so, we're
kind of stuck with subop�mal arrangement on that.
I think one aspect of this is that the staff forecasts could be published and that is what
other central banks do. And we have not done that in the US, although it seems like
aspects of the staff forecasts do seem to be ge�ng into the press more than they were
historically. So maybe there will be a trend toward releasing a more official forecast from
the Federal Reserve than just the dot plot.
Also, the dot plot gets stale very fast. As soon as new informa�on comes in, 30 days
later, people are already changing their posi�ons slightly from what they would have
been at the �me of the dot plot. So, if that's what's going on, then why aren’t you
upda�ng on a more a more con�nuous basis? So many aspects to this, but I think the
idea of the dot at the �me was to signal that the commitee was really serious about
keeping interest rates low and not going to raise interest rates any �me soon, given that
infla�on was below target.
And in that sense, it was successful. But once you're away from that situa�on, it's not so
clear that the SEP is playing the same role that it played at that �me and now it's maybe
at �mes has caused more problems than it solved. So that's a major challenge for the
commitee going forward and there's not an easy solu�on.

[00:50:40]

Page 16 of 20

Wheelock:

So, you were out front in arguing for state dependent monetary policy, the aggressive
use of large-scale asset purchases, par�cularly to avoid a low infla�on trap and other
things. And I'm wondering to what extent were your policy views informed by your
research? You're a prominent macroeconomic researcher, well published. How do you
view the role of research, par�cularly in shaping your own personal policy views?

[00:51:09]
Bullard:

Yeah, I mean, on the issue of the trap that the Japanese seem to have goten in over the
last 25 years, I think it's been a crucible for the macroeconomics profession and the
monetary policy component of the macro profession, because no one seems to have a
very good explana�on.
But this is a case where I think there is a piece of literature that’s purely theore�cal, or at
least the ini�al atempts at it, were purely theore�cal. It's been Benhabib, SchmitGrohé, and Uribe papers on The Peril of Taylor Rules, which is about 20 years old now.
But they, you know, you might say, well, this is dressed up in and some all these
theore�cal arguments, but it’s actually a very simple argument if you if you pick it apart.
And it suggests that there definitely is an equilibrium, not just a temporary situa�on, but
a long-run equilibrium that would have infla�on be very low and nominal interest rates
be very low, and that this could persist prety much indefinitely.
And the refusal, I would say, within the Federal Reserve system and across the
profession to acknowledge this equilibrium—these are published papers in major
journals and major players, I would say, in the in the profession—and the refusal to
acknowledge this I think was a deficiency of judgment in the profession and the
willingness to bring up other arguments and somehow dismiss this possible outcome
when you have a major economy, prety much as an example of ge�ng stuck there,
wasn't just a theore�cal possibility, but a reality. So, I think that we did a good job during
the post—so, I published this paper, The Seven Faces of the Peril, which illustrated these
points.
I did think that the commitee, generally speaking, did a good job of trying to stay out of
the Japanese situa�on during, let's say, the 2010 to 2019 period and manage to keep
infla�on from sinking even further away from the 2% target, on the low side. Europe, I
think, did not. And before the pandemic, Europe appeared to be prety much stuck in
the same equilibrium that the Japanese were.
The pandemic came along and sort of rescued the whole thing. A big enough shock, I
guess, can knock you out of anything. And now we're struggling to get back to an
equilibrium where infla�on’s back at 2%.
So, but it's a major lesson and will be studied for years in the literature. But I don't think
you should dismiss the low infla�on, low interest rates, steady state.
Page 17 of 20

[00:54:23]
Branding:

Great. Okay, I'm going to fly the airplane higher and talk about the Bank itself. And the
moto for this Bank, which is “Central to America's Economy”, was born on your watch.
So, tell us how you think the Bank measures up to that ambi�on.

[00:54:39]
Bullard:

Yeah, I've always liked that as a moto. I think it cuts a lot of different ways. We are part
of the central bank, so the central no�on comes in there. We're in the middle of the
country, that comes out. The idea that we play an important role within the world’s
leading central bank, that comes out of the model.
So, I think it fits the ins�tu�on well. It's a litle bit more zippy maybe than some of the
other central banks. You know, when we had consultants in talking about it, they said,
well, dedicated public servants or, you know, something like that. And I think you want
to—those are fine, and we are dedicated public servants—but, I think you want
something a litle more with a litle more pizzazz than that to sort of illustrate the iconic
nature of the ins�tu�on and the role that we've played in the postwar U.S. monetary
economics and macroeconomics world. So, I've always liked it, but, you know, I don't
know, maybe there'll be a brand refresh a�er I leave, but we'll see.

[00:55:58]
Branding:

Okay. My last ques�on. So, the Fed, the Federal Reserve, it’s a constantly evolving
organiza�on. From your perspec�ve, what are the biggest challenges and changes that
you see for the Fed going forward?

[00:56:12]
Bullard:

Yeah, I think the challenges are—the biggest challenges are very clear, I think. It's the
evolu�on of the payment system in the banking world. How is this going to—it's been
evolving for 30 years, you have far less banks today than you would have had 30 years
ago. But probably even more important, you have a larger and larger frac�on of financial
intermedia�on occurring outside the banking system. You've got foreign players in. So,
it's very unclear how this is going to proceed now going forward. Silicon Valley
con�nuing a pace to dominate the world. They absolutely want to dominate the
payments space as well. So, this seems like it is changing the whole paradigm of how we
think about monetary policy, how we think about banking and payments, how we think
about bank regula�on. So, these things are all very integral to central banking. And, you
know, it's happening every day. So, there's a litle bit of the frog in the pot element to it.
Page 18 of 20

But on the other hand, you know, if you look out 30 years, it's going to be a different
world 30 years from now than it is today, or even five years from now or one year from
now.
So, I think the other thing about this issue is that some�mes it appears that there's a lot
of things being talked about, a lot of things going on, but nothing is really happening.
And then one day you wake up and they get the killer applica�on, and everyone adopts
that applica�on and the whole thing really collapses very suddenly.
We certainly saw that with check processing, and I would just hold that out as an
example. When the Minneapolis Fed built a new building in 1973, they did a study and it
projected that there would be no checks being processed in 1977. And so, they built the
building without much in the way of a check processing facility, but they were wrong by
about 20 years. And so, by the �me they got to the late nine�es, they were again
building a new building. And at that point they decided checks were here to stay. So,
they built some check processing facility. But then check processing actually declined
precipitously very shortly a�er that.
So, I think that's the kind of thing when you were si�ng there in 1973, you're saying to
yourself, these paper checks, it can't go on forever, surely there's going to be more sort
of database processing of payments. But to get the �ming exactly right was a big
ques�on mark. So, the Internet had to come along, and then other types of changes had
to come along. But when it did, then check processing went down very drama�cally.
That reduced employment in the Federal Reserve on the order of 30%. You had to
manage that down over just a couple of years, basically down to close to zero compared
to where you were before.
So, I would just take that as a cau�onary tale about—it might seem like not too much is
happening, but then, you know, it doesn't change, doesn't change, doesn't change, then
all of a sudden it changes. So, I would say innova�on in banking might be similar to that,
where it appears like people are going to con�nue exactly the same way forever, but
then all of a sudden, they all change all at once.

[00:59:52]
Branding:

Dave, any more ques�ons?

[00:59:54]
Wheelock:

No. Thank you, Jim, very much.

[00:59:56]
Branding:

Jim Anything else?
Page 19 of 20

[00:59:57]
Bullard:

Nope. I'm. I'm all set. I’m talked out here. [Laughs.]

[01:00:00]
Branding:

Well, Jim Bullard, thank you very much for your service to this Bank, to the Fed system
and to the na�on. We wish you the very best.

[01:00:09]
Bullard:

Thanks very much.
###

Page 20 of 20