View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Prefatory Note
The attached document represents the most complete and accurate version available
based on original files from the FOMC Secretariat at the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
Please note that some material may have been redacted from this document if that
material was received on a confidential basis. Redacted material is indicated by
occasional gaps in the text or by gray boxes around non-text content. All redacted
passages are exempt from disclosure under applicable provisions of the Freedom of
Information Act.

Content last modified 01/14/2022.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC – Restricted Controlled (FR)

Report to the FOMC
on Economic Conditions
and Monetary Policy

Book B
Monetary Policy:
Strategies and Alternatives
April 21, 2016

Prepared for the Federal Open Market Committee
by the staff of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

The top panel of the first exhibit, “Policy Rules and the Staff Projection,”
provides near-term prescriptions for the federal funds rate from four policy rules: the
Taylor (1993) rule, the Taylor (1999) rule, an inertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule,
and a first-difference rule.1 These prescriptions take as given the staff’s baseline
projections for the output gap and inflation in the near term, shown in the middle panels.
The Taylor (1993) and Taylor (1999) rules call for sizable adjustments in the policy rate
to levels of about 2¾ percent by the third quarter of 2016, whereas the inertial Taylor
(1999) rule, which places a considerable weight on keeping the federal funds rate close to
the rate in the previous quarter, calls for raising the policy rate to about 1 percent over the
same period. The first-difference rule prescribes more moderate increases in the federal
funds rate, to about ¾ percent in the third quarter of 2016, as it also places a considerable
weight on the lagged federal funds rate. The Taylor rules’ prescriptions are a bit lower
than those derived from the March Tealbook projections, reflecting the slightly lower
level of output relative to potential in the second and third quarters of 2016. The firstdifference rule calls for higher levels of the federal funds rate than it did in March
because the staff projection implies a somewhat faster growth rate of output relative to
potential in the near term.
The bottom panel of the first exhibit reports the estimate of a Tealbook-consistent,
medium-term notion of the equilibrium real federal funds rate that is generated using the
FRB/US model. This Tealbook-consistent FRB/US r* corresponds to the real federal
funds rate that, if maintained over a 12-quarter period, would close the output gap in the
final quarter of that period in the model. The current-quarter estimate of r*, at
1.66 percent, is essentially unchanged from the estimate derived from the staff’s outlook
in March. The panel also reports the average of the real federal funds rate in the
Tealbook baseline projection for the same 12-quarter period used to compute r*.2 This
average is 0.56 percent, about 1 percentage point below the estimate of r*. The panel

1

The appendix to this section provides details on each of the four rules.
While r* and the average projected real federal funds rate are calculated over the same
12-quarter period, they need not be associated with the same macroeconomic outcomes even when their
values are identical. The reason is that, in the r* simulations, the real federal funds rate is held constant
over the entire 12-quarter period, whereas in the Tealbook baseline, the real federal funds rate can vary
over time. Distinct paths of real short-term rates can, in turn, generate different paths for inflation and
economic activity, even if they have the same 12-quarter average.
2

Page 1 of 52

Strategies

Monetary Policy Strategies

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Strategies

Policy Rules and the Staff Projection
Near−Term Prescriptions of Selected Policy Rules1
(Percent)

2016:Q2

2016:Q3

Taylor (1993) Rule
Previous Tealbook

2.52
2.65

2.65
2.67

Taylor (1999) Rule
Previous Tealbook

2.48
2.71

2.74
2.82

Inertial Taylor (1999) Rule
Previous Tealbook outlook

0.68
0.72

0.99
1.03

First−difference rule
Previous Tealbook outlook

0.55
0.33

0.78
0.35

*

Key Elements of the Staff Projection
PCE Prices Excluding Food and Energy

GDP Gap
Percent

Percent

Four−quarter average

3

3.0

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook
2.5

2

2.0
1
1.5
0
1.0
−1

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

0.5

−2

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

Real Federal Funds Rate Estimates2
(Percent)

Tealbook−consistent FRB/US r*
Average projected real federal funds rate
Current real federal funds rate

Current
Tealbook

Current−Quarter Estimate
as of Previous Tealbook

Previous
Tealbook

1.66
0.56
−1.23

1.57
0.62

1.33
0.41
−1.00

*
1. For rules that have a lagged policy rate as a right−hand−side variable, the lines denoted "Previous Tealbook outlook" report rule
prescriptions based on the previous Tealbook's staff outlook, but jumping off from the realized value for the policy rate last quarter.
2. The "Tealbook−consistent FRB/US r*" is the level of the real federal funds rate that, if maintained over a 12−quarter period in the
FRB/US model, sets the output gap equal to zero in the final quarter of that period. The "current real federal funds rate" is the
difference between the federal funds rate and the trailing four−quarter change in core PCE. The "average projected real federal funds rate"
is the average of the real federal funds rate under the Tealbook baseline projection calculated over the same 12−quarter period as the
Tealbook−consistent FRB/US r*.

Page 2 of 52

0.0

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

further reports a measure of the current real federal funds rate that, at –1.23 percent, is

The second exhibit, “Policy Rule Simulations,” reports dynamic simulations of
the FRB/US model under the Taylor (1993) rule, the Taylor (1999) rule, and the firstdifference rule. These simulations reflect the endogenous responses of the output gap
and inflation when the federal funds rate follows the paths implied by the different policy
rules.3 The results for each rule presented in these and subsequent simulations depend
importantly on the assumptions that policymakers will adhere to the rule in the future and
that market participants as well as price and wage setters fully understand the policy rule
that will be pursued and its implications for real activity and inflation.
The second exhibit also displays the implications of following the baseline
monetary policy assumptions in the current staff forecast, under which the federal funds
rate is assumed to follow the prescriptions of the inertial version of the Taylor (1999)
rule. The nominal federal funds rate increases about 1 percentage point per year for the
next three years, reaching 3.3 percent in the fourth quarter of 2018. The pace of
tightening subsequently slows, and the federal funds rate peaks at around 4 percent in
2021, before eventually returning to its longer-run normal level of 3¼ percent.
The Taylor (1993) and Taylor (1999) rules call for an immediate sharp tightening
and produce paths for the real federal funds rate that lie significantly above the Tealbook
baseline path over the next few years. The sharp tightening mostly reflects that these
rules do not include lagged values of the federal funds rate as a determinant of their
current policy prescriptions. Given that the Taylor (1993) and Taylor (1999) rules have
as intercepts the longer-run normal real federal funds rate of 1¼ percent, that the output
gap is essentially closed, and that core inflation is about ½ percentage point below the
Committee’s objective, these rules prescribe rates only moderately below their longer-run
level of 3¼ percent. Over the next few years, these rules would cause the unemployment
rate to undershoot the staff’s estimate of the natural rate somewhat less than in the staff’s
baseline projection. The Taylor (1999) rule prescribes somewhat higher policy rates than
the Taylor (1993) rule over the period shown because it places more weight on the output
gap. As a consequence, the Taylor (1999) rule also generates a higher trajectory of the

3

Because of these endogenous responses, prescriptions from the dynamic simulations can differ
from those shown in the top panel of the first exhibit.

Page 3 of 52

Strategies

about ¼ percentage point lower than in the March Tealbook.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Strategies

Policy Rule Simulations

Unemployment Rate

Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent
7

Taylor (1993) rule
Taylor (1999) rule
First−difference rule
Tealbook baseline

6.0

Staff's estimate of the natural rate
6
5
5.5
4
3
2

5.0

1
0
2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

Real Federal Funds Rate

2021

4.5

Percent
4
4.0
3
2015

2
1
0

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

PCE Inflation
Percent

Four−quarter average

3.0

−1
2.5
2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

−2
2.0

Real 10−year Treasury Yield
Percent
3

1.5

1.0

2

0.5
1

0.0
0

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2015

2021

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

Note: The policy rule simulations in this exhibit are based on rules that respond to core inflation. This choice of rule
specification was made in light of the tendency for current and near−term core inflation rates to outperform headline
inflation rates as predictors of the medium−term behavior of headline inflation.

Page 4 of 52

−0.5

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

unemployment rate and a slightly lower trajectory of inflation than the Taylor (1993)

In contrast to the Taylor-type rules, the first-difference rule prescribes a pace of
increase in the federal funds rate similar to the Tealbook baseline through 2018. At that
point, the federal funds rate levels off under the first-difference rule, whereas it keeps
rising under the Tealbook baseline. This divergence occurs because the first-difference
rule, which responds to the expected change in the output gap rather than to its level,
reacts to the slower pace of economic growth projected late in the decade. The lower
path of the federal funds rate beyond 2018 under the first-difference rule, in conjunction
with expectations of higher price and wage inflation in the future, leads to lower longterm real rates and thus to higher levels of resource utilization and inflation in the short
run. The first-difference rule generates outcomes for the unemployment rate over the
forecast period that are markedly below the staff’s estimate of the natural rate as well as
the unemployment rate paths generated under the other policy rules. The first-difference
rule also leads to a somewhat higher inflation path over the period shown relative to the
other simple rules.
The third exhibit, “Optimal Control Policy under Commitment,” compares
optimal control simulations for this Tealbook’s outlook with those reported in March.
Policymakers are assumed to place equal weights on keeping headline PCE inflation
close to the Committee’s 2 percent goal, on keeping the unemployment rate close to the
staff’s estimate of the natural rate of unemployment, and on minimizing changes in the
federal funds rate. The concept of optimal control that is employed here corresponds to a
commitment policy under which the plans that policymakers make today are assumed to
constrain future policy choices; see the appendix for details.4
The optimal control path for the federal funds rate is significantly higher than the
path in the Tealbook outlook. In the current baseline projection, unemployment falls well
below the staff’s estimate of the natural rate over the next several years. Under the
preferences embedded in the standard implementation of optimal control, policymakers
judge this undershooting of the natural rate to be costly, leading them to tighten policy
appreciably more than in the Tealbook baseline. Accordingly, the path for the real
4

The results for optimal control policy under discretion (in which policymakers cannot credibly
commit to carrying out a plan involving policy choices that would be suboptimal at the time that these
choices have to be implemented) are similar.

Page 5 of 52

Strategies

rule.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Strategies

Optimal Control Policy under Commitment

Unemployment Rate

Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent
6.0

7

Optimal control (current Tealbook)
Optimal control (previous Tealbook)
Tealbook baseline

Staff's estimate of the natural rate
6
5
5.5
4
3
2

5.0

1
0
2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

Real Federal Funds Rate

2021

4.5

Percent
4
4.0
3
2015

2
1
0

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

PCE Inflation
Percent

Four−quarter average

3.0

−1
2.5
2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

−2
2.0

Real 10−year Treasury Yield
Percent
3

1.5

1.0

2

0.5
1

0.0
0

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2015

Page 6 of 52

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

−0.5

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

federal funds rate is almost 1 percentage point higher, on average, than the Tealbook
also higher. The tighter policy under optimal control results in a path of the
unemployment rate that runs substantially closer to the staff’s estimate of the natural rate
of unemployment; headline PCE inflation is slightly lower than in the Tealbook baseline
over the simulation period, consistent with lower levels of resource utilization.
The optimal control paths for the federal funds rate, the unemployment rate, and
inflation are similar to those derived in the March Tealbook. However, the path of the
real 10-year Treasury yield is lower over the next few years than the optimal control path
in the March Tealbook, reflecting the downward revision by the staff of its estimate of
the term premiums in longer-term Treasury yields that is discussed in the Domestic
Economic Developments and Outlook section of Tealbook A.

OPTIMAL CONTROL WITH ASYMMETRIC WEIGHT ON UNEMPLOYMENT
GAP AND STEEPER PHILLIPS CURVE
In the standard optimal control simulations discussed above, welfare losses arise
from deviations—positive or negative—of the unemployment rate from the staff’s
estimate of the natural rate. However, some policymakers may place little, if any, weight
on current and projected unemployment deviations on the grounds that the welfare costs
of unemployment running somewhat or even substantially below the staff’s estimate of
the natural rate are by themselves small. These policymakers may even view the
unemployment rate falling below its natural rate as a useful means to speed up the return
of inflation to 2 percent. Alternatively, they may see a small weight on the
unemployment gap as a pragmatic response to uncertainty about estimates of the natural
rate of unemployment and to the risk that poorly estimated unemployment gaps could
lead to policy mistakes. At the same time, some policymakers might be concerned that
inflation is likely to be more responsive to declines in the unemployment rate going
forward than appears to have been the case in recent years when there was ample slack in
the labor market.
The exhibit “Optimal Control with Asymmetric Weight on Unemployment Gap
and Steeper Phillips Curve” compares the Tealbook baseline and our standard optimal
control simulations with two other simulations. The first simulation (the blue dashed
lines) uses a loss function that assigns no loss to unemployment rate outcomes below the

Page 7 of 52

Strategies

baseline path over the period shown. The trajectory for the real 10-year Treasury yield is

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Strategies

Optimal Control with Asymmetric Weight on Unemployment Gap and Steeper Phillips Curve

Unemployment Rate

Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent
8

OC: Standard weights
OC: Asymmetric weight on UG
OC: Asymmetric weight on UG, steep PC
Tealbook baseline

6.0

Staff's estimate of the natural rate

7
6

5.5

5
4

5.0

3
2

4.5

1
0
2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

4.0

2021

3.5

Real Federal Funds Rate

Percent
4
3.0

3
2015

2
1
0

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

PCE Inflation
Percent

Four−quarter average

3.0

−1
2.5
2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

−2
2.0

Real 10−year Treasury Yield
Percent
3

1.5

2
1.0
1
0.5
0
0.0
−1
2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

Note: The lines labeled "OC: Standard weights" correspond to the standard optimal control policy under commitment shown in the
previous exhibit. The lines labeled "OC: Asymmetric weight on UG" correspond to an optimal control policy that uses a loss function that
assigned no loss to unemployment rate outcomes below the natural rate but is otherwise identical to the standard loss function. The lines
labeled "OC: Asymmetric weight on UG, steep PC" correspond to an optimal control policy that uses the same asymmetric loss function
and further assumes a steeper Phillips curve. The lines labeled "Tealbook baseline" correspond to the Tealbook baseline projection.

Page 8 of 52

−0.5

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

natural rate but is otherwise identical to the standard loss function. The second
assumes a larger response of inflation to economic activity (that is, a steeper Phillips
curve) than in the Tealbook baseline.
In the scenario in which policymakers incur no losses from the unemployment
rate falling below the natural rate, the optimal control path of the federal funds rate is
considerably below the corresponding path under the standard loss function, and also
below the Tealbook baseline path. This relatively low path for the policy rate stems from
policymakers’ desire to raise inflation back to 2 percent; a greater undershooting of the
natural rate of unemployment helps achieve that outcome. In this simulation, inflation
returns to 2 percent more quickly than in the Tealbook baseline as a result of the tighter
labor market, and then edges above the Committee’s longer-run objective for a few years.
A key assumption underlying the results from the usual optimal control
simulations is the low sensitivity of inflation to resource slack in the FRB/US model, a
feature that is consistent with estimates of the relationship between inflation and slack in
recent decades. This low sensitivity limits the effects of monetary policy on inflation.
To demonstrate the role of this feature of the model, the green dot-dashed lines in the
exhibit show an optimal control simulation in which policymakers incur no losses from
the unemployment rate falling below its natural rate, but that replaces the standard wage
Phillips curve in the FRB/US model with one in which wage inflation is four times more
responsive to the unemployment gap. While the calibration is meant to be illustrative, it
is within the range of plausible empirical estimates.5
Under the alternative specification with the steeper wage Phillips curve, the path
for the federal funds rate is higher and the inflation gap closes slightly faster than in the
case in which policymakers place no weight on the unemployment gap with the standard
specification of the wage Phillips curve. The accompanying higher path for the real 10year Treasury yield constrains economic activity and results in both a smaller
undershooting of unemployment relative to its natural rate and a slightly larger
overshooting of inflation relative to 2 percent. In essence, the steeper slope of the wage
5

This calibrated response of inflation to slack is within two standard deviations of the FRB/US
model estimate informed by the 1985–2007 subsample. Using a different model specification, Kumar and
Orrenius (2014) report a significantly larger response of wage inflation to a fall in the unemployment rate
when the unemployment rate is below its historical average as compared to when the unemployment rate is
above its historical average.

Page 9 of 52

Strategies

simulation (the green dot-dashed lines) also uses this alternative loss function but further

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Phillips curve makes the undershooting of unemployment relative to its natural rate more
Strategies

powerful for returning inflation to 2 percent, resulting in less aggressive policy stimulus.
In the above simulations, as in the standard optimal control exercise, longer-term
inflation expectations are assumed to remain well anchored in every period. If
policymakers judge that longer-term inflation expectations are at risk of drifting above or
below 2 percent, then they may accordingly prefer a higher or lower path for the federal
funds rate than in the simulations shown to ensure that those expectations remain well
anchored. Additionally, if, in order to maintain the credibility of their inflation objective,
policymakers thought it necessary to return inflation to 2 percent fairly quickly, then they
might prefer a lower path for the federal funds rate than otherwise.
The final two exhibits, “Outcomes under Alternative Policies” and “Outcomes
under Alternative Policies, Quarterly,” tabulate the simulation results for key variables
under the policy rules described earlier.

Page 10 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Outcomes under Alternative Policies

Measure and policy

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Extended Tealbook baseline²
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

1.3
2.7
2.8
1.3
1.4
1.9

2.4
3.2
3.5
2.4
2.6
3.7

3.3
3.8
4.1
3.3
3.4
4.8

3.9
3.9
4.3
3.9
3.5
5.3

4.1
4.0
4.2
4.1
3.4
5.2

Real GDP
Extended Tealbook baseline²
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

2.0
1.8
1.7
2.0
2.0
1.7

2.4
2.3
2.2
2.4
2.6
1.8

2.0
2.1
2.0
2.0
2.2
1.7

1.7
1.9
1.8
1.7
1.9
1.6

1.5
1.7
1.7
1.5
1.7
1.7

Unemployment Rate¹
Extended Tealbook baseline²
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

4.8
4.9
4.9
4.8
4.7
4.9

4.4
4.6
4.7
4.4
4.3
4.8

4.2
4.3
4.4
4.2
4.0
4.8

4.2
4.2
4.4
4.2
3.9
4.8

4.4
4.3
4.5
4.4
4.0
4.9

Total PCE prices
Extended Tealbook baseline²
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

1.1
1.1
1.1
1.1
1.1
1.0

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.8
1.5

1.8
1.9
1.8
1.8
2.0
1.7

1.9
2.0
1.9
1.9
2.1
1.8

2.0
2.1
2.0
2.0
2.2
1.9

Core PCE prices
Extended Tealbook baseline²
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

1.5
1.5
1.5
1.5
1.6
1.4

1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6
1.8
1.5

1.8
1.9
1.8
1.8
2.0
1.7

1.9
2.0
1.9
1.9
2.1
1.8

2.0
2.1
2.0
2.0
2.2
1.9

1. Percent, average for the fnal quarter of the period.
2. In the extended Tealbook baseline, the federal funds rate follows the prescriptions of the inertial Taylor (1999) rule.

Page 11 of 52

Strategies

(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Outcomes under Alternative Policies, Quarterly
Strategies

(Four-quarter percent change, except as noted)

2016

2017

Measure and policy
Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Extended Tealbook baseline²
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

0.4
0.4
0.4
0.4
0.4
0.4

0.6
2.5
2.5
0.7
0.7
0.9

1.0
2.6
2.6
1.0
1.0
1.4

1.3
2.7
2.8
1.3
1.4
1.9

1.5
2.7
2.7
1.6
1.8
2.4

1.8
2.8
3.0
1.8
2.1
2.9

2.1
3.0
3.2
2.1
2.4
3.3

2.4
3.2
3.5
2.4
2.6
3.7

Real GDP
Extended Tealbook baseline²
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

1.5
1.5
1.5
1.5
1.5
1.5

1.6
1.5
1.5
1.6
1.6
1.5

2.0
1.8
1.7
2.0
2.0
1.7

2.4
2.1
2.0
2.4
2.5
2.0

2.5
2.2
2.1
2.5
2.6
1.9

2.5
2.3
2.1
2.5
2.6
1.9

2.4
2.3
2.2
2.4
2.6
1.8

Unemployment Rate¹
Extended Tealbook baseline²
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

4.9
4.9
4.9
4.9
4.9
4.9

4.9
4.9
4.9
4.9
4.9
4.9

4.8
4.9
4.9
4.8
4.8
4.9

4.8
4.9
4.9
4.8
4.7
4.9

4.7
4.8
4.9
4.7
4.6
4.9

4.6
4.8
4.8
4.6
4.5
4.9

4.5
4.7
4.7
4.5
4.4
4.8

4.4
4.6
4.7
4.4
4.3
4.8

Total PCE prices
Extended Tealbook baseline²
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

1.0
1.0
1.0
1.0
1.0
1.0

0.8
0.8
0.8
0.8
0.8
0.8

0.8
0.8
0.8
0.8
0.8
0.7

1.1
1.1
1.1
1.1
1.1
1.0

1.5
1.5
1.5
1.5
1.6
1.4

1.6
1.6
1.5
1.6
1.7
1.4

1.6
1.7
1.6
1.6
1.8
1.5

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.8
1.5

Core PCE prices
Extended Tealbook baseline²
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6

1.5
1.5
1.5
1.5
1.5
1.5

1.5
1.5
1.5
1.5
1.6
1.5

1.5
1.5
1.5
1.5
1.6
1.4

1.4
1.5
1.4
1.4
1.6
1.4

1.5
1.5
1.5
1.5
1.6
1.4

1.5
1.6
1.5
1.5
1.7
1.4

1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6
1.8
1.5

1. Percent, average for the quarter.
2. In the extended Tealbook baseline, the federal funds rate follows the prescriptions of the inertial Taylor (1999) rule.

Page 12 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

POLICY RULES USED IN “MONETARY POLICY STRATEGIES”
The table below gives the expressions for the four policy rules regularly reported in
“Monetary Policy Strategies.” In the table, denotes the nominal federal funds rate for quarter
t, while the right-hand-side variables include the staff’s projection of trailing four-quarter core
PCE inflation for the current quarter and three quarters ahead ( and
| ), the output gap
estimate for the current period (gapt), and the forecast of the three-quarter-ahead annual change in
the output gap (4gapt+3|t). The value of policymakers’ longer-run inflation objective, denoted
πLR, is 2 percent.
Taylor (1993) rule

0.5

Taylor (1999) rule

0.5

Inertial Taylor (1999) rule
First-difference rule

0.85
0.5

0.5

0.15

0.5

|

0.5Δ

|

The first two of the selected rules were studied by Taylor (1993, 1999), while the inertial
version of the Taylor (1999) rule has been featured prominently in analysis by Board staff.1 The
, are chosen so that they are consistent with a 2 percent
intercepts of these rules, denoted
longer-run inflation objective and a longer-run real federal funds rate of 1¼ percent, a value used
in the FRB/US model.2 The prescriptions of the first-difference rule do not depend on the level of
the output gap or the longer-run real interest rate; see Orphanides (2003).
Near-term prescriptions from the four policy rules are calculated taking as given the
Tealbook projections for inflation and the output gap. When the Tealbook is published early in a
quarter, the prescriptions are shown for the current and next quarters. When the Tealbook is
published late in a quarter, the prescriptions are shown for the next two quarters. Rules that
include a lagged policy rate as a right-hand-side variable are conditioned on the lagged federal
funds rate in the Tealbook projection for the first quarter shown, and then conditioned on their
simulated lagged federal funds rate for the second quarter shown. The lines labeled “Previous
Tealbook outlook” report prescriptions conditional on the previous Tealbook projections for

1

See, for example, Erceg and others (2012).
All nominal and real federal funds rates reported in the Monetary Policy Strategies section are
expressed on the same 360-day basis as the published federal funds rate. Consistent with the methodology
in the FRB/US model, the simple rules are first implemented on a fully-compounded, 365-day basis and
then converted to a 360-day basis.
2

Page 13 of 52

Strategies

Appendix

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Strategies

inflation and the output gap; for rules that include a lagged policy rate, the prescriptions for the
first quarter shown use the lagged policy rate in the current Tealbook projection.

REAL FEDERAL FUNDS RATE ESTIMATES
The bottom panel of the exhibit, “Policy Rules and the Staff Projection,” provides an
estimate of one notion of the equilibrium real federal funds rate, r*. This measure is an estimate
of the real federal funds rate that, if maintained over a 12-quarter period (beginning in the current
quarter), makes the output gap equal to zero in the final quarter of that period using the output
projection from FRB/US, the staff’s large-scale econometric model of the U.S. economy. This
“Tealbook-consistent FRB/US r*” depends on a broad array of economic factors, some of which
take the form of projected values of the model’s exogenous variables. It is generated after the
paths of exogenous variables in the FRB/US model are adjusted so that they match those in the
extended Tealbook forecast. Model simulations then determine the value of the real federal funds
rate that closes the output gap conditional on the exogenous variables in the extended baseline
forecast.
The “current real federal funds rate” reported in the panel is constructed as the difference
between the midpoint of the prevailing target range for the federal funds rate and the trailing fourquarter change in the core PCE price index.
The “average projected real federal funds rate” reported in the panel is the average of the
real federal funds rate under the Tealbook baseline projection calculated over the same
12−quarter period as the Tealbook-consistent FRB/US r*. The average projected real federal
funds rate and r* need not be associated with the same macroeconomic outcomes even when their
values are identical. The reason is that, in the r* simulations, the real federal funds rate is held
constant over the entire 12-quarter period to close the output gap at the end of this timeframe
whereas, in the Tealbook baseline, the real federal funds rate can vary over time. Distinct paths
of real short-term rates can, in turn, generate different paths for inflation and economic activity.

FRB/US MODEL SIMULATIONS
The exhibits of “Monetary Policy Strategies” that report results from simulations of
alternative policies are derived from dynamic simulations of the FRB/US model. Each simulated
policy rule is assumed to be in force over the whole period covered by the simulation; this period
extends several decades beyond the time horizon shown in the exhibits. The simulations are
conducted under the assumption that market participants as well as price and wage setters have
perfect foresight, and are predicated on the staff’s extended Tealbook projection, which includes
the macroeconomic effects of the Committee’s large-scale asset purchase programs. When the
Tealbook is published early in a quarter, all of the simulations begin in that quarter. However,
when the Tealbook is published late in a quarter, all of the simulations begin in the subsequent
quarter.

Page 14 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

The optimal control simulations posit that policymakers minimize a discounted sum of
) from the Committee’s
weighted squared deviations of four-quarter headline PCE inflation (
2 percent objective, of squared deviations of the unemployment rate from the staff’s estimate of
the natural rate (this difference is also known as the unemployment rate gap,
), and of
squared changes in the federal funds rate. The resulting loss function, shown below, embeds the
assumptions that policymakers discount the future using a quarterly discount factor
0.9963
and place equal weights on squared deviations of inflation, the unemployment gap, and federal
funds rate changes (that is,
).

The optimal control policy is the path for the federal funds rate that minimizes the above
loss function in the FRB/US model, subject to the effective lower bound constraint on nominal
interest rates, under the assumption of perfect foresight, and conditional on the staff’s extended
Tealbook projection. Policy tools other than the federal funds rate are taken as given and
subsumed within the Tealbook baseline. The path chosen by policymakers today is assumed to
be credible, meaning that decision makers in the model see this path as being a binding
commitment on the future Committees; the optimal control policy takes as given the initial lagged
value of the federal funds rate but is otherwise unconstrained by policy decisions made prior to
the simulation period. The discounted losses are calculated over a period that ends sufficiently
far into the future that extending that period farther would not affect the policy prescriptions
shown in the exhibits.

REFERENCES
Erceg, Christopher, Jon Faust, Michael Kiley, Jean-Philippe Laforte, David López-Salido,
Stephen Meyer, Edward Nelson, David Reifschneider, and Robert Tetlow (2012). “An
Overview of Simple Policy Rules and Their Use in Policymaking in Normal Times and
Under Current Conditions.” Memo sent to the Committee on July 18, 2012.
Orphanides, Athanasios (2003). “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor Rule,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50 (July), pp. 9831022.
Taylor, John B. (1993). “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 39 (December), pp. 195214.
Taylor, John B. (1999). “A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules,” in John B. Taylor,
ed., Monetary Policy Rules. University of Chicago Press, pp. 319341.

Page 15 of 52

Strategies

COMPUTATION OF THE OPTIMAL CONTROL POLICY UNDER COMMITMENT

Authorized for Public Release

Strategies

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 16 of 52

April 21, 2016

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Monetary Policy Alternatives
The Tealbook presents three policy alternatives—labeled Alternative A,
Alternative B, and Alternative C—for the Committee’s consideration. Key
considerations for the Committee at this meeting will be whether conditions that warrant
increasing the target range are in place now, and if not, what to convey about the
prospects that such conditions will be in place by the time of the June FOMC meeting.
Alternative B maintains the current target range while keeping open the option for a
target range adjustment in June. It allows policymakers to wait and see additional data
without giving a firm indication of the likely timing of the next policy move.
perceived by market participants as unlikely to be met in the near term. Alternative C
increases the target range and would thereby lead market participants to expect that
further gradual increases would likely be forthcoming this year.
The drafts of Alternatives A, B, and C each begin by noting that labor market
conditions have improved further, but then give differing descriptions of recent and
expected economic activity. While Alternative A states that economic activity “has
slowed” recently, Alternative B and Alternative C say that economic activity “appears to
have slowed,” suggesting that the current estimates of weak GDP growth in the first
quarter may understate the fundamental strength of economic activity. Alternative B
reinforces that suggestion by indicating that, while growth in household spending in
particular has moderated, “households’ real income has risen at a solid rate and consumer
sentiment remains high;” Alternative C simply looks through the recent step-down in
household spending growth. Alternative A is less sanguine, stating that growth of
household spending has declined without highlighting the positive fundamentals.
Looking forward, Alternative B and Alternative C repeat language from the March
statement noting the Committee’s expectation that “economic activity will expand at a
moderate pace.” Alternative A expresses an expectation that economic growth “will pick
up to a moderate pace.”
In light of incoming data indicating that 12-month inflation moderated in
February and March after rising for a number of months, all three alternatives drop the
language from the March statement that inflation “picked up in recent months,” though
Alternative C still gives some attention to the earlier increase by stating that “inflation

Page 17 of 52

Alternatives

Alternative A specifies conditions for raising the target range that would likely be

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

has stepped up since last year.” The three alternatives convey different degrees of
concern about inflation continuing to run below 2 percent, with those readings “largely”
reflecting earlier declines in energy prices and falling prices of non-energy imports
according to Alternative C, “partly” reflecting those factors according to Alternative B,
and “only partly” in Alternative A. Each alternative notes that the Committee will
closely monitor inflation. Alternative A also expresses concern about indicators of
longer-term inflation expectations, noting that the Committee will be closely monitoring
these measures as well. All three statements reaffirm the Committee’s expectation that
inflation will “remain low in the near term,” in part because of earlier declines in energy
prices, but that inflation will rise to 2 percent over the medium term as the transitory

Alternatives

effects of these declines dissipate and as the labor market strengthens further.
The three alternatives contain substantially different assessments of the risks to
the outlook. Alternative B drops the statement from March that global economic and
financial developments pose risks to economic activity and the labor market, but adds
those developments to the set of things that the Committee “continues to closely
monitor,” along with inflation indicators. The change is intended to allow the inference
that the Committee views downside risks from global developments as less pressing but
still a matter of concern. In contrast, Alternative A cautions that the Committee “sees
downside risks” to the economic outlook. Alternative C returns to statement language
from October, stating that the Committee “sees the risks to the outlook for both economic
activity and the labor market as nearly balanced.”
In the policy decision, Alternative B maintains the current target range and
repeats paragraphs 3 and 4 of the March statement. By contrast, Alternative A
communicates a judgment that the economic outlook and associated risks warrant
deferring increases in the target range “until inflation moves closer to 2 percent on a
sustained basis and the risks to the economic outlook are more closely balanced.” The
staff forecast presented in Tealbook A suggests that the inflation condition is unlikely to
be met in short order. By the time these inflation and risk conditions are met, the labor
market could have strengthened substantially further, a situation that would call for
relatively rapid increases in the target range. Accordingly, Alternative A drops the
indication that future adjustments to the stance of policy will be “only gradual.”
Alternative C raises the target range by 25 basis points and maintains the existing
guidance about future monetary policy actions, consistent with a view that the economy
will likely evolve in a way that will warrant further gradual increases in the federal funds
rate target range.

Page 18 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

The next pages contain the March postmeeting statement, the three draft
statements, and summaries of the arguments for each alternative. These elements are
followed by drafts of the implementation note regarding the decisions taken by the
Federal Reserve to implement the monetary policy stance announced by the Committee.
The first draft could be issued if the Committee decides to maintain the current setting of
the target range for the federal funds rate, as in Alternative A and Alternative B. The
second draft could be issued if the Committee decides to raise the target range for the
federal funds rate, as in Alternative C. In either case, the implementation note, which
contains the Committee’s domestic policy directive to the Desk, will be released with the

Alternatives

Committee’s postmeeting statement.

Page 19 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

MARCH 2016 FOMC STATEMENT

Alternatives

1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in January
suggests that economic activity has been expanding at a moderate pace despite the
global economic and financial developments of recent months. Household spending
has been increasing at a moderate rate, and the housing sector has improved further;
however, business fixed investment and net exports have been soft. A range of recent
indicators, including strong job gains, points to additional strengthening of the labor
market. Inflation picked up in recent months; however, it continued to run below the
Committee’s 2 percent longer-run objective, partly reflecting declines in energy
prices and in prices of non-energy imports. Market-based measures of inflation
compensation remain low; survey-based measures of longer-term inflation
expectations are little changed, on balance, in recent months.
2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. The Committee currently expects that, with gradual
adjustments in the stance of monetary policy, economic activity will expand at a
moderate pace and labor market indicators will continue to strengthen. However,
global economic and financial developments continue to pose risks. Inflation is
expected to remain low in the near term, in part because of earlier declines in energy
prices, but to rise to 2 percent over the medium term as the transitory effects of
declines in energy and import prices dissipate and the labor market strengthens
further. The Committee continues to monitor inflation developments closely.
3. Against this backdrop, the Committee decided to maintain the target range for the
federal funds rate at ¼ to ½ percent. The stance of monetary policy remains
accommodative, thereby supporting further improvement in labor market conditions
and a return to 2 percent inflation.
4. In determining the timing and size of future adjustments to the target range for the
federal funds rate, the Committee will assess realized and expected economic
conditions relative to its objectives of maximum employment and 2 percent inflation.
This assessment will take into account a wide range of information, including
measures of labor market conditions, indicators of inflation pressures and inflation
expectations, and readings on financial and international developments. In light of
the current shortfall of inflation from 2 percent, the Committee will carefully monitor
actual and expected progress toward its inflation goal. The Committee expects that
economic conditions will evolve in a manner that will warrant only gradual increases
in the federal funds rate; the federal funds rate is likely to remain, for some time,
below levels that are expected to prevail in the longer run. However, the actual path
of the federal funds rate will depend on the economic outlook as informed by
incoming data.
5. The Committee is maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments
from its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency
mortgage-backed securities and of rolling over maturing Treasury securities at

Page 20 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Alternatives

auction, and it anticipates doing so until normalization of the level of the federal
funds rate is well under way. This policy, by keeping the Committee’s holdings of
longer-term securities at sizable levels, should help maintain accommodative
financial conditions.

Page 21 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

APRIL 2016 ALTERNATIVE A

Alternatives

1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in January
March suggests indicates that labor market conditions have improved further
even as growth in economic activity has been expanding at a moderate pace despite
the global economic and financial developments of recent months slowed. Growth
in household spending has been increasing at a moderate rate, and declined. Since
the beginning of the year, the housing sector has improved further; however, but
business fixed investment and net exports have been soft. A range of recent
indicators, including strong job gains, points to additional strengthening of the labor
market. Inflation picked up in recent months; however, it has continued to run below
the Committee’s 2 percent longer-run objective, only partly reflecting earlier
declines in energy prices and in falling prices of non-energy imports. Market-based
measures of inflation compensation remain low; survey-based measures of longerterm inflation expectations are little changed, on balance, in recent months.
2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. The Committee currently expects that, with gradual
adjustments in the stance of appropriately accommodative monetary policy, growth
in economic activity will expand at pick up to a moderate pace and labor market
indicators will continue to strengthen. However, global economic and financial
developments continue to pose risks. Inflation is expected to remain low in the near
term, in part because of earlier declines in energy prices, but to rise to 2 percent over
the medium term as the transitory effects of declines in energy and import prices
dissipate and the labor market strengthens further. The Committee continues to sees
downside risks to the economic outlook and is closely monitoring inflation,
developments indicators of longer-term inflation expectations, and global
economic and financial developments closely.
3. Against this backdrop, the Committee decided to maintain the target range for the
federal funds rate at ¼ to ½ percent. The stance of monetary policy remains
accommodative, thereby supporting further improvement in labor market conditions
and a return to 2 percent inflation. The Committee judges that an increase in the
target range will not be warranted until inflation moves closer to 2 percent on a
sustained basis and the risks to the economic outlook are more closely balanced.
4. In determining the When adjustments to the target range become appropriate,
their timing and size of future adjustments to the target range for the federal funds
rate, the Committee will assess will depend on the Committee’s assessment of
realized and expected economic conditions relative to its objectives of maximum
employment and 2 percent inflation. This assessment will take into account a wide
range of information, including measures of labor market conditions, indicators of
inflation pressures and inflation expectations, and readings on financial and
international developments. In light of the current shortfall of inflation from 2
percent, the Committee will carefully monitor actual and expected progress toward its
inflation goal. The Committee expects that economic conditions will evolve in a

Page 22 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

manner that will, for some time, warrant only gradual increases in maintaining the
federal funds rate; the federal funds rate is likely to remain, for some time, below at
levels below those that are expected to prevail in the longer run. However, the actual
path of the federal funds rate will depend on the economic outlook as informed by
incoming data.

Alternatives

5. The Committee is maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments
from its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency
mortgage-backed securities and of rolling over maturing Treasury securities at
auction, and it anticipates doing so until normalization of the level of the federal
funds rate is well under way. This policy, by keeping the Committee’s holdings of
longer-term securities at sizable levels, should help maintain accommodative
financial conditions.

Page 23 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Alternatives

APRIL 2016 ALTERNATIVE B
1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in January
March suggests indicates that labor market conditions have improved further
even as growth in economic activity has been expanding at a moderate pace despite
the global economic and financial developments of recent months appears to have
slowed. Growth in household spending has been increasing at a moderate rate
moderated, and although households’ real income has risen at a solid rate and
consumer sentiment remains high. Since the beginning of the year, the housing
sector has improved further; however, but business fixed investment and net exports
have been soft. A range of recent indicators, including strong job gains, points to
additional strengthening of the labor market. Inflation picked up in recent months;
however, it has continued to run below the Committee’s 2 percent longer-run
objective, partly reflecting earlier declines in energy prices and in falling prices of
non-energy imports. Market-based measures of inflation compensation remain low;
survey-based measures of longer-term inflation expectations are little changed, on
balance, in recent months.
2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. The Committee currently expects that, with gradual
adjustments in the stance of monetary policy, economic activity will expand at a
moderate pace and labor market indicators will continue to strengthen. However,
global economic and financial developments continue to pose risks. Inflation is
expected to remain low in the near term, in part because of earlier declines in energy
prices, but to rise to 2 percent over the medium term as the transitory effects of
declines in energy and import prices dissipate and the labor market strengthens
further. The Committee continues to closely monitor inflation indicators and global
economic and financial developments closely.
3. Against this backdrop, the Committee decided to maintain the target range for the
federal funds rate at ¼ to ½ percent. The stance of monetary policy remains
accommodative, thereby supporting further improvement in labor market conditions
and a return to 2 percent inflation.
4. In determining the timing and size of future adjustments to the target range for the
federal funds rate, the Committee will assess realized and expected economic
conditions relative to its objectives of maximum employment and 2 percent inflation.
This assessment will take into account a wide range of information, including
measures of labor market conditions, indicators of inflation pressures and inflation
expectations, and readings on financial and international developments. In light of
the current shortfall of inflation from 2 percent, the Committee will carefully monitor
actual and expected progress toward its inflation goal. The Committee expects that
economic conditions will evolve in a manner that will warrant only gradual increases
in the federal funds rate; the federal funds rate is likely to remain, for some time,
below levels that are expected to prevail in the longer run. However, the actual path

Page 24 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

of the federal funds rate will depend on the economic outlook as informed by
incoming data.

Alternatives

5. The Committee is maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments
from its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency
mortgage-backed securities and of rolling over maturing Treasury securities at
auction, and it anticipates doing so until normalization of the level of the federal
funds rate is well under way. This policy, by keeping the Committee’s holdings of
longer-term securities at sizable levels, should help maintain accommodative
financial conditions.

Page 25 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

APRIL 2016 ALTERNATIVE C

Alternatives

1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in January
March suggests indicates that labor market conditions have improved further
even as growth in economic activity has been expanding at a moderate pace despite
the global economic and financial developments of recent months appears to have
slowed. Household spending has been increasing at a moderate rate, and the housing
sector has improved further; however, business fixed investment and net exports have
been soft. A range of recent indicators, including strong job gains, points to
additional strengthening of the labor market. Inflation picked up in recent months
has stepped up since last year; however, though it has continued to run below the
Committee’s 2 percent longer-run objective, partly reflecting largely because of
earlier declines in energy prices and in falling prices of non-energy imports. Marketbased measures of inflation compensation remain low; survey-based measures of
longer-term inflation expectations are little changed, on balance, in recent months.
2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. The Committee currently expects that, with gradual
adjustments in the stance of monetary policy, economic activity will expand at a
moderate pace and labor market indicators will continue to strengthen. However,
global economic and financial developments continue to pose risks. The Committee
sees the risks to the outlook for both economic activity and the labor market as
nearly balanced but is monitoring global economic and financial developments.
Inflation is expected to remain low in the near term, in part because of earlier declines
in energy prices, but to rise to 2 percent over the medium term as the transitory
effects of declines in energy and import prices dissipate and the labor market
strengthens further. The Committee continues to monitor inflation developments
closely.
3. Against this backdrop, the Committee decided to maintain increase the target range
for the federal funds rate at ¼ to ½ to ¾ percent. The stance of monetary policy
remains accommodative, thereby supporting further improvement in labor market
conditions and a return to 2 percent inflation.
4. In determining the timing and size of future adjustments to the target range for the
federal funds rate, the Committee will assess realized and expected economic
conditions relative to its objectives of maximum employment and 2 percent inflation.
This assessment will take into account a wide range of information, including
measures of labor market conditions, indicators of inflation pressures and inflation
expectations, and readings on financial and international developments. In light of
the current shortfall of inflation from 2 percent, the Committee will carefully monitor
actual and expected progress toward its inflation goal. The Committee expects that
economic conditions will evolve in a manner that will warrant only gradual increases
in the federal funds rate; the federal funds rate is likely to remain, for some time,
below levels that are expected to prevail in the longer run. However, the actual path

Page 26 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

of the federal funds rate will depend on the economic outlook as informed by
incoming data.

Alternatives

5. The Committee is maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments
from its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency
mortgage-backed securities and of rolling over maturing Treasury securities at
auction, and it anticipates doing so until normalization of the level of the federal
funds rate is well under way. This policy, by keeping the Committee’s holdings of
longer-term securities at sizable levels, should help maintain accommodative
financial conditions.

Page 27 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

THE CASE FOR ALTERNATIVE B
Weighing information received over the intermeeting period about the labor
market, spending, and foreign economic and financial developments, policymakers may
view the data as consistent, on balance, with their modal forecasts at the time of the
March FOMC meeting. Although weaker-than-expected readings on components of final
demand led to downward revisions in GDP projections for the first quarter, labor market
conditions have continued to improve, with nonfarm payroll employment expanding
solidly through March and the labor force participation rate moving up for six
consecutive months. Moreover, financial conditions have continued to improve, on
balance, and foreign output growth appears to have picked up. Thus, policymakers may
Alternatives

think that sluggish domestic output growth is likely to prove transitory, and expect a
return to moderate growth in the rest of the year. Regarding inflation, policymakers may
view the recent deceleration as simply reversing the impact of erratic components and
volatile seasonal movements earlier this year. While measures of inflation compensation
and longer-run inflation expectations have remained soft, policymakers may continue to
judge that this softness likely reflects changes in risk and liquidity premiums and the
well-known excess sensitivity of survey responses to gasoline prices.
In light of such an assessment of recent developments and the outlook, and in
particular, given the large downward revision in projected growth for the first quarter,
policymakers may judge it prudent to wait for evidence that domestic demand is
rebounding, or that job growth does not slow appreciably, before taking the next step in
normalizing the stance of monetary policy. Policymakers may also prefer to avoid
signaling the timing of the next policy move, and instead want to emphasize the
data-dependent nature of policy decisions and the FOMC’s commitment to achieving its
inflation goal. In addition, policymakers might judge that downside risks from global
economic and financial developments are less acute than in March but still large enough
to warrant concern, and thus bear close watching. With nominal interest rates close to the
effective lower bound, policymakers might conclude that the optimal response to such
risks is to choose a shallower path for the federal funds rate than would otherwise be
appropriate.
Some participants may judge it unlikely that an increase in the target range will be
warranted in the near term. In light of still historically low readings on measures of
inflation compensation and expectations, they may have become less confident that
inflation will move up to 2 percent. Or they may view the low sensitivity of inflation to

Page 28 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

resource utilization as requiring a period of unemployment well below its longer-run
normal rate to ensure a return of inflation to 2 percent over the medium run.
Nevertheless, those who judge that the outlook and risks to the outlook make near-term
rate hikes inadvisable may conclude that, by not increasing the target range in April, the
Committee would go far enough, for now, in reinforcing the message that policy is data
dependent and that the FOMC is committed to achieving both of its dual mandate goals.
In addition, they may see the new language indicating that the Committee is closely
monitoring inflation and global economic and financial developments as continuing to
provide an appropriate signal of concern about the risks to the outlook.
Other policymakers may see the incoming data, in particular the continued strong
that worries about the recent market volatility and foreign developments significantly
restraining the U.S. economy are exaggerated. They might also point to solid household
balance sheets and measures of consumer confidence as suggesting that the fundamentals
for domestic demand are strong. These policymakers may view the higher inflation
readings this year, the moderate rebound in oil prices and lower level of the dollar, and
the further strengthening of the labor market as reinforcing the expectation that inflation
will rise toward 2 percent over the medium term. That said, these policymakers may note
that again postponing the decision to raise the target range until the next meeting is
unlikely to generate large costs because real GDP growth remains moderate, inflation
continues to run below 2 percent, wage growth is tepid, measures of longer-term inflation
expectations are at or below normal levels, and asset valuation pressures are generally
moderate. Moreover, these policymakers may recognize that the Committee could
readily tighten policy somewhat more rapidly than expected by markets were it
necessary, and that the language in Alternative B emphasizing the Committee’s pursuit of
a data-dependent approach indicates that the Committee stands ready to do so.
A decision to maintain the current target range would be largely in line with the
expectations of financial market participants. According to the Desk’s latest Survey of
Primary Dealers and Survey of Market Participants, respondents perceive there to be only
a negligible probability that the Committee will alter the target range at this meeting.
Many respondents expect the Committee to indicate that risks from abroad have
diminished; many also expect the statement to recognize the weakness in first-quarter
spending. Moreover, respondents do not anticipate any changes to the Committee’s
forward guidance or reinvestment policy (that is, to paragraphs 4 or 5 of the statement),
both of which Alternative B maintains. In terms of the Committee’s actions in the future,

Page 29 of 52

Alternatives

job gains, as providing additional evidence that the economic expansion is resilient and

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Alternative B may not lead market participants to significantly increase the odds they
place on a target range increase at the June meeting from its current level of roughly 20
percent. Rather, Alternative B may lead market participants to increase those odds over
time if data received between the April and June meetings prove to be largely consistent
with the Committee’s expectation for a rebound in growth of spending and real GDP, and
for continued solid job gains.

THE CASE FOR ALTERNATIVE C
Policymakers might view the continued improvement in labor market data as
having brought the economy to maximum sustainable employment, or close to it. Based

Alternatives

in part on repeated experience with weak first-quarter growth in recent years, they may
also see the slowdown in first quarter GDP growth as transitory. Moreover,
policymakers may judge that conditions remain favorable for solid consumption growth
and further improvement in the housing sector even with a further increase in the target
range. Household balance sheets have improved, gains in disposable income have been
healthy, consumer confidence is high, job prospects are good, and, as explored in a box in
Tealbook A, low gasoline prices are providing a boost to consumer spending. Finally,
they may view the risks to the economic outlook as nearly balanced, and see the
downside risk from global economic and financial developments in particular as having
diminished compared with earlier this year. Policymakers might view alternative
scenarios such as the “Stronger Foreign Growth and Weaker Dollar” or “Weaker Labor
Productivity, Stronger Labor Market” scenarios in the “Risks and Uncertainty” section of
Tealbook A as increasingly likely. Consequently, they may no longer see a case for
delaying the next increase in the federal funds rate.1
Regarding the Committee’s inflation objective, policymakers may note that
various measures of the trend in inflation have moved closer to 2 percent than was the
case last year, with the 12- month change in core PCE inflation and the Dallas Fed’s
trimmed mean PCE inflation edging up to 1.7 percent and 1.8 percent, respectively, in
February. These policymakers may conclude that the effect of transitory factors has
begun to subside, given the recent firming in oil prices and decline in the dollar.
Moreover, participants may have only limited concerns about low readings on longer-

1

Alternatively, the Committee might view the language in the draft statement for Alternative C as
premature in present circumstances but might nonetheless discuss whether this language, especially
paragraphs 2, 3, and 4, would be appropriate when the time arrives for another increase in the target range
for the federal funds rate.

Page 30 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

term inflation compensation because they judge that these indicators are depressed by
movements in liquidity and risk premiums that are unrelated to longer-run inflation
outcomes. Similarly, they may attribute the softening in the median Michigan survey
respondent’s expectation of average inflation over the coming 5 or 10 years to the
transitory influences of earlier declines in gasoline prices rather than to a reduction in
expected inflation over the longer run. Therefore, policymakers may have confidence
that headline inflation will be close to the 2 percent objective once the effects of earlier
declines in energy and import prices fade, and that the projected further tightening of the
labor market will suffice to return headline inflation to the Committee’s longer-run
objective.

in the face of rapid job growth and a closed unemployment rate gap would likely foster
expectations of a prolonged shallow path for the federal funds rate that would be
insufficiently responsive to economic conditions, creating excess demand and risking an
upward drift in inflation expectations, and thus eventually making it necessary to raise the
federal funds rate rapidly rather than gradually. Leaving the stance of monetary policy
unchanged thus runs the risk that inflation will persistently overshoot 2 percent, eliciting
an upward drift in inflation expectations. In addition, such an expected path could induce
further “reach for yield” or excessive risk-taking behavior in financial markets.
Some policymakers might also believe that monetary policy should focus
primarily on progress toward the Committee's longer-run objectives. These policymakers
may be concerned that the public might misinterpret a statement like Alternative B as an
indication that the FOMC is continuing to place too much weight on transitory financial
and economic developments, and too little weight on a solid central outlook for the
economy, labor markets, and inflation.
For all of the above reasons, these policymakers may judge that it is appropriate
to announce a 25 basis point increase in the target range for the federal funds rate to ½ to
¾ percent, as in Alternative C. Policymakers may note that, even with this increase, the
real federal funds rate would still lie well below the Tealbook-consistent estimate of the
equilibrium real federal funds rate reported in the “Monetary Policy Strategies” section of
Tealbook B. An increase in the target range would also be consistent with the level of the
federal funds rate prescribed by the optimal control policy reported there.

Page 31 of 52

Alternatives

These policymakers might further argue that continuing to leave rates unchanged

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Respondents to the Desk’s latest surveys perceive there to be no material odds
that the Committee will change the target range at this meeting, and so a decision to
increase the target range would be very surprising. If market participants infer that, all
else equal, the Committee intends to pursue a less accommodative stance of policy going
forward than they had expected, then medium- and longer-term real interest rates would
rise, equity prices and inflation compensation would likely decline, and the dollar would
appreciate. In addition, financial market volatility might increase, given responses to the
Desk’s survey which attribute some of the recent decline in volatility to Federal Reserve
communication signaling a flatter path for the federal funds rate. However, if investors
see a statement like Alternative C as primarily reflecting an upbeat assessment of the
strength of the U.S. expansion and the economic outlook, then equity prices and inflation
Alternatives

compensation might fall less than otherwise, or even rise.

THE CASE FOR ALTERNATIVE A
Though the Committee has made substantial cumulative progress toward its
employment objective, policymakers might stress that both core and headline inflation
have run below 2 percent for a number of years, and project that headline inflation will
linger at low levels well into 2016 because of earlier movements in the exchange value of
the dollar and in the prices of oil and other commodities. These policymakers may note
that FOMC participants, the staff, and many other forecasters, have repeatedly
overpredicted inflation in recent years, and that, as shown in Tealbook A, the inflation
forecast for 2016 has been revised down on net since the December Tealbook.2 These
policymakers might want to see actual inflation move more convincingly toward their
objective before increasing the target range. Such policymakers may be hesitant to
continue to predicate their policy decisions on inflation forecasts that hinge on the weak
and imprecisely estimated relationship between inflation and labor market slack and on
the assumption that inflation expectations are, and will remain, well anchored. In sum,
these policymakers might prefer a statement along the lines of Alternative A, which
asserts that the Committee judges that an increase in the target range “will not be
warranted until inflation moves closer to 2 percent on a sustained basis and the risks to
the economic outlook are more closely balanced.”
Policymakers might also find the unexpected weakness of spending indicators for
the first quarter to be a cause for concern. They may view the data as weaker than can be

2

See “Sources of Inflation Forecast Revisions since the December 2015 Tealbook.”

Page 32 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

explained by any identifiable transitory factors, and note that the slowdown was broadbased. In addition, while policymakers may recognize the positive tone of incoming data
on the labor market, they may believe that more still needs to be done to reach maximum
employment. The still-high rate of involuntary part-time employment, the low level of
the employment-to-population ratio for prime-age workers, and the surprisingly limited
extent to which aggregate data have indicated upward pressure on wage growth may all
suggest some remaining slack in labor markets. Policymakers may also see virtues in
allowing the labor market to firm more, beyond simply taking up slack, in order to induce
increased labor force participation over the medium term as a way of repairing the
damage to the labor market that resulted from a prolonged period of weak labor demand.

global economic and financial situation continues to pose downside risks, and see the
factors that led to sharp deterioration in financial conditions earlier this year as still
largely unaddressed. Policymakers might also see new risks emerging in the global
outlook, such as those discussed in the “Disorderly Brexit” scenario in the “Risks and
Uncertainty” section of Tealbook A. They might observe that, given the proximity to the
effective lower bound, the scope for conventional policy measures to support the
economy would be quickly exhausted in the event that scenarios worse than those
portrayed in Tealbook A were to materialize. In addition, policymakers might judge that
the neutral rate of interest is low relative to its historical norm and likely to remain so for
quite some time, thus exacerbating the risk that conventional policy could be constrained
going forward. They might also judge that unconventional monetary policies provide
imperfect substitutes for conventional policy. Therefore, these policymakers may believe
that risk management considerations call for signaling that any further removal of policy
accommodation is some time off.
Policymakers might also worry that the failure of inflation to rise to target over
the past several years has become ingrained in longer-term inflation expectations. They
might note that the preliminary April reading of the Michigan survey measure of longerterm inflation expectations declined to a very low level, and that the New York Fed’s
measure of three-year-ahead expected inflation remains at the low end of its historical
range. They might add that market-based measures of inflation compensation have been
at low levels for so long that it is difficult to believe that these declines are entirely due to
liquidity and risk premiums, and view an alternative scenario such as “Lower Long-Term
Inflation Expectations” in the “Risks and Uncertainty” section of Tealbook A as likely.
On balance, they may see the weakness in those various measures as suggesting that the

Page 33 of 52

Alternatives

In terms of the domestic economic outlook, policymakers might argue that the

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

inflation expectations relevant for wage and price setting have declined slightly. Some
policymakers might further dismiss the recent uptick in core inflation as likely to prove
transitory, and instead point to the recent decline in wage inflation to the low levels seen
over the past several years as evidence that there is little upward pressure from resource
utilization and little reason to be confident that inflation will return to 2 percent in the
medium term absent a stronger commitment to bring inflation to that level. Moreover,
these policymakers might argue that the chronic failure of policy to return inflation
toward 2 percent risks eroding the credibility of the FOMC’s commitment to achieving
that objective, or the credibility of the claim that deviations from this objective are
considered on a symmetric basis.

Alternatives

Most respondents in the Desk’s latest surveys expect the Committee to continue
to emphasize the gradual nature of its normalization approach and to convey that it still
expects to raise rates this year. Many respondents also reported an expectation that the
April statement would note an improvement in global financial market conditions.
Therefore, the issuance of a postmeeting statement like Alternative A would surprise
financial market participants. Investors would likely push further into the future the
expected date of the next rate increase, the expected path for the federal funds rate would
likely flatten further, and longer-term yields would decline. If the statement is primarily
seen as more accommodative, equity prices and inflation compensation might rise, and
the dollar would depreciate. But if investors interpret the statement as reflecting an
unexpectedly downbeat assessment of global economic conditions and greater-thananticipated concerns over the downside risks to the outlook, equity prices and inflation
compensation could fall.

Page 34 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

IMPLEMENTATION NOTE
If the Committee decides to maintain the current target range for the federal funds
rate, as in Alternative A or Alternative B, an implementation note that indicates no
change in the Federal Reserve’s administered rates—the interest rates on required and
excess reserves, the offering rate on overnight reverse repurchase agreements, and the
discount rate—would be issued. If the Committee instead decides to raise the target
range for the federal funds rate, as in Alternative C, an implementation note that
communicates the changes the Federal Reserve decided to make to these three policy
tools would be issued.

directive and implementation note; bold red underlined text indicates added language;
blue underlined text indicates text that links to websites.

Page 35 of 52

Alternatives

On the following pages, struck-out text indicates language deleted from the March

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Implementation Note for April 2016 Alternative A and Alternative B
Release Date: March 16 April 27, 2016
Decisions Regarding Monetary Policy Implementation
The Federal Reserve has made the following decisions to implement the monetary policy
stance announced by the Federal Open Market Committee in its statement on March 16
April 27, 2016:
The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System left unchanged the
interest rate paid on required and excess reserve balances at 0.50 percent.



As part of its policy decision, the Federal Open Market Committee voted to
authorize and direct the Open Market Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, until instructed otherwise, to execute transactions in the System Open
Market Account in accordance with the following domestic policy directive:

Alternatives



“Effective March 17 April 28, 2016, the Federal Open Market Committee
directs the Desk to undertake open market operations as necessary to
maintain the federal funds rate in a target range of ¼ to ½ percent,
including overnight reverse repurchase operations (and reverse repurchase
operations with maturities of more than one day when necessary to
accommodate weekend, holiday, or similar trading conventions) at an
offering rate of 0.25 percent, in amounts limited only by the value of
Treasury securities held outright in the System Open Market Account that
are available for such operations and by a per-counterparty limit of $30
billion per day.
The Committee directs the Desk to continue rolling over maturing
Treasury securities at auction and to continue reinvesting principal
payments on all agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in
agency mortgage-backed securities. The Committee also directs the Desk
to engage in dollar roll and coupon swap transactions as necessary to
facilitate settlement of the Federal Reserve’s agency mortgage-backed
securities transactions.”
More information regarding open market operations may be found on the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York’s website.


The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System took no action to change
the discount rate (the primary credit rate), which remains at 1.00 percent.

This information will be updated as appropriate to reflect decisions of the Federal Open
Market Committee or the Board of Governors regarding details of the Federal Reserve’s
operational tools and approach used to implement monetary policy.

Page 36 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Implementation Note for April 2016 Alternative C
Release Date: March 16 April 27, 2016
Decisions Regarding Monetary Policy Implementation



The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System left unchanged the
interest rate paid on required and excess reserve balances at 0.50 percent voted
[ unanimously ] to raise the interest rate paid on required and excess reserve
balances to 0.75 percent, effective April 28, 2016.



As part of its policy decision, the Federal Open Market Committee voted to
authorize and direct the Open Market Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, until instructed otherwise, to execute transactions in the System Open
Market Account in accordance with the following domestic policy directive:
“Effective March 17 April 28, 2016, the Federal Open Market Committee
directs the Desk to undertake open market operations as necessary to
maintain the federal funds rate in a target range of ¼ to ½ to ¾ percent,
including overnight reverse repurchase operations (and reverse repurchase
operations with maturities of more than one day when necessary to
accommodate weekend, holiday, or similar trading conventions) at an
offering rate of 0.25 0.50 percent, in amounts limited only by the value of
Treasury securities held outright in the System Open Market Account that
are available for such operations and by a per-counterparty limit of $30
billion per day.
The Committee directs the Desk to continue rolling over maturing
Treasury securities at auction and to continue reinvesting principal
payments on all agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in
agency mortgage-backed securities. The Committee also directs the Desk
to engage in dollar roll and coupon swap transactions as necessary to
facilitate settlement of the Federal Reserve’s agency mortgage-backed
securities transactions.”
More information regarding open market operations may be found on the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York’s website.



In a related action, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System took
no action to change the discount rate (the primary credit rate), which remains at
1.00 voted [ unanimously ] to approve a ¼ percentage point increase in the
discount rate (the primary credit rate) to 1.25 percent, effective April 28,
2016. In taking this action, the Board approved requests submitted by the
Boards of Directors of the Federal Reserve Banks of … .

Page 37 of 52

Alternatives

The Federal Reserve has made the following decisions to implement the monetary policy
stance announced by the Federal Open Market Committee in its statement on March 16
April 27, 2016:

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Alternatives

This information will be updated as appropriate to reflect decisions of the Federal Open
Market Committee or the Board of Governors regarding details of the Federal Reserve’s
operational tools and approach used to implement monetary policy.

Page 38 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Projections
BALANCE SHEET AND INCOME
The staff has prepared projections of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet and key
elements of the associated income statement under two scenarios for the paths of
monetary policy and longer-term interest rates. The first set of projections (labeled
“April Tealbook baseline” in the accompanying exhibits) reflects the policy assumptions
incorporated in the staff’s baseline forecast presented in Tealbook A. The second set
(labeled “Higher term premiums”) incorporates a steeper near-term path for term
premiums on longer-duration Treasury securities, as assumed in the scenario labeled
“Sharp Increases in Term Premiums” in the Risks and Uncertainty section of Tealbook A.
The paths of interest rates and macroeconomic variables differ across the two
scenarios. In the April Tealbook baseline scenario, term premiums on Treasury securities
increase gradually from current negative levels to their historical averages. In the higher
term premiums scenario, term premiums return to their historical averages more abruptly
than in the baseline, rising more than 200 basis points in one year. The resulting sharp
increases in various interest rates trigger a slowdown in economic growth.

the Taylor (1999) rule. In addition, reinvestments of maturing Treasury securities and
agency debt as well as principal received on agency MBS are assumed to cease at the end
of 2016 when the federal funds rate is projected to be above 1 percent. Once
reinvestments cease, the SOMA portfolio shrinks through full redemptions of maturing
Treasury and agency debt securities as well as paydowns of principal from agency MBS.
Regarding the Federal Reserve’s use of its policy normalization tools, the scenarios
assume that overnight reverse repurchase agreements (ON RRPs) run at a level of
$100 billion through the end of 2018 before declining to zero by the end of 2019, and that
term deposits and term RRPs are not used.1 Some key features of the two scenarios are
highlighted below.

1

Use of term RRPs or term deposits would result in a shift in the composition of Federal Reserve
liabilities—a decline in reserve balances and an equal increase in term RRPs or term deposits—but would
not produce a change in the overall size of the balance sheet. We also assume that RRPs associated with

Page 39 of 52

Projections

Under both scenarios, the federal funds rate is determined by an inertial version of

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Total Assets and Selected Balance Sheet Items
April Tealbook baseline
Higher term premiums

Total Assets

March Tealbook

Reserve Balances
Billions of dollars

Monthly

Billions of dollars

5500

Monthly

3500

5000
3000
4500
4000

2500

3500
2000

3000
2500

1500

2000
1000

1500
1000

500
500
0

SOMA Treasury Holdings

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

2014

SOMA Agency MBS Holdings
Billions of dollars

Monthly

3000

Billions of dollars

Monthly

2400
2200
2000

2500

1800
1600

2000

1400
1200

1500

1000
800

1000

600
400

500

200
0

Page 40 of 52

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

2014

2012

2010

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

2014

2012

0
2010

Projections

2012

2010

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

2014

2012

2010

0

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)



April 21, 2016

Balance sheet. Under the baseline scenario, the size of the portfolio is
normalized in the third quarter of 2021, unchanged from the March Tealbook (see
the solid black lines in the exhibit titled “Total Assets and Selected Balance Sheet
Items” and the table that follows).2 At that time, total assets are projected to stand
at $2.4 trillion, with about $2.2 trillion in total SOMA securities holdings. Total
assets and SOMA Treasury holdings rise thereafter, keeping pace with the
increases in both Federal Reserve notes in circulation and Federal Reserve Bank
capital.
Under the higher term premiums scenario, even though higher interest rates on
longer-dated Treasury securities put upward pressure on mortgage rates, the
trajectory of MBS prepayments is only slightly lower than in the baseline.
Consequently, the path of the balance sheet after reinvestments cease at the end of
2016 is not meaningfully different from the baseline scenario.



Federal Reserve earnings remittances. After record remittances to the Treasury
in 2015 of nearly $100 billion, remittances under the baseline scenario are
projected to decline to about $79 billion this year (see the solid black lines in the
“Income Projections” exhibit).3 The large step-down in 2016 primarily reflects
increased interest expense on reserves. Annual remittances continue to decline in

Projections

subsequent years, reaching a low of roughly $29 billion in 2019, with no deferred

foreign official and international accounts remain near their March 31, 2016, level of $247 billion
throughout the projection period.
2
The size of the balance sheet is assumed to be normalized when the securities portfolio reverts to
the level consistent with its longer-run trend, which is determined largely by currency in circulation and a
projected steady-state level of reserve balances. The projected timing of the normalization of the size of
the balance sheet depends importantly on the level of reserve balances deemed necessary to conduct
monetary policy; currently, we assume that level of reserve balances to be $100 billion. However, ongoing
regulatory and structural changes could result in a higher underlying demand for reserve balances. In turn,
a higher steady-state level for reserve balances would, all else equal, imply an earlier normalization of the
size of the balance sheet. For instance, with a $500 billion steady-state level of reserve balances, the
balance sheet would likely normalize at the end of 2020.
3
We assume that the interest rate paid on excess reserve balances will average about 15 basis
points above the effective federal funds rate and the ON RRP rate will average about 10 basis points below
the effective federal funds rate.

Page 41 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Federal Reserve Balance Sheet
End-of-Year Projections -- April Tealbook baseline
(Billions of dollars)

Mar 31, 2016
Total assets

4,482

2017

2019

2021

2023

2025

4,066 2,965 2,391 2,543 2,714

Selected assets
Loans and other credit extensions*
Securities held outright
U.S. Treasury securities

2

0

0

0

0

4,244

3,871 2,801 2,250 2,412 2,592

2,461

2,271 1,491 1,176 1,512 1,825

Agency debt securities
Agency mortgage-backed securities

0

29
1,753

4

2

2

2

2

1,596 1,308 1,072

899

765

Unamortized premiums

186

153

119

95

82

73

Unamortized discounts

-16

-14

-11

-9

-7

-6

46

48

48

48

48

48

Total other assets

Total liabilities

4,442

4,023 2,918 2,341 2,488 2,654

1,397

1,548 1,705 1,834 1,980 2,146

Projections

Selected liabilities
Federal Reserve notes in circulation
Reverse repurchase agreements
Deposits with Federal Reserve Banks
Reserve balances held by depository institutions
U.S. Treasury, General Account

551

347

247

247

247

247

2,486

2,123

961

255

255

255

2,125

1,968

806

100

100

100

314

150

150

150

150

150

47

5

5

5

5

5

2

0

0

0

0

0

40

43

46

50

55

60

Other deposits
Earnings remittances due to the U.S. Treasury

Total capital**

Source: Federal Reserve H.4.1 statistical releases and staff calculations.
Note: Components may not sum to totals due to rounding.
*Loans and other credit extensions includes primary, secondary, and seasonal credit; central bank liquidity swaps; and net portfolio holdings of Maiden Lane LLC.
**Total capital includes capital paid-in and capital surplus accounts.

Page 42 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Federal Reserve Balance Sheet
End-of-Year Projections -- Higher term premiums
(Billions of dollars)

Mar 31, 2016
Total assets

4,482

2017

2019

2021

2023

2025

4,098 3,000 2,397 2,552 2,723

Selected assets
Loans and other credit extensions*
Securities held outright
U.S. Treasury securities

2

0

0

0

0

4,244

3,903 2,837 2,255 2,422 2,602

2,461

2,271 1,491 1,156 1,502 1,820

Agency debt securities
Agency mortgage-backed securities

0

29
1,753

4

2

2

2

2

1,628 1,343 1,097

917

780

Unamortized premiums

186

153

119

95

82

72

Unamortized discounts

-16

-14

-11

-9

-7

-6

46

48

48

48

48

48

Total other assets

Total liabilities

4,442

4,055 2,954 2,346 2,497 2,663

1,397

1,548 1,705 1,839 1,990 2,156

Federal Reserve notes in circulation
Reverse repurchase agreements
Deposits with Federal Reserve Banks
Reserve balances held by depository institutions
U.S. Treasury, General Account

551

347

247

247

247

247

2,486

2,155

997

255

255

255

2,125

2,000

842

100

100

100

314

150

150

150

150

150

47

5

5

5

5

5

2

0

0

0

0

0

40

43

46

50

55

60

Other deposits
Earnings remittances due to the U.S. Treasury

Total capital**

Source: Federal Reserve H.4.1 statistical releases and staff calculations.
Note: Components may not sum to totals due to rounding.
*Loans and other credit extensions includes primary, secondary, and seasonal credit; central bank liquidity swaps; and net portfolio holdings of Maiden Lane LLC.
**Total capital includes capital paid-in and capital surplus accounts.

Page 43 of 52

Projections

Selected liabilities

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Income Projections
April Tealbook baseline
Higher term premiums

Interest Income

March Tealbook

Interest Expense
Billions of dollars

Annual

Billions of dollars

140

Annual

160

120

140

100

120
100

80

80
60

60

140
120

40

40

20

20

0

0

−20

−20

Memo: Unrealized Gains/Losses
Billions of dollars

Page 44 of 52

2024

2022

2020

2018

End of year

2016

120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

End of year

2012

Billions of dollars

2014

Deferred Asset

2024

60

2022

60

2020

80

2018

80

2016

100

2012

100

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

2014

2024

Annual

120

2014

2022

Billions of dollars

140

2014

Annual

2012

2020

Earnings Remittances to Treasury
Billions of dollars

2012

2018

0
2016

0
2014

20
2012

20

Realized Capital Gains

Projections

40

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

2014

2012

40

400
300
200
100
0
−100
−200
−300
−400
−500
−600

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

asset being recorded.4 Under this scenario, the Federal Reserve’s cumulative
remittances from 2009 through 2025 total about $1.1 trillion.
Under the higher term premiums scenario, cumulative remittances over the 2009
to 2025 period are projected to be about $71 billion greater than in the baseline
projection, reflecting higher interest income and, to a larger extent, lower interest
expense through the projection period (see the dashed blue lines in the “Income
Projections” exhibit). Regarding interest income, the lower trajectory of MBS
prepayments results in slightly greater MBS coupon income. Regarding interest
expense, the sudden increase in term premiums leads to a tightening in overall
financial conditions, inducing higher unemployment and a weakening in the pace
of economic expansion. As a consequence, because of the wider output gap, the
inertial Taylor (1999) rule implies that the federal funds rate increases at a slower
pace than in the baseline scenario, and that fatter path for the funds rate is
reflected in a slower increase in IOER and interest expense.


Unrealized gains or losses. The staff estimates that the SOMA portfolio was in a
net unrealized gain position of about $219 billion at the end of March.5 Going
forward, the net unrealized gain or loss position of the portfolio will depend
importantly on the path of longer-term interest rates. Under the baseline scenario,
because of the assumed rise in longer-term interest rates over the next several
of 2017, about one quarter later than estimated in the March Tealbook. The
delayed onset of a net unrealized loss position reflects a slightly lower path for
long-term interest rates. The portfolio is then expected to record a peak
unrealized loss of about $230 billion in 2019, close to what was projected in the
March Tealbook. At that time, of the $230 billion loss, about $90 billion is
attributable to losses on holdings of Treasury securities and $140 billion to losses
on holdings of agency MBS. The unrealized loss position then contracts through
2025, as the value of securities previously acquired under the large-scale asset

4

In the event that a Federal Reserve Bank’s earnings fall short of the amount necessary to cover
its operating costs and pay dividends, a deferred asset for interest on Federal Reserve notes would be
recorded.
5
The Federal Reserve reports the level and the change in the quarter-end net unrealized gain/loss
position of the SOMA portfolio to the public in the “Federal Reserve Banks Combined Quarterly Financial
Reports,” available on the Board’s website at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_fedfinancials.htm#quarterly.

Page 45 of 52

Projections

years, the portfolio is projected to shift to a position of unrealized loss at the start

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Projections for the 10-Year Treasury Term Premium Effect
(Basis Points)
Date

April Tealbook
baseline

Higher term
premiums

March
Tealbook

Quarterly Averages
-103
-99
-95

-106
-102
-98

-103
-98
-94

2017:Q4
2018:Q4
2019:Q4
2020:Q4
2021:Q4
2022:Q4
2023:Q4
2024:Q4
2025:Q4

-78
-65
-55
-46
-39
-33
-27
-21
-15

-81
-67
-56
-47
-40
-34
-28
-22
-16

-77
-64
-54
-45
-38
-32
-26
-20
-15

Projections

2016:Q2
Q3
Q4

Page 46 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

purchase programs mature and new securities are added to the portfolio at
prevailing market yields.
Under the higher term premiums scenario, the portfolio is projected to shift to a
position of unrealized loss next quarter, as the sudden increase in term premiums
triggers price drops in SOMA Treasury and MBS holdings. The mark-to-market
value of the portfolio declines more precipitously than in the baseline scenario,
recording a peak unrealized loss of about $300 billion in 2017. The net
unrealized loss position of the SOMA portfolio under both scenarios converge in
2020, in line with the corresponding paths for longer-term interest rates.


Term premium effects. As shown in the table “Projections for the 10-Year
Treasury Term Premium Effect,” under the baseline scenario, the Federal
Reserve’s elevated stock of longer-term securities is estimated to hold down the
term premium embedded in the 10-year Treasury yield by 103 basis points in the
current quarter. Over the next couple of years, the estimated term premium effect
diminishes at a pace of about 4 basis points per quarter, reflecting in part the
gradual projected shrinking of the portfolio. The projection for the term premium
effect under the baseline scenario is about unchanged from the March Tealbook.
Under the higher term premiums scenario, because the path of the SOMA
change in the term premium effect stemming from SOMA holdings.6



SOMA Characteristics. Regarding the size of the portfolio, under both the
baseline and the higher term premiums scenarios, approximately $216 billion in
SOMA Treasury holdings will mature this year, and a total of $1.3 trillion will
mature between 2016 and 2020 (see the top panel of the exhibit “Projections for
the Characteristics of SOMA Holdings”).7 The amounts of Treasury securities

6

The overall term premium on longer-dated Treasury securities reflects investors’ willingness to
bear interest rate risk as well as the effects of the elevated stock of longer-term securities in the Federal
Reserve’s portfolio. The spike in the term premium assumed in the context of the “Sharp Increases in Term
Premiums” scenario is entirely driven by the first component and is thus unrelated to the effect stemming
from the Federal Reserve’s portfolio holdings.
7
While following its current reinvestment policy, the Desk replaces maturing Treasury security
holdings with newly issued debt at Treasury auctions. Consistent with longstanding practice, these
rollovers are carried out at Treasury auctions by placing bids for the SOMA in a par amount equal to the

Page 47 of 52

Projections

portfolio is not meaningfully different from the baseline scenario, there is little

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

Projections for the Characteristics of SOMA Holdings
Projected Receipts of Principal on SOMA Securities
Billions of Dollars

Projected MBS Paydowns
Treasury Maturities
80

60

40

20

0
2017

2018

2019

2020

SOMA Weighted−Average Treasury Duration
Monthly

Years

Projections

April Tealbook baseline
Higher term premiums

10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

Page 48 of 52

2018

2020

2022

2024

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

maturing each month vary considerably, while projected MBS paydowns are
much less variable. However, realized MBS paydowns will reflect the evolution
over time of interest rates and other factors and could thus be significantly more
volatile than projected.
The weighted-average duration of the SOMA Treasury portfolio is currently about
6½ years (see the bottom panel of the exhibit). Under the baseline and the higher
term premiums scenarios, it is projected to be about four and five months shorter,
respectively, at the end of this year.8 The weighted-average duration is projected
to decline through 2017 under both scenarios, reflecting the end of reinvestments
as well as the aging of the portfolio, and subsequently to rise through 2021, when
the size of the balance sheet is normalized.9 After reaching its peak, duration is
projected to resume its decline in both scenarios as the Desk starts purchasing
Treasury securities to keep pace with the increase in currency. In particular, the
duration contour in this latter portion of the projection is based on the key
assumption that the Federal Reserve will buy only Treasury bills until those
holdings are equal to approximately 30 percent of the Treasury portfolio, similar
to the pre-crisis composition of the portfolio (currently there are no Treasury bill
holdings). Thereafter, purchases of Treasury securities are assumed to be spread

Projections

across the maturity spectrum.10

value of holdings maturing on the issue date of a newly issued security. Moreover, across the various
maturities, these bids are placed proportionately to the issue amounts of the new securities. The Desk’s
bids at Treasury auctions are placed as noncompetitive tenders and are treated as add-ons to announced
auction sizes.
8
The July 2015 Tealbook B box “History and Projections for the Characteristics of SOMA
Treasury Holdings” provides more information on the duration of the SOMA Treasury portfolio.
9
The duration of the SOMA Treasury portfolio initially declines once reinvestments cease, as
Treasury securities in the portfolio approach maturity. Once the pace of roll-offs accelerates starting in
2018 and longer tenor securities account for a larger share in the remaining portfolio, duration increases
until the balance sheet is normalized.
10
We assume zero purchases of agency MBS after reinvestments cease.

Page 49 of 52

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

Projections

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 50 of 52

April 21, 2016

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

Abbreviations
ABS

asset-backed securities

BEA

Bureau of Economic Analysis, Department of Commerce

BHC

bank holding company

CDS

credit default swaps

CFTC

Commodity Futures Trading Commission

C&I

commercial and industrial

CLO

collateralized loan obligation

CMBS

commercial mortgage-backed securities

CPI

consumer price index

CRE

commercial real estate

Desk

Open Market Desk

DSGE

dynamic stochastic general equilibrium

ECB

European Central Bank

EDO

Estimated, dynamic, optimization-based model

ELB

effective lower bound

EME

emerging market economy

FDIC

Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation

FOMC

Federal Open Market Committee; also, the Committee

GCF

general collateral finance

GDI

gross domestic income

GDP

gross domestic product

GSIBs

globally systemically important banking organizations

HQLA

high-quality liquid assets

ISM

Institute for Supply Management

LIBOR

London interbank offered rate

MBS

mortgage-backed securities

MMFs

money market funds

Page 51 of 52

April 21, 2016

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

April 21, 2016

NBER

National Bureau of Economic Research

NI

nominal income

NIPA

national income and product accounts

OIS

overnight index swap

ON RRP

overnight reverse repurchase agreement

PCE

personal consumption expenditures

repo

repurchase agreement

RMBS

residential mortgage-backed securities

RRP

reverse repurchase agreement

SCOOS

Senior Credit Officer Opinion Survey on Dealer Financing Terms

SEP

Summary of Economic Projections

SFA

Supplemental Financing Account

SLOOS

Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices

SOMA

System Open Market Account

TBA

to be announced (for example, TBA market)

TGA

U.S. Treasury’s General Account

TIPS

Treasury inflation-protected securities

TPE

Term premium effects

Page 52 of 52