View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

EXAMINING THE RELATIONSHIP
BETWEEN PRUDENTIAL REGULATION
AND MONETARY POLICY AT THE
FEDERAL RESERVE

JOINT HEARING
BEFORE THE

SUBCOMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS
AND CONSUMER CREDIT
AND THE

SUBCOMMITTEE ON MONETARY
POLICY AND TRADE
OF THE

COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES
U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
ONE HUNDRED FIFTEENTH CONGRESS
FIRST SESSION

SEPTEMBER 12, 2017

Printed for the use of the Committee on Financial Services

Serial No. 115–40

(
U.S. GOVERNMENT PUBLISHING OFFICE
WASHINGTON

29–541 PDF

:

2018

For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Publishing Office
Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) 512–1800; DC area (202) 512–1800
Fax: (202) 512–2104 Mail: Stop IDCC, Washington, DC 20402–0001

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00001

Fmt 5011

Sfmt 5011

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES
JEB HENSARLING, Texas, Chairman
PATRICK T. MCHENRY, North Carolina,
Vice Chairman
PETER T. KING, New York
EDWARD R. ROYCE, California
FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma
STEVAN PEARCE, New Mexico
BILL POSEY, Florida
BLAINE LUETKEMEYER, Missouri
BILL HUIZENGA, Michigan
SEAN P. DUFFY, Wisconsin
STEVE STIVERS, Ohio
RANDY HULTGREN, Illinois
DENNIS A. ROSS, Florida
ROBERT PITTENGER, North Carolina
ANN WAGNER, Missouri
ANDY BARR, Kentucky
KEITH J. ROTHFUS, Pennsylvania
LUKE MESSER, Indiana
SCOTT TIPTON, Colorado
ROGER WILLIAMS, Texas
BRUCE POLIQUIN, Maine
MIA LOVE, Utah
FRENCH HILL, Arkansas
TOM EMMER, Minnesota
LEE M. ZELDIN, New York
DAVID A. TROTT, Michigan
BARRY LOUDERMILK, Georgia
ALEXANDER X. MOONEY, West Virginia
THOMAS MacARTHUR, New Jersey
WARREN DAVIDSON, Ohio
TED BUDD, North Carolina
DAVID KUSTOFF, Tennessee
CLAUDIA TENNEY, New York
TREY HOLLINGSWORTH, Indiana

MAXINE WATERS, California, Ranking
Member
CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York
NYDIA M. VELÁZQUEZ, New York
BRAD SHERMAN, California
GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York
MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts
WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri
STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts
DAVID SCOTT, Georgia
AL GREEN, Texas
EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri
GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin
KEITH ELLISON, Minnesota
ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado
JAMES A. HIMES, Connecticut
BILL FOSTER, Illinois
DANIEL T. KILDEE, Michigan
JOHN K. DELANEY, Maryland
KYRSTEN SINEMA, Arizona
JOYCE BEATTY, Ohio
DENNY HECK, Washington
JUAN VARGAS, California
JOSH GOTTHEIMER, New Jersey
VICENTE GONZALEZ, Texas
CHARLIE CRIST, Florida
RUBEN KIHUEN, Nevada

KIRSTEN SUTTON MORK, Staff Director

(II)

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00002

Fmt 5904

Sfmt 5904

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

SUBCOMMITTEE

ON

FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS

AND

CONSUMER CREDIT

BLAINE LUETKEMEYER, Missouri, Chairman
KEITH J. ROTHFUS, Pennsylvania, Vice
Chairman
EDWARD R. ROYCE, California
FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma
BILL POSEY, Florida
DENNIS A. ROSS, Florida
ROBERT PITTENGER, North Carolina
ANDY BARR, Kentucky
SCOTT TIPTON, Colorado
ROGER WILLIAMS, Texas
MIA LOVE, Utah
DAVID A. TROTT, Michigan
BARRY LOUDERMILK, Georgia
DAVID KUSTOFF, Tennessee
CLAUDIA TENNEY, New York

WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri, Ranking
Member
CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York
GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York
DAVID SCOTT, Georgia
NYDIA M. VELÁZQUEZ, New York
AL GREEN, Texas
KEITH ELLISON, Minnesota
MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts
DENNY HECK, Washington
GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin
CHARLIE CRIST, Florida

(III)

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00003

Fmt 5904

Sfmt 5904

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

SUBCOMMITTEE

ON

MONETARY POLICY

AND

TRADE

ANDY BARR, Kentucky, Chairman
ROGER WILLIAMS, Texas, Vice Chairman
FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma
BILL HUIZENGA, Michigan
ROBERT PITTENGER, North Carolina
MIA LOVE, Utah
FRENCH HILL, Arkansas
TOM EMMER, Minnesota
ALEXANDER X. MOONEY, West Virginia
WARREN DAVIDSON, Ohio
CLAUDIA TENNEY, New York
TREY HOLLINGSWORTH, Indiana

GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin, Ranking Member
GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York
BILL FOSTER, Illinois
BRAD SHERMAN, California
AL GREEN, Texas
DENNY HECK, Washington
DANIEL T. KILDEE, Michigan
JUAN VARGAS, California
CHARLIE CRIST, Florida

(IV)

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00004

Fmt 5904

Sfmt 5904

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

CONTENTS
Page

Hearing held on:
September 12, 2017 ..........................................................................................
Appendix:
September 12, 2017 ..........................................................................................

1
43

WITNESSES
TUESDAY, SEPTEMBER 12, 2017
Calomiris, Charles W., Henry Kaufman Professor of Financial Institutions,
Columbia Business School, Columbia University ..............................................
Cecchetti, Stephen G., Rosen Family Chair in International Finance, Brandeis
International Business School, Brandeis University ........................................
Sivon, James C., Partner, Barnett Sivon & Natter P.C., on behalf of the
Financial Services Roundtable ............................................................................

5
7
8

APPENDIX
Prepared statements:
Calomiris, Charles W. ......................................................................................
Cecchetti, Stephen G. .......................................................................................
Sivon, James C. ................................................................................................

(V)

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00005

Fmt 5904

Sfmt 5904

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

44
117
125

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00006

Fmt 5904

Sfmt 5904

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

EXAMINING THE RELATIONSHIP
BETWEEN PRUDENTIAL REGULATION
AND MONETARY POLICY AT THE
FEDERAL RESERVE
Tuesday, September 12, 2017

U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES,
SUBCOMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS
AND CONSUMER CREDIT,
AND SUBCOMMITTEE ON MONETARY
POLICY AND TRADE,
COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES,
Washington, D.C.
The subcommittees met, pursuant to notice, at 2:02 p.m., in room
2128, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Andy Barr [chairman
of the Subcommittee on Monetary Policy and Trade] presiding.
Members present: Representatives Luetkemeyer, Barr, Rothfus,
Royce, Huizenga, Pittenger, Tipton, Hill, Emmer, Davidson,
Kustoff, Tenney, Hollingsworth; Clay, Moore, Sherman, Scott, Foster, Kildee, and Heck.
Ex officio present: Representative Hensarling.
Chairman BARR. The subcommittees will come to order.
Without objection, the Chair is authorized to declare a recess of
the subcommittees at any time.
Today’s hearing is entitled, ‘‘Examining the Relationship Between Prudential Regulation and Monetary Policy at the Federal
Reserve.’’
I now recognize myself for 21⁄2 minutes to give an opening statement.
Congress tasked the Federal Reserve System with responsibilities for both monetary policy and financial regulation. A fundamental question for today is whether these responsibilities complement or conflict with each other. The stakes are much more
than academic. Monetary policy and financial regulation play
foundational roles in the economic opportunities that can and
should be available to every American household.
To fully realize these opportunities, we need monetary policies
and financial regulations to build from the ground up. Only in that
way can real goods and services, which include labor, reliably find
their most promising opportunities and do so in a timely and efficient manner.
Today, we will examine how this most basic of economic services
can be produced more consistently and distributed more broadly.
We will examine whether monetary policy and financial regulation
(1)

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00007

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

2
should be housed under the same roof as it is in our Federal Reserve System or if monetary policy and financial regulation could
both work better with greater independence and accountability.
If monetary policy and financial regulation do not work, then our
economy cannot work. When monetary policies and financial regulations lack independence and accountability, even the most dutiful
efforts from households and businesses cannot bridge the gap to
our full potential. Viewed in this light, Americans are rightly disappointed with our economic opportunities. Despite 8 years of recovery, growth has been slow and weak, and our economy has yet
to realize its full potential. The accumulated loss of economic opportunity has risen to almost $13 trillion. That is almost $100,000
per household on average and considerably larger than China’s
economy, the world’s second largest.
Putting an end to these losses is not enough. We must reestablish a more vibrant and resilient economy. The 3-percent growth
we produced last quarter is a good start. To build on that promising economic report, however, we must make sure that our institutions for monetary policy and financial regulation are effectively
organized.
I look forward to testimony from this afternoon’s distinguished
witnesses on how we can do just that.
The Chair now recognizes the ranking member of the Subcommittee on Monetary Policy and Trade, the gentlelady from Wisconsin, Gwen Moore, for 5 minutes for an opening statement.
Ms. MOORE. Thank so much, Mr. Chairman.
Good morning to our witnesses. I have to warn you to prepare
yourself for a discussion on the dual mandate of the Fed, despite
the title of this hearing. The other side always wants to challenge
the propriety of being concerned about employment, which sounds
like a good idea to me. I don’t know why we would turn employment into a bogeyman.
But that being said, the central question that the Republicans
will be asking here today is whether Congress should hamper the
Federal Reserve’s bank supervision authority. Now let me really
quickly address the bad idea of creating a distinction between monetary policy and supervisory functions of the Fed as a raison d’etre
for the GOP to cripple banking regulations through the appropriations process so that they can come in and just take money away
from the Fed if they don’t like what regulations come down the
pike.
First, the Fed sets a single interest rate, and then those rates
are transmitted to dealer banks. So the Fed uses the institutions
it regulates as agents in transmitting monetary policy.
Secondly, the Fed acts as a lender of last resort. So it makes
sense for it to oversee and have supervisory functions over those
institutions that may one day need liquidity support, unless you
want the Fed playing behind the eight ball in a crisis.
Thirdly, the Fed in its function as a central bank sets leverage
requirements and underwriting standards. These are both supervisory and useful and targeted tools to combat market bubbles.
Fourth, the supervision provides valuable insight on the economic outlook, which plays a role in how the Fed sets the monetary
policy.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00008

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

3
Finally, the Fed, of course, is the systemic regulator of our financial system. Following the 2008 financial crisis, Dodd-Frank corrected a glaring hole—no, let me just call it a crater—in making
the Fed the regulatory agency of systemically significant firms.
The U.S. economy has grown post-Dodd-Frank, and the financial
system is far safer and fairer for consumers. So the ‘‘wrong choice’’
Act was a little more than a poisonous tonic for a healthy system.
And I would reserve the balance of my time, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman BARR. The Chair now recognizes the chairman of the
Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit, the
gentleman from Missouri, Blaine Luetkemeyer, for 21⁄2 minutes for
an opening statement.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate the opportunity to hold this hearing with you. And thank you
for your leadership on these issues.
The Financial Institutions Subcommittee has examined the growing role and influence of Federal financial regulators in the postDodd-Frank and Obama era. The Federal Reserve in particular
seems to be taking its supervisory authority to unparalleled
heights. Financial institutions operate in a world of ambiguous
guidance and aggressive enforcement. There is a near unanimous
feeling that document productions fall into a black hole with the
Fed providing little to no meaningful feedback on supervisory
issues.
Financial institutions also recognize that Fed policies are inconsistent. Several weeks ago, I had a conversation with two financial
institutions that offered a nearly identical product. One Fed district
expressed interest in seeing the product offered more widely. Another said the product was a danger to consumers and should be
shut down. I have also shared the story of small town and mid-Missouri that I represent, which has been in Fed purgatory for 5 years.
The Fed staff decided it didn’t like certain products, products to
which the FDIC and State of Missouri did not object and in fact
suggested be made more readily available. This inconsistent approach to regulation has a negative effect on the economy at the
local, national, and global levels. Federal Reserve officials have
said their work as prudential regulators informs their monetary
policy decisions, helping them to meet the charge to ensure global
financial stability. But the reality is that the Federal Reserve’s regulatory regime does not necessarily translate to a more stable economy. So we ask ourselves whether or not it is appropriate for the
Federal Reserve to be both a prudential regulator and the sole dictator of monetary policy.
As I said in the past, it is time to take the power out of Washington and demand a reasonable financial regulatory structure. It
is time to ensure that monetary policy decisions that impact the
daily lives of our constituents are made in a sound, unbiased manner. We have a distinguished panel with us today, and I look forward to the testimony.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
And I yield back the balance of my time.
Chairman BARR. The gentleman yields back.
The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from California, Mr.
Sherman, for 2 minutes for an opening statement.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00009

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

4
Mr. SHERMAN. When we are talking about the structure of the
Fed, we see a dramatically antidemocratic institution exercising
governmental power. First, the New York Bank gets a seat on the
Open Market Committee, whereas the California Bank, with twice
as many people, doesn’t. Second, substantial Fed powers in the
hands of those who are put on the Board in an election by banks.
This is the only institution of governmental power in our country
where we have the one—not ‘‘one person, one vote’’ but ‘‘$1 billion
in banking, one vote.’’
Second, our system does not provide capital to small businesses,
other than SBA. Small businesses are told: Use your credit cards
to finance business expansion or get some sort of shadow bank 36
percent loan. This is where the jobs, technology, and innovation is
going to come from, but it won’t come from small business if we tell
people, tell banks they can’t make a prime-plus-5 loan. That is in
effect what we have done. Back in the old days, you used to be able
to go to a business that had a 1 in 20 chance, 1 in 40 chance of
failure, and still make a loan and charge a few extra percentage
points. Now we have crushed that out of the banking system to the
huge disadvantages of small business.
Speaking of huge, too-big-to-fail is too-big-to-exist. And as the
Wells Fargo example shows us, it is too-big-to-manage.
Finally, when it comes to the Fed, we need lower interest rates
to create the labor shortage necessary to create major increases in
wages in our country. And we have low inflation, so we can do that
instead. In this committee room, the Fed is often told to raise interest rates, and that is antithetical to creating the labor shortage
that is necessary to help most Americans. And, of course, we need
more, not less, quantitative easing.
Finally, the Fed was able over to turn over $100 billion of profit
to the United States Government. We usually have the debt clock
in back of our witnesses, and now we have been pressuring the Fed
to stop giving us the $100 billion by reducing its balance sheet.
I yield back.
Chairman BARR. The gentleman’s time has expired.
We will now turn to our witnesses.
Dr. Charles Calomiris is the Henry Kaufman professor of financial institutions at the Columbia Business School, director of the
Business School’s Program for Financial Studies and its Initiative
on Finance and Growth in Emerging Markets, and a professor at
Columbia’s School of International and Public Affairs. His research
spans the areas of banking, corporate finance, financial history,
and monetary economics. He is a distinguished visiting fellow at
the Hoover Institution, a fellow at the Manhattan Institute, a
member of the Shadow Open Market Committee and the Financial
Economists Roundtable, and a research associate of the National
Bureau of Economic Research. He received a BA in economics from
Yale University, magna cum laude, and a Ph.D. in economics from
Stanford University. Professor Calomiris holds an honorary doctorate from the University of Basel.
Dr. Steven G. Cecchetti is the Rosen Family Chair in International Finance at the Brandeis International Business School, a
research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research,
and a research fellow of the Center for Economic Policy Research.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00010

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

5
His research interests include monetary policy, the economics of financial regulation, macroeconomic theory, and price and inflation
measurement. From 2008 to 2013, Professor Cecchetti served as
economic adviser and head of the Monetary and Economic Department at the Bank for International Settlements. During his time
at the Bank for International Settlements, Dr. Cecchetti participated in numerous post-crisis, global regulatory reform initiatives.
Professor Cecchetti holds an undergraduate degree from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, a doctorate from the University
of California, Berkeley, and an honorary doctorate in economics
from the University of Basel.
Mr. James Sivon is a partner in the Washington, D.C., law firm
of Barnett, Sivon & Natter, and is testifying today on behalf of the
Financial Services Roundtable as a specialist on financial services
law and regulations. Mr. Sivon is a member of the Executive Council of the Federal Bar Association’s Banking Law Committee and
the Executive Committee of the Exchequer Club. He is a former
senior vice president and general counsel for the Association of
Bank Holding Companies, and he served as the staff director for
the Republican Members of the U.S. House Committee on Banking,
Finance, and Urban Affairs. He received his undergraduate degree
from Denison University, and his law degree from Georgetown University Law Center.
Each of you will be recognized for 5 minutes to give an oral presentation of your testimony. And without objection, each of your
written statements will be made a part of the record.
Dr. Calomiris, you are now recognized for 5 minutes.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
STATEMENT OF CHARLES W. CALOMIRIS, HENRY KAUFMAN
PROFESSOR OF FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS, COLUMBIA BUSINESS SCHOOL, COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY

Chairman Barr, Chairman Luetkemeyer, Ranking Members
Moore and Clay, it is a pleasure to be with you today, and I will
deliver a summary of my written testimony, which I have submitted.
The Federal Reserve is now more politicized than it has been at
any time in its history, and, consequently, it is also less independent in its actions than almost any time in its history.
As the Fed accumulates more and bigger political lightning rods
of discretionary power, the Fed finds itself increasingly politicized
and less independent, both in the realm of monetary policy and in
regulatory and supervisory reactions. With discretionary power inevitably comes attacks by special interests seeking to manipulate
those powers. The Fed finds itself making political deals with special interests and their representatives largely as a result of its
burgeoning discretion.
Also, Fed leaders routinely offer distorted and self-interested
opinions about reform proposals while pretending that their opinions should be viewed as unbiased professional analysis. Fed Chair
Janet Yellen’s August 2017 Jackson Hole speech was a fullthroated defense of the status quo of financial regulation. But that
speech ignored scores of studies that contradict the narrative that
she offered. Many of the studies she ignored were written by econo-

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00011

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

6
mists working at the Federal Reserve Board, the various Federal
Reserve banks, the OFR, as well as top academic researchers.
Don’t be fooled by the charade: Financial regulatory policy is unbalanced, unlikely to prove effective in achieving its stated objectives, and fails to meet basic standards of due process for a democracy operating under the rule of law.
Reforms can fix those problems. And I want to emphasize I am
here to talk about reform, not just deregulation.
The ideal set of reforms would include clear rules to guide both
monetary policy and regulatory policy, would avoid undesirable
conflicts of interest, especially by placing day-to-day regulatory and
supervisory authority in an agency other than the Fed, and would
establish administrative and budgetary discipline over the process
of regulation supervision.
A less drastic set of reforms that wouldn’t remove the Fed from
those activities could still accomplish a great deal of improvement.
Specifically, if it were possible to establish clear rules governing
both monetary and regulatory policy and impose administrative
and budgetary discipline on the process of regulation, then, even if
regulatory and supervisory powers remained vested in the Fed, the
problems associated with Fed conflicts and politicization would be
substantially reduced.
Requiring Congress to weigh the social costs and benefits that
arise in regulation likely would limit special interest manipulation
of regulatory discretion after regulations are passed. I would refer
you to a recent paper by two political scientists, Gordon and Rosenthal, for a discussion of how the delegation to regulatory discretion
undermined the intended risk-limiting provisions of Dodd-Frank
with respect to the mortgage market.
Most importantly, to improve and depoliticize regulation, Congress must establish clear rules that limit the use of unaccountable
discretion, must establish budgetary authority for regulatory implementation, and must limit the abusive reliance on guidance in regulatory actions by requiring a much greater reliance on formal
rulemaking consistent with the Administrative Procedures Act. If
this were done alongside the establishment of a flexible monetary
policy rule, that would go a long way toward restoring balance in
the regulatory process, depoliticizing the Fed, and ensuring accountability of monitoring regulatory policy. These changes would
have major positive consequences for the economy.
Only by clarifying the goals of the Fed and requiring it to work
within clear rules can regulatory and monetary policy be improved
to make those policies focus on long-run objectives, avoid short-run
politicization, ensure appropriate balance and due process in regulation supervision, and make the Fed accountable to the will of the
people. Thank you.
[The prepared statement of Dr. Calomiris can be found on page
44 of the appendix.]
Chairman BARR. Thank you.
Dr. Cecchetti, you are now recognized for 5 minutes.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00012

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

7
STATEMENT OF STEPHEN G. CECCHETTI, ROSEN FAMILY
CHAIR IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE, BRANDEIS INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS SCHOOL, BRANDEIS UNIVERSITY

Mr. CECCHETTI. Thank you, Chairman Barr, Ranking Member
Moore, Ranking Member Clay, and members of the subcommittees.
Thank you for inviting me to present my views on the relationship
between prudential supervision and monetary policy.
The U.S. financial system is far more resilient today than it was
a decade ago. And the likelihood of another systemwide crisis is
now lower. As a consequence of post-crisis regulatory reforms,
banks have more loss-absorbing equity capital than they had in
2007, and they also face liquidity requirements. And the biggest
among them must meet rigorous stress tests. Importantly, this new
environment ensures that all large complex financial organizations
are much less likely to become a burden on the taxpayer.
It is important that we build on this progress. Regulations must
remain sufficiently strict and supervisors must interpret and imply
the rules rigorously.
My comments today focus on governance. I will make two points.
First, prudential supervision needs to be an independent function
sheltered from day-to-day political influence with control of its own
budget. And, second, the central bank should be a lead supervisor,
supervising systemically important institutions.
Starting with independence, we all agree that, because of their
ability to take a long view, independent central banks deliver lower
inflation without sacrificing higher employment and higher growth.
What is true for monetary policy is true for supervisors. Supervisors can maintain a long-term view if they are sheltered from political influence, including having control over their own budget.
This form of independence gives them the ability to credibly enforce
rigorous regulatory standards, thereby promoting financial resilience and reducing public costs.
It is equally important that the central bank be a leading supervisor. Supervision is integral to the central bank’s core functions as
the lender of last resort, the monetary authority and the organization responsible for the health and stability of the overall financial
system. Let me explain why.
To protect the integrity of the system and the public finances,
the lender of last resort needs to be able to determine a borrowing
institution’s solvency and the value of the collateral being posted
to back a loan. That is, a lender needs to know whether the borrower will be able to repay. This requires confidential financial assessments, knowledge of the firm’s business practices, and the
skills to value illiquid assets—all things that supervisors generally
have.
Importantly, this information has to be available to high-ranking
central bank officials on very short notice. In some cases, decisions
have to be made in a matter of minutes. So the quality of data
must be without question, and it cannot be in the hands of people
who may or may not choose to share it.
Turning to the relationship between monetary policy and prudential supervision, to quote from Paul Volcker’s testimony before the
Financial Services Committee in May of 2010, these two functions
are inextricably intertwined. As a practical matter, it is impossible

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00013

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

8
to say where one stops and the other one starts. This is true because the people engaged in these functions operate as a team,
sharing knowledge and expertise that each requires from the other.
That is, monetary policymakers require supervisory information to
evaluate the state of the financial system and supervisors use monetary policymakers’ understanding of economic prospects to evaluate the safety and soundness of individual institutions.
Finally, there is the fact that the central bank is responsible for
systemic stability. The Federal Reserve does not have an explicit
financial stability mandate, but without a stable financial system,
the Fed would surely fail to achieve their statutory objectives of
maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.
Identifying threats to the financial system requires a specialized
set of skills as well as day-to-day access, all things that the Federal
Reserve has information on.
In closing, let me emphasize my firm belief that when supervisors are independent of political interference, complete with
budgetary autonomy, the financial system is more stable and taxpayer costs are lower. Furthermore, a supervisory function is essential for effective and efficient execution of core central bank
functions. As the lender of the last resort, the monetary policy authority, and the guardian of health and stability of the overall financial system, it is essential that the Federal Reserve remain a
leading supervisor, especially for systemically important institutions. The American public would be ill-served if that were to
change.
Thank you. And I would be pleased to respond to questions.
[The prepared statement of Dr. Cecchetti can be found on page
117 of the appendix.]
Chairman BARR. Thank you.
And Mr. Sivon, you are recognized for 5 minutes.
STATEMENT OF JAMES C. SIVON, PARTNER, BARNETT SIVON &
NATTER P.C., ON BEHALF OF THE FINANCIAL SERVICES
ROUNDTABLE

Mr. SIVON. Chairman Barr, Ranking Member Moore, Chairman
Luetkemeyer, Ranking Member Clay, and members of the subcommittees, my name is Jim Sivon, and I am appearing on behalf
of the Financial Services Roundtable (FSR). Thank you for inviting
FSR to participate in the hearing.
A decade ago, gaps in regulations contributed to a financial crisis. Subsequent actions by Congress and regulators in the industry
itself have restored the stability of the financial system. Since the
crisis, large bank holding companies have increased their capital
levels by $700 billion and increased their aggregate holdings of
highly liquid assets by more than 50 percent.
Yet some of the regulations put in place since the crisis are holding back a more robust recovery. Data on loans to mortgage borrowers and small businesses illustrates this problem. Also, an analysis of post-crisis lending conducted by the Federal Reserve Board
has found that lending growth by the more heavily regulated large
banks lags behind lending growth of small banks.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00014

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

9
FSR believes that the goal of prudential regulation should be to
promote both financial stability and economic growth. FSR appreciates the steps the Board has taken to tailor some regulations.
However, more could be done.
I will briefly describe some of FSR’s recommendations for tailoring existing regulations, starting with the capital planning and
stress testing rules.
The capital planning and stress testing rules have helped FSR
members build stronger capital positions and improve risk-management practices. Recent stress test results show that large bank
holding companies can withstand an economic downturn even more
severe than the 2008 financial crisis. However, the rules could be
adjusted without impairing their fundamental purpose. FSR supports more disclosure regarding the models used by the Board in
conducting stress tests. Disparities in loss projections between the
models used by FSR members and those used by the Board create
a level of uncertainty that impacts lending practices.
The stress test results also indicate that we have reached a point
where the capital and liquidity rules could be adjusted to promote
more economic growth without jeopardizing financial stability. For
example, FSR recommends that the supplementary leverage ratio
exclude risk-free assets from the calculation of a company’s total
assets and that the liquidity rule be revised to give more favorable
treatment to certain securities and the runoff assumptions in that
rule be aligned with the historical experience.
Resolution planning has helped FSR members rationalize operations and contracts, yet this requirement, combined with separate
recovery planning requirements, is an area where greater coordination among the agencies is needed. As a result of the Dodd-Frank
Act, the Board gained regulatory authority over a number of insurance companies. While the Board has indicated a willingness to tailor regulations for those companies, FSR believes the Board could
be more attentive to the differences between the business of insurance and the business of banking.
FSR recommends that the Board and other Federal regulators
revisit the Volcker Rule. For example, FSR recommends that the
Rule exempt institutions that are not complex or interconnected
and that the prohibitions on trading and investments be narrowed.
FSR also has three general recommendations for better aligning
financial regulation with economic growth. First, FSR recommends
that prudential standards be based upon risk assessments, not arbitrary asset thresholds. Second, FSR encourages Congress to promote greater coordination among Federal financial regulators. Enhancing coordination would not require restructuring of the agencies. Greater coordination could be achieved through the enactment
of a set of guiding principles, such as those proposed by the Executive Order on core principles for regulating the U.S. financial system.
Finally, FSR recommends that Congress evaluate the impact of
the current expected credit loss, or CECL, accounting standard,
which we believe will require an adjustment on how bank capital
standards are calculated.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00015

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

10
Thank you again for the opportunity to address the Board’s role
as a prudential regulator, and I would be pleased to answer any
questions.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Sivon can be found on page 125
of the appendix.]
Chairman BARR. The gentleman yields back.
And the Chair now recognizes himself for 5 minutes for questions.
Dr. Calomiris, in Dr. Cecchetti’s testimony, he argued that monetary policy and prudential supervision are complementary, and I
believe he quoted former Chairman Volcker in making the argument that the two are inextricably intertwined. And I hear this frequently when I have conversations with Fed officials who make the
argument that their supervisory activities inform their monetary
policy decisionmaking.
There are dissenting views on this argument. Vincent Reinhart,
the former Secretary of the Fed’s Monetary Policy Committee, observed that if the FOMC made materially better decisions because
of the Fed’s role and supervision, there should be instances of informed discussion of the linkages. Anyone making the case for beneficial spillovers should be asked to produce numerous relevant excerpts from that historical resource. I don’t think they will be able
to do so.
Lars Svenson, who served on the faculty of Princeton and as a
Deputy Governor for the Central Bank of Sweden, presented research to the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston in 2015, arguing
that, ‘‘monetary policy cannot achieve financial stability.’’
And even former Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke expressed concern
about expanding the Fed’s dual mandate to also include responsibility for ‘‘reducing risks to financial stability.’’
So my question to you, Dr. Calomiris, is, could we enjoy better
monetary policy and financial regulation if there was more independence and accountability?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Absolutely. And I think there is a confusion between—that often comes up among three different activities. One
of them is called regulation. The other is called supervision. And
the third one is called examination. Now, in the Treasury White
Paper of 2008, where they proposed removing the Fed from day-today control over regulation, supervision, they specifically pointed
out that that would not mean that the Fed would be removed from
constant contact with financial institutions and from the participation examination process which is necessary to its role as lender of
last resort. And that is what Paul Volcker was referring to. And
when Paul Volcker was testifying about those matters, he also
pointed out, very much consistent with my testimony, that the increased regulatory functions that were envisioned in Dodd-Frank
for the Fed were going to be a politicization problem.
Chairman BARR. Can I follow up right there?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. It is a very important distinction.
Chairman BARR. In the argument about politicization, can you
give a concrete example or two of how the combination of Fed regulation and monetary policy politicizes each of them?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Yes. Well, the most common pattern over the
past few decades has been that Fed officials are extremely con-

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00016

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

11
cerned about insulating their independence in monetary policy, and
they often basically use regulatory policy as a sacrificial lamb. So
they make political deals on the regulatory policy side in order to
preserve the monetary policy autonomy. Now they wouldn’t need to
do that if monetary policy actually followed rules, because then
that would ensure, that would defend them against those attacks.
So, by combining the regulatory policy and the monetary policy,
basically, the Fed has often been put into a position—I am not attacking individual Fed policymakers—where they make concessions
to special interests on regulatory policy in order to try to defend
their discretion in monetary policy.
I can give you a few recent examples. I think the Fed’s complicity
in Operation Choke Point was a disgrace. That was true of the
other regulators too, by the way. But this is something where basically if we can have our regulatory officials engaging in Operation
Choke Point, there is pretty much nothing that we can’t have them
engaged in. We are not protected in any way for living in a country, a popular sovereignty country under rule of law. And that was
clearly under political pressure and, again, deals that are being
made with certain constituencies.
And I think that there are other examples. There have been rumors at the highest levels of the Federal Reserve, people I know,
that actually Members of Congress have been very involved in trying to get appointments to occur in certain Federal Reserve presidencies. I can go on. There is a long list.
Chairman BARR. In the remaining time, do you think that funding the Fed’s regulatory and supervisory responsibilities through
appropriations would strengthen monetary policy independence?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Absolutely. And it would because it would, again,
help defend the Fed policymakers as all rules do against this kind
of special interest interventions.
I would also—
Chairman BARR. My time has expired on that so I am going to
have to cut you off there. Thank you for the testimony.
The Chair now recognizes the distinguished ranking member,
Congresswoman Gwen Moore, for 5 minutes.
Ms. MOORE. Thank you so much, Mr. Chairman.
As I expected, this is a tremendous panel, a tremendous knowledge base, and I appreciate the witnesses for being here.
I am just feeling a little bit puzzled and confused because this
hearing is talking about the supervisory responsibilities of the Fed
and setting monetary policy and discussions about the independence of the Fed. And it is not clear to me how subjecting them to
the appropriations process makes them more independent. I have
meetings in my office all the time with bankers who—people who
want us to do this or to do that. And if you can get the ear of
whomever is in the Majority at any given time, and the appropriators, then you can wield your weight. So it is not really clear to
me how subjecting them to the appropriations process makes them
independent. It is kind of oxymoronic.
Wouldn’t you agree with that, Dr. Cecchetti?
Mr. CECCHETTI. Yes, I would. I think that—
Ms. MOORE. And please give us the examples you weren’t able
to give us during your short testimony about how this works.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00017

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

12
Mr. CECCHETTI. Yes, there is a set of very straightforward examples. First of all, let my start by saying that one of the Basel Committee’s core principles for effective supervision is independence of
the supervisors, including independent budgetary authority. I agree
with you that it is very difficult to understand how giving politicians the control of budget is a way of improving people’s independence.
I do agree, however, that in a Congressional, in a democratic
process with the Congress, that it is your role to give objectives to
independent authorities and then to hold them accountable for
meeting those objectives.
The examples that I would point to would be primarily—there
are two examples that I would point to domestically and several
internationally. So the Federal Home Loan Banks were subjected
to the appropriations process, and we ended up with the savings
and loan crisis. OFHEO was subjected to the appropriations process, and we ended up with Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac on the
government’s—as being in conservatorship.
If I look internationally, I can point to the cases in Korea, Indonesia where the crises in the late 1990s occurred, and those were
crises that occurred as a consequence of supervision being political.
And, finally, I would say—
Ms. MOORE. How about Zimbabwe?
Mr. CECCHETTI. Zimbabwe has even bigger problems. They don’t
have independent monetary policy either. So I think that these—
in most of these other examples, we at least independent monetary—
Ms. MOORE. Let me ask you this follow-up question. Unless I am
hearing wrong, it almost sounds to me that people are challenging
the role of central banks globally. If we are suggesting a model
where we create some new ghost agency that does the supervision
versus our central banks, what are we proposing to model for the
rest of the world, and how would this work? Central banks typically have the credibility because they are independent—can you
just weigh in on that?
Mr. CECCHETTI. Yes, I think that is an extremely good point. And
I think that—one of the things that I would say is that the lender—I emphasized in my comments and you did as well in your introduction about the lender-of-last-resort function. I think the lender-of-last-resort function relies extremely heavily on supervisory information, on the information about the safety and soundness of an
institution and about the quality of the assets that it has on its
balance sheet. If someone else is doing that, then what that means
is that you are going to have the lending being done outside the
central banks. So, as you point out, you would need to create a
shadow central bank somehow. And I can’t imagine having a second central bank.
Ms. MOORE. One last question in my remaining seconds here
that is a source of confusion for me. If we are pushing for independence of the bank—I keep hearing this notion that we need to have
some sort of monetary rule. We had Dr. Taylor here, for example.
How does having some kind of rule square with a bank being independent?

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00018

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

13
Mr. CECCHETTI. I think we are out of time, but the answer is it
doesn’t really square with that. And what we need is an objective
that is set by you, the Congress, and then accountability for meeting that objective.
Ms. MOORE. Thank you for your indulgence and thank you.
Chairman BARR. The gentlelady’s time has expired.
The Chair now recognizes the chairman of the Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit Subcommittee, Mr. Luetkemeyer, for 5
minutes.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Before I begin my questioning, I would like to recognize that we
are missing a few of our colleagues today. Some, like Mr. Posey and
Mr. Ross, are home in Florida dealing with the aftermath of Hurricane Irma. Our thoughts are with them and all those impacted by
not only Irma but Hurricane Harvey as well.
Our prayers are also with our friend and colleague, Barry
Loudermilk, who was injured in a car accident early this morning.
Both Congressman Loudermilk and his wife were transported to
the hospital with non-life-threatening injuries and have been released. We will keep both of them in our thoughts, and pray for a
speedy recovery for both Barry and his wife, Desiree.
As we can see, life goes on, but life is affected, and it is very,
very important. As important as this hearing is, keep it in perspective.
Thank you, gentlemen, for being here today. It is certainly an
honor to be able to discuss with you some concerns and some information we would like to get from you with regards to Fed regulation and monetary policy.
Mr. Sivon, last month, I sent a letter to Chair Yellen expressing
concern over the FBO rule and the impact it would have, not only
on foreign banks in the United States but also on U.S. banks operating internationally. We are on the cusp of seeing capital unnecessarily ring-fenced across the globe. Does that really contribute to
global financial security? As a follow-up, is there any argument to
be made that the Fed’s actions have dampened the global economy?
Mr. SIVON. Thank you, Congressman.
In my testimony, I expressed that one of the major concerns of
the Roundtable is a lack of coordination and cooperation here domestically among the various Federal financial regulatory agencies.
That applies globally as well. And so the issue that you have raised
is illustrative of the fact that there is a lack of sufficient coordination among international regulators that is leading to some consequences, and one of those consequences is ring-fencing, where institutions are asked to trap certain assets and capital in certain locations and then do not have the ability and flexibility to move
those as business needs.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. And in your judgement, I assume you
believe that does affect the global economy?
Mr. SIVON. Yes, I do, and I would suggest that there is a need
for some kind of overarching principles that international regulators, including the Fed, could agree upon to avoid that type of
consequence.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. You talked about the coordination not
only globally, but you also mentioned within our country here. And

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00019

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

14
one of the things—I point to the Treasury report recently put out
back in, I think it was June. And in the back of the report here,
it has a lot of recommendations, and one of them deals with trying
to stop the overlap of regulations, to find more coordination between all the different regulatory agencies. And I guess in here, it
talks—it lists the agency that it should be applicable to, and it has
gotten the Fed in a lot of these situations. Have you seen the report? And do you believe that this is a pretty good synopsis of what
needs to transpire to improve our financial structure?
Mr. SIVON. Yes, sir. We have looked at that report. FSR submitted its own set of recommendations to Treasury as they prepared that report. And many of our recommendations in fact are
reflected in the final report. We do think there is a need for greater
coordination among the regulators. And one of the specific suggestions that we have in the testimony today is that Congress could
adopt some overarching principles to guide the regulators in their
separate missions. The core principles that were put out in the Executive Order on financial stability would provide some guidance
for them.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. Our good friend, the ranking member,
seems to worry about the independence of the regulators. I can tell
you, being a former regulator, there is no reason for them not to
have some oversight as well. Everybody needs to have oversight.
And regulators need to have oversight as well. I think it is important.
You also made a comment in your testimony with regards to systemically important financial institutions and indicated that you
preferred a risk-based assessment model versus a threshold. Could
you elaborate just for a few seconds?
Mr. SIVON. Yes, I would be happy to. In fact, FSR specifically
supports the legislation that you introduced that would provide for
the designation of systemically important institutions through
some type of risk methodology rather than a simple asset threshold. We think that is a more constructive and tailored approach
than what exists today.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. Very quickly, you also talked about
CECL. Could you elaborate on it just a little bit and explain what
it is and your thoughts?
Mr. SIVON. CECL was a fundamental accounting change that
changes the way banks have set up reserves for the past 40 years.
Previously, banks have, and today they still set up reserves based
on the probability of a loss, and then when the loss occurs, they
will book the reserve.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. How does that affect the monetary policy?
Mr. SIVON. Let me just finish with what CECL does. What CECL
does is, it says: You have to put up your reserve at the beginning
of the loan. You have to estimate where the economy is going, forecast then the amount to put into your reserve.
Our concern is that CECL doesn’t hit monetary policy as much
as it hits capital requirements. We think that what this does is it
creates the loss reserve to be the equivalent of capital, and so the
loss reserve, in our opinion, should get tier 1 capital treatment
under the capital rules.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00020

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

15
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. So you think one of the tools for being
a banker today is having a crystal ball?
Mr. SIVON. It is very difficult to predict the future.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. That would seem to be the approach.
Thank you very much. My time has expired.
Chairman BARR. The gentleman’s time has expired.
The Chair now recognizes the ranking member of the Financial
Institutions Subcommittee, Mr. Clay from Missouri.
Mr. CLAY. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Dr. Cecchetti, as you know, the Dodd-Frank Act, among other
things, significantly enhanced the macroprudential responsibilities
of the Federal Reserve. In testimony by former Vice Chairman
Donald Kohn before this committee back in 2009, Vice Chairman
Kohn wrote, ‘‘The Federal Reserve’s monetary policy objectives are
closely aligned with those of minimizing systemic risk. To the extent that the proposed new regulatory framework would contribute
to greater financial stability, it should improve the ability of monetary policy to achieve maximum employment and stable prices.’’
Do you agree with Dr. Kohn’s assessment?
Mr. CECCHETTI. I do agree with his assessment. I think that this
is true for several reasons. The first one is that financial stability
is necessarily the basis for stability in the entire economic system.
And so, if it is the case that the monetary policy is to achieve its
mandated objectives of stable prices and maximum sustainable employment, then financial stability is a foundation for that.
The second thing that I would say is that, if it is the case that
the financial system becomes unstable and monetary policy needs
to react to that financial instability, it takes away from its ability
to do its primary job. And I think what that means is that there
is really another set of tools that we need. And this is why it is
that many people have focused on trying to generate tools that
would ensure financial stability and allow interest rates especially
to be the instrument that is used for price stability and maximum
sustainable growth.
Mr. CLAY. And if you had the Federal Reserve and its leadership
in one of your courses at the university, what grade would you give
them for the past 4 or 5 years? How have they performed?
Mr. CECCHETTI. I think they have performed extremely well. You
have to take into account that they did it in real time. Maybe, in
hindsight, we could give them an A-minus, but if we had to grade
them along the way, we would give them an A.
Mr. CLAY. Mr. Chairman, that is a pretty good grade from what
I know about school and educating people.
Let me ask all of the witnesses: In addition to strengthening the
capital positions of the Nation’s banks, can each of you comment
on how the collection of a standardized data set from the largest
financial institutions in the U.S. is likely to help inform the Fed’s
various policymaking roles, including its supervisory and monetary
policy function?
Starting with you, Dr. Calomiris, 30 seconds.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Yes. That’s an interesting question. I have actually been pointing to some deficiencies in the data that is being collected and used that I think should be remedied. The most obvious
one is, for example, Fed stress tests are currently based on Y–14

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00021

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

16
and Y–9 data, which are pretty irrelevant for stress test purposes.
They should be collecting information based on the managerial accounting of the bank, which would allow them to really understand
the bank as a business. They don’t do that.
Mr. CLAY. Dr. Cecchetti?
Mr. CECCHETTI. I think the Fed is the guardian of financial stability and needs to be able to measure aggregate systemic risk, and
to judge how it is distributed in the financial system. And this requires, in my view, access to intermediaries’ exposure information,
which is more than we are getting right now. All we have is accounting of assets and liabilities, primarily in some derivatives.
The degree to which they are going to be able to transmit shocks,
so we need to be able to create network models of how banks are
related to each other. This is extremely detailed, and I think it
would be very valuable.
Mr. CLAY. Thank you.
Mr. Sivon, how would data collection—
Mr. SIVON. As Professor Calomiris indicates, the Fed stress tests
today are based on FRY–14 data that is collected. And we have
some concerns about the manner in which—while the Fed is—and
the FSR have had a nice dialogue on the manner in which it is collected, we do have some concerns that the monthly reports are not
really needed and that institutions need some additional time to
implement changes in those reporting requirements.
We would also like to see the release of some of that data on aggregated basis.
Mr. CLAY. Thank you.
My time is up. I yield back.
Chairman BARR. The gentleman’s time has expired.
The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Pennsylvania, Mr.
Rothfus.
Mr. ROTHFUS. Thank you.
Mr. Sivon, in your testimony, you brought up some of the challenges associated with the supplementary leverage ratio, or SLR,
and how it is calculated. I share your concerns about this problem.
I have introduced legislation, H.R. 2121, the Pension, Endowment,
and Mutual Fund Access to Banking Act, to address this issue for
custody banks. Many members of this committee are cosponsors of
this bill. In your testimony, you wrote, ‘‘Banking regulators should
revise the calculation of the supplementary leverage ratio to exclude risk-free assets from the calculation of a company’s total assets for purposes of the ratio. This would include reserves held at
the Federal Reserve, cash, and Treasury securities.’’
As you may know, the Treasury Department’s recent report on
banks and credit unions also endorses this idea. Governor Powell
and Chair Yellen have also expressed openness to this concept.
Why do you believe that excluding risk-free assets, like cash held
at central banks, from SRL makes sense?
Mr. SIVON. First of all, FSR supports your legislation and would
like to see it expanded to cover all types of banks, not just custody
banks, because we do think it makes sense. It would free up some
assets that could then be put into more productive use. These are
risk-free assets that, in our opinion, do not need to be counted as
part of the leverage ratio.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00022

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

17
Mr. ROTHFUS. Is there a specific impact for custody banks with
respect to this?
Mr. SIVON. It poses a special issue for custody banks because
that is the very nature of those institutions. They are holding a lot
of deposits, and so they place them at the Fed for security purposes.
Mr. ROTHFUS. Dr. Calomiris, as you know, Professor Cecchetti
takes a very different view of the extent and benefits of interaction
between monetary policy and supervisory and regulatory functions
at the central bank. In his testimony, he writes that, ‘‘a supervisory
function is essential for effective and efficient execution of core central bank functions.’’
However, in your testimony, you assert, ‘‘There is no evidence of
any synergy between monetary and regulatory policy.’’ Why do you
take a different view from the professor?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Again, I think language is very important. People often confound the informational or examination with the regulatory role. Regulation is setting the rules. There is absolutely no
connection between making law and doing monetary policy. There
is a lot of connection between having an ongoing access to examination to participate in examinations. Again, this was exactly the distinction that was made very clear in the 2008 Treasury White
Paper, and I support that distinction. So I think there is a little
bit of confounding of language here.
Mr. ROTHFUS. If I could go back to Mr. Sivon, in your testimony,
you suggested that an assessment of the impact of the current expected credit loss, or CECL, accounting standard on lending and
economic growth should be conducted. What impacts do you anticipate as this standard is implemented?
Mr. SIVON. As I mentioned, the new standard requires institutions to forecast forward where the economy may go and set up at
a reserve. Needless to say, that becomes much more difficult when
you get into longer-term loans, such as a 30-year mortgage. So we
are concerned that it could have an impact in pulling—causing institutions to make fewer mortgage loans or maybe fewer small
business loans. We think one way to offset this is to give institutions credit for this reserve as part of capital.
Mr. ROTHFUS. If I could go back to Dr. Calomiris. This didn’t
jump out at me from your testimony, but I am curious about it, and
that has to do with the Fed’s balance sheet, which is, frankly, a
consequence of the Fed’s unconventional monetary policy. Does
that balance sheet raise any conflict of interest with respect to its
regulatory side of work, and how?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Yes. There are multiple conflicts of interest that
have come from the new Fed powers that the Fed has taken on in
the last several years. One obvious one that is actually related to
the supplementary leverage requirement is that the Fed has become a competitor in the repo market. And it was, in fact, a
strange coincidence that the supplementary leverage requirement
rule was passed at the exact same time that the Fed entered—
which applied to repos—was passed at exactly the same time that
the Fed became a competitor in that market. And the Fed profited
from that rule.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00023

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

18
Now I am not saying that the Fed did it only to profit, but there
is no question that there was a clear conflict of interest.
Mr. ROTHFUS. Does that have anything to do with the nature of
the assets in the Fed’s balance sheet, Treasuries and GSEs—GSE
notes?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. This has to do with the repo function that the
Fed has entered.
With respect to the assets, there is a different conflict.
Mr. ROTHFUS. What is that?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. And that is, mortgage-backed securities that the
Fed is holding, as you raise interest rates, if the Fed sells those securities, it will experience capital losses, which have political consequences for the Fed through their ramifications for the Fed’s contribution to the budget deficit. They are extremely worried about
that. So that could actually keep them from selling off mortgagebacked securities as quickly as they might otherwise. So these are
the reasons why it is good to have a monetary authority that is not
doing fiscal or regulatory policy.
Mr. ROTHFUS. I yield back.
Chairman BARR. The gentleman’s time has expired.
The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Georgia, Mr.
Scott, for a word before his time begins.
Mr. SCOTT. Sure. Thank you very much.
I, too, want to join with my Republican colleagues and certainly
from this side of the aisle in wishing a speedy recovery to our good
friend, Congressman Loudermilk. Congressman Loudermilk, as we
know, was in a car accident. The car flipped over 2 or 3 times. He
was en route up from, and the accident occurred near, Knoxville,
Tennessee, and they have been flown back to Atlanta for further
medical treatment. So we will get a report on that.
And this is just the second time in a matter of a short period of
time that very near-death incidents have happened. As you will recall, he was there on the ball field when our Republican colleague,
Steve Scalise, was shot. So I just ask everybody that we join in a
prayer for him and wish him a very speedy recovery. And thank
you for giving me that time.
Chairman BARR. Thank you.
Mr. SCOTT. Barry Loudermilk and I not only share—
Ms. MOORE. I would love to associate myself with the comments
of Members on both sides of the aisle and make it part of the
record that we are prayerful during this hearing.
Mr. SCOTT. Thank you very much. What I wanted to say was in
addition, it is very important that Barry Loudermilk and I not only
serve Georgia together, but we share counties together. We share
Cobb County together. And so we work very closely on very important issues for our joint constituencies.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I have been sitting here listening to this debate, and it called to
my mind the great words of—we had a great many Founding Fathers, and none more valuable or greater than the great Alexander
Hamilton. And it was Hamilton who said that a strong centralized
national banking system shines at its most brilliant in a time of
national crisis.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00024

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

19
And that is what happened when we suffered the Wall Street
bailout situation, and we were very fortunate to have that strong
national banking system there. And we responded by establishing
Dodd-Frank. And in that we were able, because we had, which was
represented by the Federal Reserve, the apparatus there. And we
put stress testing there. And it surprises me that some of my Republican colleagues might not be as mindful of how that benefitted
us.
So, Dr. Cecchetti, what do you make of all this? It is my understanding that the Federal Reserve is not only doing a great job
with stress testing, but it is because of that that our banking system is flourishing now.
Mr. CECCHETTI. Yes, thank you.
Let me just start, your colleague Congressman Clay asked me to
grade the Federal Reserve only over the last 4 or 5 years. If I were
to grade them from 2007, 2008, 2009, I would have given them an
A-plus. And that is not unrelated to your question, because stress
tests grew out of the crisis.
Stress tests came in the winter and spring of 2009 when the
banking system was on the verge of collapse. And what happened
was that by stress testing the banks, what the Federal Reserve did
was it made everybody more confident that those banks were
healthy. And so I think that it is absolutely essential.
Stress testing, which we discovered then by accident essentially
as a crisis management tool, I think has now become the most important crisis mitigation tool and the tool that we use to ensure the
resilience of the financial system more broadly.
Mr. SCOTT. Yes. And Hamilton went on to say that the greatness
of this system is that it had the power, it has the authority, and
it is free from persuasive, divisive politics. And that is why it is so
important to have this away from the regular appropriations process for their funding.
Now, my staff tells me that the Fed has hundreds of Ph.D. economists who constantly are combing over data so that talented folks
like Chair Yellen can make informed decisions, and her predecessors, and people will follow her.
So let me ask you about this idea of how important it is to keep
the Fed independent away from what Hamilton refers to as this political persuasiveness and division?
Mr. CECCHETTI. I think it is absolutely essential. I think what is
essential is that monetary policy and supervision both be done by
people who can have long horizons, that they not be under the influence of short-term political pressures or those of constituencies
that would want them to behave differently from what is in the
long-term interest.
My view of this is that if we are to minimize the cost to taxpayers in the long run we need to make them independent, accountable to all of you surely for meeting their objectives, but independent in terms of their daily actions and in terms of the budgets
to get their work done.
Mr. SCOTT. Right. And you mentioned the key word. It is who determines their budget, who determines their money. As the guy
said in the great movie, ‘‘Follow the money.’’ That is what determines your power and authority.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00025

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

20
And I thank you for your comments there on how important it
is to keep the funding in an independent way. Thank you, sir.
Chairman BARR. The gentleman’s time has expired.
The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from North Carolina,
Mr. Pittenger.
Mr. PITTENGER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
And I thank each of you for joining us today.
Just a comment in reference to my good friend Mr. Scott’s perspective on the net effect of the regulatory policy from the Fed as
a result of the Dodd-Frank bill. In North Carolina, we have lost 50
percent of our banks since 2010 because of the compliance requirements. And of course that has resulted in less capital and credit
for small businesses so important for our economy.
Mr. Sivon, the Volcker Rule with its immense complexities ensures full employment, it appears to me, for the Washington lawyers and consultants and bureaucrats, but it continues to really
harm others who are in small and medium-sized companies that
aren’t able to expand their businesses.
In your testimony you stated and suggested that the Volcker
Rule would ‘‘impair liquidity in the Nation’s capital markets, which
as a consequence would force business to face higher borrowing
costs, resulting in less economic activity and translating into fewer
jobs.’’
Having said that, do you believe this still to be a valid concern?
And specifically, what actions should Congress take to remedy this
situation and help these businesses ensure full economic opportunity?
Mr. SIVON. Thank you, Congressman.
When the rule was contemplated, there were concerns that it
could have some impact on liquidity, and recent studies are starting to bear that out. In fact, studies by the Federal Reserve itself
have started to bear that out.
So we recommend that the rule be revisited. We are not alone
in making this recommendation. The agencies themselves and the
Treasury Department are starting to acknowledge that it is overly
complex and there could be some improvements.
In my own practice I have helped a number of mid-sized banks
develop their compliance programs for this rule, and what that exercise turns out to be is a demonstration that they are not engaged
in proprietary trading, they are not making investments, so it becomes proving the negative.
Clearly, there is a category of institutions that this rule should
not apply to, the scope of the prohibitions could be narrowed, the
compliance requirements could be more streamlined.
Mr. PITTENGER. What role then should the Fed play in trying to
implement any changes?
Mr. SIVON. The Fed is one of the five agencies that are responsible for writing this rule. So the Fed could coordinate with the
other agencies in helping to streamline and address these issues.
Mr. PITTENGER. Thank you.
Mr. Calomiris, as you are well-aware, the Fed was established
more than 100 years ago. According to the Board of Governors
website, it says that it was established to provide a safer, more
flexible, and more stable monetary and financial system. Yet the

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00026

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

21
research suggests that the U.S. has been the most financially unstable developed economy in the world for two centuries.
As you know, Dr. Calomiris, Dodd-Frank gave the Fed a prominent role in the prudential regulation of our financial system.
Should we believe that this time is different, that we finally found
the optimal regulatory structure for a crisis-prone financial system,
or is the new regulatory structure the same as the old one, fragile
by design?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I don’t think that it is very promising looking forward. I agree with my colleagues here who have said the banking
system right now is more stable than it was before. That is not
really the interesting question. The interesting question is, when
we go through the next unstable period, will these regulations work
better than the last ones? And I think it is pretty clear that they
won’t.
I have just completed a book that I know all of you have because
I made sure you all got a copy explaining why I don’t think it is
going to work.
And that also underlines my point that this shouldn’t just be a
discussion about deregulation, this should be a discussion about
strengthening regulations that are not credible. And I would say
that the implementation of Dodd-Frank is not very credible.
We are already seeing mortgage markets looking very similar to
what they were doing in the late 1990s and early 2000s. That is
the result of government decisions, FHA decisions, FHFA decisions.
These were political decisions. They are putting us back into the
same direction.
We saw the QM and the QRM standard, because they were given
to the regulatory agencies to decide the details of, we saw those
being whittled away. And we saw, of course, what Barney Frank
has bemoaned as the loophole that ate the standard.
So I think that we have a lot of reasons not to be very confident.
Mr. PITTENGER. Thank you.
My time has, unfortunately, expired. Thank you very much.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I’m sorry if I went on too long.
Mr. PITTENGER. I appreciate your testimony.
Chairman BARR. The time of the gentleman has expired.
The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Illinois, Mr. Foster.
Mr. FOSTER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
And thank you to our witnesses.
There have been two great financial crises, I guess, in our lifetime: the 2008 crisis; and the savings and loan crisis. In which one
of these did the taxpayer have to write a bigger check? Anyone who
wants to answer it? Just roughly?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. The first one.
Mr. FOSTER. That is my impression, that it was the check was
about 2 percent of GDP, right?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. A little bit more. But it is a tough one because
if you are asking write a check, that is a complicated question to
answer. The total exposure of the taxpayer, potential loss exposure,
was greater in the second crisis, but the actual—
Mr. FOSTER. Potential, but the actual losses were higher. I think
they were—the nominal losses at least were near zero—
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I agree with that, yes.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00027

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

22
Mr. FOSTER. So I think that is a significant point. And I am trying to get back to your point, Dr. Cecchetti, about what we are
hearing here is that the solution to our problems is to subject regulators to the appropriations process, which is something you pointed out had been done to the regulators of the S&L. And we are also
talking about the crosstalk between monetary policy and regulation.
And it is my sort of simpleminded understanding of the S&L crisis is it was a bunch of smaller institutions getting on the wrong
side of an interest rate bet, and then when the Fed made a big
move in monetary policy they were in big trouble. And it was the
lack of any communication between the regulators and understanding what sort of stress that would put the regulated institutions under when the Fed made a big interest rate move that actually was the driving mechanism. Of course it spiraled into fraud
and everything else.
But I was just wondering, is that a fair evaluation of how useful
subjecting regulators to the appropriations is?
Mr. CECCHETTI. I believe that it is. And let me just say that I
think you have exactly the right pathology in mind, which is to say
that interest rate increases generally harm bank profitability and
bank equity positions.
It is important, therefore, for the people who are contemplating
those increases to understand what their overall impact is likely to
be. They are going to be in the best position also to ensure that
when they do raise interest rates, which they will ultimately have
to do under circumstances in order to ensure that prices remain
stable and that growth remains stable, that they understand what
the consequences of those actions are going to be at a relatively detailed level.
Mr. FOSTER. And that had there been better communication between regulators and monetary policy actually would have been our
best shot at preventing that largest taxpayer bailout of history in
the savings and loan crisis.
Mr. CECCHETTI. I am not sure I would go quite that far. But I
do believe that what was missing, especially in the last crisis, was
having someone who was clearly responsible for the financial system as a whole and especially for the largest, say, three or four
dozen financial intermediaries that are systemic where any one of
them failing had large consequences for the system as a whole.
Mr. FOSTER. Okay. Thank you.
And, Dr. Calomiris, you have written extensively on contingent
capital, which you are aware I am a big fan of as a mechanism,
a market-based mechanism to make sure that it is not the taxpayer
who is left holding the bag.
Could you just say a little bit about what you think the experience has been internationally with using these and what the prospects should be for avoiding future bank bailouts?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Very quickly, the right instrument that I have
been proposing has never been created yet. What we do know, however, is that the demand for contingent capital-type instruments
has turned out to be very high by ultimate investors, so I think
that is the evidence that is the most promising.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00028

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

23
What we also know, though, is that we have created this total
loss-absorbing capital concept, which the contingent capital could
be used now in the context of that concept as the form required at
the bank holding company. But it has to be required in a much
larger amount than is currently present. So I think we have a lot
of inadequacies that the contingent capital could help.
Mr. FOSTER. But there is also an important difference here, that
the TLAC triggers that insolvency not violation of capital requirements.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Exactly.
Mr. FOSTER. And so a market-based instrument that warns the
banks two steps back from the cliff rather than at the point of insolvency has real merit.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. That is exactly right. And I think that is the essence of why this is so important, because I don’t have confidence
in the FDIC’s ability to resolve these very large institutions, despite what they say under Title II. So we have to keep them far
away from that point so we don’t test that.
Mr. FOSTER. Thank you, and keep on this subject. I am a big fan.
Chairman BARR. The gentleman’s time has expired.
The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Colorado, Mr. Tipton.
Mr. TIPTON. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
And I thank the panel for taking the time to be here.
Mr. Sivon, I would like to return back to a question, and maybe
get a little more comment from you, that Chairman Luetkemeyer
had raised in regards to rules and regulations and the overlaps
that we have had.
We sent a letter to Secretary Mnuchin, 31 members of this committee, asking him in his capacity regarding the FSOC to be able
to address rule and regulation overlap, to be able to streamline
some of those processes. We have had Chair Yellen before this committee on numerous occasions, also noting that regulatory policy
does have a trickle-down effect that is impacting smaller institutions, as well.
Can you maybe speak a little bit to some of the costs that are
going to be associated with having that duplicative overlapping regulatory policy and how that impacts people literally at home?
Mr. SIVON. Yes, thank you. It is a major issue for the members
of the roundtable, which are larger institutions. But you are absolutely correct that there is a trickle-down effect. Even though rules
may be tailored, they are often applied to institutions below the
specific rule.
Some examples. Today, institutions have to prepare resolution
plans for a holding company. They also have to prepare resolution
plans at the individual bank level. Some recovery planning is required by some regulators, which is a plan that before you get into
a failing situation. There are duplicating requirements on risk
management standards that the OCC and the Fed have put out.
So there are examples of instances where we are quite concerned
that the agencies are not coordinating as much as they should be.
FSOC could play a role here as an organization where all these
agencies do sit, and maybe in the new Administration it will play
more of a coordinating role.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00029

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

24
Mr. TIPTON. Thanks. I appreciate that. I think that is a lot of the
challenge, particularly at the community bank level, that we are
seeing, our smaller institutions. Best practices. It may not be theoretically applicable to you, but indeed it becomes applicable to you,
and that tends to flow down the list.
And I just had an opportunity during the August break to be
able to visit with a lot of our community banks, and I think a number of them would actually be applauding you when you are saying
make the loan loss reserves Tier I capital. You used to think of this
as something separate and unto itself to be able to deal with it, but
it is now impacting that ability really to be able to make some
loans and to be able to help our folks at home to be able to grow
the economy.
Would you maybe talk a little bit more—I thought it was interesting when you were talking about some of the modeling on the
stress tests, to be able to reveal some more information so that you
our banks—we understand we don’t want anybody to be able to
game the system. But would you maybe speak to that just a bit
more?
Mr. SIVON. Yes. I would agree with others on the panel that
stress testing is one of the more important reforms that has been
put in place since the crisis. And, in fact, if you look at the results
of the latest stress tests, they do demonstrate that large institutions could survive a crisis of worse magnitude than we went
through in 2008.
The problem that we see with the manner in which the stress
tests are operated today, though, is the models that the board
maintains are not shared, they are not transparent with the industry. So you have bankers who are trying to estimate what the
board’s model may show and modifying their loan activity to try to
meet that standard, whereas that may not be the most appropriate
manner in which they should be engaging in their particular community given their risk profile and the market in which they operate.
So we think there is a little disconnect between the lack of transparency under the current structure.
Mr. TIPTON. Thank you.
And, Dr. Calomiris, I would like to maybe just return a little bit
to the ability to be able to use a little bit of the power of the purse,
the appropriations process, in terms of some questions that have
been asked in terms of making the Fed actually more accountable.
When we look at 15 percent of the U.S. mortgage market securities are currently held in the Fed, is that going to impact some of
theirs? Is there an appropriate way or would using that monetary
policy be negative?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I am very worried about the Fed keeping those
on its balance sheet. And I support a recommendation, which I also
have made a long time ago, and that Charles Plosser has also been
pushing, for us to engage in a swap between the Treasury and the
Fed, to swap those for Treasury securities so that we get the Fed
out of the mortgage business.
And that is also an inappropriate fiscal intervention. The Fed is
clearly intending to affect the relative cost of particular financial
instruments. That is not monetary policy.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00030

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

25
Mr. TIPTON. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. The time has
expired. I yield back.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER [presiding]. The gentleman yields back.
We are playing musical chairmen here today, so I will be chairing
for a little bit, for the rest of the hearing.
So with that, we also have an important moment here. The gentleman from Indiana is going to be recognized to question for 5
minutes. But I understand it is a very, very important day in his
life.
Happy birthday. Is that correct, sir?
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. Yes, that is correct. Thank you. Very, very
important may be overstating it.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. It is very important, very important.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. I am happy to make another milestone.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. Older and wiser. There you go.
The gentleman is recognized for 5 minutes.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. Good afternoon, gentlemen. I really appreciate you taking the opportunity to come talk to us today. And so
far it has proven enthralling, I can tell you. And for the dozens of
my constituents back home watching this, it is indeed enthralling
for them, I am sure, right?
But I wanted to come back to something because I have heard
it implied or even explicitly stated a few times, that the lack of a
crisis in the last 9 years is somehow evidence that this extra regulatory burden will forever and always keep us safe from a crisis instead of some recognition that by the same logic the fact that we
had regulators and regulations before the last crisis seems to be
some evidence that regulation, and especially by edict out of D.C.,
instead of enabling and empowering lenders to be able to pursue
their own business models, it might in fact be one of the root
causes for some of the instability.
And I would love it if Dr. Calomiris would comment on that.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. There are so many pieces to it. Of course, I wrote
a book that went through that in some detail.
But it is important to remember that as we are worried about
too-big-to-fail institutions, we are running up inordinate risks having to do with the mortgage market, that the Fed was the institution that first of all was managing the merger process that created
too-big-to-fail institutions, and it was the Fed that was also managing the prudential regulatory process that decided whether they
had adequate capital. And I would say the Fed was extremely politicized.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. Right.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. And that its extreme politicization led it to approve of mergers in a way that created mortgage risk and then
therefore could not set capital requirements that would have created adequate capital.
So that was, to my way of thinking, probably the single best example of the kinds of problems that come from a politicized regulator that is a central bank.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. One of the deep challenges I have—and
again, my statistics is rusty—but the use of the counterfactual
here, somehow saying because we have not had a crisis that we are
okay. But what we haven’t talked about is the tremendous costs on

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00031

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

26
the U.S. economy of the misallocation of capital across it because
of government intervention, government distortion, and excessively
burdensome government regulation, which continues to misallocate
capital and not get it in the hands of those that could most productively use it, and the economy has suffered because of that. People
back home have suffered because of that. And I would love it if you
would comment a little bit on that.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. The most obvious area has been small business
lending, especially because small banks have a lot to do with small
business lending, and small banks have been really hit a lot by the
overhead costs of the regulatory burden. That is one part of it.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. And just what I hear from my small bankers in the community is what they say is: We have been essentially
forced to combine because the regulatory burden is so heavy and
that fixed cost is so heavy we have to amortize that over more and
more customers, more and more loans, more and more products,
and so we have combined and gotten larger. And thus, they find
themselves less capable of serving the communities and find themselves more and more, in their feeling, in servitude of a bureaucracy in D.C. instead of focusing on enabling and empowering their
customers.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. It shows in all the statistics I have quoted in my
various work. One thing that I would also point out is we are going
to great lengths through a variety of measures to push mortgages
rather than small business lending, is what small banks do.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. Right.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. And so it is not just that small banks have been
hurt, it is also that if we actually required banks to be more diversified across their lending we would help small businesses quite a
lot.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. Indeed.
And, Mr. Sivon, I wanted to ask you specifically about a bill that
I have recently introduced. This bill, H.R. 3179, the Transparency
and Accountability for Business Standards Act, is really simple. It
is about harmonizing regulation across jurisdictions. And the fact
is that the United States has gold-plated many of the standards
coming back from overseas. And I wondered if you could talk a little bit about the global competitiveness of U.S. institutions in the
face of a heavier regulatory burden here at home than others may
face in other jurisdictions.
Mr. SIVON. Thank you, Congressman. It is one of the issues highlighted in our testimony. We do think that the layering on of additional requirements for the larger U.S. institutions does raise competitive issues for them in global markets. And the legislation that
you have introduced provides for the regulators to do a cost-benefit
analysis before imposing that kind of a standard.
We strongly support that. We think the idea of cost-benefit analysis makes sense there as well as in other regulations that the
agencies are proposing.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. So the net-net is, when I think about the
regulatory burden in this country, the misallocation of capital is
costing opportunities for higher economic growth, for people to realize meaningful wages. And then in addition, that regulatory burden
is costing U.S. companies competitiveness around the world to be

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00032

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

27
able to export some of the great things that we have developed
here to other countries.
And with that, I will yield back, sir.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. The gentleman’s time has expired.
We now go to the gentleman from Minnesota, Mr. Emmer, who
is recognized for 5 minutes.
Mr. EMMER. Thank you very much, and thanks to the panel for
being here.
I just don’t even know where to start. So much of this has been
covered. It is a very interesting discussion. But I think I want to
start with Dr. Calomiris.
You had talked about one of the reforms being budgeting authority, having more oversight on budgeting authority. What about the
argument that we hear constantly, and I think Dr. Cecchetti made
this argument at some point, that this would impact the Federal
Reserve’s independence, putting their budget under the supervision
of Congress, for instance? How would you respond to that?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I think the important first step is to ask, when
we talk about Fed independence, what are we talking about? Independence in the literature for decades has always meant independent of special interest pressures, independent of short-term
pressures coming from the Administration. It has never, ever
meant that laws that the Fed administers should be made independently of the United States Congress.
So I just want to be clear, when I use the word, ‘‘independence,’’
I don’t think that it is consistent with our Constitution to think
that the Fed should be writing regulations that are not overseen
by the U.S. Congress. I think that is a very radical and new idea
that seems to me to be just wrong.
So the question then is, well, what is the role of budgetary discipline? Congress under the Constitution is the only agency, is the
only institution that is supposed to be sending funds for whatever
purpose in the government. So I don’t really understand how you
can read the Constitution and find this authority for the Fed to
have a blank check to spend money any way it wants.
Mr. EMMER. Thank you.
Dr. Cecchetti, you had testified, and I wrote it down, early this
afternoon that you need to have an objective and then there need
to be guidelines on how to get to that objective. How is that different from having a rule in place which is in effect a guideline?
I think the proposal from this Congress or this committee has been,
one of the proposals, to put a rule in place so that at least people
in the public know what to expect. But it doesn’t have to be followed, and if it is not followed then it would require an explanation
as to why we are not following it. How is that different?
Mr. HUIZENGA. I am so sorry, but would the gentleman yield for
just a second?
Mr. EMMER. Absolutely.
Mr. HUIZENGA. As the author of the FORM Act, and I know
Chairman Barr has been working on this, we actually had said
that the Fed could make up their own guideline and just have it
out there and then explain when they were going to deviate from
that. So that was not even anything that we on this panel or the

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00033

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

28
House or the Senate or anybody else would put forward, it would
actually be a guideline created by the Fed and measure themselves.
So I yield back.
Mr. EMMER. Great context. How is that different from what you
said?
Mr. CECCHETTI. So what I was trying to say is that I view the
job of the Congress as to set the objectives and to hold the Federal
Reserve accountable for meeting those objectives. I do not believe
that it is worthwhile for the Congress to be involved directly in setting policy.
Mr. EMMER. But actually, to interrupt, because we are going to
run out of time, that is exactly what my colleague just said that
they were proposing, is go ahead and set the objective, you do the
policy so all of us know what it is, and then you have the guidelines, the policy guidelines and you explain. It sounds to me, sir,
as though we actually agree on this.
I have to go back with the limited time I have left to Dr.
Calomiris, because I have some concerns with this conflict of interest and the politicizing of the Federal Reserve. We have lost so
many community banks, family-owned community banks and credit
unions over the last 7 years since Dodd-Frank was in existence,
and, in fact, it started even before that, but it has been accelerated
in the last 7 years.
And it seems as though, looking at it and reading your testimony, listening to you here today, and perhaps your colleague
might weigh in as well, in order to exist with this regulatory function and the monetary policy function you have to have a lot of resources in order to exist, and we are not creating new banks. Is
there a favoritism towards the larger institutions?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I just have a new volume coming out that I am
editing on this. And some of the rules are hitting the large institutions, of course. Some of the rules are hitting the small institutions.
The main problem with the small institutions is, how do you
spread the overhead from having to comply with these things over
a small balance sheet? And I think that is why it just becomes existential for them.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. The gentleman’s time has expired.
The gentleman from Arkansas, Mr. Hill, is recognized for 5 minutes.
Mr. HILL. I thank the chairman. I thank both chairmen for this
interesting topic, to continue our exploration of the Fed and the
role of the Fed both in monetary policy and in regulatory policy.
And I am sorry I have been in and out today. It is one of those
days on Capitol Hill.
I would like to talk and follow up with my friend from Indiana’s
comments about misallocation of capital and get your views just
from a little different perspective. Obviously market prices provide
a lot of information to market participants. And you have had the
Fed really over the last few years be unprecedented in sustained
decline of zero interest rates, plus doubling down with QE1, QE2,
QE3.
And we have the third most expensive S&P 500 now in history.
Only 1997 to 2001 and 1929 exceed the price earnings multiple on
the S&P 500 right now. And we have historically low cap rates for

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00034

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29
long-tailed commercial real estate properties, for example. And I
think at the last count something like $13 trillion of sovereign debt
is at a negative yield.
So these are clearly unprecedented times.
But one of the key components of that was back in 2012 the Fed
established an inflation target of 2 percent, which we have not hit.
And I wonder if that calls into question whether they should even
have set such a target if they can’t hit it. I think Gary Shilling
said, and I am paraphrasing, if you can’t hit a target, maybe we
need to question our authority to even try to do that.
So I am interested in your views on that inflation target. Should
that be maintained or should we, as we normalize the balance
sheet or attempt to, also let that go by the wayside as a test for
the last years? Each of you, if you would comment on that, please?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I will be quick. I would have preferred a 1 percent target rather than a 2 percent target, which is the one Alan
Greenspan, as I read it, suggested in 2006. But now that they have
stated the 2 percent target, I think it is important that it not be
subject to change. I think that they need to stick with it because
they have now said that that is their long-run target. That should
be subject, of course, to your approval, but I think that it is a good
idea to stick with it.
I also don’t agree with people who say the Fed has undershot its
target, because this is a long-run target. It is not clear yet whether
being at 1.5 percent for current inflation means that they are pursuing policies that are long run below the target. So I don’t think
that we want to be too critical of the Fed for coming in at 1.5 rather than at 2.
Mr. HILL. I just want to add one nuance to that. At 1.7 percent,
should we just declare victory and say we have hit 2 percent if it
is going to not let us take other policy decisions in the monetary
policy arena surrounding the balance sheet that maybe we should
because it is just one factor considered, not the only factor?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. So just very quickly, monetary policy remains accommodative. In real English what that means is monetary policy
is still pushing toward going to a higher rate of price growth. And
that is appropriate given that the Fed has a 2 percent objective. I
think it should be less accommodative than it is.
So I think the Fed is basically doing behavior that is so far consistent with a 2 percent policy objective, and I think that we
shouldn’t beat them up too much.
Mr. CECCHETTI. I agree with my esteemed colleague that 2 percent, now that you have it, I think you have to keep it. If you start
changing it then everybody is going to wonder when you are going
to change it.
And the most important thing, I think, for all of us and for individuals, for small businesses, for households, for investors is that
they be able to have some security in what inflation will be over
the long run. And in this I think Dr. Calomiris and I completely
agree that these modest deviations over relatively short periods of
time are not a problem.
Mr. HILL. Mr. Sivon, quickly, sir?
Mr. SIVON. On monetary policy, the members of the FSR will operate in any interest rate environment.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00035

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

30
Mr. HILL. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back.
Chairman BARR. The gentleman’s time has expired.
The gentleman from California, Mr. Royce, is recognized for 5
minutes.
Mr. ROYCE. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Dr. Calomiris, as you may know, I have spent a lot of time concerned about the drug of leverage, as you referred to it. In fact,
when the House considered GSE reform back in legislation in 2005,
I introduced an amendment to give the regulator the authority to
curtail the systemic risk posed by Fannie and Freddie’s portfolio.
The regulator would have had the ability to deleverage those portfolios.
That amendment was defeated by a large margin, leaving the
underlying legislation incapable of curtailing the risk exposure
from these portfolios. The opponents of my amendment on both
sides of the aisle claimed Fannie and Freddie posed no threat to
the financial markets and that systemic risk was, in one of these
debates I remember here, a theoretical term.
In reality the opposition was looking to preserve the status quo.
They were looking to allow Fannie and Freddie to grow at a very
alarming rate without any meaningful constraints, and I would add
without any oversight from this institution.
You have said we need the political courage to give up the drug.
Do you think we have learned from that crisis? Have we brought
transparency to the GSEs and the Federal Reserve and the role
they play in terms of subsidizing our housing markets, do people
really understand that, or is the moral hazard that I pointed out
then still in play today?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. It has gotten worse. So let me remind you that
as soon as Mr. DeMarco was replaced by Mr. Watt, one of the first
things Mr. Watt did was to lower the downpayment requirements
for GSE mortgages from 5 percent to 3 percent. Five percent is way
too low. Three percent is unbelievably low. The FHA also cut insurance premiums.
Has the FSOC, who is supposed to be looking for systemic risk,
ever used the word, ‘‘mortgage’’ or the words, ‘‘real estate’’ in any
of their discussions? Almost none. Why? The Secretary of the
Treasury is the head of the FSOC, so why would the Administration that appointed Mr. Watt then also say that Mr. Watt just created risk. They wouldn’t, right?
So the problem is the FSOC is politicized and is not going to be
honest about mortgage risk. And it is currently a threat. It is going
to get worse.
Mr. ROYCE. Let me ask Mr. Sivon a question, because you are
someone who has opined on insurance regulation for many years.
Could you take a minute or 2 to describe how we ended up where
we are today? Because this is no longer a discussion about State
versus Federal regulation. It is now a discussion about layered regulation. That is the difference. The Federal Reserve now plays a
pronounced role in this regulation.
And I can think of some of the possible positives from the outcome. You could argue that maybe now on the monetary policy side
the Fed better understands the impact prolonged low interest rates
have on life insurers trying to plan for the long term. That is a

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00036

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

31
positive. But on the regulatory side, it is unclear what the proper
role for the Fed is in the future. So I offer you the floor here with
the remaining minutes.
Mr. SIVON. One of the major changes in the Dodd-Frank Act was
to give the Fed regulatory and supervisory authority over a number
of insurance companies. In fairness to them, I think they have been
moving slowly in the manner in which they have been exercising
that authority.
On the other hand, as I noted in my testimony, we think it is
very important for the agency to appreciate the distinction between
the business of insurance and the business of banking, and some
of the supervisory policy statements that they have put out have
been more aimed at banking than recognizing the distinct issues
that an insurance company faces.
The most recent action that they took last year was to propose
capital standards for the insurers that they regulate. They proposed two alternative standards: one called the consolidated approach for the very largest insurers that they regulate; and another
called a building block approach for the savings and loan holding
companies that are owned by insurance companies.
The building block approach is based upon State insurance regulation. And so it is our strong view that as the Fed moves forward
in regulating capital requirements for the insurers that it regulates
it doesn’t layer on yet a new type of capital requirement, but look
to what the States have done and build on this building block approach for capital requirements for insurance companies.
Mr. ROYCE. Thank you very much.
And I thank you again, Mr. Chairman, and I thank our witnesses.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. The gentleman’s time has expired.
We have a situation where we are truly enthralled by your expertise today, and we have another round of questions that we
would like to ask if you guys have some time. We would like to impose on you to be able to do that. Or do you guys have some other
places to go shortly? No? Okay.
Otherwise, we would like to start a second round, and we will
start with the gentleman who is the chairman of the Oversight
Subcommittee, the gentleman from Kentucky, Mr. Barr.
Chairman BARR. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
And I appreciate the indulgence of our witnesses. We appreciate
the very interesting exchange of ideas here today. What I have
heard from all of the witnesses is a general agreement that Fed
independence, a Fed free from politicization is a goal that we share.
But I think a strong argument can be made that the Fed’s aggressive implementation of the Dodd-Frank Act, that their zealous
supervisory activities, their overregulation arguably, that that has,
in fact, diminished economic growth, that that has undermined
credit availability in capital formation, and that that process, that
process of being engaged in the regulatory supervisory process, has
actually induced the Fed to pursue a radically unconventional and
accommodative monetary policy to offset the growth-destroying effects of the regulatory policies.
And that obviously, that monetary policy has distorted financial
asset values. It has discouraged financial capital from freely engag-

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00037

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

32
ing in its most promising opportunities. And witnesses in this committee, in this subcommittee, have expressed concern about the
Fed’s balance sheet stepping out of what is necessary for the conduct of monetary policy and obviously into unprecedented unchartered credit policy.
So the point I am trying to make is that this conduct, I would
submit, does not really look like a government agency free of politics. That to me looks like a government agency that is totally politicized. And so I invite your feedback on that observation.
Dr. Calomiris?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I think that it is true. It is inevitable. When you
get into things like mortgage-backed securities markets and you
are making changes in relative interest rates for different financial
instruments, that is what we economists call fiscal policy. That is
a decision to subsidize some kinds of uses of funds at the expense
of others.
So when you get engaged in that, just like any political institution, you become a political institution and you become a lightning
rod for influence. This is one of the reasons why monetary policy
just has to stay away from those kinds of things.
Chairman BARR. Just to follow up to your answer there, and I
want to hear from the other witnesses on that, but I think you
have made the point, Dr. Calomiris, that as an owner of over 15
percent of U.S. mortgage market securities, the Fed’s monetary policymakers are quite conflicted when it comes to interest rate policy.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. That is right.
I also just want to say I think your analysis of the motivation
of the Fed is right, that the Fed having been part of the problem
of creating the growth slowdown has actually tried to do things to
try to prop things up. It is not working very well. And Marco
DiMaggio, my former colleague, his study found that the only part
of QE that really had a positive effect of QE2 and QE3 was the
mortgage-backed security part.
Chairman BARR. Dr. Cecchetti, I do want to give you an opportunity to respond. And as you respond, could you also address the
testimony that you offered earlier that the job of the Congress is
to set objectives and hold the Fed accountable? But how do you
hold, how does Congress hold the Fed accountable on rulemaking
if they are completely immune from the meaningful oversight of
the appropriations process?
Mr. CECCHETTI. I believe that you can hold them accountable
with—let me start with your first points. I think there are two
points.
First of all, on the mortgages, I think that many people, including me, are uncomfortable with the fact that the Federal Reserve
owns so many mortgages, the mortgage-backed securities. But
these were purchased as the Fed was trying to support the mortgage market during a collapse, and I think that they will let those
run off as soon as they practically can.
On the issue of stringent capital requirements, I think it is important to understand that capital requirements facilitate lending.
Strong banks lend. Banks that have strong underlying capital positions are lending, and they are doing it now, and I think that that

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00038

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

33
is a very, very important thing that I hope that everybody appreciates.
There is an issue which has come up a number of times which
I will comment very briefly on, and that is that I think there is also
broad agreement that a $1 trillion bank and a $1 billion bank
should not be treated identically. And the question then is how do
you change that treatment?
Chairman BARR. I yield back.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. The gentleman’s time has expired.
We now go to the ranking member of the Financial Institutions
Subcommittee, the gentleman from Missouri, Mr. Clay.
Mr. CLAY. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
And, Dr. Cecchetti, the outlook of the economy, including whether financial conditions are likely to lead to faster or slower future
growth, has a significant impact on both inflation and employment.
Given this, can you talk about how the information that the Fed
learns through its supervision of the financial system would inform
and enhance the Fed’s outlook on how it may need to adjust its
monetary policy stance in order to achieve its statutory full employment and price stability objectives?
Mr. CECCHETTI. Yes, Congressman, I would be happy to.
The Federal Reserve’s interest rate actions operate through the
banking system. So it is essential when they set their interest rate
to know what it is that the banking system is doing.
The information that the Federal Reserve has access to today
prior to making those decisions includes information about individual borrowers and individual lenders. They know about the size
of loans, they know who it is that is doing the borrowing, and they
know what the terms are of those loans. They use that information—aggregating it, obviously—in a way that then informs them
on how it is they need to set their policy in order to ensure that
the easing or tightening of the policy has the desired impact.
Mr. CLAY. And to what extent does the Fed’s forecasting function
tend to rely on analysis of supervisory data?
Mr. CECCHETTI. I think the answer to that is that we are going
to know more and more about that over the next few years.
As Dr. Calomiris pointed out, the Federal Reserve as part of its
accountability mechanism releases transcripts of the Federal Open
Market Committee meetings with a 5-year lag. So right now we
don’t actually have access to the discussions and the meetings for
the past 5 years, but my understanding from speaking to some people inside of the Federal Reserve is that the kind of information
that we are describing here now has found its way in that time period, because it hasn’t been collected in a consolidated and consistent way until the last few years, that it is now finding its way
into those decisions and into those discussions.
Mr. CLAY. Thank you for that.
And, Dr. Calomiris, considering the performance of the U.S. economy over the last year, do you think the Federal Reserve has made
the correct moves as far as being able to lower unemployment and
the strong market indicators that we see now? Do you give them
any credit for that performance?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Absolutely. As I said, I think we are below our
long-run inflation target. I think that according to the Fed’s own

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00039

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

34
measures, though, of unemployment, it has been a moving target.
So the Fed doesn’t really have a very good sense of what the longterm right level of unemployment is, and that has been one of the
things we have been learning.
So it has been a tough job. I think that qualitatively they have
done a fair job. My friend, Mr. Cecchetti, is an easier grader than
I am. But I would say that they have done a decent job under a
circumstance of extreme uncertainty about the long-run unemployment rate.
Mr. CLAY. Thank you for your response.
I would prefer to take a course from Dr. Cecchetti, I think.
And with that, Mr. Chairman, I yield back.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. The gentleman from Missouri yields
back the balance of his time. As the gentleman who actually got
an A or two in school, we are okay with either one of these guys.
I think we could make it work.
With that, we go to the gentleman from Indiana, Mr. Hollingsworth, for 5 minutes.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. I really appreciate the testimony again,
and thank you for being here.
So one of the things that was said a few minutes ago was that
strong banks make loans, and I don’t doubt that loan growth hasn’t
been zero, but it certainly hasn’t been as robust as it otherwise
would be.
When we look back at prior recessions and loan growth post-recessions, we have continued to see this one lags back behind by
many, many dozens of statistics and measures, and that is a real
challenge.
It is a real challenge because capital formation out in especially
where I come from, in the heartland, is really, really poor, and we
have to fix that.
So that is one thing that I talk a lot about, which is kind of the
wet blanket effect of all of these regulations.
The other thing, which isn’t talked about as much but I have
been pushing really hard, is the effect on bank balance sheets of
these many intrusive regulations. And let me tell you what I think
I mean, which is the more and more that we develop a higher and
higher regulatory threshold in a variety of different areas, the more
and more we force institutions to look more and more similar to
each other. By government saying we are going to weight these and
not these, we are pushing banks into a corner.
And you have to be really careful when you line banks up like
that because you better hope you got everything right, because now
you have lined them up to where the moment there is an issue it
is a very quick transmission from institution to other institutions
because their balance sheet looks very familiar.
What I fundamentally believe is that robustness and resiliency
are emergent qualities from a system, not qualities that can be demanded by fiat.
And so Mr. Sivon had talked about this a little bit earlier, just
allowing for diversity of businesses to exist within the financial
landscape and a diversity of business models. And I wondered if
you might touch on that again and talk about how maybe a resil-

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00040

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

35
ient, robust system, one that can withstand shocks, probably derives from that diversity of business models, risks, and profiles.
Mr. SIVON. Yes. Thank you. Clearly, the system is stable today
in part because of many of the steps that have been taken by the
industry and regulators and Congress.
Our view is that we probably have some excess capital and some
excess liquidity requirements today that could be put to more productive use and help economic growth. And that is the nature of
the recommendations that we make in our testimony in terms of
adjusting the capital requirements and the liquidity rule and the
Volcker Rule and the supplemental leverage ratio and so on. There
are quite a number of changes that could be done in a fine-tuning
way to help economic growth.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. Dr. Calomiris, could you comment?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I will, like a broken record, just point out that
it can’t possibly be a good thing that, putting aside the largest
banks, that the banks throughout our country have about threequarters of their loans in real estate.
When you are asking, are we in a situation that is going to be
resilient, when all those balance sheets are basically lending to one
sector that is very correlated with the business cycle and has a
very hard time selling assets during a downturn, how are we dealing with systemic risk? I think it is kind of a joke.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. Dr. Cecchetti?
Mr. CECCHETTI. Two quick comments.
First of all, I think it would be very difficult to disagree with
your comment about the need for what I would call a diverse ecology in the financial system in order to ensure its resilience. I think
that is absolutely, absolutely essential. And to the extent that the
regulatory environment is overly constraining in certain ways, it
will decrease that diversity and reduce the resilience.
I would, however, want to comment on the issue of the lending
levels. I think that we did not come into the crisis with levels of
debt that were sustainable. And so the fact that levels of debt
today are lower and that growth rates during the recovery have
been lower than those in previous recoveries I think is something
that we should not be terribly upset about.
The distribution of those loans is a separate issue, as my colleague just described. And so I might—I would agree that if all you
are doing again is lending to real estate, that that is an issue.
Mr. HOLLINGSWORTH. I certainty understand that perspective,
but back home in Indiana there are a lot of people who feel like
it is something to be upset about.
And the lack of loan growth, and especially loan growth to the
incremental individual who might be on the bubble of creditworthiness but is trying to start that business, trying to make a difference, trying to build a better financial future for themselves, to
them the lack of loan growth or credit growth or credit availability
has been a real challenge, and they feel like it is being more and
more directed by bureaucrats in a fashion towards others and not
towards empowering them across the heartland.
And with that, I will yield back, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman BARR. The gentleman’s time has expired.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00041

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

36
The gentleman from Georgia, Mr. Scott, is recognized for 5 minutes.
Mr. SCOTT. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Cecchetti, it seems to me that some of my Republican friends
want to strip the Fed of its supervisory and regulatory functions
and leave the Fed, in my opinion, and I want your opinion on this,
wouldn’t that leave the Fed ill-equipped to be able to judge the conditions of the financial institutions that they are in business to do?
Wouldn’t that make it very difficult, particularly when the Fed has
a role of being the lender of last resort?
Mr. CECCHETTI. I certainly believe that. Making a loan to a
bank—for the central bank to make a loan to a bank I think is a
very important financial stability tool. At the same time it is extremely important that the central bank, the Federal Reserve, not
make a loan to an insolvent bank. You cannot be in the business
of lending money to people who are already bankrupt.
Mr. SCOTT. Right.
Mr. CECCHETTI. There are many reasons for that. The first one
is that is basically a bailout. The second one is that you are subordinating existing debt holders. Because the Federal Reserve is
going to require collateral, it is going to come in senior to everybody else that is out there.
The second thing you are going to do is you are going to make
the cleanup more costly.
And the third thing is that if you make loans to bankrupt institutions, what is going to happen is that people are going to come
to know that you make loans to bankrupt institutions, and then
others are going to assume that if you go for a loan you are bankrupt, and nobody is going to want to go for a loan, so it is going
to be very stigmatizing.
So I think that the only way to ensure that the Federal Reserve
or any central bank does not make loans to insolvent institutions,
to bankrupt institutions, is to have supervisory information, because you need things that are very, very current, and you need
people who you can trust providing you with that information.
Mr. SCOTT. And it seems to me that they want to take it away
from the Fed and put it to some outside entity. What outside entity
are they talking about?
Mr. CECCHETTI. I think you would have to create a new one. Either that or you are going to have to combine the Federal Reserve’s
supervisory and regulatory authority with an existing agency, and
I don’t see anyone suggesting that. But I don’t see how you could
do it.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. There are many ways to do it. Let me remind
you that in 2009 Senator Dodd, that was his vision of how we
should have crafted the Dodd-Frank Act, and I agree with that. I
think we should have gone in that direction.
Furthermore, that the 2008 Treasury Blueprint that I keep referring to specifically made the same distinction. It seems like Professor Cecchetti and I are sort of in agreement, because the key
point is you want the lender of last resort and the monetary authority to have continuous unfettered access to all information and
to participate actively in the examination process, that aspect of
supervision.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00042

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

37
But you don’t need them to be deciding who gets to merge and
who doesn’t. You don’t need them to be setting laws down. It is a
different function.
Mr. SCOTT. But it just seems to me that if you are the lender of
last resort and that power and authority rests with you, you are
the fulcrum of the welfare of the entire economy. But if you take
away that ability to give it to an outside source, that really is a
mystery. You just can’t pluck it out the air here and give it to it.
I would think it would be devastating turbulence to our whole
economy.
Mr. CECCHETTI. I think that I am not the historian that Dr.
Calomiris is, but I will say that the Federal Reserve was started
in 1914 by the Congress in order to actually do this. And so it is
hard for me to see how you would organize this in a different way.
Mr. SCOTT. Let me just ask you on the appropriations process,
Mr. Cecchetti, what will subjecting the Fed’s nonmonetary functions to the appropriations process, in your opinion, do to the economy?
Mr. CECCHETTI. I think it would be bad, but I think you have run
out of time.
Mr. SCOTT. You did say it—
Mr. CECCHETTI. It would be bad. I think it would not serve us
well.
Mr. SCOTT. All right. Thank you.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. The gentleman’s time has expired.
The gentleman from Illinois, Mr. Foster, is recognized for 5 minutes.
Mr. FOSTER. Thank you, again.
One of the issues in the inflation target is whether we actually
measure inflation properly. I guess Larry Summers and others
have been going around giving talks that we are making a bad mistake in how we—one simple example that everyone points out is
this supercomputer in my hand here is the equivalent to a couplemillion-dollar Cray-1 supercomputer. And so everyone in my family
can now afford their own private supercomputer that used to cost
a million dollars in 1970 dollars.
And so we are not doing inflation—or Wikipedia. Every middleclass family used to put 500 bucks down into World Book Encyclopedias for their children that they now get for free or essentially
free.
And so that especially in items having to do with the digital
economy, it is not at all clear we are doing inflation right. And if
you look at people’s leisure time, it is going more and more into
free things on the internet that we used to pay a lot for. Just a long
list of these things.
And you can make a case that we are badly mismeasuring inflation. If that is true, it has real implications for monetary policy.
And I was wondering what your attitude is on this part of the
debate, because the digitalization of our economy is accelerating,
and this is going to be more important in the future.
Anyone?
Mr. CECCHETTI. We are trying to pass this around.
I think this is an extremely difficult question. And my own view
is that these problems have existed to one degree or another for a

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00043

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

38
very long time. Television is very much like some aspects of the
internet. So television comes on in the 1950s and provides us with
free television in exchange for advertising.
Google provides us with free lots of things in exchange for advertising, which then the advertising, of course, costs get impounded
into the costs of all of the other products that we have, that we
purchase.
So the question is whether or not that has gotten materially
worse. I love my supercomputer in my pocket, as well, and I use
it quite a lot, and it is it is much more than a—I would have put
the price at more like $30 million in 1970 dollars than $1 million.
It is a lot.
But I think that are we today worse than we were, say, during
the time there was the Boskin Commission in the 1990s that estimated the bias in the Consumer Price Index at roughly 1 percentage point per year. One percentage point seems to me to be a reasonable number. That means that actual inflation is closer to 1
than—when it reads 2 it is closer to 1.
Mr. FOSTER. That has real implications, for example, politically
where there is a narrative that real wages have not gone up in the
last generation. And if you change that by 1 percent, that is a big
change in that narrative.
Mr. CECCHETTI. I agree with that completely. And the person
whom I would point to as the biggest champion of that is actually
Martin Feldstein, who I think normally testifies for your Republican colleagues.
Mr. FOSTER. Let’s see. I guess there is a line of commenting actually that has been happening about the politicization of the Fed. I
was just wondering when in the past have Presidents seen fit to
appoint
political
operatives,
campaign
operatives
and
speechwriters, to Chair the Federal Reserve. I am only aware of
that happening one time in my historical knowledge. Any other example than Chair Greenspan?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I can’t think of a—
Mr. FOSTER. Of a second example.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Just to answer that more constructively, I don’t
think it is about the personalities or the backgrounds of the people
as much as it is about the incentives of the institution.
Mr. FOSTER. I presume you have read Chair Greenspan’s book,
I take it you probably all have, and you see he talked in glowing
terms about his experience as a campaign operative and also his
sadness when George Herbert Walker Bush, George Bush, Sr., accused him of being responsible for George Bush, Sr.’s losing the
election because he appropriately tightened credit at the wrong
time.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I know a little bit about that story if you want
to hear about it.
Mr. FOSTER. Did he correctly report it, in your belief, in his book?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. So Nicholas Brady told me, and he told me because he knew I was a financial historian and he wanted the
record to contain this, that Alan Greenspan had made a promise
to him that he reneged on. And I think that was the nature, that,
in fact, George Bush’s promise to or willingness to consider tax increases was premised on that agreement.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00044

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

39
That is how Washington works, which you know better than I.
And so I think a lot of the bitterness had to do with the fact that
President Bush actually made a concession on tax policy expecting
the Fed to do something that they then backed out on.
Mr. FOSTER. I see. And is it fair to say, though, my last question,
that for President Bush II, when he had the opportunity to tighten
credit at a time that you could make a strong argument for, that
he did not repeat his mistake?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. Which Bush are we talking about?
Mr. FOSTER. We are talking about Bush II and the question of
whether keeping the housing bubble inflating potentially to influence the reelection of George Bush, Jr.
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I don’t know whether that was part of the calculation.
Mr. FOSTER. Okay. Well, thank you. I appreciate it.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. The gentleman’s time has expired.
With that, we are going to wrap up the questioning. I have a few
comments and a few questions here. So we will try and be brief
here.
Mr. Sivon, all large banks have on-site examiners from the Federal Reserve. How have the Federal Reserve supervisory practices
changed since the crisis? Have the supervisors been adequately
transparent?
Mr. SIVON. Thank you, Congressman.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. I know you represent a lot of big banks
with the Financial Services Roundtable.
Mr. SIVON. Thank you, Congressman. It is true that the larger
banks have on-site examiners.
I think, in fairness, the supervisory policies of all the agencies
have tightened since the crisis, the Fed included. And where we are
at this juncture and what our testimony is trying to indicate is that
we are at a tipping point where we think that there could be some
refinement both in regulation and in supervisory policy.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. I have just a few thoughts here. We
have had a very lengthy discussion today, and I don’t want to drag
this out any longer, but just a couple of little thoughts here with
regards to some of the comments that were made and some of the
testimony that we have heard.
I think, Mr. Sivon, you made the comment with regards to stress
test models, and I am kind of concerned sometimes that the stress
testing that is being done doesn’t actually reflect a stressed or a
situation that could actually occurred. That is my concern with
some of the stress tests.
I know there are some difficulties in modeling because the Fed
doesn’t tell the banks how to do this. They are kind of doing it on
a guesstimate way of going about it. But at the same time I am
kind of concerned at the way the Fed’s modeling on these things
is going, that they are really not modeling a real situation that
could actually occur in today’s world, and that is a concern of mine.
Mr. SIVON. One of our recommendations to address that specific
concern is that the Fed’s stress test scenarios be put out for public
comment so that they could be scrubbed and the Fed could benefit
from that type of input from people on this panel.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. Dr. Calomiris, do you have—

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00045

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

40
Mr. CALOMIRIS. I agree with that. I have a specific version of
that, which I have proposed.
But I also want to come back to the point of the stress test. The
stress test using the current data can’t answer the question they
want to answer. What they want to answer is, how will we be able
to tell whether banks might be suddenly losing their economic
value? That is what causes a crisis.
The failure of banks to be able to roll over their short-term debt
and to be able to behave normally reflects a sudden loss of economic value. That is not going to be captured unless you model the
creation of economic value. You can’t model the loss of it.
Relying on book value of equity ratios and using the kind of data
that are used in these financial reports simply cannot answer the
question.
So I would say that stress tests are close to useless as a forecasting tool for the sudden loss of economic value, and I don’t believe the scenarios are very meaningful. So I do think currently
they are not helpful, but they are currently for most of the banks
the binding constraint on capital. So I think that is very troubling.
I am a big fan of stress tests as an idea, but the current procedures have the secrecy problem, which is unaccountability, and
therefore bad modeling is quite likely. But even more deeply, conceptually they are just not addressing the right question, and they
don’t have the data to address them.
Mr. CECCHETTI. I would just like to be the defender of what is
going on today. I believe that the Federal Reserve is doing a reasonable job of this. I think they are trying to improve every day
that they go to work to do a better job. I think they are trying to
do that both on the modeling side, the scenario side, and on the
side of the data that is being collected.
What I would say is that I think we want to be very, very wary
of transparency on the scenarios and on the models. I think that
the idea that people are going to game the system is a very real
one and that we want to guard against that.
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. It is interesting, because in this very
committee, in that far corner over to the left, we had a stack of
paper to represent 20,000 pages, what is sometimes a small stress
test for some of these institutions, and it took up that whole table
and then some. And yet, I don’t know that anybody even reads it
when it gets to the Fed.
And so as a former regulator, the Fed already has all this information. This is one of my concerns with the stress tests. To me it
is an exercise where they don’t seem to be willing to do their job,
which is to assess risk themselves. The Fed does its own systemic
risk analysis for all those institutions, yet I am not sure why we
need a stress test. It is done by the bank itself, which seems to be
a game of ‘‘gotcha.’’ Am I wrong?
Mr. CALOMIRIS. If it were done properly the stress test could answer questions, a well-posed question: In the event that these
things happened, would you suffer a very large sudden loss of
value?
So I think it does have a function that is unique. I am not
against stress tests as an exercise. I just don’t think they are currently ready for primetime.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00046

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

41
Chairman LUETKEMEYER. My time has expired here, so we need
to move on. I will let you gentlemen get home. And again, thank
you for your expertise and your willingness to be with us and share
your knowledge today. It has been a great hearing.
And I thank the chairman of the Oversight and Investigations
Subommittee, Mr. Barr, for all his hard work and participation in
putting this together and his great comments.
The Chair notes that some Members may have additional questions for this panel, which they may wish to submit in writing.
Without objection, the hearing record will remain open for 5 legislative days for Members to submit written questions to these witnesses and to place their responses in the record. Also, without objection, Members will have 5 legislative days to submit extraneous
materials to the Chair for inclusion in the record.
With that, this hearing is adjourned.
[Whereupon, at 4:15 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.]

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00047

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00048

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

APPENDIX

September 12, 2017

(43)

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00049

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

44

Reforming and Depoliticizing the Federal Reserve

Testimony of Charles W. Calomiris
Before the U.S. House of Representatives
Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit
and Subcommittee on Monetary Policy and Trade
of the Committee on Financial Services

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00050

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.001

September 12,2017

45
Tbe Federal Reserve is now more politicized tban it bas been at any time in its history, and
consequently it is also less independent in its actions than at any time in its history, with the
ex,~eption

of the years 1936-1951 when it lacked effective monetary policy authority.

Tbe Fed's leadership argues that the accumulation of a variety of discretionary powers
enhances its effectiveness and independence, but history and logic tell a different story. As the
Fed accumulates more and bigger political lightning rods of discretionary power- often through
its own active lobbying for increased power, as during the aftermath of the 2007-2009 crisisthe Fed finds itself increasingly politicized, and less independent, both in the realm of monetary
policy and in regulatory and supervisory actions.
The Fed's discretionary powers

which now encompass monetary, fiscal, regulatory, and

supervisory matters on a grand scale- have been growing over the past decades and today are
greater than ever. With that discretionary power inevitably comes attacks by special interests
seeking to manipulate those powers. The Fed finds itself making political deals with special
interests and their representatives largely as a result of its burgeoning discretion. Examples of
how this has affected regulatory policy include the politicization of CRA enforcement and bank
merger deals in the 1990s and 2000s, which also led the Fed to fail in its job as prudential
regulator of risk prior to the crisis, and the disgraceful complicity of the Fed in ··operation
Chokepoint"' in recent years.
Fed leaders intent on preserving their discretionary power wrongly argue that unlimited
flexibility helps them to be more effective. They resist proposed clarification of their mandates
or requirements that they follow clear rules when crafting policy despite the compelling
economic arguments in favor of those proposals. It is downright unseemly to see Fed leaders go
to great pains to defend the status quo of vague and unaccountable mandates placed on their

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00051

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.002

1

46
actions. They resist and mischaracterize the proposed establishment of a flexible, rule-based
system to enhance Fed monetary policy accountability, as they actively seek new authorities to
make and enforce financial regulations without adhering to formal rule making procedures or
seeking Congressional approval. They actively and successfully resisted efforts (like those of
Senator Dodd in 2009) to transfer powers from the Fed to other less conflicted regulatory entities
that might operate more independently.
Fed leaders defending their power also offer distorted and self-interested opinions about
important public policy questions, while pretending that their opinions should be viewed as
unbiased professional analysis. Fed Chair Janet Yellen's August 2017 Jackson Hole speech was
a prime example. It was a full-throated defense of the status quo of financial regulation, and the
Fed's status as financial regulator in chief. But Chair Yellen ignored scores of studies that
contradict her narrative of the goldilocks status quo. For a literature review, see my May 2017
book, RefiJrming Financial Regulation After Dodd-Frank (Calomiris 2017a), and the
f01thcoming special issue of the Journal of Financial Intermediation containing original
empirical studies of regulatory problems arising from post-crisis regulatory policies. Many of the
studies she ignored were written hy economists working at the Federal Reserve Board, the
various Federal Reserve Banks, and the Office for Financial Research, as well as by top
academic researchers. Don't be fooled by her charade. Financial regulatory policy is unbalanced,
unlikely to prove effective in achieving its objectives, and fails to meet basic standards of due
process for a democracy operating under the rule of law.
The core problem that must be addressed is the absence of clear rules guiding the
procedures followed by the Fed when setting monetary policy or adopting regulations or
supervisory practices. Basing decisions on such rules- which could be designed to be J1exiblc

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00052

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.003

2

47
and to change as needed over time- would ensure greater effectiveness and accountability of
monetary policy and regulatory policy, and enhance Fed independence. As I explained in my
April 4, 2017 testimony before this committee (Calomiris 20 17b). "paradoxically, unlimited Fed
discretion does not result in greater independence of action because unlimited discretion invites
political interference." Fed independence is best achieved by imposing discipline on the process
of monetary and regulatory policies in a way that sets clear objectives for both sets of policies
and enhances accountability with respect to achieving those objectives.
As I show in Cal om iris (20 13). which I attach as an exhibit to this report, in the absence
of clear rules, pressures on policy makers tend to make them cede ground to special interests, and
they do so in a myopic way, reflecting current political pressures of special interests rather than
long-run public interests. For example, when monetary authority is not delegated to an
independent central bank acting under clear rules that limit special interest pressures, elected
officials and others can pressure central bankers to print money in lieu of taxes to pay for
ekction-year concessions to powerful constituents. The existence of clear mandates and the
requirement that clear rules be enunciated and followed insulates the central bank from those
sorts of undesirable shmt-term pressures. The same logic that explains the desirability of rulesbased independent monetary policy also applies to regulatory policy. Bank regulation should be
vested in an accountable agency that follows rules established by Congress and is subject to
Congressional budgetary discipline.
In April, I testified about the appropriate way to structure Fed monetary policy using a
flexible rules-based approach. and I also discussed a variety of other changes in the governance
structure of the Fed that would enhance the diversity of thinking, quality of analysis,
accountability and independence of monetary policy.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00053

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.004

3

48
In that testimony I made several recommendations to address the need to reduce existing
conflicts of interest in Fed powers and responsibilities that are distorting monetary and
regulatory policy decision making, and I proposed some budgetary refonns that would prevent
the use of Fed revenues for fiscal policy actions not controlled by Congress. I will not repeat all
those arguments here, but instead focus here on alternative measures

which are less ambitious

than my proposal to implement the 2008 Treasury Blueprint for regulatory restructuring to
remove the Fed from day-to-day regulation and supervision, and therefore. perhaps easier to
accomplish.
I reiterate that, in my opinion, the ideal set of reforms would establish clear rules to guide
both monetary policy and regulatory policy, would avoid undesirable conflicts of interest by
placing day-to-day regulatory and supervisory authority in an agency other than the Fed, and
would establish administrative and budgetary discipline over the process of regulation and
supervision.
Fed leaders often claim that their role as lender of last resort requires them to maintain
regulatory and supervisory authority over banks. That is a fatuous argument. Despite Fed
officials' defenses of their growing regulatory powers by arguing for synergies between
monetary and regulatory policies, there is no evidence of any synergy between monetary and
regulatory policy. Vincent Reinhart (2009), a former high-level Fed official, has questioned the
Fed leaders' arguments in favor of such synergies: "There is an easily verifiable test. The arm of
the Fed that sets monetary policy, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), has
scrupulously kept transcripts of its meetings over the decades. (I should know. as l was the
FOMC secretary for a time.) ... .Ifthc FOMC made materially better decisions because of the
Fed's role in supervision, there should be instances of informed discussion of the linkages.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00054

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.005

4

49
Anyone making the case for beneficial spillovers should be asked to produce numerous relevant
excerpts from that historical resource. I don't think they will be able to do so." The information
needed by the lender of last resort pertains to examinations and is unrelated to day-to-day
regulatory or supervisory power. As the 2008 Treasury blueprint noted, the Fed could participate
in examinations, as needed, without having to craft regulations and be responsible for day-to-day
supervision.
The history of growing Fed involvement in the regulation and supervision of banks did
not result from a perceived synergy between monetary and regulatory policy but rather because
of accidents of history that made it more expedient to locate new powers in the Fed (Calomiris
20 13). In the 1930s, the Fed was given new regulatory powers because it happened to have been
collecting infonnation that turned out to be relevant to new regulatory mandates. More recently,
Administrations and Congresses have vested power in the Fed precisely because doing so made
it more likely that the Fed would respond to certain favored special interests. For example, the
"third way" espoused by the Clinton Administration explicitly depended on the Fed to apply
pressure on banks to grant concessions to special interests that the Administration favored as part
of the bank regulatory approvals (Calomiris and Haber 2014, Chapter 7). Fed officials welcomed
new power because they saw additional regulatory power as a means of insulating monetary
policy from political pressures by giving concessions to special interests on regulatory policy.
Despite the advantages of avoiding such conflicts by removing regulatory policy from the
Fed, a less drastic set of reforms could accomplish a great deal of improvement. Specifically, if it
were possible to establish clear rules governing both monetary and regulatory policy and impose
administrative and budgetary discipline on the process of regulation, then even if regulatory and
supervisory powers remained vested in the Fed, the problems associated with Fed conflicts and

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00055

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.006

5

50
politicization would be substantially reduced. Clear rules and procedures establishing budgetary
and administrative discipline would make the location of regulatory authority less important.
Budgetary and administrative discipline over regulation should ensure that Congress
retains its Constitutional authority to make laws and control government spending. Not only
would such discipline restore the intent of our Constitution, it would also result in many practical
advantages. Requiring Congress to weigh the social costs and benefits that arise in regulation
likely would limit special interest manipulation of regulatory discretion after regulations are
passed through pressures applied to regulators (see Gordon and Rosenthal2017 for a discussion
of how delegation to regulatory discretion undermined the risk-limiting provisions of the DoddFrank Act with respect to the mo1igage market). Most importantly, to improve and depoliticize
regulation, Congress must establish clear rules that limit the use of unaccountable discretion,
must establish budgetary authority for regulatory implementation, and must limit the abusive
reliance on ·'guidance" in regulatory actions by requiring a much greater reliance on formal rule
making consistent with the Administrative Procedures Act. If this were done alongside the
establishment of a flexible monetary policy rule, that would go a long way toward restoring
halance in the regulatory process, while also depoliticizing the Fed and ensuring the
accountability of monetary and regulatory policy.
The Fed will not improve itself without action by Congress to require rules-based
behavior, to restore proper Congressional budgetary authority over regulatory matters, and to
require adherence to due process in regulation. As Reinhart (2012) explains, the Fed avoids
creating clear rules because it lacks an incentive to do so. Reinhart shows that this is a
consequence of three factors, which Reinhart labels '·ambiguity" (of its mandate), ''diversity" (a
lack of agreement about what its goals should be, given that ambiguity of mandate), and

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00056

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.007

6

51
.. democracy" (the fact that the FOMC is a collection of different people). Only by clarifying the
goals of the Fed and requiring it to work within clear rules can regulatory and monetary policy
be improved to make those policies focus on long-run objectives, avoid short-run politicization,
ensure appropriate balance and due process in regulation and supervision, and become
accountable to the will of the people.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00057

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.008

7

52
References

Calomiris, Charles W. 2013. How To Promote Fed Independence. Unpublished working paper,
Columbia University, March II.
Calomiris, Charles W. 2017a. Reforming Financial Regulat01y Reform After Dodd-Frank. New
York: Manhattan Institute.
Calomiris, Charles W. 20!7b. Reforming the Rules That Govern the Fed. Testimony before the
Subcommittee on Monetary Policy and Trade of the Committee on Financial Services, April4.
Calomiris, Charles W., and Stephen H. Haber. 2014. Fragile By Design: The Political Origins of
Banking Crises and Scarce Credit. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Gordon, Sanford, and Howard Rosenthal. 2017. Political Actions By Private Interests: Mortgage
Market Regulation in the Wake of Dodd-Frank. Unpublished working paper, New York
University.
Re:inhart, Vincent. 2009. The Right Role for the Fed, Washington Post, December 3,
htt~ww .vvashingtonpost.com/wp-dvn/contcnt/artic lc/2009/ 12/02/AR700912020i690

pf.html

Reinhart, Vincent. 2012. Macro Matters: The Campaign Season, Fed Style, US Macro
Dashboard, Morgan Stanley, August I 0.
U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2008. The Department of the Treasury Blueprint for a
Modernized Financial Regulatory Structure. March. https://www.treasurv.!.!ov/press-ccnter/pressr..eJeascs/Documents/B lueprint.pd [
Yellen, Janel. 2017. Financial Stability a Decade after the Onset of the Crisis. August 25. Speech
at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Symposium entitled "'Fostering a Dynamic Global
Recovery."'

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00058

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.009

8

53

APPENDIX TO TESTIMONY

How To Promote Fed Independence:
Perspectives from Political Economy and US History

Charles W. Calomiris*

March 11, 2013

Parts of this paper borrow heavily from joint work with Stephen Haber (Fragile By Design:
Banking Crises. Scarce Credit and Political Bargains, Princeton University Press, forthcoming).
For helpful discussions, I thank Stephen Haber, Marvin Goodfriend, Allan Meltzer, David
Wheelock, Geoffrey Wood, and larry Wall.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00059

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.010

1

54
I. Introduction

Practically everyone can agree that central bank independence is desirable, within the confines
of a clear mandate to guide central bankers, which ensures their accountability to their citizens. Yet
differences persist about the answers to five fundamental questions about central bank independence
and the mandates within which that independence is expressed. What is the precise meaning of
independence? On what does its existence depend? Why is it desirable? How independent is the current
Federal Reserve System (Fed), and how independent has it been over its hundred year history? What
could be done to enhance Fed independence by improving the current mandate within which the Fed
operates?

These five questions have been present constantly in policy debates about the institutional
design of central banks, especially since Milton Friedman's classic 1962 article addressing them. 1 Yet
despite many decades of thinking, a working definition of Fed independence remains elusive, judgments
differ about its extent and feasibility, and policy advocates continue to advocate very different kinds of
rules for improving Fed independence.

In this article, I show that convincing answers to the five fundamental questions about Fed
independence must begin by recognizing the status of the Fed within American democracy. As a matter
of the logic of political economy, that means not only identifying the momentary statutory powers of

1
Friedman (1962) considers three possibilities: a fully discretionary, independent central bank, a commodity
standard, and a monetary rule. Friedman argues that the most desirable of these is a monetary rule. I conceive of a

more flexible arrangement than a rule: one in which the central bank has a clear statutory mandate or explicit rule

(e.g., a Taylor Rule) that it commits to follow, but it can deviate from the rule. I recognize, following Capie and
Wood (2012), and in the spirit of Meltzer (2012), that inflexible rules are not credible, especially in the presence of
financial crises. Thus, I favor a "comply·and-explain" regime, in which departures from the rule are dearly
announced and explained. The central bank describes why it is deviating from the rule, and commits to do so
rarely. The leadership of the central bank, therefore, bears significant personal reputational risk if the supposed
reasons for the deviation from the rule are considered to have been inappropriate, on the basis of hindsight. One
could make this personal responsibility explicit by requiring that the terms of all Governors and Presidents would
come up for renewal two years after they deviated from the rule, which would put discourage departure from the
rule unless the circumstances dearly warranted it.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00060

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.011

2

55
the Fed, but analyzing how alterations in those powers arise. All political constructs

including the Fed-

are the result of a political bargaining process. Independence is impossible to define without considering
the process through which power is delegated or withdrawn.

When considering the political bargains that give rise to changes in Fed powers, it is crucial to
consider decisions to combine different authorities within the Fed. The combination of authorities given
to the Fed has been important in shaping the independence with which the Fed implements each aspect
of its authority. It can be very misleading to focus- as many scholars do- only on the monetary powers
that have been delegated to the Fed. Deciding what combination of powers to allocate to the Fed has
been an important part of the political bargain affecting Fed independence. The range of the Fed's
powers has not been constant over time, and changes in powers can have important implications for
changes in the degree of Fed independence. Nor are changes over time in independence uniform across
the various types of authority wielded by the Fed (which we will divide into monetary policy and
regulatory policy powers). In the context of contemporary Fed actions, I define monetary policy as
consisting of open market operations that expand or contract high-powered money (bank reserves plus
currency) by buying or selling short-term Treasury securities, or that affect low-powered money through
changes in properly bank reserve requirements. 2 The relationship between the extent of Fed power and
Fed independence is not straightforward. In particular, it is not true that increased power always

2
1do not consider Fed "credit" powers in this essay. By credit powers, I mean fiscal activities of the Fed related to
the absorption of credit risk through lending and the purchases of risky securities. As Goodfriend (2011, 2012)
notes, such powers are an inappropriate circumvention of proper procedures for appropriating funds in a
democracy, which should be the purview of Congress and the Administration, not the central bank. These Fed
powers became especially important in the recent crisis. Delegation of regulatory powers can have a similarly fiscal
aspect, as I will show in the discussion of regulatory policy. I include reserve requirements in my definition of
monetary policy. I recognize that this is a controversial definition. Reserve requirements that pay interest below
the market (fed funds) interest rate on required balances constitute a tax on banks. Although Fed reserve
requirements currently do not pay fed funds rates as a matter of policy, I propose that they should (as discussed
further below). I do not explore credit policy for two reasons. First, others, especially Goodfriend (2011, 2012),
have already commented on these issues at length. Second, considering the possible means for creating a credit
policy authority separate from the Fed to deal with emergency subsidization of credit risk during a crisis would
require a lengthy treatment.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00061

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.012

3

56
produces greater independence. Increases in powers can result in reduced independence along some
dimensions and increased independence along other dimensions.

A convincing treatment of the logic and history of Fed independence could be the subject of a
lengthy book. In this article, my ambitions are more modest. I construct a working definition of Fed
independence that reflects the realities of American democracy- one that is informed by Fed history,
and that takes account of the interactions among the various aspects of Fed power in affecting the
extent of policy independence. I structure the discussion by first summarizing the argument of the paper
in the form of eight sets of propositions, in Section II, which together address the fundamental questions
about Fed independence that I posed in the first paragraph. More detailed evidence in support of those
propositions is provided in Sections Ill and IV. Section V concludes.

II. Eight Sets of Propositions about Fed Independence

Proposition 1: Independence of authority of any agency is usefully defined as the ability to act, within
th<~

confines of a mandate, on the basis of judgment, and to do so with an expectation of impunity. An

expectation of impunity is crucial to the existence of independence. An independent authority is
independent not simply by virtue of the granting of de jure authority at a moment in time, but also by
virtue of its reasonable expectation that the delegation of power will not be withdrawn as a
consequence of undertaking legitimately independent decisions (that is, decisions that are made
according to due process and within the confines of the entity's statutory mandate).

Proposition 2: The de jure granting of independent authority does not itself guarantee legitimate
independent action. Legitimate central bank independence, as a behavioral reality, "generally requires"
that four separate conditions must all be satisfied: (i) the presence of a clear statutory mandate

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00062

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.013

4

57
(otherwise there is no way to gauge legitimacy -that is, to see whether the mandate has been
exceeded}, (ii} the granting of statutory power for independent action within the constraints of the
mandate, (iii} expected statutory authority persistence (a reasonable expectation that the exertion of
independent authority within the confines of the preexisting mandate will not result in a change in the
mandate}, 3 and (iv} central bank leadership that is desirous of acting independently. It is possible for a
central bank to gain legitimate independence without one or more of these requirements (by virtue of
exceptional leadership, successful policies, and spontaneous public approval}, but this is unlikely.

Proposition 3: Independence is desirable because it constrains the ability of elected officials to make

policy decisions. Presumably, the potential value of such constraints revolves around two aspects of
political decisions in a democracy, which may be considered undesirable in economic policy making:
myopia and logrolling. Myopia refers to the tendency of elected officials to sacrifice long-term objectives
in order to retain their political power via reelection. Logrolling (mutual back-scratching among vested
interests} makes it possible that policy choices that would benefit everyone may not be chosen because
they are not a top priority of any powerful special interest. A political bargain that cobbles together a
voting majority by making a concession to each member of its coalition will avoid supporting some
desirable economic policies, especially if those policies make it harder to fulfill the top priorities of the
various special interests that support the coalition.

3
Consider an illustration of this point from the history of the Supreme Court. Under the Constitution, Supreme
Court Justices serve for life. Lifetime tenure by itself would mean little if the Congress could act to amend the law
to >horten the tenure of federal judges. The fact that it would require a Constitutional amendment to alter their
tenure contributes to the Court's independence. Similarly, the fact that under current law, the number of Justices

is limited to nine is important, as it limits the ability of Congress and the Administration to pack the court with new

appointments to push through a point of view (for example, this was done by President Grant to achieve an
outcome with respect to the constitutionality of inflationary legal tender laws in the 1870s, and President
Roosevelt threatened this action in the 1930s during his battle with the Court). The nine-Justice limit, however, is
arguably less potent a protection of independence than lifetime tenure because it is more easily reversed (it is a
matter of statute, not the Constitution).

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00063

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.014

5

58
For example, as the result of myopia and logrolling, if monetary authority is not delegated to an
independent central bank, elected officials may choose to print a large amount of money (rather than
increase taxes, which would run afoul of one or more powerful constituents affected by that tax) to pay
for election-year grants to some of their most powerful constituents. Elected officials may choose to do
so despite the consequences of inflation in the future.

Monetary policy is an ideal candidate for delegation to a central bank precisely because the
costs of incremental decisions to inflate are small and widely distributed in the population, and because
they tend to arise with a lag. Problems of myopia and logrolling- which are especially pronounced in
populist democracies like that of the United States- will therefore tend to benefit from delegation of
monetary policy to a truly independent central bank. (Of course, myopia and logrolling may also make it
far less likely that populist democracies will choose to create truly independent central banks in the first
place- a problem to which I will return.)

Even a truly independent central bank may not choose to adhere to monetary policies that are
in the interest of its citizens, however, for one of three possible reasons: (1) The central bank may
choose objectives that are contrary to the public interest, either because of its freedom to dictate
objectives, or because it is under the pressure of particular political factions. (2) Even in the absence of
political factions, without a constraining mandate that requires the central bank to adhere to particular
long-term objectives, it may make policy choices that are popular on a moment-to-moment basis, but
that are contrary to the public interest because of a time inconsistency problem (Kydland and Prescott
1977). (3) The central bank may be incompetent in exercising its discretionary authority. Thus
independence by itself, in the absence of a constraining mandate that guides policy objective and a
competent agency, is no guarantee of desirable policy.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00064

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.015

6

59
The same logic that explains the desirability of independent monetary policy also applies to
regulatory policy, and explains why bank regulation is also a candidate for delegation to a truly
independent agency (not necessarily the central bank). Regulation (most obviously, selective relaxation
of entry barriers) can also be used to serve vested interests at the expense of the general populations.
Entry barriers in fact have been used in precisely this way throughout U.S. banking history. Thus, if an
independent regulatory agency can be established, it could conceivably produce decisions that are not
influenced by myopia and logrolling.

Proposition 4: Unfortunately, for most of Fed history, with respect to both of its main categories of

authority (monetary policy and regulatory policy), one or more of the four necessary conditions for
independent behavior has been absent. As a consequence, it has been rare for the Fed to act
independently. Independence has been rare in monetary policy; the only eras in which independent
action in monetary policy was clearly evident were 1921-1933 and 1979-2006 (comprising less than half
of the Fed's history). In the area of regulatory policy, an area of Fed authority that has become
increasingly important since the 1980s, Fed policy has been much more politicized. The variation over
time in the extent of Fed independence is not associated with statutory changes in the Federal Reserve
Act, but rather with changes in the economic and political circumstances in which the Fed acted, and
with its leadership.

Proposition 5: The greater politicization of regulatory policy, in comparison with monetary policy,

reflects political trends that favored their use as hidden tax-and-transfer policy tools, especially
beginning in the 1990s, as part of the "third way" policy approach of the Clinton Administration, which
sought to use financial system regulation to achieve objectives that it could not achieve through the
normal appropriations process. Fed leadership did not resist that trend, but rather, embraced its

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00065

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.016

7

60
newfound powers and vocally sought to obtain increasing regulatory authority, which it did obtain in the
1990s and subsequently.

The leadership of the Fed has always given greatest priority to obtaining and preserving
independence with respect to monetary policy. The Fed's quest for increased regulatory authority, and
its willingness to act as a political intermediary with respect to the uses of regulatory policy, may be
seen as an attempt to enhance and preserve the Fed's monetary policy autonomy. Because the Fed's
leadership gives greatest priority to preserving and enhancing its monetary policy independence,
delegating enhanced decision making powers in the area of regulatory policy to the Fed tends to
encourage political tradeoffs that result in relatively less independent regulatory policy, but relatively

more independent monetary policy. This likely has been anticipated in the political bargains that have
allocated regulatory policy authority over the past three decades; the increasing breadth of powers
granted to the Fed, therefore, can be seen as the outcome of a political bargain trading off of one aspect
of Fed independence for another.

In the area of regulatory policy, the Fed has generally been willing to act as a compliant
intermediary to implement the political bargains hashed out by Congress and the Administrationincluding bargains that used regulatory policy as a hidden form of fiscal policy. There are many examples
of this phenomenon, but the most obvious and socially costly example was the Fed's oversight of bank
mergers during the 1990s and 2000s. The Fed's intermediation ofthe grand political bargain with
respect to bank mergers during that era was likely a greater contributor to the crisis of 2007-2009 than
the Fed's frequently criticized departure from the Taylor Rule in 2002-2005. One interpretation of the
Fed's desire to obtain regulatory power and acted its willingness to act as an intermediary of politicized
regulation is that doing so is perceived as helping to preserve its monetary policy independence.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00066

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.017

8

61
Proposition 6: Even in the area of monetary policy, greater Fed independence generally has not

produced better policy outcomes; indeed, times of relatively great independence have been associated
with all three of the major errors of monetary policy in the United States during the Fed's history (the
Great Depression of 1929-1933, the Great Inflation of 1965-1979, and the loose-money prelude to the
subprime crisis of 2002-2005).

The Great Inflation of the 1960s and 1970s is mainly attributable to the limits on independent
action by the Fed during that period, owing to a combination of political pressures on the Fed to
monetize government debt in the 1960s and 1970s and to the political agenda of Fed leaders during that
time. Nevertheless, to the extent that Fed leadership enjoyed independence during that era, its
adherence to simple Keynesian Phillips Curve analysis encouraged the tolerance for accelerating
inflation; thus, even in the absence of politicized choices, flawed thinking about monetary policy likely
would have produced an inflationary acceleration.

With respect to the other two major monetary policy errors during Fed history- the monetary
contraction of 1929-1933 and the monetary expansion of 2002-2005- it is important to recognize that
Fed independence was at its peak during those periods. In the first case, the Fed's discretionary errors
were attributable to its pursuit of a flawed policy rule, which combined adherence to the "real bills
doctrine" (a monetary policy doctrine with no current adherents) and money illusion (the failure to
distinguish between nominal and real interest rates). In the 2002-2005 period, the Fed's errors reflected
a willingness to depart from its Taylor Rule behavior in the interest of avoiding the short-term downside
risk of a recession.

The tendency to make important errors in discretionary judgment during these three eras of
monetary policy would have been substantially circumscribed if the Fed had faced a clearer mandate to
ensure price stability, or if it had adopted a transparent rule as its interpretation of its unclear mandate.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00067

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.018

9

62
Either of these options would have constrained the latitude of policy makers by forcing them to
articulate a long-term rule for monetary policy (e.g., a Taylor Rule), which would have required them to
articulate a long-term objective for policy and explain any departures from it. Thus, the adoption of a
clearer statutory mandate, or of a rule-based interpretation of the existing mandate, would not only
have increased Fed independence (by insulating the Fed against political pressure- see Proposition 2), it
would also have improved the outcomes resulting from the wielding of independent authority. This logic
is especially relevant now, as the risks to the erosion of Fed independence going forward are substantial,
and as the recent QE policy experiment has removed any semblance of adherence to a Taylor Rule, or
any other rule, from monetary policy.

Proposition 7: The Fed's leadership tends to exaggerate the independence of the Fed, while seeking

unfettered discretionary authority and resisting rule-based mandates that would increase Fed
accountability. These actions do not foster legitimate independence, or maximize the benefits of
independence that is achieved. They may reflect, in part, the increasing dominance of professionally
trained macroeconomists in the leadership and staffs of the Fed. With some important exceptions, Fed
leaders and economists increasingly have become professionally trained macroeconomists. The majority
of them have been schooled in highly simplified models of monetary policy, and they tend to place too
much faith in the latest versions of these faddish and unrealistic models, perhaps because doing so
reinforces their credentials as policy experts and improves their career prospects. There is, of course,
nothing wrong with using simplified and formal models as heuristic devices for honing one's reasoning.
But one should not pretend that those models can serve as the basis for confident judgments about the
consequences of discretionary actions.4

4

As Meltzer (2012) notes: "Recently, the Board staff and principal members used a model based on Woodford's
(2003) elegant modeling. This, too, is deficient. In the model, money and credit do not matter for monetary policy.

And prices of assets are not part of the transmission mechanism. Only short-term interest rates and rational
expectations are relevant. How could we have a credit crisis? Could anyone believe that the decline in housing

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00068

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.019

10

63
The bias toward undisciplined discretion encourages a resistance within the Fed to clearer,
rules-based limits on the exercise of Fed discretion. That resistance to rules- while often pursued in the
name of promoting Fed independence- actually makes legitimate Fed independence much less likely
(Proposition 2), and also makes the exercise of Fed discretionary authority more prone to error.

Furthermore, the emphasis on many years of training in highly technical macroeconomic
modeling generally results in pervasive ignorance about history or about the Fed's role in regulatory
policy. This ignorance contributes to a lack of interest in and understanding of the Fed's uses of
regulatory policy tools, and aggravates the Fed's willingness to allow political pressures to determine
regulatory policy outcomes.

Proposition 8: To promote independence along both dimensions of economic policy (monetary and
regulatory) two sorts of policy reforms are required: (i) separation of authority over the two areas into
two distinct agencies (to avoid tradeoffs that reduce independence of regulatory policy), and (ii) the
establishment of clear mandates and accountability procedures for each category of policy. In particular,
with respect to monetary policy, the Fed's mandate should be expressed in the form of a "comply or
explain" rule (e.g., a Taylor Rule, or some other similar rule) that would make clear the objectives of
monetary policy, and thus permit and require greater accountability. These policy actions would
substantially increase the likelihood that the four necessary conditions of policy independence would
hold, and thus would promote greater independence of policy.

I do not attempt to "prove" these eight complex and controversial propositions in this article.
Rather, as a first step, I present them as an interpretive narrative to stimulate discussion and debate.

prices was a rational expected response to policy? I find it incredible that a central bank ignores changes in money
and credit. Simply put. that is a mistake that not only ignores much that economists have learned about monetary
economics from analysis and history. No less surprising is the total neglect of the role of asset prices in the
transmission mechanism of monetary impulses. Earlier work by Brunner and Meltzer (1993) and by Tobin (1969)
did not neglect asset prices or credit."

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00069

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.020

11

64
They reflect my understanding of the logic of political bargaining and a much broader historical narrative
of politics, banking and central banking in the United States (see, for example, Meltzer 2003, 2009,
2010, Calomiris and Haber 2013). Neither do I claim originality for any of these ideas. Since Milton
Friedman's classic work on these problems, many other scholars have made similar arguments to those
contained in the eight sets of propositions, although I do not believe that any previous study has
integrated all of these various propositions.

Ill. The Logic of Central Bank Independence and the Monetary Policy History of the Fed

In what sense is any government entity (hereafter referred to as an "agency") within a
democracy "independent"? Clearly, independent action is not usefully defined to be synonymous with
tyrannical action. To be legitimate within a democracy, independent action must occur within the
confines of Constitutional and statutory mandates that define the purposes of independent action.
Furthermore, in pursuit of those mandates, the independent agency also must follow proper
procedures, consistent with democratic oversight and accountability, and adherence to the rule of law.

It follows, therefore, that statutory authority that delegates decision making responsibility is
necessary for legitimate independence to exist. But it is not sufficient. For example, if an agency knows
that the delegation of authority will be withdrawn unless a particular outcome is chosen by the agency,
th••n that agency is not truly independent in its actions. Unless an agency can act with impunity- so long
as the agency's actions conform to the mandates that define its purposes and the required procedures
that govern its deliberations- the agency cannot be independent.

In order to act with the impunity necessary to foster true independence, the statutory mandate
of the agency must be clear. A lack of clarity in the mandate makes it hard to tell when the central bank

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00070

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.021

12

65
is achieving its goals and when it is not. An unclear mandate therefore makes it harder to hold the
agency accountable for doing what it is supposed to do (thereby ceding too much authority to the
agency to pursue its own goals). Just as bad, an unclear mandate makes the agency a target for
politically motivated attacks that can threaten its independence.

These principles are illustrated well by the monetary policy history of the Fed, which is replete
with examples of how statutory delegation of authority to the Fed has not been sufficient to ensure its
true independence. Indeed, de jure and de facto independence have not been closely associated over
time, and sometimes have moved in the opposite direction over time (see also Taylor 2013). The
Banking Act of 1935, which restructured the Federal Reserve System, made the Fed more politically
responsive by centralizing authority and increasing the power of government appointees within the Fed.
But this restructuring had little immediate effect on Fed policy or independence because of the
effective substitution of Treasury authority over monetary policy until1951. The creation of the socalled dual mandate for the Fed in 1977 (which was really a triple mandate requiring the Fed to maintain
price stability, maximum employment, and interest rate stability, without defining priorities or weights
across these often competing objectives) might have been expected to make the Fed less independent.
The creation of multiple, unclear and conflicting mandates might have contributed to the politicization
of the Fed. As we will see, however, it coincided roughly with the beginning of an era of high de facto
Fed independence.

World War/

Most of the changes in the extent of Fed monetary policy independence had nothing to do with
statutory changes. The first meaningful change

which reduced Fed independence- came with World

War I. The Fed was established in 1913 on the basis of the "real bills doctrine" (the view that bills related
to trade should be the exclusive asset bought and sold or held as collateral against loans to member

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00071

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.022

13

66
banks). Government debt was excluded as collateral from Fed discounting operations to ensure that the
Fed did not act as a source of funding to the government. Importantly, the Fed's charter required it to
maintain gold convertibility, which substantially circumscribed its actions. The Fed's initial structurewhich gave primary authority to its Reserve Banks, which were owned and controlled by the Fed
member banks in their respective districts- also limited the extent to which political pressures could
control Fed actions.

Under the pressures of World War l's financial challenges, however, the Fed began to become
an important partner in assisting the U.S. government to market its debts. In 1917, reserve
requirements were reduced to permit expanded credit to finance the war (Meltzer 2003, p. 79, footnote
31). And collateral rules for Federal Reserve note issues were relaxed in 1917: the total amount of
collateral was reduced, and perhaps more importantly, promissory notes of member banks secured by
government bonds could be used as collateral for the notes (Meltzer 2003, p. 89)-' At the end of World
War I, in the interest of boosting demand for outstanding Treasury debts, the Fed also reduced its
discount rate for loans collateralized by Treasury securities.

The accommodation policies of World War I had long-term effects. The discount rate reduction
led the Fed to abandon its "penalty" rate policy for targeting the discount rate, which had been one of
its core founding principles (Meltzer 2003, pp. 73, 86) 6 This change subverted the Fed founders' intent
that the Fed would use a penalty discount rate as its primary tool of managing the cyclical and seasonal
availability of credit in the money market. More broadly, the World War I precedent of making the Fed
subservient to the interests of marketing Treasury debt not only produced the short-term inflationary

5
Despite the real bills doctrine, the Fed always had the ability to purchase government securities as part of its
open market operations. The extent of such purchases were constrained, however, by the need to maintain gold
convertibility, by the rules governing the gold backing for Federal Reserve notes, and by the dominant role of
discounting in the Fed's balance sheet prior to 1932.
• There have been moments when the discount rate was above the market rate, but that was not part of a
consistent policy rule implemented to achieve that outcome.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00072

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.023

14

67
binge of 1917-1920 (Meltzer 2003, pp. 90-107), it also set the stage for subsequent changes that
eventually made the Federal Reserve a fiscal instrument of the U.S. Treasury.

The Great Depression

Those changes were completed during the 1930s, in reaction to the political upheaval that
accompanied the Great Depression. First, in the 1932 Glass-Steagall Act, a temporary measure that was
later made permanent, the Fed was permitted the use of Treasury securities as collateral for Federal
Reserve note issues (Calomiris and Wheelock 1998, Meltzer 2003, pp. 358,417-418, Calomiris 2013). In
March 1933, the United States left the gold standard, freeing monetary policy from its constraining price
level anchor. In 1934, the Treasury gained substantial new monetary powers through the Gold Reserve
Act of 1934 and the Silver Purchase Act of 1934 (see Calomiris and Wheelock 1998), which meant that it
could exert separate control of monetary policy, if it so desired. In 1935, the Fed was restructured to
centralize its policy actions in the Board of Governors, which was the part of the system whose leaders
were government appointees (Calomiris and Wheelock 1998, Meltzer 2003).

The Fed is regarded as having operated reasonably independently in setting its monetary policy
from about 1923 until 1932 (before the political backlash of the Depression eliminated many of the
constraints that had insulated the Fed from political manipulation). After 1933, however, control over
monetary policy was effectively transferred to the U.S. Treasury, not as the result of statutory changes
with regard to Fed powers, but rather by creating new policy options for the Treasury to offset Fed
actions through its new monetary powers created in 1934. After 1933, the Fed's balance sheet was small
compared to the new monetary issuance powers that had been granted to the U.S. Treasury in 1934.
Any attempt to tighten monetary policy by shrinking its balance sheet would have simply been undone
by a Treasury policy of monetary expansion (Calomiris and Wheelock 1998). As Edwin Kemmerer (1934)
lamented, " ... the Federal Reserve would be powerless to control the market in the face of the

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00073

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.024

15

68
operations of the Treasury Department with its new two billion dollar stabilization fund. These
operations will of necessity dominate the situation." Secretary of the Treasury Morgenthau mused
about his ability to control monetary policy through the threat of using his new powers in his diary,
where he noted that this arrangement also would allow him to escape blame for mistakes in policy
because the Fed would be incorrectly regarded as in charge of monetary policy.

The 1951 Accord ond the Great Inflation

In 1951, the famous Treasury-Fed Accord led to what is widely regarded as the re-establishment
of Fed independence. It is noteworthy that there was no statutory change associated with the Accord,
but rather an agreement between the Fed and the Truman Administration that the Fed could now
engage in monetary policy rather than simply pegging interest rates on government debt under Treasury
instruction. This new arrangement reflected an important fact: the Fed's balance sheet had grown so
much due to its monetization of government debt during World War II that the Fed's ability to contract
now was far in excess of the Treasury's monetary powers to expand, implying that the Fed would be
able to win any prospective game of chicken with the Treasury over the setting of the money supply.

After the 1951 Accord, the Fed operated somewhat independently ofthe Treasury, but not
completely so. Its "even keel" policies specifically intended to stabilize markets during Treasury debt
offerings. Additionally, the Fed sometimes acted specifically at the behest of the Treasury to support
special funding needs. Critics of the Fed that sought greater independence -like Senator Paul Douglaswithheld support for Martin's reappointment as Fed Chairman in 1956 (Meltzer 2010, pp. 132-3). These
critics pointed to the main brake on Fed independence since 1951: the willingness of Fed leadership to
act independently. That lack of willingness to act independently sometimes reflected political threats. In
the 1950s, a longtime critic of the Fed, Rep. Wright Patman (Texas) constantly offered proposals to

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00074

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.025

16

69
reform the Fed, restructure it, and audit it. One of his proposals, in January 1955, would have required
the Fed to "support the price of United States Government securities at par" (Meltzer 2010, p. 226).

Political pressures on the Fed became intense in 1967 under the combined fiscal pressures of
financing the VietNam War and the Great Society. Under heavy lobbying by the Secretary of Treasury
and prominent members of Congress, in July of 1967 the Fed Board denied requests by the Federal
Reserve Banks to hike their discount rates. As Meltzer (2010, p. 511) put it: "Coordination [with the
Treasury] now dominated independence for many at the Federal Reserve, so political concerns
dominated economics." In August, in an attempt to limit interest rate increases, Congress also proposed
legislation limiting interest rates on time deposits, and increasing reserve requirements on time
deposits. The Fed Board negotiated with members of Congress to withdraw the bill in exchange for its
commitment to use its judgment as necessary to achieve the desired result. In other words, the Fed
traded explicit limits on its independence for implicit ones. The implicit threats of government action to
curb Fed powers if the Fed hiked interest rates were an important contributor to the acceleration of
inflation during the 1960s. The Fed's commitment to keep interest rates low constituted a commitment
to monetize booming government deficits. Meltzer (2010, pp. 527-29) lists four main errors by the Fed
that contributed to the acceleration of inflation in the 1960s, and the first of these was that "the Federal
Reserve tried to coordinate policy with the administration and persisted in doing so long after it became
a serious impediment to carrying out its responsibilities. Even when Martin recognized that a tax
increase was unlikely, he resisted even mild steps toward restriction ... Coordination was the enemy of
central bank independence... " (p. 527).

As inflation accelerated in the late 1960s, an important contributor to the lack of willingness of
Fed leadership to act independently was that lack of desire to do so. This reflected political preferences
that led Chairman Arthur Burns to put loyalty to the Nixon administration above the pursuit of proper

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00075

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.026

17

70
policy objectives. As Meltzer (2009) shows, Arthur Burns, in particular, was so loyal to President Nixon
that he served the interests of Nixon's electoral ambitions, despite the consequences for rising inflation.

Central to the limits on Fed independence that came from both political threats and misplaced
loyalties was the lack of statutory clarity about the objectives of monetary policy. That lack of clarity
avoided accountability of the right kind- which would have been so useful to constrain Arthur Burns'
willingness to allow inflation to accelerate. It also encouraged political attacks. Because any Fed critic
W<JS

free to point to some shortcoming in the economy related to the long list of ill-defined Fed policy

objectives, it was very hard for the Fed to defend itself against political attack. If the Fed had been given
the single, overarching objective of ensuring price stability (like the Bank of England and the European
Central Bank have been given), or had been given a more complicated, but clear, rule to follow (e.g., a
parameterized Taylor Rule with a clearly specified long-run target rate of inflation) then the Fed would
have been able to defend itself against attacks by referring to its compliance with its statutory mission.
In the event, however, critics were free to attack the Fed along any dimension they chose, and could
point to evidence that this dimension was part of the Fed's ill-defined mandate. Once freed from the
constraint of adherence to the gold standard, and the nominal anchoring that this entailed, it was
almost inevitable that an era of high fiscal deficits would produce monetary accommodation and high
inflation. The absence of a clear mandate, made it virtually impossible to even define Fed independence
(which is properly defined as latitude to act to achieve a specified goal), or to distinguish it from Fed
diktat, or to objectively evaluate Fed performance in order to defend the Fed's record. In short, the
absence of a clear mandate made legitimate independence very difficult to achieve.

Volcker, Greenspan, and the Great Moderation

But not impossible, as Paul Volcker would soon demonstrate. There is no doubt that Paul
Volcker brought a different brand of leadership- and a clear commitment to independence- to the Fed

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00076

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.027

18

71
when he assumed its leadership. But this change did not occur in a vacuum. High inflation had a silver
lining: it was very unpopular. When Paul Volcker agreed to take on the job of Fed Chairman, he made it
clear to Jimmy Carter before he was appointed that he would aggressively fight inflation, and that the
consequences would not always be pleasant. President Carter supported his nomination in spite of (or
perhaps because of} that commitment.

Volcker's commitment to beat back inflation, and his new brand of leadership, instilled a new
cu!'ture of independence at the Fed, one that celebrated courage and a new commitment to the
medium- and long-term objective of price stability, and which sought to enhance and preserve
monetary policy independence against momentary political influences. There was no better proof of the
Fed's new independence than the economic decline of 1979-1982. The Fed did not deny its role in
producing tough economic times; instead, it argued for the necessity of maintaining its commitment
despite those costs.

Volcker's relationship with Fed staff, however, could be a bit rocky. He was not impressed by
formal modeling or by opinions based on the latest macroeconomic fads- whether from "saltwater" or
"freshwater" macroeconomists. And although he branded his policy approach "pragmatic monetarism"
neither did he subscribe to the views of the academic monetarist camp. As it turned out, Volcker's lack
of interest in the modeling vanities of economists served him well. As Allan Meltzer (2012) put it:

From the mid-1970s to the early 1980s, the Federal Reserve inflation forecast was below actual
inflation for 16 consecutive quarters. The staff used the Phillips Curve to forecast inflation.
There is considerable research showing that Phillips Curve forecasts are unreliable ... When Paul
Volcker became chairman of the Board of Governors, he told staff that their inflation forecasts
were inaccurate. He repeated the message publicly and in Congressional testimony .... Paul
Volcker not only rejected use of the Phillips Curve, he developed and promoted what I call the
anti-Phillips Curve. Unlike the staff approach relying on quarterly data, Volcker emphasized
longer term responses. His approach, based on empirical observations, was that during the
1970s, inflation and real growth or the unemployment rate rose and fell together. There was no
tradeoff in the longer period. In a television program as early as 1979, shortly after announcing
his new policy procedure of targeting reserve growth and allowing interest rates to be set in the
market, he was asked what he would do when unemployment rose and how policy reduced

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00077

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.028

19

72
inflation. His reply cited the co-movement for the 1970s when employment rates and inflation
rose together. He predicted that they would fall together under his policy. They did. His
prediction was correct.

Alan Greenspan was able to build on Volcker's achievements, both because of his own
commitment to similar principles, and because the strong growth and low inflation enjoyed during the
Great Moderation of 1986-2003 seemed to vindicate the short-term sacrifices made during the Volcker
years. Greenspan, like Volcker, did not passively accept the views of his staff. "As chairman, Alan
Greenspan told the staff that he did not find their inflation forecasts useful. like Volcker, he explicitly
rejected the Phillips Curve" (Meltzer 2012). Greenspan's success in out-forecasting the models became
legendary. He became the "maestro." The Fed's credibility, and its chairman's, was never greater. This
mattered for enhancing Fed independence. Although political pot shots from Congress continued, the
record of success insulated the Fed from any serious attacks on its monetary policy independence.

Off the Rails, Again

Unfortunately, from 2002 to 2005, the Fed decided to make use of its high degree of
independence to pursue an unusually expansionary monetary policy. In doing so, it departed from its
pri,or adherence to something approximating a Taylor Rule with a roughly 1-2% long-run inflation target.
Over the course of these four years, the fed funds rates was maintained at levels that averaged more
than 2 percentage points below the "warranted" fed funds rate that was consistent with adherence to
the Taylor Rule. This was also the only four-year period in postwar history (other than the late 1970s)
that saw a persistently negative real fed funds rate. This pattern, unfortunately, demonstrated that
independence- when not guided by clear, rules-based mandates- may have costs as well as benefits.

As in the high-independence period of 1929-1933, and the somewhat independent era of 19511979, fed policy in 2002-2005 reflected beliefs about monetary policy that were soon discredited. In the

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00078

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.029

20

73
two earlier periods, adherence to the real bills doctrine (in the form of the Riefler-Burgess doctrine), and
a lack of understanding of the relationship between nominal interest rates and inflation, were central to
the errors of the Fed in the two earlier periods (Brunner and Meltzer 1964, 1968, Wheelock 1991,
Meltzer 2003, 2010). In the case of the 1960s and 1970s, another contributor to accelerating inflation
was the belief in a simple Keynesian Phillips Curve (Meltzer 2009, 2010). In the 2000s, it is harder to
identify precisely the ideological source of the Fed's decision to depart so dramatically from the Taylor
Rule. That decision seems to have reflected concerns about oil prices and other very short-term
concerns that were seen as downside risks for the economy. Governor Frederic Mishkin, in particular,
was vocal in defending the departure from the Taylor Rule to protect against short-term downside risk.

Many critics, including Taylor {2010, 2011, 2012, 2013). have attributed much oft he problem in
the recent financial crisis to the impact of loose monetary policy on financial and economic overheating
in the years leading up to the subprime bust. That view may somewhat exaggerate the role of monetary
policy in the recent crisis because it places too little weight on micro-economic distortions produced by
government policies that drove the decline in mortgage underwriting standards during the 1990s and
2000s (Pinto 2011, Wallison 2011, Calomiris and Haber 2013), but there is no doubt that loose monetary
policy contributed substantially to the narrowing of credit risk spreads and to increases in the prices of
real estate and common stock. The literature documenting the recent effects of expansionary monetary
policy on risk spreads and risky asset pricing is now quite large, and includes Deii'Ariccia, lgan and
Laeven (2008), Jimenez, Ongena, Peydro-Aicalde and Saurina {2007), Mendoza and Terrones (2008), and
Bekaert, Hoerova and Lo Duca (2010).

What If Monetary Policy Had Been Given a Clear Mandate?

The important role of Fed discretion in contributing to the three major monetary policy errors of
the past century illustrates another important benefit of establishing a clear mandate to guide Fed

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00079

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.030

21

74
policy. In the presence of a clear mandate, Fed officials would have had to explicitly defend their
purposeful departures from an explicit, publicly disclosed rule (e.g., the Taylor Rule), rather than simply
make vague pronouncements about changes in beliefs, discussed in the absence of any explicit
commitment to a rule. The burden of proof would have been on the use of discretion, and this would
increase the adverse personal consequences of employing discretion counterproductively. In the
presence of a rule, and the greater accountability that it would bring, not only would legitimate
independent monetary policy be more achievable, independence would produce better outcomes by
giving less latitude to faddish ideas or personal proclivities, which history has shown have a very poor
track record in monetary policy.

Monetary Policy Independence at Risk?

Once one recognizes the key role of economic and political events in shaping the extent of de
facto Fed independence, the prospects for preserving the current degree of monetary policy
independence under the status quo are very bleak. It is not clear how much the Fed's recent actions
(particularly QE2, Operation Twist 2, QE3, and the unprecedented use of very specific forward guidance)
reflect politicization of the Fed leadership. Did the Fed pursue these measures under political pressure,
or perhaps to limit political pressure by appearing to do something in the face of high and persisting
rates of unemployment? It is hard to say, but these actions clearly have created objective grounds for
worrying about the ability of the Fed to maintain its monetary policy independence in the future.

The key risk that monetary policy poses to the economy now is the possibility that the Fed will
be too slow to contract the supply of money and credit once the economy returns to normal. A normal
economy will see the money multiplier grow substantially. Unless the Fed contracts its balance sheet or
increases required reserves substantially to keep the money multiplier from rising, the return to normal
will imply substantial price inflation. Why might the Fed fail to respond by contracting its balance sheet

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00080

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.031

22

75
or raising reserve requirements? Because of the de facto political limits to its independence. What
would produce political threats to contractionary monetary policy? There are five readily identifiable
potential sources of trouble.

The first is the long-run risk of what has become known as "fiscal dominance" -pressures from
deficit finance that effectively could constrain monetary policy's ability to tighten. In short, if the U.S.
government issues more government debt than it can credibly commit to repay (which I will label an
"unsustainably" large amount of debt), one of two things must occur: monetization of the debt or
default. While it is true, in principle, that the Fed could refuse to monetize the unsustainable debt of the
government and force it to default, in practice that would not happen. Congress and the Administration
can always amend the Federal Reserve Act, as needed, to ensure that the Fed purchase sufficient
government debt to avoid a default, and of course, they would have every incentive to do so if a
recalcitrant Fed leadership failed to "voluntarily" monetize the government's unsustainable debt. The
current path of government entitlement spending places the U.S. on a clearly unsustainable path.
Absent significant entitlement reform, the U.S. government debt-to-GDP ratio will rise to clearly
unsustainable levels within the next twenty years.

The second threat related to fiscal dominance is much more imminent. Whether or not the U.S.
government eventually reduces its entitlement spending commitments, a decision to tighten monetary
policy and drive up interest rates could imply significant increases in the government's deficit. As the
economy recovers and long-term interest rates begin to rise (through a combination of expectations of
higher real rates of interest, or of possible monetization of government debt) the interest costs of
government debt held by the public will rise. A moderate rise of, say, two percentage points in interest
rates could mean an increase in funding costs of roughly $100 billion. Furthermore, holding constant the
interest rates on government debt, any shrinkage of the Fed's holdings of government debt as a means

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00081

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.032

23

76
of monetary tightening would increase the federal deficit by shifting government debt from the
"interest-free" category to the "interest-paying" category.' The large existing level of federal deficits,
the prospects of sharp increases in interest rates from their historic lows, and the vast Fed holdings of
government debt all imply significant risk that the Fed will feel severe pressure from some members of
Congress and possibly from the Treasury to delay tightening in the interest of limiting the rise in deficits.
Thus the inflationary monetization of government debt could occur long before the explosion of
entitlement expenditures.

Third, a contraction of the Fed's balance sheet would require it to disgorge itself not only of
government debt but also of mortgage-backed securities (MBS) which it has been buying in vast quantity
for the past few years. Any attempt to reverse the flow and dump these into the private market will
drive up MBS spreads, and hence mortgage rate spreads. The housing lobby (which is as strong as it is
bipartisan) will waste no time appealing to its supporters in Congress and the Administration to pressure
the Fed to slow any sales of MBS.

Fourth, in a rising interest rate environment, Fed sales of government bonds and MBS will cause
it to incur large capital losses. The Fed does not mark its portfolio to market, but rather, recognizes
losses as it sells assets. As interest rates rise, the prices of those assets will decline, and the implied
losses could be quite large. A large amount of sales could render the Fed insolvent. Although, as a
matter of economics, Fed insolvency on a book value basis is irrelevant to its ability to pursue monetary
policy, a Fed insolvency would provide a golden political opportunity for Fed critics. Anticipating those
political attacks, the Fed might prefer not to raise interest rates on excess reserves very aggressively.

A fifth problem that could discourage monetary tightening relates to another policy option- the
use of interest payments on reserves- which in principle offers a means of tightening without shrinking
7

Government debt owned by the Fed earns interest, but those interest payments are returned to the Treasury, net
of 1=ed operating expenses.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00082

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.033

24

77
the Fed's balance sheet. As the economy recovers, banks will want to expand their lending at prevailing
interest rates. By paying high rates of interest on excess reserves, it is argued, the Fed can entice banks
to maintain those reserves rather than lend them. This will keep the money multiplier from increasing,
and thereby constrain the growth of money, credit, and prices without having to shrink the Fed's
balance sheet. There are, however, two rather severe political problems that could arise in reaction to
this policy. Given how much bankers are despised by a large segment of the public, and given that
interest payments on reserves might have to be very high to convince banks to hold vast quantities of
excess reserves, large interest payments payments to "fat cat banksters" is not likely to go over well in
Congress or the Administration. Furthermore, similar to the effect of realized capital losses from selling
assets, high interest payments on excess reserves would render the Fed insolvent on a book value basis.

There is a possible way out of these problems, namely a significant increase in the reserve
requirement" By requiring banks to hold reserves, the Fed would not have to pay a very high interest
rate on them. Currently, the Fed pays zero interest on required reserves. This is inappropriate because
setting requirements for the holding of zero-interest reserves is tax policy, which should be outside the
purview of the central bank. A statutory change that would require the Fed to pay the short-term fed
funds rate on required reserves (which would avoid imposing a large tax on an already weakened
banking system) not only would be desirable as a long-run policy change as a matter of limiting the Fed's
powers, it would probably allow the Fed to prevent an acceleration in inflation without shrinking its
ba!ance sheet, paying high interest rates to "banksters" or imposing a huge new tax burden on banks.
Not only would this policy make sense economically, it would also be less likely than the other
approaches to inflation prevention to create political hazards for the Fed. Perhaps surprisingly, Fed
8

Some Fed officials have also advocated the use of reverse repos on a massive scale as a way to contract the
effective balance sheet of the Fed without actually selling assets, at least for a period of time. Repos are a way to
repeatedly lend securities without actually selling them, but in doing so, to reduce the effective size of the Fed's
balance sheet. Given the scale of the transactions that would be required, and given the skepticism with which the
reverse repo idea has been greeted by some market participants, it is highly uncertain whether this tool will be
able to provide a means of preventing a surge in inflation.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00083

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.034

25

78
ofticials thus far have shown no interest in this policy option' Of course, even an increase in reserve
requirements will imply some rising pressure on the fiscal deficit; payments on required reserves will
reduce the amount of revenue the Fed can return to the U.S. Treasury. 10

In summary, a combination of the current size of the Fed's balance sheet, its composition, the
fiscal problems of the U.S. government, and the potential for sharp increases in interest rates over the
next few years create significant risk of inflation. That risk of inflation, in large part, reflects the
implications of these economic factors for the political challenges that the Fed will face if it chooses to
tighten monetary policy to try to forestall an increase in inflation. As in the past, it is unlikely that the
Fed's statutory powers will change. And, as in the past, the implicit or explicit threats to change the
Fed's powers will likely be enough to undermine the Fed's commitment to independent action.

What specific form might these political threats take? The most obvious threat was illustrated
by the comments of Former Congressman Barney Frank, who suggested altering the governance of the
regional Feds to make their Presidents political appointees. One could also imagine changes that would
dilute the voting role of the regional Presidents. It is widely believed that the Presidents tend to be the
source of greatest independent actions within the Fed, precisely because they are appointed locally,
through a process that gives weight to local business interests rather than the national political interests
that determine the appointment of Governors. Clearly, politicians also understand this argument. One
could argue that the mere suggestion of the possibility of such a change damages Fed independence by
making Fed Presidents more circumspect in voicing their opposition to positions supported by Fed
Governors. As the Grand Inquisitor (and presumably Barney Frank) was aware, sometimes you only need
to "show them the instruments."

9

For a proposal along these lines, see Calomiris (2012).
One issue to be considered is which deposits or debts reserves requirements would be held against. My view is
that the base should be broad- total assets less common equity. This would prevent regulatory arbitrage through
the redefinition of deposits as repos.

10

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00084

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.035

26

79
IV. Independence and the Fed's Regulatory Policy Powers

The authority of the Fed in performing its monetary function is well understood and often
commented upon (e.g., the timing, membership, voting rules, and press releases related to FOMC
meetings). The Fed's role in banking regulation, or more broadly in financial regulation, receives less
attention, is not as well understood, and has been much more subject to change over time.

The Fed plays an important role as a regulatory policy advocate in Washington, as a writer of
regulations, and as a supervisor. It also represents the United States at the Basel Committee, which sets
international prudential regulatory standards for banks. These regulatory functions are performed by
the Fed alongside many other (sometimes "competing") financial regulators -the Office of the
Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), the Securities
Exchange Commission (SEC), the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC), and the state banking
and insurance authorities, as well as the courts. This is an activity that increasingly occupies a great deal
of time and energy at the Fed- especially since the 1980s

as the structure and rules of the financial

regulation game have changed dramatically and much more frequently in the U.S. over the past three
decades than the structure and rules for monetary policy. The Fed has taken on a newly dominant role
as a regulator- one that has important implications for the future of Fed independence.

M()dest Beginnings

From the beginning, the Federal Reserve Banks played a regulatory role, but that role began
very modestly, became significant after the Great Depression, and expanded dramatically in the last two
decades of the 20'h century and beyond. For Fed member banks that are state-chartered (rather than
nationally chartered) the Fed has always been the primary federal supervisory and regulatory authority,

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00085

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.036

27

80
and it shares regulatory and supervisory authority over state-chartered banks with the relevant states'
chartering authorities. The Federal Reserve Board was given significant nationwide regulatory authority
for the first time in the Banking Act of 1933, and its authority was then expanded as the regulator of
bank holding companies under the Bank Holding Company Act of 1956.

The initial limits on the Fed's role as a regulator reflected the unit banking structure of the U.S.
banking system, in which both nationally chartered and state-chartered banks were restricted to
operate in only one state, and typically were required to maintain only one banking office. Given the
absence of a national system of banks there was little obvious need for a national regulator or
supervisor of banks. Indeed, the Fed itself was a highly decentralized system, with control residing
mainly in the twelve Reserve Banks, at least until the 1933 and 1935 Acts. Furthermore, the Fed was not
itself a chartering authority, and Fed membership was voluntary (indeed, for much of the 201h century,
most U.S. banks were not Fed member banks). Finally, the Federal Reserve Banks were owned and
controlled by their members. Under these circumstances, not surprisingly, the Federal Reserve System
was given little regulatory authority and showed little ambition to impose regulatory constraints on its
members. Indeed, the creation of the Fed itself was only possible as the result of some rather significant
deregulation. Prior to 1913, national banks were prohibited from lending against real estate. 11 In order
to secure political support for the Federal Reserve Act, especially in agriculture-dominated areas, the Act
specifically permitted member banks (including national banks) to lend against rea! estate.

The Great Depression

This changed as a result of the Great Depression. The political fallout for banks from the Great
Depression was extreme. It was also extremely misguided. Economic historians now agree that the
11

National banks evaded this regulation by lending without collateral and then accepting real estate collateral
after the fact as part of an ongoing negotiation with the borrower. Nonetheless, this restriction did lead to
significantly less lending against real estate by national banks than by state-chartered banks {for a more complete
discussion, see Calomiris and Carlson 2013).

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00086

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.037

28

81
primary causes of financial and economic distress during the Depression were traceable to a
combination of misguided monetary policy targeting rules based on "real bills doctrine" thinking and the
fragile unit banking structure of the U.S. banking system. Unfortunately, however, the regulatory policy
changes relating to banks were based on a very different view, namely that bank consolidation and
banks' involvement in securities markets (both of which had been pronounced during the 1920s) had
caused the collapse of the banking system. Although this view is demonstrably false it nonetheless
formed the basis for the ill-conceived banking reforms of the 1930s (Calomiris 2010). Ironically, those
reforms were consciously designed by Messrs. Glass and Steagall (who were, respectively, the principal
defenders of the real bills doctrine and unit banking in Congress) to strengthen the regulatory
commitment to the real bills doctrine and unit banking.

The principal banking reforms included the separation of commercial and investment banking,
interest rate limits on deposits, the creation of Federal Deposit Insurance, and a variety of measures
designed to limit the expansion of banking "groups." Glass was the champion of the first two sets of
measures, and Steagall was the champion of the second two. These measures were not universally
welcomed by informed policy makers, but opponents were unable to counter the strong public support
for these measures, which reflected, in part, the highly publicized Pecora Hearings, which attacked Wall
Street bankers. In particular, although the President Roosevelt, the Fed, the Treasury Secretary, and
Senator Glass all opposed deposit insurance as a destabilizing measure, Representative Steagall was able
to push it through on a tide of public support 12 Glass focused his attention on measures designed to
insulate the banking system from securities markets by prohibiting connections between banks and
securities related affiliates, limiting lending against securities, and limiting bank lending to affiliates.

"The opposition to deposit insurance reflected the disastrous experience with eight states' deposit insurance
experiments, all of which collapsed in the 1920s. For more discussion of the views on deposit insurance and the
politics and economics that underlay them, see Golembe (1960), Calomiris (1989, 1990, 1992), Flood (1991),
Patrick (1993), Calomiris and White (1994), Calomiris (2010), and Calomiris and Haber (2013).

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00087

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.038

29

82
Interest rate limits were primarily advocated as a means of undermining the interbank deposit market,
which had the effect of concentrating funds in New York City banks, which were often used for securities
lending. Deposit insurance and limits on banking groups, advocated by Steagall and other unit banking
supporters, were designed to protect unit banks from competition 13 Deposit interest rate ceilings were
also motivated as a limit to competition.

The architects of the 1933 reforms needed someone to enforce these new arrangements and
there was no practical alternative to the Federal Reserve Board. Who else had sufficient informational
access, through the Fed member banks, to monitor the nationwide and international network of
banking relationships. Such monitoring was essential for the enforcement of the separation of
commercial and investment banking and the new limits on group control of banks, as well as
enforcement of Clayton Act limits on interlocking directorships (which would take effect in 1934, and
become part of what would become known as Regulation l). The Board played a central role in defining
what constituted an affiliate for purpose of the various statutory limits, as well as for examining banks
and affiliates to determine whether they were in violation of the various new rules on securities
activities, group control, or interlocking directorates. It was also charged with setting margin
requirements on securities loans.

It is noteworthy that this new delegation of regulatory responsibilities to the Fed occurred in the
context of a highly volatile political environment with respect to controversies over the reform of
monetary policy. The 1932 Act had already required the Fed to make use of government securities as
collateral for its discounting. Soon the 1934 Gold and Silver Acts would effectively substitute Treasury
control of monetary policy for Fed control, and the 1935 Act would centralize Fed power and give
13

Limits on branching prevented consolidation via that channel, but "group" banking (control of multiple banks by
a common company) or "chain" banking (control of multiple banks by a common group of shareholders) could

circumvent such limits to some extent

by allowing a group of investors or a bank to purchase stock in

multiple

banking organizations. The 1933 Act and the Clayton Act made this more difficult by limiting the voting rights and
corporate governance structures of groups.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00088

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.039

30

83
greater weight to the politically appointed Board of Governors. The Fed did not support all aspects of
the reforms that were remaking its world (for example, the Fed Board opposed the creation of deposit
insurance, and the use of government securities as collateral for discounting was anathema to real bills
thinking), but the Fed was not in a position to push back the political tide that was fundamentally
reshaping the monetary and regulatory rules. All it could do was accept those new rules, roll with the
punches, and try to maintain and competently execute whatever authority was left to it.

The Fed's stock was not very high in Washington in the mid 1930s, which may also explain why
the Fed was not the institution charged with overseeing the government's main policy changes toward
banks. The creation of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) and the creation of the
Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC) meant that two new powerful banking regulators would now
operate as parallel organizations to the Fed with their own distinct authorities. Furthermore, it was
these two institutions that were given primary responsibility for examining banks in 1933-1934 to
determine which would reopen, which would reopen with RFC assistance, and which would be shut
permanently. The Fed's regulatory role was primarily as a "preventative" regulator charged with
preventing the mixing of commercial and investment banking, excessive lending against securities, and
any backdoor consolidation of the banking system via banking groups.

Five Post-Depression Decades af Narrow, Fragmented Banking

The Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 (further extended in 1970 to apply to single-bank
holding companies) created further limits regarding the entities that could control banks, and expanded
the authority of the Federal Reserve Board in its oversight of the parties in control of banks. Any entity
assuming control of a bank had to receive the approval of the Fed Board. The Holding Company Act also
gave the Board authority to prevent changes in control that would lead to the control of banks by

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00089

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.040

31

84
entities that were involved in non-banking activities (the so-called separation of banking and
commerce). 14

In 1960 and 1966, in reaction to an increase in bank merger activity during the 1950s, and under
the continuing pressure of unit bank lobbying (especially, the Independent Bankers Association),
Congress enacted legislation (the Bank Merger Act) intended to limit mergers among banks. Bank
regulators, including the Federal Reserve Board, now had to consider the competitive consequences of
mergers before approving them. Although promoted as a measure to ensure competition, in fact these
measures are better understood as measures designed to preserve the market power of inefficient unit
banks by limiting the ability of successful banks to grow. 15

As this brief review makes clear, from 1933 to 1980, the dominant trend in banking regulation,
and the role of the Fed and other bank regulators during that period, revolved around the restrictions
on bank consolidation and the range of banking activities. Consistent with this trend, virtually no
relaxation of branching restrictions occurred, either at the state or federal level, during this period.

Deregulation of Branching and Underwriting Activities after 1980

After 1980, there was a dramatic reversal in banking regulation with respect to consolidation
and bank powers (see Figure 1, taken from Calomiris and Haber 2013, Chapter 6). The relaxation of
branching barriers took the form of state-level policies (often as part of regional interstate agreements),
as well as federal legislation. This coincided with an unprecedented merger wave in banking, and a
dramatic expansion of banks' powers, culminating in the Gramm-leach-Biiley Act of 1999.

14

For a review of these Acts, see Carnell, Macey and Miller (2009). The approval of individuals to take controlling
interests in a bank- based on the considerations of character, the nature of his/her business dealings, and
competitiveness concerns- was required under the Change in Bank Control Act of 1978.
15
For a review of the legislative history, political economy, and enforcement of these statutes, see Klebaner
(1967), Traber (1969), Shull and Horvitz (1971), and Carey (1975). for a summary of their content, see Carnell,
Macey and Miller (2009).

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00090

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.041

32

85
What caused this dramatic reversal? As Calomiris and Haber (2013) discuss, five forces worked
to undo the sway of the unit banker-agrarian populist coalition. The first was demographic: during the
20'h century, the United States was transformed from a predominantly rural to a predominantly urban
country, which meant that voting power shifted away from rural interests- which had generally been
supportive of unit banking- toward America's cities. As of 1900, 45.8 million Americans lived in rural
areas, compared to 30.2 million in cities and towns with more than 2,500 inhabitants. By 1940 the
number living in cities or towns had grown to 74.4 million, compared to 57.2 million rural inhabitants.
After World War II, the urban population share took off; by 1970, 133.4 million Americans lived in
locations with more than 2,500 inhabitants, compared to 69.8 million living in rural areas. 16

The second force was technological progress that eroded the ability of banks to extract rents
from borrowers and depositors. With respect to borrowers, beginning in the 1970s, the computer
revolution drove down the cost of information storage and retrieval, allowing prospective lenders
anywhere in the country to assess a borrower's credit-worthiness reasonably well without having to rely
as much on "soft information" that could only be obtained locally. With respect to depositors,
technology also spurred much greater competition, especially via networked automated teller machines
(ATMs that are linked via computer). The networked ATM was patented in 1974, and it was only two
years before unit bankers started filing cases in both federal and state courts seeking to block their
proliferation. One of those cases, Independent Bankers Association of New York State v. Marine Midland
Bank, ultimately wound its way to the Supreme Court, which in 1985 ruled that an ATM was not a bank
branch, thereby eviscerating state laws that set limits on banks with branch networks."

The third influence was accelerating price inflation in the 1960s and 1970s, which spurred
disintermediation from the regulated banking system, and created the first of the post-1960 "shadow

16
17

These figures are from Calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 6.
Calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 6.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00091

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.042

33

86
banking systems" of relatively unregulated finance companies and money market mutual funds.
Regulation Q limited the interest rate that could be paid on bank deposits. As inflation and nominal
market rates of interest rose, the real interest rate payable on regulated deposits became increasingly
negative, making it hard for banks to attract deposits. Instead, institutional depositors increasingly
began to put their money into commercial paper. Households soon followed institutional depositors as
"money market mutual funds" began to allow customers to write checks against their portfolios of
treasury bills and commercial paper.

As technological change and inflation spurred the growth of alternatives to regulated banking,
and produced declines in the domestic "core" deposit and loan market shares of regulated banks, a
fourth worrying factor reared its head. U.S. banks- which were relatively small and constrained in their
geographic reach and permissible product lines, compared with the banks of other developed countries
-were losing global market share. large foreign banks were even making inroads into U.S. markets by
building relationships with large U.S. corporations. The Fed and many U.S. politicians became advocates
of the deregulation of interest rate ceilings, the removal of branching restrictions, and the elimination of
limits on bank powers (especially the limits on corporate securities underwriting by banks), all as a
means of allowing U.S. banks to compete with their foreign counterparts. For example, consider Alan
Greenspan (1988):

The ability of banks to continue to hold their positions by operating on the margins of customer
services is limited. Existing constraints, in conjunction with the continued undermining of the
bank franchise by the new technology, are likely to limit the future profitability of banking ... If
the aforementioned trends continue, banking will contract either relatively or absolutely.
Greenspan (1990) went on to argue:
In an environment of global competition, rapid financial innovation, and technological change,
bankers understandably feel that the old portfolio and affiliate rules and the constraints on
permissible activities of affiliates are no longer meaningful and likely to result in shrinking the
banking system.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00092

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.043

34

87
The fifth force driving reform of banking regulation was a wave of banking distress in the 1980s,
which set into motion a political movement in favor of bank consolidation. The 1980s saw an unusual
confluence of shocks affecting banks. The spike in interest rates in the early 1980s caused banks and
thrifts (savings and loan associations, or S&Ls) with large exposures to real estate loans (which paid fixed
interest rates) to suffer major losses 18 Agricultural price collapses in the early 1980s caused many small,
rural banks to fail. 19 Oil and gas price collapses in the early 1980s wiped out many banks in Texas and
Oklahoma 20 The revocation of the tax laws governing accelerated depreciation for commercial real
estate transactions caused major declines in the commercial real estate market in the northeast,
negatively affecting the banks that lent in this market. Evidence that banks had contributed to the size
of their losses through aggressive risk taking and abuse of the protection afforded by deposit insurance
and access to the Fed's discount window, sometimes after they were already deeply insolvent, further
galvanized opposition to preserving the status quo."

The extreme banking distress of the 1980s even encouraged many unit bankers, as well as bank
borrowers, and government officials, to favor the relaxation of branching restrictions. A unit banker
facing the failure of his bank saw acquisition by a branching bank as a way to exit with some stock
wealth and perhaps even a job in the new bank, a desirable alternative to losing everything. The
borrowers at failing unit banks saw the branching banks that were willing to buy weak banks as a crucial
source offunding. For the FDIC and federal government officials, the big banks willing to acquire small
failing banks reduced the costs of paying off failed banks depositors. For state governments, the new
bank entrants were a welcome means of restoring local economic growth.

18

See, for example, Barth, Bartholomew and Labich (1989) and Wheelock (2006).
See Calomiris, Hubbard, and Stock (1986).
20
See Horvitz (1991).
21
See Barth, Bartholomew and Labich (1989), Brewer and Mondschean (1991), White (1991), Brewer (1995),
Gilbert (1994), and Schwartz (1992).

19

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00093

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.044

35

88
As Calomiris and Haber (2013) show, just as had occurred in 1907 and in the Great Depression, a
financial crisis exposed the inherent instability of financial institutions that could not diversify risk by
pooling the risks of different regions, and that could not respond to difficulties by shifting resources
across branches of an interconnected network. But this time regulators and politicians saw an advantage
in permitting large banks to acquire failing banks in exchange for limiting the cost ofthose failed banks
to the FDIC. From 1979 to 1990, 15 states relaxed their branching restrictions 21 Many states also
permitted their banks to be acquired by large, out-of-state banks, many of which hailed from states like
North Carolina, Ohio, and California, which had long permitted within-state branching.

A major blow to the state laws that prohibited interstate branching came in 1982, when
Congress, in response to the Savings and Loan crisis, amended the Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 to
allow failed banks to be acquired by any bank holding company, regardless of state laws. This induced
many states to enter into regional or national reciprocal arrangements whereby their banks could be
merged (not just purchased by a holding company) with banks from another state. Between 1984 and
1988, 38 states joined one of these reciprocal arrangements. 23 Banks operating national branching
networks accounted for only ten percent of the U.S. banking system in the early 1980s. By the mid1990s, they accounted for more than 70 percent. 24 The final blow to the unit banks came in 1994, when
Congress codified the process that had been taking place at the state level by passing the Riegle-Neal
Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act. Banks could now branch both within states and across
state lines.
The consolidation of banking was also accompanied by an expansion of the permissible activities
of bank holding companies into securities underwriting and insurance. The expansion into underwriting
occurred in several discrete stages over the period 1987-1999, beginning with the Fed's discretionary

22

23

24

Calomiris (2000).
Kroszner and Strahan (1999).
Calomiris (2010).

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00094

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.045

36

89
decision in 1987 to allow small inroads by bank holding companies into investment banking. The initial
opening resulted from a Supreme Court change in the 1980s, which suggested that the Court would
adopt a more limited interpretation of the Glass-Steagall restrictions on mixing investment banking and
commercial banking, thus opening the door to some investment banking by commercial banks.
limitations were relaxed slowly, however, and many so-called "firewalls" were established initially to
isolate investment banking affiliates' underwriting activities from the activities of the core banking
enterprise. The first investment banking (Section 20) affiliates were established in 1987. There was a
further relaxation of the extent of activity by these affiliates in 1989. In 1997, the Fed eliminated
firewalls that it had established to keep the operations of Section 20 affiliates separate from the other
operations of the bank (Phillips 1997). Ultimately, in 1999, Gramm-Leach-Biiley eliminated any
restrictions on the amount of investment banking activities in commercial banks. Over time, the Fed and
other advocates of change were able to build the case that the fears of some policy makers about
conflicts of interest arising from the combination of investment and commercial banking were illfounded, and that the presumed benefits from the combination were real.

Gradual changes created a favorable track record, which laid the groundwork for the
Administration's and Congress's willingness to eliminate virtually all financial activity restrictions on the
newly created "financial holding companies" entirely in 1999 (a policy change the Fed actively
advocated in the 1990s).

Political support for the relaxation of activity limits, as in the case of consolidation, reflected the
declining global position of U.S. banks. By the mid-1980s, U.S. banks had declined in international
importance and profitability. Large U.S. banks had made significant profits in the growing areas of credit
card lending and private equity investing, and without those profits the losses from nonperforming
loans, sovereign defaults, and increasing competition and deposit disintermediation would have placed

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00095

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.046

37

90
most large banks into extreme difficulties (ironically, equity investing by a handful of the largest banks
was underway on a large scale long before debt or equity underwriting was permitted).

Evidence from numerous academic studies that it makes sense to combine commercial banking
and securities underwriting within the same financial intermediary supported the elimination of the
regulatory barrier between the two. There is now a huge literature showing, in theory and in practice,
that it can be beneficial for bank customers to permit banks to engage in underwriting of corporate debt
and equity (see the summary in Calomiris and Pornrojnangkool2009). In essence, savings of information
production costs lie at the heart of this policy. The historical prohibition on combining commercial
banking and investment banking had been based on faulty premises and a lack of evidence, and this
became increasingly apparent during the 1990s.

The growth in the market shares of commercial banks in investment banking in the 1990s and
2000s was dramatic. As of 1992, only 10 percent of corporate debt and less than one percent of
corporate equity flotations were underwritten either solely or jointly by commercial banks. By 2002, 66
percent of corporate debt and 36 percent of corporate equity flotations were underwritten either solely
or jointly by commercial banks (Calomiris and Pornrojnangkool 2009).

The Role of the Fed
It was during the period of consolidation and the expansion of bank powers that the Fed
became the dominant supervisor and regulator of banks, and later of the entire financial system. This
expansion of Fed power reflected various influences- including the perception of the Fed as both an
institution full of highly competent, knowledgeable, and reputable people. But there was more to the
story than that. The Fed was also a savvy political intermediary.

On the surface, the deregulation of banking was a technical issue, decided on its merits as a
matter of economics, and the Fed played an important role as an honest broker of information, helping

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00096

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.047

38

91
to inform policy makers, and thereby helping them to achieve a rationalization of the structure of the
banking system. But there was more to the political decisions shaping deregulation than "efficiency"
concerns, and there was more to the Fed's role than its provision of information to policy makers. The
Fed also was a political player in the deeper drama that permitted and shaped deregulation- what
Calomiris and Haber (2013) call the Game of Bank Bargains. Deregulation was a political deal. The Fed
was both an intermediary that helped to enforce the political bargains shaping the banking system, and
itself a party to those bargains. Most importantly, the expansion of Fed power reflected the Fed's
willingness to ally itself with the dominant coalition that controlled how consolidation of the banking
system would occur.

In this regard, it is instructive to note that the Fed initially did not welcome the consolidation of
banking. It did so only after consolidation was well underway and regarded as politically safe to support.
Hawke (1988) summarizes the Volcker Fed's attitude toward relaxation of branching laws:

The Federal Reserve under Volcker was largely a bystander in this profound change in the
structure of American banking. While Volcker consistently supported very limited intrusions into
state authority to facilitate the interstate takeover of large failing and failed banks, his Board did
nothing whatsoever to encourage broader interstate banking. On the contrary, in its grudging
and suspicious treatment of the desires of banking organizations to acquire thrifts; in its
response to such developments as "stake-out" investments nonvoting equity investments in
banks by bank holding companies not yet permitted to make full-scale acquisitions in the target
bank's state; and in its pinched and niggling approvals of requests by bank holding companies to
use nonbank banks as a means of interstate expansion, the Board seemed to view itself as the
little Dutch boy of interstate banking, with a duty to plug each supposed leak in the dike as it
appeared. Its perverse attitude was exemplified by its treatment of the credit-card bank "usury
haven" cases.

Why the change in Fed advocacy on branching? Given the tectonic economic shifts that favored
consolidation, the political landscape in Congress regarding branching changed completely in the late
1980s. Consequently, the Fed's advocacy reflected, and lagged behind, a broader political movement

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00097

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.048

39

92
throughout the country. The Fed advocated consolidation only after it was clear that doing so did not
threaten to cause it little difficulty with Congress or the Administration. 25

Can one identify a "philosophy of regulation" that underlay the regulatory advocacy of the Fed
and Chairman Greenspan after 1987. Did the Greenspan Fed have a point of view on regulatory
matters? I will show that, although the Fed's advocacy on various matters may appear somewhat
contradictory, or at least, philosophically heterodox, the Fed has behaved in a manner that is
remarkably predictable, once one takes account of the political arena in which both regulatory and
monetary policy are made.

The Greenspan years did not illustrate a pure economic philosophy offinancial regulation, but
rather a politico-economic philosophy, which one might term "pragmatic and political-bargain-based
deregulation." I would not argue that Chairman Greenspan's regulatory advocacy was optimal, either
from the unconstrained standpoint of an ideal regulatory system, or from the constrained (realistic)
13

There is no doubt that Chairman Greenspan was an active proponent of branching deregulation (see Greenspan
1988, 1990, 1997a-e, 1998, 1999, 2001). On May 3, 1997, for example, in a speech before the Conference of State
Bank Supervisors, he advocated Congressional action to place state banks on an equal footing with national banks
with respect to the permissible activities of branches located outside the state in which their headquarters are
located. Advocates of eliminating branching restrictions, including myself, have long pointed to the gains from
greater competitiveness and greater diversification of risk that comes from permitting banks to branch freely. It is

noteworthy that Chairman Greenspan's May 1997 speech was directed toward enhancing the scope and powers of
state-chartered bank branches. That is, his recommendation would have increased the importance of the regional
Feds relative to the OCC as regulators of banks (as opposed to holding companies). One of the concerns that Fed
officials had about bank branching, which the Chairman recognized in his testimony before the Congress on June
171 1998, was that interstate branching was expected to "induce shifts from state to national bank charters,
reducing the Fed's supervisory role." Improving the powers of state-chartered branches would have offset some of

those expected defections. In his June 1998 testimony, Chairman Greenspan argued that the Board of Governors'
position in support of interstate branching was a piece of evidence that directly contradicted theories of Fed
advocacy that emphasized political turf battles. He pointed with some pride to the fact that the Board of
Governors supported interstate branching despite its anticipated effect of inducing shifts toward the national
banking system. But that argument is not convincing for two reasons. First, the Fed Board, as opposed to the
regional Feds, regulates bank holding companies. Interstate banking, by enhancing the size and scope of bank
holding companies, and by ushering in the era of universal banking, set the stage for the shift in regulatory power
away from both the OCC and the regional Feds and toward the Federal Reserve Board, and Chairman Greenspan
was already advocating such a shift in authority toward the Board alongside his support for interstate branching.
Second, the Fed's advocacy algorithm takes into account the interests of its strongest political allies, the big banks,
who surely stood to gain greatly from interstate banking. Thus, despite the possibility of local charter switching
toward national banks, interstate branching was a predictable big win for enhancing the power of the Federal
Reserve Board.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00098

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.049

40

93
standpoint of what is possible in the real world. My goal is not to highlight errors so much as to make
the positive claim that there is a fairly straightforward logic implicit in the Fed's regulatory advocacy, a
fairly simple algorithm of advocacy. To understand its logic, one must begin with an understanding of
the Fed as a political player in the Washington drama, as a creature of the federal government subject to
its oversight, as a competitor with other regulators for influence within the financial services industry
and within the political realm, and as a prioritizing agent that decides which battles (monetary or
regulatory) to fight when, and how hard.

To explain the reversal in Fed advocacy of deregulation in some areas, but not in others,
Calomiris (2006) categorizes financial regulatory issues into four categories, according to his
interpretation of the Fed's actions and the dominant motives for those actions: one category is labeled
"Fed advocacy of beneficial deregulation," and three other categories include cases where the Fed has
opposed beneficial regulatory policies, which he attributes to three reasons: "Too politically hot to
handle," or "Not in the interest of the big banks," or a "Fed regulatory power play" to boost its own
political influence 26 His proposed regulatory advocacy algorithm for the Fed is fairly simple: the Fed

26
The growth of commercial bank involvement in underwriting created a regulatory turf battle in the mid-1990s
between the Fed and the OCC. The OCC sought to allow national banks (for which it is the primary regulator) to
underwrite securities through bank subsidiaries (which the OCC regulated) rather than through affiliates of the
bank (subsidiaries of the bank holding company, which were regulated by the Fed). Ultimately, despite Fed

opposition, the Gramm-leach-Bii!ey Act did permit bank subsidiaries to engage in underwriting and most other

activities in which affiliates are permitted to engage. The Fed opposed this proposal on the grounds that there was
a possibility of conflict and a risk of bank instability arising from underwriting occurring within bank subsidiaries.

Chairman Greenspan testified in Congress on April 28, 1999 that allowing investment banking to occur in bank
subsidiaries "would be especially risky." This argument is hard to fathom (indeed, if anything, the opposite should
be true, since some problems of asset substitution risk cannot occur between banks and their subsidiaries, but can
occur between banks and their affiliates). It was a pure Fed power play. One of Chairman Greenspan's great
rhetorical skills, which this and many other cases where he opposed deregulation illustrate, is to shift the burden
of proof to suit his argument. When he advocated deregulation (as in the case of expanding underwriting powers
via affiliates), he argued that there was no clear evidence that deregulation would cause harm. When he opposed
deregulation, he argued that there was no clear evidence that deregulation would not cause harm. In the case of
permitting underwriting, he used gradualism to compromise with worrisome critics, and build a record of
performance on which to base further relaxation of constraints. But he did not advocate gradualism and
experimentation as a means to overcome uncertainties on the party of policy makers in other areas {notably, with
respect to permitting underwriting in subsidiaries, or as discussed below, with respect to allowing commercial
firms to provide financial services). Chairman Greenspan knew how to overcome Congressional fears of change

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00099

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.050

41

94
supported consolidation and activities deregulation because doing so did not (1) stir up significant
political opposition to the Fed within Congress or the Administration, which might threaten its monetary
policy independence, (2) harm the large commercial banks (who were key allies of the Fed in some of its
political battles in Washington), or (3) undermine the Fed's competitive position vis a vis other
regulators.

Furthermore, Calomiris (2006) argues that these three constraints (opposition by politicians,
opposition by big banks, and erosion of Fed regulatory power} led the Fed not only to fail to support
some beneficial regulatory changes (e.g., allowing financial holding companies to actively compete in
real estate brokerage, reining in the growth of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac during the 1990s, and
requiring banks to expand and improve their capital requirements), but to actively support a very
harmful approach to bank consolidation 27

when he wanted to, and he also knew how to use Congress's fear of change as a tool to limit deregulation. Which
Congressman would want to bear the responsibility of having ignored Alan Greenspan's warning? Fortunately, in
the case of the debate over subs vs. affiliates, those tactics did not win the day.
27
With respect to Fannie and Freddie, the political landscape started to change dramatically around the middle of
2000. At that time, Congressmen Richard Baker (who occupies a "safe seat" in Louisiana, who has what appears to
be a sincere philosophical opposition to the risks and costs posed by the GSEs, and who also may have been

searching for an issue of national importance to call his own) began a campaign to bring to light the various GSE
abuses. Magazines started to publicize the networks of GSE political connections, and the large amounts of

compensation earned by GSE executives (and their lack of banking skills, but strong backgrounds in lobbying).
Unseemly power plays and Congressional arm twisting by the GSEs over modest proposed reforms of their capital
standards encouraged more scrutiny and opposition, which came from all parts of the political spectrum. And the
recent accounting scandals added further fuel to the fire. The White House became particularly interested in GSE
reform after 2003, as the result of the accounting scandals. The growing chorus of academic and political
opposition to the GSEs, coupled with the strong push from the large banks, and the new shift in the Administration
and Congress away from supporting the GSE status quo seems to have tipped the balance for Chairman
Greenspan. For the past several years, he has been a vocal advocate of GSE reform. On May 19, 2000, he sent an
open letter (Greenspan 2000) to Chairman Baker, pointing out the risks and costs inherent in the GSEs and
supporting the case for reform. Subsequent remarks by Chairman Greenspan have elaborated on his initial May
2000 letter (most recently in his April 6, 2005 testimony to the Senate Banking Committee- Greenspan 2005), and
open season on the GSEs has been declared for Fed researchers, who had long been chomping at that bit. Now
Chairman Greenspan is practically leading the charge for GSE reform. Thus, a regulatory reform that started off as
"too hot to handle" became transformed (as in the fairy tale) to be "just right."

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00100

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.051

42

95
Most importantly, Calomiris (2006) and Calomiris and Haber (2013) argue that the Fed did not
prevent undesirably anticompetitive bank mergers, and also that it failed to act properly as a prudential
regulator of merging banks, especially with respect to identifying and constraining the mounting risks

that banks took on as part of their contractual agreements with activist organizations (which enjoyed
powerful political support in the government}, as a means of gaining support for proposed mergers.
These two failings were two sides of the same political bargain: the bank merger wave, at its heart, was
a political bargain to create rents (by creating market power) and to distribute those rents among
politically powerful entities (mega banks and power urban activist organizations). The Fed was a willing
intermediary of this bargain, and its willingness to play that role was rewarded with increased regulatory
power, and with its increasingly unthreatened monetary policy independence. But the social costs of
that bargain were large.

The Fed's as Intermediary of the Megabanks-Urban Activists Merger Bargain

The Riegle-Neallnterstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994, by knocking down the
last barriers to interstate banking, marked the demise of the unlikely political coalition between unit
bankers and agrarian populists that had dominated banking policy for over a century and a half
(Calomiris and Haber 2013). It permitted a wave of mergers and acquisitions that created the
mega banks that now have a branch in nearly every city or town in the United States. JP Morgan Chase
was created out of the merger of no less than 37 banks, creating a mega bank with more than 220,000
employees and $2 trillion in assets as of 2011. The Bank of America, which had initially been a Californiabased bank, merged with or acquired more than 50 other banks."

The creation of the new megabanks generated tremendous profits for merging banks-from
economies of scale, economies of scope, the potential for market power, and too-big-to-fail government

28

Calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 7.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00101

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.052

43

96
protection. Political actions that create profit also create new opportunities for deciding how to divide
them. Calomiris and Haber (2013) show that, in the new U.S. Game of Bank Bargains defined by
branching deregulation, populist politics continued to play a role in determining the allocation of profits,
although the center of populist power had shifted from rural to urban areas.

Each merger and acquisition required approval from regulators, most particularly from the
Federal Reserve Board. The process of approval required that banks show that they had been good
citizens of the communities in which they operated, and this fact provided a source of leverage for
activist groups, such as the Association of Community Organizations for Reform Now (ACORN), who
could block or delay a merger by claiming that the banks were not in compliance with the Community
Reinvestment Act of 1977. What had been a largely moribund piece of legislation now became a very
valuable chip in the Game of Bank Bargains, which perhaps explains why the Act was revised eight times
once the merger wave got underway, each revision usually increasing its stringency. Bankers seeking to
become nationwide enterprises had to ally with activist groups to obtain their political blessing. In
exchange, the activist groups obtained contractual guarantees from the would-be merging banks to
direct mortgage and other credit, as well as cash contributions, to themselves and their constituents.

The incentives to become a mega bank were multiple. Potential advantages included
diversification, the ability to spread overhead costs over a larger operation, economies of scope (a large
bank could afford to provide a broader range of products and services). Additional potential advantages
of becoming a mega-bank was were the potential for obtaining market power and the potential implicit
subsidy of too-big-to-fail protection.

The Federal Reserve Board had the key decision making authority over mergers, as the regulator
of bank holding companies, but other bank regulators and the Justice Department also could weigh in to
oppose mergers, if they chose to do so. There were several criteria that could be used to block approval

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00102

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.053

44

97
of a bank merger. First, an acquiring bank had to be financially strong. Second, the merged bank could
not have excessive market power. This was not much of a constraint, because the Fed typically assessed
market power by looking at a merged bank's deposit market share, rather than its ability to set prices in
credit markets.

The Fleet Financiai-BankBoston merger of 1999 is a telling example: by combining the only two
New England banks of significant size it created a mega bank that could set prices for business
borrowers. Mid-sized businesses that were too big to borrow from the remaining small, local banks, and
too small to be able to borrow in global markets, were particularly affected. Not only did they object to
the merger on these grounds, the Mayor of Boston and the Attorney General of Massachusetts did as
well. All to no avail: the Fed approved the merger, and interest spreads for business borrowers rose by
a full percentage point. 29

The third criterion by which a merger could be blocked was "good citizenship" (as regulated
under the CRA) and Calomiris and Haber (2013) show that, unlike market power, this was indeed a
binding constraint. The language of the CRA focuses on making sure that banks serve their local
communities, but this largely translated into ensuring that low-income urban communities with minority
populations were not subjected to discrimination in lending. The early years of the CRA do not appear
to have produced much in the way of results: as Figure 2, taken from Calomiris and Haber (2013)
Chapter 7, shows, from 1977 to 1992, only $43 billion in CRA commitments by banks had been
announced, and almost all of that occurred after 1989. As of 1995, however, revisions to the CRA meant
that banks faced adverse consequences for running afoul of federal government bank supervisors who
monitored and rated their CRA compliance. As President Clinton boasted in a July 1999 speech, "[CRA]

29

Calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 7.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00103

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.054

45

98
was pretty well moribund until we took office. Over 95 percent of the community investment... made in
the 22 years of that law have been made in the six and a half years that I've been in office." 30

Clinton embraced the idea of CRA commitments as part of his more general belief in a "third
way" to promote the economic well-being of disadvantaged Americans without harming other
individuals or business interests. This "third" approach stood in contrast to either a laissez-fa ire
approach or a traditional tax and transfer approach to public policy.

Why did banks care about their CRA ratings? Banks could receive a range of CRA "grades"Outstanding, Satisfactory, Needs to Improve, and Substantial Noncompliance-and these depended on
the degree to which a bank was serving the needs of the low-income and minority groups in the
communities where it operated. The main penalty for getting a weak rating was that it could potentially
scuttle a bank merger on the basis of "bad citizenship." A bank that was not pursuing an aggressive
strategy of mergers and acquisitions did not, therefore, need to pay much attention to its CRA rating. A
bank with big ambitions to grow, however, needed to a good rating from CRA.

A bank that wanted to expand through a strategy of mergers and acquisitions faced a strategic
choice: it could either create its own CRA lending program or it could enlist community activist groups as
partners in creating a joint CRA lending program. The advantage of the former was that the bank
retained control of decision-making about the allocation of the CRA loans. The advantage of the latter
was that the bank could enlist the support of community activist groups for its merger and acquisition
activities, in exchange for which it effectively gave up control over the CRA portfolio. That is, the
partnership between banks and activist groups aligned the incentives of activist groups with the bank, so
that the activist groups would testify on behalf of a merging bank about its commitment to good
citizenship.

°Calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 7.

3

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00104

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.055

46

99
Of course, a formal partnership agreement with a bank was a welcome source of fee income
and power for the activist groups. At least to judge from the merger of Fleet Financial and BankBoston,
a bank-run program was cause for activists to oppose a merger. As the transcript of the Fed hearing for
that merger makes clear, a coalition of Massachusetts activist groups testified against the merger
because Fleet-BankBoston had committed $14.6 billion to CRA lending, but refused to continue Fleet's
CRA partnership with ACORN. Fleet-BankBoston, anticipating this opposition, actually paid the travel
expenses of out-of-state activist groups in order to testify on the bank's behalf. 31
It was, therefore, often in a bank's interest to enter into an explicit partnership with an activist
group in advance of a Fed hearing, rather than running its own CRA credit program. Some critics of the
CRA described those deals as a form of "legalized extortion." 32 Regardless of the words used to describe
them, the deals struck by banks and activist groups were a predictable outcome of the situation at hand.
Banks had every incentive to merge: they could capture scale economies in administration, diversify risk,
obtain market power, and perhaps grow large enough to obtain too-big-to-fail protection. Activist
groups had every incentive to threaten to show up at Fed hearings to complain that a bank involved in a
merger was not a good citizen: their organizations would prosper as the result of the CRA agreements
that they negotiated, and their constituents would enjoy increased access to credit. Given the existence
of the CRA, both sides had incentives to strike a deal, because failure to do so meant that the bank
merger might be blocked, thereby forcing the bank to forego the opportunity to increase its profits and
forcing the activist group to forego the opportunity to serve its members and increase the resources at
its disposal. The politicians whose policies made these deals possible saw no reason to get in the way of
them. As President Clinton proudly proclaimed in a 1999 speech, the banking reform legislation of that

31
32

Calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 7.
Calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 7.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00105

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.056

47

100
year "establishes the principles that, as we expand the powers of banks, we will expand the reach of the
[Community Reinvestment] Act." 33

There was nothing subtle about the manner in which the deals between merging banks and
activist groups were arranged. In fact, an umbrella organization for activist groups, the National
Community Reinvestment Coalition (NCR C), actually put together a 101-page guide on how to negotiate
with banks that were in the process of merging. The NCRC guide did not shy away from encouraging
activist organizations to take advantage of their leverage over a prospective bank merger: "When a
lender desires to merge with another institution or open a branch, the lender must apply to the Federal
Reserve Board and/or to its primary regulator for permission. If the lender has received low [sic] CRA
rating, the federal agency reviewing the lender's application has the authority to delay, deny, or
condition the lender's application." 34 The guide goes on to say: "Merger and acquisition activity presents
significant opportunities for community groups to intervene in the approval process and raise CRA
concerns and issues. Some banks are very desirous of Outstanding ratings so that they can present a
clean reinvestment record to regulators when they ask for permission to merge.... Activists should keep
in mind that changes from Outstanding to Satisfactory ratings (and back again) is effective in leveraging
reinvestment as well as changes from passing to failing ratings (and back again to passing). This is true
regardless of whether the movement in ratings is the overall rating for the bank or a rating for particular
geographical areas." 35

The guide then explains how to affect a bank's grade: " ... community organizations can offer
written comments on a bank's CRA and fair lending performance when a bank has submitted an
application to merge or acquire another bank or thrift. NCRC can assist community organizations in

"Calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 7.
Calomiris and Haber {2013), Chapter 7.
"Calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 7.

34

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00106

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.057

48

101
preparing comments on merger applications." 36 Finally, the guide made clear that simply creating noise
in a bank's merger application file could allow a group to leverage resources, even if the bank had been
CRA compliant: "Timely comments can influence a bank's CRA rating by directing examiners to particular
areas of strength or weakness in a bank's lending, investments, or services in low- and moderate-income
neighborhoods .... Even changing a rating from Outstanding to Satisfactory in one state or one part of the
exam can motivate a bank to increase the number of loans, investments, and services to low- and
moderate-income communities.""

Activist groups were successful in negotiating many long-term contracts with banks, in which
they received specific monetary and other commitments for their organizations. Calomiris and Haber
(2013) show that between 1977 and 2007 there were no fewer than 376 such agreements, involving
scores of groups. These agreements included a $760 million commitment from the Bank of New York to
ACORN, an $8 billion agreement between Wachovia Bank and New Jersey Citizen Action, and a $70
billion agreement between the Bank of America and the California Reinvestment Coalition. 38 In return,
the activist groups did not oppose the approval of those banks' pending mergers and acquisitions.
Sometimes, they submitted documentation and testified in support of the merger. For example, when
Nations Bank merged with the Bank of America in 1998, creating the largest bank in the United States,
with $525 billion in assets, the President of ACORN Housing, George Butts, testified at the Fed hearing
on behalf of the merging banks. 39

The commitments that activist organizations obtained from banks came in two forms. First,
banks committed to supply mortgage and small business credit to borrowers identified by the activist
organizations. As Calomiris and Haber {2013) show, over the period 1977-2007, these directed credit

36

Calomiris and
Calomiris and
38
Calomiris and
39 Calomiris and
37

Haber (2013),
Haber (2013),
Haber (2013),
Haber (2013),

Chapter 7.
Chapter 7.
Chapter 7.
Chapter 7.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00107

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.058

49

102
commitments totaled $867 billion, with almost all of that growth coming in the years after 1992. Banks
also provided a second source of support to activist groups, by paying them fees for administering the
directed credit programs into which they had entered or by making direct contributions to those groups.
Between 1993 and 2008, for example, ACORN, received $13.5 million from the Bank of America, $9.5
million from JP Morgan-Chase, $8.1 million from Citibank, $7.4 million from HSBC, and $1.4 million from
Capital One. As of 2000, the U.S. Senate Banking Committee estimated that the total of such fees and
contributions to all activist groups came to $9.5 billion, which Calomiris and Haber (2013) regard as
likely an understatement of the true amount 40

Had it not been for the CRA, banks would have made fewer and less risky loans in the 1990s and
2000s. A recent study, by Agarwal, Benmelech, Bergman and Seru (2013) compares the portfolios of
banks in the six quarters prior to a CRA evaluation relative to the portfolios of other banks not slated for
an evaluation, and finds that an impending a CRA examination caused banks to increase their lending by
5%, and increased the default risk of those banks mortgage loans by more than 15 percentage points 41
This approach provides lower-bound estimates of both increased lending and increased levels of default
risk resulting from the CRA. Another approach to measuring the impact of CRA compliance is to focus
on the increase in the level of CRA commitments over time. This is the approach taken by Pinto (2011),
who assumes, conservatively, that the CRA had no binding effects on bank lending until the Clinton
Administration's CRA policy push. Under that assumption, Pinto concludes that, by 2007, there were

4

°Calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 7.

41

Agarwal, Benmelech, Bergman and Seru (2012) summarize their results as follows: "We find that adherence to
the act leads to riskier lending by banks: in the six quarters surrounding the CRA exams, lending is elevated on
average by about 5 percent and these loans default about 15 percent more often .... We note that our estimates do
not provide an assessment of the full impact of the CRA. This is because we are examining the effect of CRA
evaluations relative to a baseline of banks not undergoing an exam. To the extent that there are adjustment costs
in changing lending behavior, this baseline level of lending behavior itself may be shifted toward catering to CRA
compliance. Because our empirical strategy nets out the baseline effect, our estimates of CRA evaluations provide
a lower bound to the actual impact of the Community Reinvestment Act. If adjustment costs in lending behavior
are large and banks can't easily tilt their loan portfolio toward greater CRA compliance, the full impact of the CRA
is potentially much greater than that estimated by the change in lending behavior around CRA exams."

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00108

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.059

so

103
$2.2 trillion dollars in CRA commitments that would not have been undertaken by banks voluntarily. In
short, however its effects on lending are measured, CRA compliance had major effects on the amount
and the riskiness of lending.

The trillions of dollars worth of CRA deals also had important consequences for the structure of
the banking industry. The arrangements made by banks and activist groups did not just mean that the
latter would not block mergers by the former; it meant that the latter, and their political allies, ironically,
became supporters of something that one would think they should have opposed: limits on bank
competition that favored mega-banks.

As Calomiris and Haber (2013) show, the partnership between mega banks and activist groups
became even more ambitious as it drew in a third set of partners- Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Banks
would not make limitless commitments to their activist partners: CRA loans implied higher levels of risk
for the bank than more traditional mortgage loans. Thus, the activist groups used their political power
in Washington to generate regulatory mandates on housing GSEs, which included the Federal National
Mortgage Association (FNMA, commonly known as Fannie Mae), and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage
Corporation (FHLMC, commonly known as Freddie Mac), and the Federal Home Loan Banks (FHLBs).
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, in particular, were required to repurchase mortgage loans that had been
made to low income, urban, and minority constituencies. This change was a win-win for activist groups
and mega-banks; more credit could be directed to targeted constituencies at less cost to the banks
because the banks were now able to resell some of their CRA-related mortgages to a GSE on favorable
terms. 42

42
Several books document the effects of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac on the mortgage market leading up to the
subprime crisis. In addition to Cal om iris and Haber (2013), see Rajan (2010), Morgenson and Rosner (2011),
Acharya, Richardson, van Nieuwerburgh, and White (2011), and Wallison (2011).

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00109

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.060

51

104
These government mandates on Fannie and Freddie were not vague statements of intent, they
were specific targets; and in order to meet those targets Fannie and Freddie had little choice but to
weaken their underwriting standards. By the mid-1990s, Fannie and Freddie were agreeing to purchase
mortgages with down payments of only three percent (instead of the 20 percent that had been the
industry standard). Soon after they were buying mortgages with weak credit scores. By 2003, they were
agreeing to purchase massive quantities of loans with no documentation of income (so called liar, or nodoc, loans). In exchange, they obtained valuable concessions from Congress, most particularly capital
standards (minimum ratios of equity capital to assets) that were only 60 percent that of commercial
banks holding similar loan portfolios. That is, the managers and shareholders of the GSEs joined the
megabank-urban activist coalition. They became a crucial ingredient to the growth of the coalition's
resources, a crucial part of the institutional glue that held the coalition together.

Weak underwriting standards were not an excludable good (or bad); they were available to

everyone. Fannie and Freddie, by virtue of their size and their capacity to repurchase and securitize
loans made by banks, set the standards for the entire industry. Thus, large swathes of the American
middle class-whether they realized it or not-were soon pulled into this large bank-urban activist-GSE
coalition by jumping on the easy credit bandwagon. This fact cannot be emphasized strongly enough:
when Fannie and Freddie agreed to purchase loans that only had a three percent down payment, no
documentation of income or employment, and a far from perfect credit score they changed the risk
calculus of large numbers of American families, not just the urban poor.

Calomiris and Haber (2013) note that one of the cruel ironies of the debasement of lending
standards was that it was not a very efficient way to raise the living standards of the urban poor.
Transferring income by distorting the incentives of bankers, the managers of GSEs, government
agencies, and large swathes of the population through implicit housing subsidies contributed greatly to

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00110

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.061

52

105
the Subprime crisis of 2007-09. That crisis likely undermined whatever short-run redistributive gains the
subsidy programs achieved. A system of on-balance sheet tax and transfer programs might have been
politically more difficult to implement, and therefore would have been of more modest scale, but it
would have produced more positive outcomes in the long-run.

What the Fed Should Have Dane in the 1990s and 2000s, and Why It Didn't Do It

In retrospect, it seems clear that the Fed would have better served the interests of the U.S.
economy and banking system if it had not been so willing to approve many of the mega-mergers of the
1990s and 2000s, or the contracts between the mega banks and the community activists that coincided
with those mergers. The Fed, as a competitiveness regulator, should have been more concerned about
the creation of concentrations of market power (as during the merger of Fleet and BankBoston). The
Fed, as a prudential regulator, should have been more concerned about the potentially destabilizing
consequences of $4.5 trillion in contractual CRA merger-related commitments. The Fed should have
recognized the systemic risks that these mergers and contracts, especially in combination with debased
underwriting standards and GSE mandates. Clearly, the Fed had the authority to stop or reshape these
mergers, to instruct banks not to enter into risky contractual commitments, or to require banks to
maintain much higher capital ratios if they undertook such risks (which by itself would have discouraged
some of the risk taking during the merger wave).

It is hard to prove why people or organizations make mistakes, but several facts no doubt
contributed to the Fed's decisions not to be stricter in its regulation of mergers, competition or risk
taking. The parties to the bargain between the megabanks and the activist organizations were extremely
powerful politically, and closely allied with influential politicians in the Congress and the Administration,
both during the Clinton years and during the George W. Bush presidency. Opposing this bargain would
not have been easy for the Fed. Doing so would have risked the wrath not only of the big banks, but of

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00111

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.062

53

106
the members of Congress and the Administration that had direct control of its authorities, both in the
realm of regulatory policy and monetary policy. A Fed that would have decided to be tougher would also
have risked losing its regulatory powers, and possibly a fair degree of its monetary policy independence,
both of which depended on its friendly relationship with the Administration and Congress.

Neither the microeconomic regulation of mergers, nor the prudential regulation of banks, has
ever been the Fed's top priority. Monetary policy is the top priority, and preserving monetary policy
independence was the paramount objective of the Fed. Putting that monetary policy independence at
risk to strike down the trillions of dollars of merger-related CRA contracts in the name of competition or
systemic risk management would have been almost inconceivable as a political calculation.
Furthermore, the Fed was involved in heated turf battles with other regulators. Fed opposition to the
political bargain between the mega banks and the activists might simply have resulted in a loss of Fed
regulatory authority rather than any change in regulatory outcome, as Congress and the Administration
might have transferred authority over prudential regulation or merger approval to other parties.

Finally, the Fed's regulatory mandate was itself unclear because it involved multiple, conflicting
objectives. On the one hand, the Fed was charged with preserving bank safety and soundness and
competitiveness {already a complicated mandate); on the other hand, the Fed had to supervise bank
compliance with the CRA, and was specifically required to measure banks' commitments to their
communities and to take CRA compliance into account when considering mergers. If the Fed had taken a
bold stand against the grand bargain between the mega banks and the activists, critics in Congress could
have argued that it was failing to fulfill its mission, and used that argument to justify either a transfer in
merger approval authority, or other changes in Fed authority.

In short, the best explanation for why the Fed failed to act properly is not that it was
incompetent or corrupt, but that it had little choice but to comply. Of course, the political actors that

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00112

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.063

54

107
made mergers possible and created the CRA amendments of the 1990s would have been aware of the
political realities that constrained Fed action. Indeed, they would have depended upon them.

V. Policy Implications

The policy implications drawn from the above history and analysis are summarized in Section ll's
eight sets of Propositions. In closing, I expand on Proposition 8. To promote independence along both
dimensions of economic policy {monetary and regulatory) two sorts of policy reforms are required: {i)
separation of authority over the two areas into two distinct agencies (to avoid tradeoffs that reduce
independence of regulatory policy), and (ii) the establishment of clear mandates and accountability
procedures for each category of policy.

With respect to the first of these proposals, so long as the Fed is vested with both monetary and
regulatory authority, it will fear political reprisals with respect to monetary independence from pursuing
regulatory policies that run counter to the political bargains of influential politicians in Congress and the
Administration. Separating regulatory and monetary authorities would ensure greater accountability of
whichever agency is charged with each and would avoid political trading off between the two (Calomiris
and litan 2000). Just prior to the recent crisis, Secretary Paulson's working group on regulatory reform
had released its findings suggesting the desirability of just such a change. Unfortunately, the political
deals surrounding the crisis and the legislative response to it moved further in the direction of
empowering the Fed as the primary regulatory of the financial system. Some supporters of this
approach have claimed that it is necessary to do so to ensure that the Fed can monitor risks of the banks
to which it lends. This is a fatuous argument. The Fed can and should retain full authority to examine all
Fed member banks. That does not require the Fed to be a merger regulator, or a prudential regulator.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00113

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.064

55

108
With respect to the establishment of clear mandates and accountability procedures for each
category of policy, I would reiterate that without clear mandates, legitimate independence is nearly
impossible to achieve. Furthermore, clear mandates limit undesirable discretion that results from
inappropriately politicized leadership (the Burns problem) or the excessive confidence of economists in
pursuit of intellectual fads (like the Riefler-Burgess doctrine, the Phillips Curve, or the DSGE framework).

On the regulatory front, on prudential grounds banks should be prohibited categorically from
making contractual commitments with activist groups. The criteria for merger approval should be based
on multiple objective criteria for measuring market power (not just deposit market shares), each of
which must be satisfied for mergers to be permitted.

With respect to monetary policy, the Fed's mandate should be expressed in the form of a
"comply or explain" rule (e.g., a Taylor Rule, or some other similar rule). 43 Such a rule would make clear
the objectives of monetary policy, and thus permit and require greater accountability. The ironic and
important truth is that constrained independence equals greater independence. The Fed currently is
tasked with achieving four objectives: price stability, interest rate stability, maximum employment, and
financial stability. There is no way to hold the Fed accountable for its monetary policy actions with this
vague, multi-dimensional mandate. This invites politically motivated attacks that limit Fed
independence, and also invites bad discretionary policy ideas.

It is not realistic to argue that the central bank could or should be bound by a rigid rule. As Capie
and Wood (2012) point out, such rules almost never survive trying times. I favor a "comply-and-explain"
regime, in which departures from the rule are clearly announced and explained. The central bank
43

A Taylor Rule is not the only possibility. A nominal GDP growth rule tied to an inflation objective (which could be
"reset" annually to avoid inflationary consequences from large supply shocks) is another possibility, which has the
advantage relative to a Taylor Rule of not requiring an estimate of the natural rate of unemployment. If a Taylor
Rule approach were chosen, the mandate would also have to set limits on the process governing the assumed
natural rate of unemployment to avoid manipulation of the formula. For example, it might be set as a moving
average of many (e.g., 20) years of lagged unemployment rates.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00114

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.065

56

109
describes why it is deviating from the rule, and commits to do so rarely. The leadership of the central
bank, therefore, bears significant personal reputation aI risk if the supposed reasons for the deviation
from the rule are considered to have been inappropriate, on the basis of hindsight, or if it exceeds the
permissible frequency of deviations from the rule. One could make this personal responsibility explicit,
for example, by requiring that the terms of all Fed Governors and Presidents would come up for renewal
two years after they deviated from the rule, which would put discourage departure from the rule unless
the circumstances clearly warranted it.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00115

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.066

57

110
References

Acharya, Viral, Matthew Richardson, Stijn van Nieuwerburgh, and Lawrence J. White (2011). Guaranteed To
Fail: Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Debacle of Mortgage Finance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Agarwal, Sumit, Efraim Benmelech, Nittai Bergman, and Am it Seru (2013). "Did the Community
Reinvestment Act (CRA) Lead to Risky Lending?" Working Paper, University of Chicago Booth School.
Barth, James R., Philip F. Bartholomew, and Carol J. Labich (1989). "Moral Hazard and the Thrift Crisis: An
Analysis of 1988 Resolutions," Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1989.
Bekaert, Geert, Marie Hoerova, and Marco Lo Duca (2012). "Risk, Uncertainty and Monetary Policy,"
Working Paper.
Brewer, Elijah J., Ill (1995). "The Impact of the Current Deposit Insurance System on S&L Shareholders'
Risk/Return Tradeoffs," Journal of Financial Services Research 9, 65-89.
Brewer, Elijah J. Ill, and Thomas H. Mondschean (1991). "An Empirical Test of the Incentive Effects of
Deposit Insurance: The Case of Junk Bonds at Savings and Loan Associations," Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago Working Paper WP-91-18.
Brunner, Karl, and Allan H. Meltzer (1964). "The Federal Reserve's Attachment to the Free Reserves
Concept," Staff Analysis, House Committee on Banking and Currency, 88'h Congress, Second Session.
Brunner, Karl, and Allan H. Meltzer (1968). "What Did We Learn from the Monetary Experience of the
United States During the Great Depression?" Canadian Journal of Economics 1, 334-48.
Calomiris, Charles W. (1989). "Deposit Insurance: Lessons from the Record," Economic Perspectives,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, May/June, 10-30.
Calomiris, Charles W. {1990). "Is Deposit Insurance Necessary? A Historical Perspective," Journal of
Economic History, 283-95.
Calomiris, Charles W. (1992). "Do 'Vulnerable' Economies Need Deposit Insurance?: Lessons from the
U.S. Agricultural Boom and Bust of the 1920s," in If Texas Were Chile: A Primer on Banking Reform,
edited by Philip Brock, San Francisco: ICS Press, 237-314,319-28,450-58.
Calomiris, Charles W. (2000). U.S. Bank Deregulation in Historical Perspective (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press).
Calomiris, Charles W. {2006). "Alan Greenspan's Legacy: An Early Look: The Regulatory Record of the
Greenspan Fed," American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings, 96, 170-73.
Calomiris, Charles W. (2010). "The Political Lessons of Depression-Era Banking Reform," Oxford Review
of Economic Policy, 26, 540-560.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00116

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.067

58

111
Calomiris, Charles W. (2012) "An Insurance Policy Against Inflation," Wall Street Journal, March 12.
Calomiris, Charles W. (2013). "Volatile Times and Persistent Conceptual Errors: US Monetary Policy, 19141951," in The Origins, History and Future of the Federal Reserve, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta,
forthcoming.
Calomiris, Charles W., and Mark Carlson (2013). Corporate Governance, Rent Seeking, Failure Risk, and
Portfolio Choice in Unprotected Banks," Working Paper, March.
Calomiris, Charles W., and Stephen Haber (2013). Fragile By Design: Banking Panics, Scarce Credit and
Political Bargains, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Calomiris, Charles W., R. Glenn Hubbard, and James Stock (1986). "The Farm Debt Crisis and Public
Policy," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 441-85.
Calomiris, Charles W., and Robert E. Utan (2000). "Financial Regulation in a Global Marketplace,"
Brookings-Wharton Papers on Financial Services 2000.
Calomiris, Charles W., and Thanavut Pornrojnangkool (2009). "Relationship Banking and the Pricing of
Financial Services," Journal of Financial Services Research 35, 189-224.
Calomiris, Charles W., and David C. Wheelock (1998). "Was the Great Depression a Watershed in
American Monetary Policy?" in The Defining Moment: The Great Depression and the American Economy
in the Twentieth Century, edited by M. Bordo, C. Goldin, and E. White, National Bureau of Economic
Research, U of Chicago Press, 1998, 23-66.
Calomiris, Charles W., and Eugene N. White (1994). "The Origins of Federal Deposit Insurance," in The
Regulated Economy: A Historical Approach to Political Economy, edited by C. Goldin and G. Libecap,
National Bureau of Economic Research, University of Chicago Press, 145-188.
Capie, Forrest, and Geoffrey Wood (2012). "Central Bank Independence: Can It Survive a Crisis?"
Working Paper, October.
Carey, Roberta Grower (1975). "Evaluation under the Bank Merger Act of 1960 of the Competitive
Factors Involved in Bank Mergers: The Regulatory Agencies Compared," Journal of Monetary Economics
1, 275-308.

Carnell, RichardS., Jonathan R. Macey, and Geoffrey P. Miller (2009). The law of Banking and Financial
Institutions. New York: Aspen Publishers.
Dell' Ariccia, Giovanni, Deniz lgan, and Luc laeven (2008). "Credit Booms and Lending Standards:
Evidence from the Subprime Mortgage Market," Working Paper, IMF, April.
Flood, Mark D. (1991). "The Great Deposit Insurance Debate," Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. louis,
74,51-77.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00117

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.068

59

112
Friedman, Milton (1962). "Should There Be an Independent Monetary Authority?," in In Search of a
Monetary Constitution, edited by Leland Yeager, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Gilbert, R. Alton (1994). Federal Reserve Lending To Banks that Failed: Implications for the Bank
Insurance Fund," Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, January/February, 3-18.
Golembe, Carter H. (1960). "The Deposit Insurance Legislation of 1933," Political Science Quarterly, 76,
181-95.
Goodfriend, Marvin (2011). "Central Banking in the Credit Turmoil: An Assessment of Federal Reserve
Practice," Journal of Monetary Economics 58, 1-12.
Goodfriend, Marvin (2012). "The Elusive Promise of Independent Central Banking," Monetary and
Economic Studies 30, November, 39-54, Bank of Japan.
Greenspan, Alan (1988). "An Overview of Financial Restructuring," in Proceedings of the 24'h Annual
Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1-9.
Greenspan, Alan (1990). "Subsidies and Powers in Commercial Banking," in Proceedings of the 26'h Annual
Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1·8.
Greenspan, Alan (1997a). Testimony before the Committee on Banking and Financial Services, U.S. House of
Representatives, March 19.
Greenspan, Alan (1997b). "Remarks at the Annual Meeting and Conference of the Conference of State
Bank Supervisors," May 3.
Greenspan, Alan (1997c). "H.R.10: The Financial Services Competitiveness Act of 1997," Testimony before
the Committee on Banking and Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives, May 22.
Greenspan, Alan (1997d). "The Financial Services Competition Act of 1997," Testimony before the
Subcommittee on Finance and Hazardous Materials of the Committee on Commerce, U.S. House of
Representatives, July 17.
Greenspan, Alan (1997e). "Technology Change and the Economy," Remarks at the Annual Convention of the
American Bankers Association, October 5.
Greenspan, Alan (1998). "H.R.10: The Financial Services Act of 1998," Testimony before the Committee on
Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, June 17.
Greenspan, Alan (1999). "H.R.10 and Financial Modernization," Testimony Before the Subcommittee on
Finance and Hazardous Materials, Committee on Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives, April28.
Greenspan, Alan (2000). Letter to Congressman Richard Baker, May 19.
Greenspan, Alan (2001). "Harnessing Market Discipline," Speech at Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis,
September.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00118

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.069

60

113
Greenspan, Alan (2005). "Regulatory Reform of the Government-Sponsored Enterprises," Testimony before
the Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, April6.
Horvitz, Paul (1991). "The Causes of Texas Bank and Thrift Failures," in If Texas Were Chile: A Primer on
Banking Reform, edited by Philip Brock, San Francisco: ICS Press, 131-61.
Jimenez, Gabriel, Steven Ongena, Jose luis Peydro-Aicalde, and Jesus Saurina (2007). "Hazardous Times for
Monetary Policy: What Do Twenty-Three Million Bank loans Say About the Effects of Monetary Policy on
Credit Risk?" Discussion Paper No. 6514, Center for Economic Policy Research, October.
Hawke, John D., Jr. (1988}. "Paul A. Volcker and Domestic Bank Regulatory Policy," Unpublished Paper,
presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, December 28.
Kemmerer, Edwin (1934). "Professor Edwin Kemmerer Analyzes the New American Dollar After the
Devaluation of 1934," in Documentary History of Banking and Currency in the United States, edited by
Herman E. Krooss, Vol. IV, 2815-23.
Klebaner, Benjamim J. (1967). "The Bank Merger Act: Background of the 1966 Version," Southern Economic
Journal34, 250-.
Kroszner, Randall S. and Philip Strahan. (1999}. "What Drives Deregulation? Economics and Politics of
the Relaxation of Bank Branching Restrictions." Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 1437-67.
Kydland, Finn, and Edward Prescott (1977). "Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal
Plans," Journal of Political Economy 85, 473-92.
Meltzer, Allan H. (2012). "How and Why the Fed Must Change in Its Second Century," Working Paper,
October.
Meltzer, Allan H. (2003). A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol. 1. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Meltzer, Allan H. (2009). A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol. 2, Book 2. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.

Meltzer, Allan H. (2010). A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol. 2, Book 1. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Mendoza, Enrique, and Marco E. Terrones (2008). "An Anatomy of Credit Booms: Evidence from Macro
Aggregates and Micro Data," Working Paper, University of Maryland, April.
Morgenson, Gretchen, and Joshua Rosner (2011). Reckless Endangerment: How Outsized Ambition,
Greed, and Corruption Led to Economic Armageddon. New York: Times Books.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00119

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.070

61

114
Patrick, Sue C (1993). Reform of the Federal Reserve System in the Early 1930s: The Politics of Money and
Banking. New York: Garland Publishing.
Phillips, Susan M. (1997). Testimony Before the Senate Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and
Regulatory Relief, March 20.
Pinto, Edward (2011). "Government Housing Policies in the lead-Up to the Financial Crisis: A Forensic
Study," Working Paper.
Rajan, Raghuram (2010). Fault lines: How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the Global Economy.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Schwartz, Anna J. (1992). "The Misuse of the Fed's Discount Window," Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
St. louis, September/October, 58-69.
Shull, Bernard, and Paul M. Horvitz (1971). "The Bank Merger Act of 1960: A Decade After," Antitrust
Bulletin 16, 859-.
Taylor, John B. (2010). "Better Living through Monetary Economics," in Better Living Through Economics,
edited by John Siegfried, Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.
Taylor, John B. (2011). "legislating a Rule for Monetary Policy," Cato Journal31, 407-15.
Taylor, John B. (2012). "Monetary Policy Rules Work and Discretion Doesn't: A Tale of Two Eras," Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking 44, 1017-32.
Taylor, John B. (2013). "The Effectiveness of Central Bank Independence Versus Policy Rules," Working
Paper, January.
Traber, Martin A. (1969). "legislative History of the 1960 Bank Merger Act and its 1996 Amendment:
Judicial Misuse and a Suggested Approach," Indiana law Journal44.
Wallison, Peter J. (2011). "Dissent from the Majority of the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission,"
Available at http://www.aei.org/papers/economics/fiscal-policy/dissent-from-the-majority-report-ofthe-financial-crisis-inquiry-commission-paper/
Wheelock, David C. (1991). The Strategy and Consistency of Federal Reserve Monetary Policy, 19241933. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wheelock, David C. (2006). "What Happens to Banks When House Prices Fall?" Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis, 76, May/June, 57-71.
White, Lawrence J. (1991). The S&l Debacle. New York: Oxford University Press.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00120

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.071

62

115
Figure 1

Number of Banks and Branches, 1920-2010
90,000

...

-

80,000
~

~

5:; 70,000
th 60,000
~

fi

c 50,000
~

"'

40,000

"'

30,000

{

.

b

.Q

E

.···
1

1. . . . . . . . .

20,000

''
I

~

....

....

..··· .·
Branches

•··

..

•.

.•

~~~==~~-~·-~~:-~~~.~~

z

10,000

1............. :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::•'::: ..

. . ..
"0
0
N

0~
0
N

0
0
N

Source: Computed by calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 6, from Federal Reserve,

Banking and Monetary Statistics, p. 16, 297; Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
website, http;/ /www2.fdic.gov/hsob/hsobRpt.asp

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00121

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.072

63

116
Figure 2
Cumulative CRA Commitments1

1977~2007

$5,000

$4.6

Trilliot'l

$4,500

54,000

~

$3,500

0
0

~

53,000

~

a

52,500

0
~

$2,000

~

iii

$1,500
$1,000
$500

$43
Billion

so
~~~~~~~#~~~~~~~~~#~*~*~~~~~~~~~

~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
Source: Calomiris and Haber (2013), Chapter 7, computed from National
Community Reinvestment Coalition, CRA Commitments data.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00122

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.073

64

117
The Relationship between Prudential Supervision and Monetary Policy
Stephen G. Cecchetti'
Testimony before the joint hearing of the
Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit
Subcommittee on Monetary Policy and Trade
Committee on Financial Services
U.S. House of Representatives
September 12, 2017
Chairman Luetkemeyer, Chairman Barr, Ranking Member Clay, Ranking Member Moore, and
distinguished members of the committee, thank you for inviting me to present my views on the
relationship between prudential supervision and monetary policy.
The U.S. financial system is far more resilient today than it was a decade ago, and the likelihood of
another system-wide crisis is now lower. As a consequence of post-crisis regulatory reforms, banks have
more loss-absorbing equity capital than they had in 2007. They also face stringent liquidity
requirements. And, the biggest among them must meet rigorous stress tests. This new environment
ensures that all financial organizations, especially those that are large and complex, are much less likely
to become a burden on the taxpayer.
It is important that we build on this progress. Regulations must remain sufficiently strict and supervisors
must interpret and apply them rigorously. We also need appropriate governance. That is, we must
organize the regulation, by which I mean the promulgation of the rules themselves, and the supervision,
which is the monitoring of compliance with the rules, to ensure that the authorities can and will be able
to do their jobs effectively.
Regulation and supervision are intimately connected, so it makes sense to house them in the same
agency. Rules will always need refinement. Technological innovation and economic advances mean that
the financial system is constantly evolving, and creative people find ways to skirt existing regulations.
This all means that rules and their application require frequent adjustment. Who better to gather the
information needed to improve the rules-to make them both less burdensome and more effectivethan the supervisors enforcing them? This process of continuous improvement, where information from
supervisors leads to regulatory enhancements, will be most efficient when the two groups are operating
under the same roof.

* Rosen Family Chair in International Finance, Brandeis International Business School; Research Associate~ National

Bureau of Economic Research; Research Fellow, Centre for Economic Policy Research; former Economic Adviser
and Head of the Monetary and Economic Department, Bank for International Settlements; former Executive Vice
President and Director of Research, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00123

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.074

1/8

118
Cecchetti

The Relationship between Prudential Supervision and Monetary Policy

My comments today focus on governance, framing the discussion in terms of supervision, with the
understanding that supervisors should also be regulators. I will address two related questions:
1) Should prudential supervision be an independent function, sheltered from day-to-day political
influence with control of its own budget?
2)

Should the central bank be a leading supervisor?

My answer to both of these questions is an unqualified yes. To do otherwise would put the financial
system at risk of costly disaster.
Some preliminary remarks on monetary policy independence

"This administration will always support the political independence of the Federal Reserve Board."
President Ronald Reagan, February 18, 1982. 1
Before getting to the specifics of my argument, I start with something that is uncontroversial: in
adjusting the instruments that Congress authorizes them to use to achieve their statutory goals, central
banks should be independent of short-run political pressures. Such instrument independence allows
monetary policymakers to deliver lower inflation without sacrificing economic growth or employment
over the long run.
The reason for this is straightforward: to be credible and successful in achieving their mandated
objectives, monetary policymakers must have a long horizon. The impact of today's interest rate
decision will not be felt for some time-several years, in many instances. Politicians realized decades
ago that their time horizons are not long enough to deliver the best outcomes. The temptation to
forsake long-term goals for short-term gains is just too strong. If people expect policymakers to pursue
overly accommodative policies to achieve short-run objectives, the long-run goals of price stability and
maximum sustainable growth will suffer.
Governments throughout the world solve this dilemma by delegating monetary policy responsibility to a
separate, largely apolitical, institution with special expertise. To insulate these policymakers from daily
political pressures, central bankers have control of their budgets and the authority to make irreversible
operational decisions. By granting central bankers long terms, governments also enhance their
credibility.
So, when it comes to monetary policy, there is broad agreement: to deliver price stability and maximum
sustainable growth, central bank's operational decisions must be independent of political influence. At
the same time, an independent central bank must act with sufficient transparency so that the
government can hold policymakers accountable for achieving the legal mandate. In the United States,
this is why the Federal Open Market Committee publishes its decisions, explains its actions, and faces
public questioning about its efforts to secure price stability and maximum sustainable employment (or
economic growth).

1
Reagan, Ronald (1982). "The President's News Confereru&" February 18, in John T. Woolley and Gerhard Peters,
eds. The American Presidency Project, website.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00124

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.075

2/8

119
Cecchetti

The Relationship between Prudential Supervision and Monetary Policy

The need for independent prudential supervision

"To be effective, bank regulators and supervisors also require an appropriate degree of
independence; in particular, the public must be confident that regulators' decisions about the
soundness of specific institutions ore not unduly influenced by politico/ pressures or lobbying."
Federal Reserve Board Chairman Ben Bernanke, May 25, 2010. 2
What about prudential supervision? Here the arguments for independence are remarkably similar to
those for monetary policy. Strict bank supervision may result in unpopular limits on certain types of
loans or even the closure of failing banks. Pressure from both bankers and their borrowers can lead to a
delay in corrective action, fostering poor incentives and increasing the risk of larger problems down the
road. Again, political interference may very well generate gains today, but the bill will come due
tomorrow. Shelter from political influence, complete with budgetary control, allows supervisors to
maintain a long-term view, giving them the credibility to enforce rigorous standards, promoting financial
resilience and reducing public costs. As is the case with monetary policy, supervisors' actions are
constrained by Congressional statute, combined with the appropriate mechanisms to ensure
accountability.
While not all banks need a single supervisor, having one agency overseeing the most systemically risky
intermediaries is key to avoiding a race to the bottom among multiple supervisors. This is exactly what
happened in December 2006, when Countrywide Financial switched regulators from the Fed and Office
of the Comptroller of the Currency to the less effective Office of Thrift Supervision. 3
Experience in the United States and elsewhere shows how costly it can be when financial regulation and
supervision are subject to political oversight. Domestically, two cases are instructive: the Federal Home
loan Bank (FHlB) system and the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO). In the first, as
a result of being subjected to the congressional appropriations process, FHlB supervision of the savings
and loan (S&l) industry allowed deep problems to fester. The eventual closing of over 1,000 institutions
from 1986 to 1995 had a direct cost to taxpayers of roughly $250 billion in today's dollars. 4 (This ignores
the large indirect costs arising from the failing S&ls' misallocation of resources.)
Established in 1992, OFHEO supervised the Government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs)-Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac, the two mortgage giants that played key roles in the 2007-09 financial crisis. Their political
influence weakened prudential oversight to the point where, for every $100 that they guaranteed, they
were required to have only $0.45 in capital; and, for each $100 in mortgages they retained on their
balance sheet, the capital requirement was only 2.5%. sIn September 2008, with their slim capital buffer
gone, the Treasury put the two GSEs into receivership, eventually providing $188 billion of taxpayer

2

Ben S. Bernanke, "Central Bank Independence Transparency. anq Accounta.Q.i!i!y," speech at the Institute for
Monetary and Economic Studies International Conference, Bank of Japan, Tokyo, Japan, May 25, 2010.
3
See National Commission on the Causes of the Financial and Economic Crisis in the United States, The Financial
===L"-"-"-'-"'-":"'-'·' Washington Q,C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, January 2011, pg. 173-4.
A description of the impact of the appropriations on supervision is in FDIC, "The Savings and loan Crisis and its
Relationship to Banking," Chapter 4 in An Examination of the Bonking Crises of the 1980s and Earlv 1990s. For
estimates of the costs, see Curry, Timothy and lynn Shibut, "The Cost of the Savings and loan Crisis: Truth and
s;onseguences," FDIC Banking Review, vol. 13, no. 2, 2000.
·
5
See Viral V. Acharya, Matthew Richardson, Stijn van Nieuwerburgh and lawrence J. White. Guaranteed to Fail:
fsmnie_i\llt:l£,_£!.eddie Mac and the Debacle of Mortgaae Finance. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2011.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00125

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.076

3/8

120
Cecchetti

The Relationship between Prudential Supervision and Monetary Policy

support to keep them afloat. (Again, that leaves out the massive costs arising from the misallocation of
resources resulting from the GSEs' behavior.)
Elsewhere in the world, examples of how political interference fueled costly financial crises with dire
consequences are easy to come by. I mention two. The fact that Korean and Indonesian supervisors
lacked independence clearly worsened the Asian Crisis of 1997-98. And, the political sensitivity of
supervisors, especially with regard to real-estate related credit, surely exacerbated Japan's decades-long
banking problems. 6
So, logical reasoning, careful research and common sense all lead to the same conclusion: independent
prudential supervisors provide the foundation for a resilient financial system. When supervisors are
independent of political interference, complete with budgetary autonomy, the financial system is more
stable and taxpayer costs are lower. For this reason, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision's
second Core Principle for Effective Banking Supervision is that supervisors possess operational
independence and have budgetary processes that do not undermine their autonomy. 7
Whether a government upholds this core principle (and others) affects the confidence people have in its
financial system. With that in mind, the IMF incorporates the principle of supervisory independence into
its Financial Sector Assessment Program, which evaluates the resilience of a country's financial system.
Today, the vast majority of countries in the world meet this standard.
This leads to the inescapable conclusion: prudential supervision should be an independent function,
housed in an entity with control of its own budget, insulated from day-to-day political influence, but
acting transparently to ensure accountability.
Why the central bank should be a leading supervisor

"Monetary policy and concerns about the structure and condition of banks and the financial
system more generally are inextricably intertwined. Other agencies, certainly including the
Treasury, have legitimate interests in regulatory policy. But I do insist that neither monetary
policy nor the financial system will be well served if our central bank is deprived from interest
in, and influence over, the structure and performance of the financial system."
Paul A. Volcker, March 17, 2010. 8
Should central banks be a leading supervisor, including supervising systemically important institutions?
The answer is clearly yes. As the lender of last resort, as the monetary policy authority, and as the
organization responsible for overseeing the health and stability of the overall financial system-what we
could call a systemic regulator-the central bank needs to be a supervisor. 9

6

For a discussion of these episodes, and others, see Marc Quintyn and Michael W. Taylor, "Should Fina_n_c:ial Sector
Regulators Be Independent?" IMF Economic Issues No. 32, 2004.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, "Core Principles for Effe~~~~" September 2012.
8
Paul A. Volcker, "Testimony before the House Financial Services Committee," March 17,2010.
9
The ~_Cji,@_Q"1_l,_<Lk.~.r:9.\!.P advocates that the central bank should serve as the systemic regulator, making clear what
that does and does not entail. See Squam Lake Group, "A Systemic R<:Rl!@.!Qr.fgr Financi9l Markets," in Squam Lake
Report, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2010, Chapter 2.
7

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00126

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.077

4/8

121
The Relationship between Prudential Supervision and Monetary Policy

Cecchetti

The lender of last resort and prudential supervision

Recall that Congress created the Federal Reserve in 1913 in response to a series of banking panics.
Financial instability after the Civil War resulted from the absence of a central bank to provide emergency
loans to solvent institutions facing sudden deposit outflows. When depositors ran on a few banks, panic
frequently spread. To promote stability, Congress authorized the Fed to serve as the lender of last
resort-lending against good collateral to solvent institutions at a penalty rate.
Operating as the lender of last resort requires two pieces of information: (1} a determination of an
institution's solvency, and; (2) a valuation of the collateral that is being posted to back the loan.
Supervisors, with their intimate knowledge of the bank's operations, are the officials expected to have
both of these. 10
On the importance of solvency, there are three reasons that it is imperative a central bank never lend to
bankrupt institutions. First, since the central bank will always require collateral, its loans further
subordinate the bank's long-term creditors. It does this both by allowing short-term depositors to run
and by inserting itself ahead of others in the queue for claiming repayment when failure inevitably
comes. Second, lending to an insolvent bank does not put an end to that institution's fragility.
Ultimately, it must be liquidated or re-capitalized. Postponing the day of reckoning is usually costly both
for the institution in question and, as a consequence of a misallocation of resources, for the economy as
a whole. Third, when people find out that the central bank is willing to lend to insolvent banks-and
they will find out-any bank that borrows will be suspected of being bankrupt. The resulting stigma will
impair the useful function of the lender of last resort as a lender to solvent, but illiquid banks. If only
those that are bankrupt borrow, the central bank's lending facility will become worse than useless.
Even with a solvent borrower, protecting public finances means that the central bank must obtain
sufficient collateral. Again, this requires intimate knowledge of the quality of a bank's assets, something
that supervisors routinely assess.
An example illustrates the challenge that a central bank fender faces in maintaining financial stability. On
November 21, 1985, a computer software error prevented the Bank of New York from keeping track of
its U.S. Treasury securities clearing operations. In line with normal practice, orders poured in and the
bank made payments without having received the funds. But when it came time to deliver the bonds
and collect from the buyers, the order information had been erased from the system. By the end of the
day, the Bank of New York had bought and failed to deliver so many securities that it was committed to
paying out nearly $23 billion that it did not have. The Federal Reserve, knowing from its up-to-date
supervisory records that the bank was solvent, made an emergency $23-billion loan, taking the entire
bank (complete with its furnished building) as collateral and averting a systemic financial crisis. The
amount of the loan exceeded the aggregate reserves in the entire U.S. banking system at the time.
Importantly, only a direct and effective supervisor was in a position to know that the Bank of New York
was solvent, that it had the necessary collateral, and that its need to borrow was legitimate. 11

° For a discussion of the role of the lender of last resort, see Paul Tucker, "The Lender of Last Resort and Modern

1

t::_el'tC~L~anking;_.fx.inslPle~

il_fl9Be_C.QQ.:;.lil!.<:.!.iQD.:' in BIS Papers No. 79, September 2014, pg. 10-43.
See the Gerald E. Corrigan, "Ig~tl_mony before the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy of th£:
Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs of the House of Representative~,'' December 12, 1985, Serial No.

11

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00127

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.078

5/8

122
Cecchetti

The Relationship between Prudential Supervision and Monetary Policy

So, in order to operate responsibly and effectively as a lender of last resort, protecting the public
interest, the central bank needs to have close access to confidential supervisory assessments,
knowledge about an institution's business practices, and the skills to evaluate the collateral a bank is
posting to secure a loan. Importantly, this information has to be available to high-ranking central bank
officials on very short notice. In some cases, decisions must be made in a matter of minutes, so the
quality of the data must be without question and it cannot be in the hands of people across town who
may or may not choose to share it.
It is difficult to overstate the importance of liquidity provision in the prevention and management of
financial crises. The Federal Reserve has a variety of methods for injecting liquidity into the banking
system on short notice, including the direct purchase of securities through open market operations and
the provision of intra-day credit through the payments system. But direct lending to banks, usually on
the order of several hundred million dollars, is sometimes the most important means to avert panic and
contain a crisis. For example, in the aftermath of the terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001, to head off
what would have been a financial system collapse, the Fed lent roughly $37 billion that day (and
subsequently provided an additional $100 billion through a variety of means). In the aftermath of the
Lehman bankruptcy, Federal Reserve lending peaked at $441 billion. Without supervisory information,
the Fed would have been flying blind, not knowing if it was lending to insolvent institutions or whether it
was accepting good collateral. Not only would this have been bad policy, it would have put taxpayers at
risk.
As a practical matter, liquidity provision is also the mechanism central banks use to achieve their
traditional interest rate objective. During normal times, when reserves are scarce, the Federal Reserve
influences the federal funds rate by adding or draining liquidity from the banking system. This means
that there is no operational difference between monetary policy actions and lending operations. In fact,
in terms of their impact on the Fed's balance sheet, the purchase of a security and a loan are identical.
Returning to the issue of governance, operations in the midst of a financial crisis are akin to maneuvers
during a war. In the heat of battle, the military relies on a clear chain of command to ensure a
consolidated view of the battle and effective coordination of resources. Separation of supervision from
the central bank would be like having multiple generals with potentially differing objectives
simultaneously giving orders to the same army. It is hard to see how this could possibly work. Successful
crisis management requires timely and effective coordination.

tv'lonetary poiicy and prudential supervision

The intimate relationship between monetary policy and prudential supervision is another important
rationale for giving the central bank a major supervisory role. As a practical matter, the two are
inseparable. The Federal Reserve is set up as a matrix organization, so it is nearly impossible to say
where one function stops and another starts. This is particularly true of the Federal Reserve Banks, who
bear the day-to-day responsibility of examining and supervising banks. Monetary policy and prudential
supervision are not in siloes, but operate in tandem, sharing knowledge, staff and expertise. And,
because they work together, they are both more effective.

99-65; and Huberto M. Ennis and David A. Price, "Discount Window lending: Policy Trade-oils and the 1985 BoNY
~.9mputer Failure," Economic Brief, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, May 2015.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00128

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.079

6/8

123
Cecchetti

The Relationship between Prudential Supervision and Monetary Policy

Prudential supervision provides important inputs into the monetary policy process. The Federal Reserve
supervises those parts of the banking system that account for nearly all of its assets. This includes
oversight of more than 5,000 holding companies and over 200 foreign banking operations. Through its
access to these financial firms, supervisors naturally learn about the health of the borrowers as well as
that of the lenders. Put differently, the Federal Reserve knows a great deal about what banks are doing,
to whom they are lending, as well as the size and the terms of the loans.
This non public information can be vital for monetary policy. 12 A deep and complete understanding of
the state of the financial markets and institutions, including the terms and conditions under which
borrowers can obtain financing, is critical for the determination of the appropriate monetary policy
stance. That is, the level of the interest rate set by the Federal Open Market Committee depends on
supervisory information.
The events of mid-2008 provide a clear instance when the use of banking system information was
critically important. Inflation was running a quarter of a percentage point above the Fed's 2-percent
objective. A mechanical rule based solely on inflation and unemployment would have dictated that
monetary policymakers raise interest rates to a level exceeding 5 percent. Fortunately, with their
understanding of financial fragilities-gleaned in part from access to supervisory information about the
deteriorating state of the banking sector-the Federal Open Market Committee judged interest rates at
2 percent consistent with inflation and growth prospects. 13 Needless to say, the next few months
provided disastrous, dictating further policy easing, not tightening.
Information and skills also flow from monetary policymakers to prudential supervisors. An assessment
of the safety and soundness of banking institutions requires an understanding of economic prospectssomething that is integral to the formulation of monetary policy. In practice, this means that the
economic and financial outlook is an input into supervisory evaluations. Nowhere is this more apparent
than in the case of stress testing. Stress tests today are the most powerful prudential tool we have for
safeguarding the resilience of the financial system. They take seriously the fact that when a large
common shock hits, there may be no one who will purchase a bank's assets or provide equity capitaL
Ensuring that each systemic intermediary can withstand significant stress raises the likelihood that the
system can survive. And, importantly, by adjusting the scenarios to reflect changing conditions,
prudential authorities ensure that the system remains resilient Formulating stress scenarios requires
both knowledge about how the entire economy operates and a sense of the financial risks that are not
adequately compensated. This is true both for domestic developments, like real estate booms, as well as
those that could come from other parts of the world, like the cyclical downturns of major trading
partners.
In sum, monetary policy and prudential supervision are complementary. Each requires information from
the other. As Paul Volcker put it, the two are inextricably intertwined.

12

See, for example, Joe Peek, Eric S. Rosengren and Geoffrey M.B. Tootell, "l_?~nk Superv]il<?itl:;entral t()_Centraj
Banki_ngj'" Quarterly Journal of Economics, voL 114, no.2, May 1999, pg. 629-653.
See the comments of William Dudley on pages 4 to 8 of the !r_il_nscript of the June 24-25 FOMC meeting.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00129

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.080

7/8

124
Cecchetti

The Relationship between Prudential Supervision and Monetary Policy

Financiai stability and prudential supervision

Finally, there is the relationship between prudential supervision and the maintenance of systemic
stability. The second of these is prudential supervision for the financial system as whole. It is clear that
the central bank is the locus of that responsibility. The Federal Reserve does not have an explicit
financial stability mandate. But it has a powerful, implicit one: without a modicum of financial stability, it
would fail to achieve the statutory objectives of maximum employment, stable prices and moderate
long-term interest rates.
With that in mind, building on the skills of its staff, its day-to-day access to and knowledge of financial
markets, and its supervisory information, the Federal Reserve has created the capacity to monitor the
financial system in order to ensure that both monetary and prudential policy are set in a way that
enhances resilience.

Concluding remarks
I began by asking two questions: should prudential supervisors be operationally independent and should
the central bank be a leading supervisor? My answer to both questions is yes. When supervisors are
independent of political interference, complete with budgetary autonomy, the financial system is more
stable and taxpayer costs are lower. Furthermore, a supervisory function is essential for effective and
efficient execution of core central bank functions. As lender of last resort, the monetary policy authority,
and the guardian of the health and stability of the overall financial system, it is essential that the Federal
Reserve be a leading supervisor, including for systemically important institutions. The American public
would be ill served if any of this were to change.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00130

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.081

8/8

125
Statement of James C. Sivon
On behalf of
The Financial Services Roundtable
Before the
Subcommittee on Monetary Policy and Trade
And the
Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit
Of the
Committee on Financial Services

September 12, 2017

Chairman Barr and Ranking Member Moore, Chairman Luetkemeyer and Ranking
Member Clay, my name is james Sivon, and I am appearing on behalf of the Financial
Services Roundtable (FSR).I FSR is a national trade association for the nation's largest
financial services companies. FSR members provide banking, insurance, payments, and
investment products and services to consumers and businesses.

FSR appreciates the opportunity to address the Federal Reserve Board's (Board)
role as a prudential regulator. FSR members recognize the need for regulations and
supervisory policies that ensure stable financial markets and protect consumers. A decade
ago, gaps in financial regulation and supervision contributed to a financial crisis and a
national recession. Subsequent actions taken by Congress, financial regulators, and the
financial services industry itself have restored the stability of the U.S. financial system.
Today, large bank holding companies have more than doubled their capital from around
$500 billion in 2009 to $1.2 trillion in the first quarter of 2017, and have more than
doubled their risk-based capital ratios from 5.5 percent to 12.4 percent over that period.

1

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00131

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.082

I am appearing in my capacity as an outside counsel to FSR. I am a partner in the law firm of Barnett Sivon &
Natter, P.C., and a counsel with Squire Patton Boggs LLP.

126
The largest bank holding companies also have increased liquid assets from about $1.5
trillion to about $2.3 trillion between 2011 and the first quarter of 2017. 2

Yet, experience has shown that some of the regulations and supervisory policies put
in place in response to the financial crisis are holding back a more robust economic
recovery. Loans to mortgage borrowers and small businesses illustrate this problem. The
Urban Institute has estimated that over 5 million consumers were unable to obtain a
mortgage loan between 2009 and 2014 because of a combination of new regulatory
requirements and increased litigation risks faced by lenders and investors. 3 Other studies
have found that since the financial crisis small businesses have suffered low rates of
formation and tepid growth due, in part, to regulations that make it difficult for small
businesses, especially those with limited credit histories, to obtain credit. 4

A recent analysis of post-crisis lending by large bank holding companies supports

these findings. That analysis, which was conducted by the economic research division of
the Board, found that, while bank lending has been robust for the past three years, lending
growth by more heavily regulated large banks (those with more than $50 billion in assets)
Jags lending growth by smaller banks. 5

FSR believes that the goal of prudential regulation and supervision should be to
promote both financial stability and economic growth. FSR appreciates the steps the Board
already has taken to tailor some prudential standards and supervisory policies. Last year,
for example, the Board revised the rules governing capital planning and stress testing for

2

jerome H. Powell, Member Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, before the Committee on
Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs U.S. Senate, june 22, 2017.
Bin Bai, Laurie Goodman and jun Zhu, Tight Credit Standards Prevented S.Z Million Mortgages Between 2009
and 2014, Urban Institute (Jan. 28, 2016).
4 Federal Reserve Banks, 2016 Srnallllusiness Credit Survey, (Apr. 2017), https:/hvww.newyorkfed.org/
medialibrary/media/smallbusiness/2016/SBCS·Report·EmployerFirrns-2016.pdf. See also Amanda Hindlian,
Sandra Lawson, Katherine Maxwell, Koby Sadan, and Sonya Banerjee, The Two Speed Economy, Goldman
Sachs Global Markets Institute (Apr. 2015).
'Cindy M. Vojtech, Post-Crisis Lending by Large Bank Holding Companies, FEDS Notes (July 6, 2017),
https: I !www.fed cralrescrve.gov! ceo nres /notes I feds· notes /post-crisis·! en ding· by -large·ba nk. hoi ding·
companies·20170706.htm.
3

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00132

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.083

2

127
bank holding companies defined as "large, non-complex" institutions. 6 More recently, the
Board has proposed changes in its supervisory policies related to boards of directors, and,
in conjunction with the other federal banking agencies, the Board has proposed some
refinements to the Basel Ill capital rules. However, more can be done to tailor existing
regulations.

The first part of my testimony highlights several proposed reforms to existing
prudential standards and supervisory policies that would enable FSR members to meet the
financial needs of consumers and businesses while preserving financial stability. The
proposed reforms are taken from a larger set of proposed reforms FSR recently submitted
to the Treasury Department.7 The second part of my testimony makes three general
recommendations for financial regulatory reform.

I.

FSR's Recommendations Related to Specific Regulations and Supervisory
Policies Administered by the Board
The Dodd-Frank Act gave the Board authority to implement prudential standards

for large bank holding companies and nonbank financial companies designated by the
Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC) for supervision by the Board. My testimony
addresses the standards related to: capital planning and stress testing; capital and liquidity
requirements; resolution planning and recovery requirements; the prudential standards
applicable to insurance companies supervised by the Board; model validation and vendor
management guidance. It also addresses the Volcker Rule.

The Capital Planning and Stress Testing Rules Should be Adjusted

6

Under the Federal Reserve's Final Rule this includes institutions with average total consolidated assets
between $50 billion and $250 billion and that have average total nonbank assets ofless than $75 billion.
7 That submission, which includes over 100 recommendations, was made in response to Executive Order
13772, which directed the Department to conduct an assessment of the extent to which the regulation of the
U.S. financial system is consistent with a set of Core Principles set out in the Order. A copy of that submission
may be found at the following Internet address: bJ;!:p..JL.wwlJ!.fsroulJ.9J;;JJ:>)e.org/-,yQ:
content/uploads /20 17/06/FSR·Letter·to-Treasury-on-Core-Principles· May· 3.pdf.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00133

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.084

3

128
The comprehensive capital analysis review (CCAR) and stress testing rules are
among the most impactful rules adopted since the crisis. Those rules have helped FSR
members build stronger capital positions and address risk management weaknesses that
contributed to the crisis. As time has passed, however, it is increasingly apparent that the
rules can be adjusted without impairing their fundamental purpose.

The General Accountability Office (GAO) has recommended several adjustments to
the capital planning and stress testing rules that are designed to increase the transparency
of these rules. 8 As GAO noted in that report, transparency is a key feature of accountability
and incomplete disclosure may limit understanding of the stress test results and hinder
public and market confidence in the program. FSR supports many of the GAO's proposed
reforms.

FSR also supports more disclosure regarding the modeling principles used in the
Board's stress testing formulas and the full disclosure of the Board's supervisory models
after a reasonable delay 9 FSR members find significant disparities between their own
internal evaluations of risk and the loss projections predicted by the models used by the
Board. This creates a level of uncertainty around the process that can impact lending
decisions. It leads companies to make assumptions about the Board's models and then
adjust their loan portfolio to conform to those assumptions in order to meet their capital
8

GAO, Additional Actions Could Help Ensure the Achievement ofStress Test Goals, (Nov. 15, 2016). (The
recommendations made in this report include the following: (1) The Board, FDIC, and OCC should harmonize
their agencies' approach to granting extensions and exemptions from stress test requirements; (2) The Board
should publicly disclose additional information that would allow for a better understanding of the
methodology for completing qualitative assessments, such as the role of ratings and rankings and the extent
to which they affect final determination decisions; (3) The Board should assess-and adjust as necessarythe overall level of severity of its severely adverse scenario by establishing a process to facilitate proactive
consideration of levels of severity that may fall outside U.S. postwar historical experience, and expanding
consideration of the trade-offs associated with different degrees of severity; (4) The Board should assess
whether a single severe supervisory scenario is sufficient to inform CCAR decisions and promote the
resilience of the banking system; (5) The Board should develop a process to test its proposed severely
adverse scenario for pro-cyclicality annually before finalizing and publicly releasing the supervisory
scenarios; and (6) The Board should improve management of model risk and ensure decisions based on
supervisory stress test results are informed by an understanding of model risk.)
9 Alternatively, the Federal Reserve could establish a process by which banks could meet individually with the
Board's staff in Washington, D.C. to discuss concerns regarding the outputs of Federal Reserve models. At a
minimum these discussions would allow banks to learn if discrepancies are being driven by specific model
assumptions or because of specific model factors that are being used by the Federal Reserve.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00134

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.085

4

129
requirements. More transparency surrounding the Board's models would reduce this
uncertainty and help to ensure that the Board's CCAR practices do not discourage
appropriate lending activities.

As I have noted, the Board recently revised the capital planning and stress testing
rules for large, non-complex bank holding companies. Under the revised rules, the Board
will assess a company's risk management practices as part of the Board's normal
supervisory process, rather than in conjunction with the capital planning and stress testing
process. In other words, the Board will not object to a company's capital plan based upon a
company's compliance with "qualitative" standards. In proposing this change, the Board
stated that it was designed to ensure that companies did not "over-invest in stress testing
and capital planning processes that are unnecessary to adequately capture the risk of these
firms."lO FSR recommends that the Board expand this treatment to all bank holding
companies, regardless of size, based upon the ongoing supervision that occurs onsite and
offsite at these institutions. 11

Additionally, capital planning and stress testing standards is an area where greater
coordination between regulators is needed. While the Board has changed its policies
regarding qualitative assessments, the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) has
retained enhanced documentation and disclosure standards that conflict with the Board's
attempt to reduce the regulatory burden requirements entailed in the annual capital
planning process. FSR recommends that the OCC modify its policies to be consistent with
those adopted by the Board.

Finally, FSR recommends that the Board revise its rules governing capital
distributions outside of the capital planning cycle. Under current rules, a company may
make capital distributions outside of the capital planning cycle only if those distributions

81 Fed. Reg. 67241 (Sept 30, 2016).
Notably, the Board has recently proposed a new rating system for large institutions that will include a
specific rating for capital planning obviating the need for a separate measure as part of the CCAR process. 82
Fed. Reg. 39049 (Aug. 17, 2017).
1o

11

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00135

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.086

5

130
meet a de minimis standard or the company obtains special permission from the Board. If a
company has successfully passed a stress test, FSR believes the company should have the
ability to manage its own capital position and distribute excess capital in situations where
its performance surpasses the projections embedded in its earlier capital plan.

Tailor the Capital Rules and Liquidity Rules

Recent stress test results show that bank holding companies subject to CCAR can
withstand an economic downturn comparable to the financial crisis in 2007-2008.12 These
results indicate that we have reached a point where the capital and liquidity rules could be
adjusted to promote economic growth, without jeopardizing financial stability. Toward that
end, FSR recommends:

•

Adjust the Supplemental Leverage Ratio- Banking regulators should revise the
calculation of the supplementary leverage ratio to exclude risk-free assets from the
calculation of a company's total assets for purposes of the ratio. This would include
reserves held at the Federal Reserve, cash, and Treasury securities. This change
would free funds to enable banks to offer products, such as derivatives clearing and
securities financing agreements that both support financial stability and foster
economic growth. The Bank of England recently exempted cash deposits held at the
central bank from its calculation of the leverage ratio 13 Similarly, FSR recommends
that the Board eliminate the "enhanced" SLR requirement for the nation's largest
banking organizations.14 The current U.S. requirements double international
standards and create a competitive disparity for U.S. banking organizations.

Revise the Capital Surcharge

FSR recommends that the capital surcharge for the

nation's largest banks be aligned with international standards. In implementing the
12 https:

llwww.federalreserve.gov /publications /files/201 7 -dfast-methodology-results-20 l70622.pdf.
"Bank of England, Financial Policy Committee Statement from its Policy Committee Meeting (July 25, 2016),

brtp.JJ_w.\"'":lld:wnkofiT!Jlli!nd&QJJk/.!lli.blications/Document~..w.>fl.QJ.6J062.pdf.

14 The enhanced SLR requires these companies to meet a 5% SLR at the holding company level and
at the bank level. The standard included in Basel III is 3%.

a 6% SLR

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00136

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.087

6

131
capital surcharge for U.S. banking organizations, the Board adopted an additional
requirement (called "method 2") for the nation's largest bank holding companies
that imposes a surcharge beyond the international standard. The internationally
accepted G-SIB surcharge framework produces a risk score derived from a firm's
attributes in five categories: size, interconnectedness, complexity, cross
jurisdictional activity, and substitutability. Method 2 replaces the substitutability
category with a measure of a firm's reliance on short-term wholesale funding. While
FSR appreciates the risks associated with overdependence on short-term wholesale
funding, these risks are already accounted for in the 30-day liquidity coverage ratio,
new rules requiring the issuance of minimum levels of unsecured debt, and the
Dodd-Frank Act enhanced prudential standards 30-day liquidity stress test. This
change would help large U.S. bank holding companies remain competitive with
foreign firms in domestic and foreign markets.

•

Expand the Scope of High-Quality Liquid Assets (HQLA) under the Liquidity RuleFSR recommends that the Board (and other federal banking agencies) adjust the
treatment of mortgage securities, municipal securities, FHLB obligations, and
securities issued by governments sponsored entities (GSEs) such as Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac in the liquidity coverage ratio (LCR). The LCR requires a banking
organization to hold enough high quality assets to cover a net outflow of cash over a
30 day period. The final rule defines three categories of high quality assets, Ievell,
level 2A and level 28. Level 2A and 28 assets are subject to haircuts of 15 and 50
percent respectively. Currently, however, most municipal securities and private
mortgage backed securities are not treated as high quality liquid assets, and FHLB
and GSE obligations are treated as level 2A assets, subject to a 15 percent haircut.
This is despite the fact that there are highly-liquid markets for each of these
obligations, and including them in the category of high quality liquid assets would
reduce reliance on Treasury securities.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00137

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.088

7

132
Revise the Outflow Assumptions in the Liquidity Rule- FSR recommends that the
Board (and other federal banking agencies) revise the run-offassumptions in the
LCR. The calculation of net cash outflows under the LCR rule is overly conservative
and should be aligned with the international LCR requirements or be adjusted to
better match the conditions experienced by failing banks in the most recent
financial crisis. Appropriate changes include: (1) eliminating the maturity mismatch
add-on component of the US LCR calculation and instead use cumulative net cash
outflow amounts over the 30-day assumed stress period to address maturity
mismatches; and (2) allowing net cash outflows to be calculated on the final
business day of every month instead of daily. Additionally, the agencies should
modify cash outflow rates and assumptions. For example, the final U.S. LCR rules
provide for 0% liquidity value for non-operating deposits and excess operational
deposits of financial institutions. This assumption does not take into account the
wide range of regulated financial companies and observed historical behaviors
during times of stress.
Coordinate Resolution and Recovery Planning Requirements

Resolution planning has helped FSR members rationalize operations and contracts
and put in place plans to respond to financial distress. Yet, this requirement, combined with
separate recovery planning requirements, is an area where greater coordination among the
agencies is needed.

The Dodd-Frank Act requires all bank holding companies with more than $50 billion
in assets to submit periodic resolution plans to the Board and the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC). Using its general authority to issue regulations under the
Federal Deposit Insurance Act, the FDIC has issued a companion rule that requires insured
banks with more than $50 billion in assets to submit annual resolution plans. 1s The Board
and the OCC separately have also required institutions under their supervision to develop
15

Resolution Plans Required for Insured Depository Institutions with $50 Billion or More in Total Asset,, Fed.
Reg. 3075 (Jan. 23, 2012) (codified at 12 C.F.R. pt. 360).

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00138

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.089

8

133
recovery plans that map actions the company may take to remain a going concern when
experiencing financial or operational distress.1 6 FSR recommends that the Board, FDIC and
OCC align these requirements so materials developed for one purpose could be
incorporated by reference into other filings.

FSR also recommends that the reporting cycle for resolution plans required under
the Dodd-Frank Act and the FDIC's rule for insured depository institutions be moved to a
two-year cycle rather than annually. This step could be taken at the sole discretion of the
Board in tandem with the FDIC. It is increasingly evident that these annual requirements
are neither efficient nor effective for both regulators and covered firms. For firms,
resolution plans do not change substantially from year to year, absent a material change in
a firm's structure. Regnlators, in turn, have been hard pressed to provide feedback on plans
under the current annual cycle.

Tailor Prudential Standards for Insurance Companies

As a result of the Dodd-Frank Act, the Board gained regulatory and supervisory
authority over insurance companies that operate as savings and loan holding companies
(SHLCs) as well as insurance companies designated by FSOC for supervision by the Board.
While the Board has indicated a willingness to consider the unique characteristics of the
business of insurance through tailored rulemaking, FSR believes the Board could be more
attentive to the differences between the business of insurance and banking.

For example, in 2011, shortly after it assumed authority for SHLCs, the Board
indicated that it would supervise SLHCs in a manner consistent with its approach to
supervising bank holding companies while taking into account any unique characteristics
of SLHCs.J7 Since then, however, the Board has issued numerous supervisory letters

16 The Board's rules apply to the nation's largest eight bank holding companies, and the OCC's rules apply to
all national banks with more than $50 billion in assets.
17 Federal Reserve, SR 11·11: Supervision of Savings and Loan llo/ding Companies (July 21, 2011),
l:J.tt!ls: //www.fcderalrcserve.gov /supervision rep /sri etters /srllll.pdf.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00139

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.090

9

134
applicable to SLHCs that do not specifically address how they should be applied to SLHCs
with substantial insurance operations.1 8 Such guidance should be better tailored to
insurance SLHCs.

Additionally, last year, the Board invited comment on two different capital
standards for the insurance companies it regulates: a "building block" approach (BBA) for
insurance companies that are SHLCs and a "consolidated" approach (CA) for the insurance
companies that have been designated by FSOC for supervision by the Board. FSR believes
the BBA should be applied to all insurers supervised by the Board, not just SHLCs. The BRAbased framework offers a uniform and effective approach that effectively accounts for the
various activities and risks of the different legal entities within a covered insurance group.
It leverages existing standards that have already been vetted, tailored, and calibrated to the
business of insurance by state insurance authorities. It also minimizes any disparate
impacts that could arise from pursuing different approaches to capital for different types of
insurance companies.

Review Model Validation and Vendor Management Standards

During the past several years, the Board (and other federal banking agencies) has
increased supervisory attention on model validation19 and vendor management.zo FSR
appreciates that these practices deserve supervisory oversight, since both impact an

13 SR 14-9 extended nearly 120 prior SR letters to SLHCs without any differentiation for insurance companies
that are SLHCs. Federal Reserve. SR 14-9: Incorporation of Federal Reserve Policies into the Saving and Loan
Holding Company Supervision Program (Nov. 7, 2014), h!!il£Lb~ww.federal!:e~erve.go.YL
supervision reg/srlette rs /sr1409 .pdf
19 See Federal Reserve, SR 11-7: Supervisory Guidance on Model Risk Management (Apr. 4, 2011),
https: //www.federalreserve.gov /bankinforeg/srletters /sr1107.htm
20 See OCC, Risk Management Guidance, OCC Bulletin 2013·29 (Oct. 30, 2103), bltp.JL\,\1_\VW.occ.treas.govjJ]_t;wsissuances/bulletins/2013/bulletin-2013- 29.html; Federal Reserve, Board Supervisory Letter 13-19 and
Guidance on Managing Outsourcing Risk (Dec. 5, 2013),
https:/lwww.federalreserve.gov /bankinforeg/srletters/srl319al.pdf: FDIC, Guidance For Managing ThirdParty Risk, Financial institutions Letter44-2008
(2008),https: 1/vvww.fdic.gov /news/news/financial/2008/fil08044a.html; NCUA, Evaluating Third Party
Relationships, NCUA Supervisory Letter 07-01 (Oct 2007)
https: l/www.ncua.gov /resources/documents/]cu2007 -13enc.pdf and FFl EC. Handbook on Outsourcing
Technology Services, http: I /ithandbook.ffiec.gov /it-booklets /outsourcing-technology-services.aspx.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00140

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.091

10

135
organization's operations, and potentially its reputation. However, in both cases, we
believe that it is time to reassess existing standards and requirements.

Model validation should be limited to models that have a material impact on an
organization. Current guidance, however, often requires firms to justify and validate noncritical analysis tools or develop and monitor models for activities that are highly
subjective, such as BSA/ AML compliance. 21 Notably, this guidance is in tension with other
supervisory letters directing banks to establish risk management processes that are
tailored to their individual needs.2 2 To remedy this conflict, FSR recommends that the
Board and OCC revise their current supervisory guidance related to model risk.

Similarly, vendor management requirements are inadvertently causing firms to only
rely on larger vendors, resulting in an increasing concentration of vendor risk. FSR
recommends that the Board (and other federal banking agencies) review current guidance
to provide some flexibility for financial institutions to engage with vendors that undergo
due diligence and are deemed not risky to the institution's customers. 23

Revisit the Volcker Rule

FSR recommends that the federal financial regulators revisit the Volcker Rule.
During the comment period on the Volcker Rule, many commenters asserted that the Rule
would impair liquidity in the nation's capital markets. That concern since has been
documented in an analysis of liquidity in the corporate debt markets conducted by

21

SR 11-7. Federal Reserve Supervisory Assessment of Capital Planning and Positions for Large and
Noncomplex Firms (Dec. 18, 2015), https: //www.fcdcralrcservc.gov /supervisionreg/srlettcrs I
sr1519_PW.pdf.
22 Sec, Federal Reserve, SR 1 S-19
OCC Bulletin 2013·29 (http://www.occ.treas.gov/news·issuances/bullclins/2013/bulletin·2013-29.html];
FRB Supervisory Letter 13-19 and Guidance on Managing Outsourcing Risk
(https: //www.federjlirescrve.gov /bankinforeg/srlet_tgrusrl319al.pd0; FDIC Financial Institutions Letter
44-2008
(ht:tJl>;JLW'.YW.fqkgQtiJlfwSLn!Cl'>'SffiJJ<>Illlil!L2008_]([108Q_1'1i1html); NCUA Supervisory Letter 07·01
(https: //www.ncua.gov /resources /documents/lcu2007 -l3enc.pd0; and FFIEC Handbook on Outsourcing
Techno logy Services (http: I fi thand book. ffi ec.gov I it-booklets I outsourcing· technology- scrviccs.il2PK).

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00141

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.092

II

136
economists at the Board.2 1 Additionally, several Governors on the Federal Reserve Board
have acknowledged that the Rule is overly complex and should be reviewed.Z 5

As part of a review of the Volcker Rule, FSR recommends that:

The Rule be tailored by exempting institutions that score below a certain threshold
on the "complexity" and "interconnectedness" indicators within the systemic
indicator framework;

The scope of the covered fund prohibitions in the Rule be amended or reinterpreted
to limit the definition of covered fund only to Section 3(c)( 1) or Section 3(c)( 7)
funds that engage in prohibited proprietary trading. This would achieve the goal of
prohibiting indirect, impermissible proprietary trading through investment in a
covered fund and limiting banking entities from bailing out sponsored covered
funds, while preserving safety and soundness and without sweeping in core asset
management, ordinary corporate structures, securitizations and related activities
that were not meant to be restricted by the Volcker Rule;

•

The prohibition on proprietary trading be adjusted not to reach client-oriented
activities. The Rule does not clearly define proprietary trading, and such ambiguity
forced dealers toward more conservative trading strategies, leading to less liquid
markets. For example, the current prohibition captures certain asset-liability
management activities and Treasury functions. To address this, we recommend that

24 jack Bao, Maureen O'Hara, and Alex Zhou. The Volcker Rule and Market-Making in Times o[Stress, Financial
and Economics Discussion Series (2016).
25 See, Departing Thoughts, Remarks hy Daniel K. Tarullo, Member Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System at The Woodrow Wilson School Princeton University Princeton, New jersey April4, 2017, (" .... several
years of experience have convinced me that there is merit in the contention of many firms that, as it has been
drafted and implemented, the Volcker rule is too complicated.") See also, Remarks by jerome H. Powell,
Member Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Salzburg Global Seminar Salzburg, Austria june
26, 2017 ("In our view, there is room for eliminating or relaxing aspects of the implementing regulation in
ways that do not undermine the Volckcr rule's main policy goals.")

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00142

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.093

12

137
the prohibition be revised to focus on trading activities that are wholly unrelated to
financial intermediation, risk management, or asset/liability management;

•

The agencies should reverse the presumption in the Volcker Rule's regulation of
short-term trading. The regulation currently presumes that a position held for 60
days or less is proprietary trading. Instead, any security or derivative held longer
than 60 days should be presumed not to be proprietary trading (i.e., not in a Volcker
trading account under the Rule). Further, any security or derivative not held in a
broker-dealer or swap dealer desk, or not subject to market risk capital rules (or
their equivalent under applicable regulations), should be presumed to be excluded
from a Volcker trading account; and

•

Banking institutions with assets of $50 billion or more not be required
automatically to meet standards for "enhanced compliance programs." While these
safeguards may be appropriate for some firms, the use of an arbitrary asset-based
threshold does not distinguish between companies with extensive trading portfolios
and covered activities and those with simple investment activities used solely for
traditional asset liability management. The regulators should amend the Rule to
replace the $50 billion asset threshold with a threshold that accounts for a
company's activities and risk profile.

II.

FSR's General Recommendations

In addition to the foregoing recommendations, FSR has three general
recommendations for aligning financial regulations and supervisory policies with economic
growth. These recommendations apply broadly to all federal financial regulatory agencies.
They are: (1) to base prudential standards on an assessment of risk rather than the size of
an institution; (2) to improve policy coordination among all federal financial regulatory
agencies; and (3) to conduct an assessment of the impact of the Current Expected Credit
Loss (CECL) accounting standard on lending and economic growth.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00143

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.094

13

138
Prudential Standards should be Based upon an Assessment of an Institution's Risk, Not
Size

Currently, many of the prudential regulations imposed on financial firms are based
upon the size of an institution, not the risk it may pose to financial stability. For example,
heightened prudential standards apply to all bank holding companies with more than $50
billion in assets and all nonbank financial companies designated by the FSOC for
supervision by the Federal Reserve Board (Board); stress tests apply to any bank holding
company with more than $10 billion in assets; and the federal banking agencies have
established other supervisory standards based upon a $250 billion threshold that was
incorporated in the Basel capital framework over a decade ago.

Such fixed dollar thresholds result in "cliff' effects for institutions near the
thresholds. These effects cause institutions to take actions simply designed to avoid the
thresholds, including not undertaking new business opportunities that could contribute to
economic growth. Similarly, institutions that cross a threshold suddenly find themselves in
a new supervisory category that carries substantial compliance costs, even though their
risk profile has not changed.

To overcome these problems, FSR recommends that prudential standards be based
upon an assessment of the risk posed by the operations and activities of a company, not
just a company's asset size. 26 Asset size could be used as a factor in such an assessment, but
should not be the determinative factor_27 Regulators could also develop an approach under
which a company that crosses an asset threshold is subject to a risk analysis to determine
whether the company should be subject to a particular prudential standard. This approach
also would allow regulators to impose prudential standards on institutions that may be
below an asset threshold but pose some risk based upon their mix of activities.

26 Making these changes requires a combination of actions by Congress and federal regulators. Several of the
current asset thresholds were established in the Dodd-Frank Act. Others, such as the $250 billion threshold,
have been set by the federal banking agencies under their general regulatory authority and can be changed
under the same process.
27 We note that information on a variety of systemic risk indicators, which could be used for such a
calculation, is already provided to the Federal Reserve via the FR-Y 15 form,

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00144

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.095

14

139
FSR is not alone in calling for prudential standards to be based upon risk rather than
size. It is now widely accepted that risk-based criteria provide a better measure of risk than
an exclusive reliance on asset size.zs Think tanks 29 and even members of the Board 30 have
called for either raising asset thresholds or replacing them with a risk assessment. FSR
further supports the bipartisan framework set out in H.R. 3312, the "Systemic Risk
Designation lmprovement Act of 2017." We thank Chairman Luetkemeyer and other
committee members for their work on this issue and pledge our support to your continued
efforts in this area.

Greater Coordination Among Federal Financial Regulatory Agencies is Needed

FSR members are subject to regulation and supervision by multiple federal
regulatory agencies. While each of these agencies has its own statutory mission, those
missions can overlap and conflict. This results in a misallocation of resources by regulators
and regulated firms, and increases the cost of financial products and services to consumers
and businesses. Greater coordination among federal financial regulators would help to
make financial regulation more predictable, reduce regulatory gaps, and minimize
regulatory conflict that can impair economic growth.

Some of the regulatory and supervisory policies addressed in this statement
illustrate this overlap and conflict. Other areas where greater coordination is needed
include examination practices, reporting requirements, 31 and cybersecurity standards.

zs Aite Group, Bank Size vs. Systemic Importance (Oct. 2015), http: l/www.fsroundtable.org/wpcontent/upioads /201 S /10 /Gank-Size-vs-Systemic-lmpor@.ni:e.Aite-Group-Study Fl NAL Oct.ober-19- 20 1.5.,j;;Q[
"llipartisan Policy Center, Dodd-Frank's Missed Opportunity: A Road Map for a More Effective Regulatory
Architecture (Apr. 2014 ), h.l:1!l.>.iLbillartisanpolicy.org/library/dodd-franks-missed-o!lllOrtunity-road-mapmore-effective- regulatory -architecture-2/.
:;o Departing Thoughts, Remarks by Daniel K. Tarullo, Member lloard of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System at The Woodrow Wilson School Princeton University Princeton, New jersey April 4, 2017, (" ... l have
said for several years now, we have found that the $50 billion in assets threshold established in the DoddFrank Act for banks to be "systemically important," and thus subject to a range of stricter regulations, was set
too low. Similarly, the $10 billion asset threshold for banks to conduct their own required stress tests seems
too low.")
31
FSR has submitted a letter to the Office of Financial Research cataloging some of the overlap in existing

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00145

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.096

15

140
Enhancing coordination among federal financial regulators does not require a
wholesale restructuring of those agencies. federal financial regulators have the ability to
coordinate policies and practices, but Jack a clear directive to do so. This problem could be
resolved through the enactment of a statutory set of guiding principles for federal financial
regulators. Once embodied in Jaw, these principles would serve as a touchstone against
which all future financial regulations and supervisory practices could be evaluated.
Statutory guiding principles encourage federal financial regulators to coordinate policies
and practices without diminishing their independent missions. The Core Principles in
Executive Order 13772 could serve as a model for statutory principles.

FSOC also is positioned to facilitate greater policy coordination among federal
financial regulators. Absent the enactment of a set of guiding principles for financial
regulation and supervision, FSR urges the Committee to use the required annual hearing on
the FSOC's activities to promote regulatory and supervisory coordination among the
members of FSOC.

The Impact ofCECL on Lending Should Be Evaluated

The Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) has finalized an accounting
standard that fundamentally alters the manner in which banks must reserve for loan losses.
Rather than establishing a reserve when a loss is likely to be incurred, the Current
Expected Credit Loss, or CECL standard, requires banks to estimate expected losses when a
loan is made.

This change is intended to increase financial stability and improve liquidity
throughout economic cycles. However, FSR members are concerned that the new standard

reporting requirements for large banking organizations. Letter to Richard Berner, Director of the Office of
Financial Research from the Financial Services Roundtable (Mar. 22, 2017), )ltJ:p:jjl'\'}l!.W.fsroundtable_,p.r,g
/wp-content/uploads/2017/09/FSR SUBMISSION TO OrR ON DUPLICATIVE DATA REQUESTS.v3.0.
final .pdf.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00146

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.097

16

141
could reduce lending in recessionary periods (i.e., be pro-cyclical), and generally reduce
lending to certain types of loans, such as mortgage loans and small business loans. An
earlier analysis of the impact of the new standard performed by the Office of the
Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) estimated that CECL would require national banks to
increase loss reserves by as mucb as 30% to 50% over current levels.32

The implementation of CECL presents immense operational challenges. In setting a
loss reserve an institution must take into consideration economic conditions not only when
the loan is made, but throughout the entire term of the loan. Thus, CECL is premised on an
institution's ability to accurately forecast future economic conditions over a period of
decades. Making such forecasts can be challenging and could greatly impact the availability
of long-term lending products such as a 30-year mortgage.

The CECL standard is scheduled to be effective for public companies, including bank
holding companies, starting December 2019, and for other companies starting in December
2020. Before this standard goes into effect, FSR recommends policymakers conduct a
comprehensive assessment of its potential impact on lending and economic growth. This
assessment should include an evaluation of the relationship between loan loss reserves and
capital requirements. In other words, if CECL goes into effect as proposed, consideration
should be given to counting an institution's loss reserve as part of its common equity Tier 1
capital, since both are designed to enable an institution to continue to operate throughout
economic cycles.3:J
:;z Curry, Thomas]. "Remarks by Thomas]. Curry, Comptroller of the Currency, Before the AI CPA Banking

Conference, Washington, D.C." September 16, 2013.
The FDIC's Risk Management Examination Manual states that one of the fundamental purposes of capital is
to enable an institution lo continue operating as going concerns during periods when operating losses or
other adverse financial results are experienced. (https: l/www.fdic.gov /regulations/safety/manual /section2.L!l.<lQ The Financial Accounting Standards Board similarly states that CECL will enable an institution to
operate in all economic conditions: "The new standard requires an organization to measure all expected
credit losses for financial assets held at the reporting date based on historical experience, current conditions,
and reasonable and supportable forecasts."
(lll.\Jl.J/www.fasb.org/cs/ContentServer?c=Document C&pagename-FASB%2FDocument C%£[DocumgntPa
ge&cid= 1176168232790.)

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00147

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.098

17

142
II.

Conclusion

Thank you again for the opportunity to address the Federal Reserve Board's role as

pprudential regulator. I would be pleased to answer any questions.

VerDate Nov 24 2008

18:46 Jul 17, 2018

Jkt 029541

PO 00000

Frm 00148

Fmt 6601

Sfmt 6601

K:\DOCS\29541.TXT

TERI

29541.099

0