View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

The Economy in Perspective
Sigmund Freud has said that every normal person, in fact, is only normal on the average. So it is
with business cycles…
Sooner or later, something will throw the U.S.
economy off the brisk growth trajectory it has followed since 1995. Reverberations from the collapse of East Asian economies might do it, despite the apparent durability of the U.S. until
now. Or the financial sector might seize up,
notwithstanding the as-yet-unshakable support of
stock market investors. Perhaps it will be something more traditional, like tight monetary policy
chasing after accelerating inflation. Whatever the
cause, lately it seems that everyone on the planet
is anxiously awaiting the economy’s return to
normal behavior. Human beings (especially the
economists among them) can tolerate ambiguity
only so long.
Recent statistical reports present an enviable
picture: Output expanded at an annual rate of
5.6% in real terms last quarter, more than double
the pace expected by many forecasters only a
few months before. Job growth continues at a
healthy clip, holding the unemployment rate at
a 28-year low. Never before has such a large
proportion of working-age Americans been
employed. Because consumer prices are barely
increasing, working people continue to enjoy
strong gains in their standard of living. In fact,
consumer sentiment remains so positive that
economy-wide household spending now
matches income, with saving coming only
through increases in the value of assets. What’s
wrong with this picture? Everything! It’s not undesirable, just unjustifiable.
Doubtless the exuberance expressed since
1995 has been unusual. But how many people recall that this beautiful swan of an economy began
its life as an ugly duckling? In the first several
years of the expansion, economic activity’s pace
was feeble in comparison with many previous
expansions. Progress in new job creation
was particularly slow. Federal Reserve Board
Chairman Alan Greenspan acknowledged the
presence of strong “headwinds” that seemed to
be restraining the expansion.
Soon enough, the pace of activity quickened.
Recognizing that the federal funds and discount
rates were set at zero (inflation adjusted), the
Federal Reserve boosted its policy rates about 300
basis points in 1994 and early 1995. By 1996, the
unemployment rate had fallen to 5.5%, a point
that mainstream economists believed was at or
below the level where inflation would accelerate.

Many urged that the Federal Reserve should raise
policy rates to preempt further inflation. Others,
expecting labor compensation’s surge to
precede inflation’s swell, opposed any additional monetary tightening.
Needless to say, inflation did not accelerate.
Indeed, deviating even further from the textbook
script, inflation actually declined as labor markets
strengthened. With each additional ¼% drop in
the unemployment rate below 5½%,warnings
were issued and then proven false. Today, with
employment sitting near 4¼%, labor compensation rates finally have bestirred themselves,
but only slightly. Yet those who preached labor
markets’ usefulness in predicting inflation have
been so thoroughly discredited that few have
strength left for wagging their fingers.
The seemingly inexplicable odyssey of equity
prices has been chronicled many times by now.
True, equity price movements can be explained
through adjustments to standard equity-valuation
models: Capital gains taxes have been lowered
over time, and people accept risk more readily.
But these adjustments are merely rationalizations
after the fact. The reality is that the old norms no
longer provide sufficient guidance.
Some observers regard the economy as surreal
and dwell on its inevitable comeuppance, while
others extoll the glories of a New Age. The first
group, expecting familiar economic relationships
to re-emerge, wants the Fed poised for restraint.
The second, envisioning eternal, inflation-free
expansion, desires a perennially accommodative
monetary policy. Neither faction is likely to
be satisfied.
Monetary policy is a blunt instrument; it cannot
be used to manage the economy’s short-term
behavior precisely. Models based on previous
experience are rough approximations of economic relationships and policy frameworks that
change through time. Business cycle dynamics
are simply tough to pin down and even harder to
generalize. Attempts to smooth out all fluctuations might cause further instability. Appropriate
interventions are those that keep price levels —
and price expectations — stable. But not even a
stable-price policy is an infallible guarantee
against recession.
It stands to reason that monetary policy will
be harder to conduct when established guideposts provide so little direction. Having fewer
guideposts, however, is not the same as having
no destination.

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Growth rates are percentage rates calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis. 1998 growth rates for sweep-adjusted base and M1 calculated
on a November over 1997:IVQ basis.
b. The sweep-adjusted base includes an estimate of required reserves saved when balances are temporarily shifted from reservable to nonreservable accounts.
c. Sweep-adjusted M1 includes an estimate of balances temporarily shifted from M1 to non-M1 accounts.
d. MZM is an alternative measure of money that is equal to M2 plus institutional money market mutual funds less small time deposits.
NOTE: Data are monthly and seasonally adjusted. Last plots for M1, M2, and MZM are estimated for January 1999. Dotted lines for M2 are FOMC-determined
provisional ranges. All other dotted lines represent growth in levels and are for reference only.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

The rate of money growth is a matter of concern because, as Milton
Friedman aptly stated, “inflation is
always and everywhere a monetary
phenomenon.” Sweep-adjusted M1
growth appears to have slowed
slightly last year (5.6% through
November 1998, compared to 6.1%
in 1997). Yet, compared to GDP
growth, even this lower level is
problematic. Although data on
sweep-adjusted M1 growth since
November are not yet available,
non-sweep-adjusted M1 fell 6.2%

from November to December,
much slower than its 1.6% average
increase in 1998. Unless sweep
activity spurted in December,
sweep-adjusted M1 also is likely to
show sharply slower growth. The
broader monetary aggregates, however, showed significantly higher
growth levels in 1998 than did these
narrower aggregates.
For example, two such aggregates, M2 and MZM, registered faster
growth than either base or M1 in
1998. What is more alarming is that

they accelerated sharply from their
1997 growth rates. M2 increased
8.7% last year, far outdistancing its
1997 growth of 5.7% and exceeding
any growth seen since 1995. MZM’s
growth rate for 1998 was even more
robust (14.3%), substantially higher
than its 8.2% growth in 1997. Compared to the GDP’s nominal growth
in 1998 (4.9%), rapid growth in
these aggregates raises fears that the
economy is poised for an increase
in inflation.
(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

NOTE: Data are quarterly and seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census;
and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

In stating that inflation is always
and everywhere a monetary phenomenon, Milton Friedman professed a long-held belief that the
cause of inflation is too much
money chasing too few goods. This
theory has merit in the long run
because velocity remains fairly constant (an exception being a one-time
shift in velocity that occurred in the
early 1990s). Over the short term,
however, inflation may deviate substantially from this prediction.
Increases in both output and
nominal interest rates are associated
with velocity — and thus prices —
over the short run. Yet basing

velocity predictions on movements
in output and interest rates is tricky.
At the end of 1997, for example, actual velocity was more than 2%
higher than would have been predicted from output and interest rates
alone. If these money-demand or
velocity errors were largely selfcorrecting, actual velocity would
tend to return to its predicted level.
This would mean that today’s velocity errors could help predict inflation
four quarters from now. The 2% difference between actual and predicted velocity levels at the end of
1997 implies that inflation was about
1% lower than it otherwise would

have been at the end of 1998. Given
that actual and predicted velocity
levels have now converged, this
suggests that inflation may tick up
about 1% over 1999.
Short-term interest rates rose
sharply at year’s end. The weekly
average 1-year and 3-month T-bill
rates exceeded 4.5% in the weeks
ending December 25, 1998 and
January 1, 1999. These changes represent increases of 35 and 52 basis
points from the final week of October for the 3-month and 1-year
T-bills, respectively. To a lesser degree, longer-term interest rates also
(continued on next page)

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Constant maturity.
b. Bond Buyer Index, general obligation, 20 years to maturity, mixed quality.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

increased over the same period.
State and local bonds with a 20-year
maturity and the 30-year Treasury
both increased roughly 10 basis
points in December 1998. Conventional mortgage rates held fairly stable at a low level.
Recent interest rate movements
could reflect weakness in consumer
loans, which shrank almost 0.5% in
1998. Commercial and industrial
loans, however, were far more robust, having grown slightly more
than 8.25% in 1998. As Chairman
Greenspan observed in his State of
the Economy testimony before the
House Ways and Means Committee

on January 20, 1999, “there is
decided softness in a number of
manufacturing industries,” which
he attributed to foreign developments. He concluded by saying that,
“with corporations already relying
increasingly on borrowing to
finance capital investment, any evidence of a marked slowing in
corporate cash flow is likely to
induce a relatively prompt review
of capital budgets.”
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) did not change either the discount rate (4.5%) or the
target funds rate (4.75%) at its February meeting. In the near term,

market participants seem to anticipate no movement in the federal
funds rate target. In early February,
they predicted that the June 1999
funds rate would be 4.81%, which is
nearly identical to its current level.
A look at implied yields on federal funds futures four weeks prior
to FOMC meetings shows that market participants did not foresee the
policy easing that occurred at the
FOMC’s September 29 meeting.
Until then, the market had expected
the funds rate to remain fairly
constant. Just after the largely unforeseen intermeeting policy easing
(continued on next page)

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Predicted rates are federal funds futures.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and the Chicago Board of Trade.

of October 16, the market began to
anticipate future rate cuts, looking
for a further funds rate reduction of
more than 75 basis points by March.
Subsequently, expectations of further target rate cuts decreased
steadily, and by November 16 the
market was anticipating the rate cut
of 25 basis points that transpired the
next day with little indication of any
future easing. Since then, the market
has anticipated that the funds rate
would continue trading near its
current 4.75% target.
The fed funds futures market is
not a perfect tool for predicting the
precise timing of policy changes. It

is, however, a reasonable indicator
of the average future federal funds
rate. A plot showing predictions
with one- and three-month lead
times, along with the actual federal
funds rate, shows that when the rate
is rising (that is, when policy is tightening), predictions tend to err on
the high side. The opposite occurs
when the rate is falling. Overall, the
futures series follow the actual funds
rate reasonably well.
The federal funds rate chosen by
the FOMC is a target rate. Reserves
are added to or drained from the
system on a daily (Monday through
Friday) basis in order to achieve this

target. Misses from the target rate
generally tend to be quite small,
averaging one-tenth of a percentage
point in 1998. The miss in the last
week of 1998 was unusually large
(45 basis points) but it was shortlived, since the rate hit the target
straight on just one week later. That
big December miss was probably
the product of many factors, including recent longer-term repurchase
operations by the trading desk,
doubts associated with the introduction of the euro, and the notorious
seasonal uncertainty that occurs at
the end of every year.

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Interest Rates

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. The spread between the 3-month Eurodollar deposit rate and the 3-month Treasury-bill rate.
b. Shaded areas indicate recessions.
c. 10-year, 3-month spread lagged four quarters.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, statistical releases.

The yield curve remains rather flat,
having shown little movement since
last month. At the long end, rates
on 30-year bonds increased a scant
six basis points; at the short end,
three-month rates dropped three
basis points.
The introduction of the euro, heralded by some as the dawn of a
new era, was decried by others as a
doomed experiment. By one measure, the Treasury-to-Eurodollar
(TED) spread, the experiment
seems a success. The spread continued its downward trend from its

peak of 109 basis points in October,
a sign that the flight to quality, so
evident after the turmoil in Russia
and East Asia, was slowing. Now, at
44 basis points, the spread has returned to its pre-crisis level. This
seems to indicate that the market, at
least, did not believe that the euro
placed any unbearable strains upon
the European banking system.
One classic application uses
spreads in the yield curve to predict
future economic activity. In the simplest approach, a yield-curve inversion signals a recession; more gener-

ally, the size of the spread provides
information about future growth.
The standard story here is that the
10-year, 3-month spread predicts
growth over the next four quarters.
Since late 1995, however, this relationship has become suspect because a relatively flat yield curve has
persisted in the face of robust
growth. The spread currently stands
at 20 basis points, historically a
rather low number, though recent
experience suggests it may not be a
cause for great concern.

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
December Price Statistics
Percent change, last:
1 mo.a

3 mo.a 12 mo.

5 yr.a

1997
avg.

Consumer prices
All items

1.5

2.2

1.6

2.4

1.7

Less food
and energy

3.5

2.5

2.5

2.6

2.2

Median b

2.4

2.4

2.7

2.9

2.9

4.7

1.9

–0.2

1.1

–1.2

12.3

4.8

2.4

1.4

0

Producer prices
Finished goods
Less food
and energy

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
c. Upper and lower bounds for CPI inflation path as implied by the central tendency growth ranges issued by the FOMC and nonvoting Reserve Bank presidents.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland.

Retail price increases remained generally modest in December, as the
Consumer Price Index (CPI) increased an annualized 1.5% to finish
the year with a 1.6% gain—0.1 percentage points less than 1997’s low
rate. Price increases were larger at
the wholesale level in December, although the Producer Price Index
(PPI) showed essentially no change
for the year as a whole.
The 12-month CPI trend finished
the year under the lower end of the
index’s central tendency projection,

set by the FOMC at midyear. The
median CPI, an alternative measure
of the inflation trend, remained
steady and considerably higher,
however, averaging 2.7% in 1998.
These two inflation estimates have
followed widely divergent trends
over the past few years.
Measuring inflation is surprisingly
difficult in both theory and practice,
and no single measure of prices can
claim the title of the U.S. “inflation”
rate. While the CPI is undoubtedly
the best-known and most widely

used inflation estimate, this statistic
does not include capital goods or
other items purchased by businesses.
Such items are part of the PPI, but
that price index does not include services — a major segment of the CPI.
An even broader index, the GDP
chain-weighted price index, covers
virtually all goods and services sold
in the economy, including those purchased by the government and foreigners. This measure has tended to
fall somewhere between the CPI and
(continued on next page)

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
Effects of Revision on CPIb

Components affected
by methodology change

Pre-1999
Generic prescription drugs
Food at home
Home ownership
Rent
All items (store sample)
Hospital services
Personal computers
All items
(updated market basket)
1999 proposed
All items (averaging technique)
All items (item sample)
Total

Percentage
point
effect on:
Year
CPI percent
introduced
change

1995
1995
1995
1995
1996
1997
1998

–0.49
–0.01
–0.04
–0.10
0.03
–0.10
–0.06
–0.06

1998

–0.15

1999
1999

–0.20
–0.05
–0.74

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Percentage-point difference.
b. Data from the U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and 1998 Economic Report of the President.
c. Data are not seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and 1998 Economic Report of
the President.

the PPI in recent years—a bit under
1% over the past four quarters.
Even within the retail category,
there are many ways to measure aggregate price increases, and different methods can yield very different
inflation rates. For example, like the
CPI, the personal consumption expenditure (PCE) deflator used in the
national income and product accounts tries to gauge the rate at
which consumer prices are rising.
But there are significant differences
in how these two price indexes are
computed. To begin with, the two
inflation measures differ greatly in

their weighting of certain items;
housing components get considerably more weight in the CPI, while
the PCE deflator gives much more
weight to medical care items. The
two inflation measures also use different methods for collecting certain
prices and for computing price
changes. The combined influence of
these differences has caused the
PCE measure of retail price growth
to track about ¾ percentage point
below the CPI over the past four
years or so.
Perhaps because of its wide use
in government contracts, such as So-

cial Security, the CPI has come
under increased pressure to improve
its methodology; indeed, the methods used to construct the index have
changed already. Between 1995 and
1998, the CPI incorporated eight
major methodological adjustments
which, according to Department of
Labor estimates, have reduced the
index’s measured trend by about ½
percentage point. This year, the CPI
will undergo two additional changes
that Labor Department statisticians
project could trim another ¼ percentage point off its trend.

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity
a,b

Real GDP and Components, 1998:IVQ
(Advance estimate)
Change,
billions
of 1992 $

Real GDP
Consumer spending
Durables
Nondurables
Services
Business fixed
investment
Equipment
Structures
Residential investment
Government spending
National defense
Net exports
Exports
Imports
Change in
business inventories

Percent change, last:
Quarter,
Four
annual rate quarters

103.5
56.0
36.4
12.3
12.0

5.6
4.4
21.4
3.2
1.7

4.1
5.2
12.5
4.5
4.0

37.8
37.5
2.8
7.7
13.1
1.0
–3.9
42.4
46.3

16.7
21.0
5.7
10.1
4.1
1.3
—
18.8
16.0

12.4
17.5
– 0.4
12.6
1.8
– 1.4
—
0.9
10.7

– 6.8

—

—

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 1992 dollars.
b. Components of real GDP need not add to totals because current dollar values are deflated at the most detailed level for which all required data are available.
c. Producers’ durable equipment.
d. Personal consumption expenditures on durable goods.
e. Computer series not available before 1995.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, January 10, 1999.

As of January 10, the Blue Chip consensus forecast was a solid growth
rate of 3.1% in 1998:IVQ. However,
advance estimates released at the
end of January indicate that GDP
grew at a 5.6% annual rate, far
above Blue Chip analysts’ expectations. The 5.6% advance estimate is
remarkably strong, amounting to
double the U.S. economy’s 30-year
average growth rate.
A major growth source in the
fourth quarter was motor vehicle

production, which accounted for 2.1
percentage points of the 5.6% GDP
increase. This was reflected in a rebound in the motor-vehicle-related
components of personal consumption expenditures for durable goods,
producers’ purchases of durable
equipment, and by exports and imports. Last summer’s General Motors
strike had held down those sectors
in the second and third quarters because its effects were focused in June
and July. Much of the fourth-quarter
strength in automotive components

probably reflects production to satisfy backlogs in addition to resumption of normal production.
Last summer’s events—the strike
as well as financial turmoil abroad—
are frequently cited as causes of a
weakening manufacturing sector, indicated by the slower growth of industrial production in 1998. The
overall slowing, however, obscures
the strong performance of some sectors. A breakdown of the manufac(continued on next page)

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Data are from the Federal Reserve Board’s Industrial Production Index.
NOTE: All data are are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; National Association of Purchasing
Management; and National Association of Realtors.

turing component of industrial production shows great variance among
sectors. Most notably, the computers
and office equipment sector grew at
annual rates of 40% and higher for
most of 1997 and 1998. In 1998:IVQ,
combined computer and motor vehicle production accounted for 45% of
GDP growth.
The fourth-quarter surge in automotive production corresponded
with a flood of steel imports from
countries affected by last summer’s financial turmoil. A sharp decline in
steel prices, resulting from the large
amount of imported steel, was associ-

ated with a decline in U.S. raw steel
production. Thus, despite the surge
in auto-related production, growth in
industrial production as a whole continued to slow through December.
Purchasing managers also were
indicating softness in the manufacturing sector. The Purchasing Managers’ Index (in which executives indicate whether business has slowed,
picked up, or remained the same)
dropped precipitously in the latter
months of 1998. In January, however, the Index recovered all the
ground it had lost, a sign that business was improving.

Construction and real estate activity continue to be very strong. Residential investment has been a consistently vigorous component of
GDP growth throughout 1998. Construction activity continues to show
healthy growth levels. A revival in
housing starts and permits since
September points toward continued
growth in 1999 residential construction. This seems to be confirmed by
evidence of lively demand in the
real estate market. New home sales
are growing very strongly, while
sales of existing homes broke
records in December.

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Labor Market Conditions
Average monthly change
(thousands of employees)
1995

1996

1997

1998

Jan.
1999

185
8
–2
10
–1

233
31
1
28
3

282
42
1
20
21

234
6
–3
28
–20

245
–7
–9
15
–13

Service-producing
178
Retail trade
37
FIREa
–1
Services
112
Business Services
38
Government
9
b
Household employment 30

202
42
14
117
45
9
228

240
34
17
142
61
20
235

229
39
22
112
39
28
157

252
30
22
114
48
36
814

Payroll employment
Goods-producing
Mining
Construction
Manufacturing

Average for period (percent)

Civilian unemployment

5.6

5.4

4.9

4.5

4.3

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Finance, insurance, and real estate.
b. January change in household employment reflects an adjustment by the Bureau of Labor Statistics.
c. Vertical line indicates break in data series due to survey redesign.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Robust labor market growth continued unabated in the first month
of 1999, contrary to early predictions of slowing. Nonfarm payrolls
increased 245,000, which is just
above 1998’s average monthly payroll growth and about equal to the
average for 1998:IVQ.
Once again large gains in the
service-producing sector compensated for small declines in the
goods-producing sector. Both mining and manufacturing lost jobs,
while construction remained strong
despite unfavorable weather in the

Midwest and Northeast. The construction industry has added 284,000
new jobs in the last 12 months. Services added 114,000 new jobs in
January, with business services experiencing an above-average gain of
48,000.
The January employment report
also revealed greater breadth in
employment growth, as measured
by the fraction of industries in which
employment is rising. For the three
months ending January 1999, 60%
of the 349 detailed industries that
were surveyed had increased their

employment. However, within manufacturing, just over 60% of the industries surveyed had decreased
their employment.
The unemployment rate held
steady at 4.3%, a 28-year low, although there was a substantial jump
in household employment. The percent of the working-age population
that is employed rose to 64.5%
in January, making it the second
straight month of record highs in
the employment-to-population ratio.
The labor force participation rate of
67.4% also was a record high.

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Employment Cost Index

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Both compensation measures are for private-sector workers.
b. Production and nonsupervisory workers.
NOTE: Unless otherwise noted, data are seasonally adjusted and apply to all civilian workers.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

From the firm’s perspective, the cost
of employing workers extends substantially beyond the wages and
salaries paid to those workers. Benefits packages represent 28% of employment costs. The Bureau of Labor Statistics publishes a quarterly
Employment Cost Index (ECI)
measuring changes in compensation
costs including wages, salaries, and
employee benefits. The benefits included in the ECI are diverse: vacations, health care insurance, and
pension benefits, as well as mandated benefits like employer contributions to Social Security and unemployment insurance. In addition, the

ECI covers the full range of the
workforce, unlike the average hourly
wage rate, which applies only to
production workers.
Despite an exceptionally strong
labor market, employment costs
continue to grow only moderately.
In 1998, overall employment costs
rose 3.4%, held down by an increase in benefits costs of only
2.6%. The limited increase in benefits costs was surprising, given
widespread concerns that health
care costs were set to go up substantially. However, unemployment
insurance systems have been reducing their employer contributions

due to low unemployment rates,
and growth in the value of pensions’ stock holdings have limited
the need for further contributions.
From the worker’s perspective,
1998 was a good year for real wage
growth, as the ECI exceeded inflation by the largest margin since 1983.
Inflation was only 1.6% for 1998, versus compensation growth of 3.4% or
wage and salary growth of 3.7%. Recent low unemployment rates may
be part of the story, although the relationship between unemployment
rates and the ECI has not been tight
during the 1990s. Some workers
(continued on next page)

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Employment Cost Index (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Seasonally adjusted.
b. Transportation and public utilities.
c. Finance, insurance, and real estate.
d. Government workers are not in the private sector.
NOTE: All data are for private-sector workers unless otherwise noted.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

have had larger or smaller gains than
average, reflecting the relative demand for different types of labor.
Sorted by industry, compensation
growth has been strongest in wholesale trade and in finance, insurance,
and real estate. Pay is flexible in
many finance industry jobs where
bonuses are common, so it is not unusual for that industry to have outsize quarterly gains; however, it has
shown faster-than-average compensation growth during the last five
years. Recent gains in construction

point to accelerating compensation
in a sector that has not historically
kept up with the average.
Other distinctions surface by occupation and by region. White-collar
workers’ gains continue to outpace
those of blue-collar workers. The latest quarter showed unusually weak
gains in the bonus-oriented executive ranks, but white-collar compensation still rose more than a percentage point faster in 1998 and more
than half a percentage point faster
per year since 1993. Similarly, some

regions have had substantially
stronger compensation growth than
others. Notably, the ECI for the West
rose much more sharply in 1998 and
has maintained its relative strength
over the last five years. These repeated small differences in compensation growth can alter relative pay
differentials. For example, the data
indicate that the premium for union
or government work is being reduced, while education-intensive occupations are moving further ahead.

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Unemployment Rates

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

A seven-year economic expansion
has brought U.S. unemployment to
4.3%, its lowest rate since the 1960s.
The change has been felt throughout the nation. When the economy
began its current expansion in
March 1991, the vast majority of
states (39) had unemployment
rates of 5.4% or higher, while only
two had unemployment rates at
or below 3%. By the end of 1998,
only eight states had unemployment rates at or above 5.4%, while
nine had rates of 3% or lower. This
general decline in unemployment
rates is not purely a business-cycle
phenomenon. Even at the peak of

the previous expansion (at that
time the longest peacetime expansion on record), 27 states had unemployment rates at or above 5.4%.
The states with the lowest unemployment rates in 1998 typically
have had lower-than-average rates
for extended periods. Several of
these states are in the upper Midwest, where moderate employment
growth has been matched with
even lower growth in the workingage population. In contrast, Virginia
has relied on robust jobs growth to
keep its unemployment rate low
while its population expanded.
Even states with historically

higher unemployment rates have
seen sizable reductions, with the
exception of Hawaii, which was adversely affected by the weak Japanese economy. West Virginia is a
good example: Despite having one
of the highest unemployment rates
in the country, it had the thirdlargest unemployment rate decline
during this period, almost six percentage points. Even California and
New York, states where the previous recession lingered long beyond
its official trough, have almost regained their pre-recession unemployment rates.

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Household Financial Conditions

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Ratio of total consumer credit to disposable personal income.
b. Seasonally adjusted.
c. Net charge-off rate is the percentage of total credit card debt that banks remove from their balance sheets because of uncollectibility, less amounts
recovered on credit cards previously charged off, expressed as an annual rate.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile; American Bankers Association, Consumer Credit Delinquency Bulletin; American Bankruptcy Institute; Mortgage
Bankers Association of America, National Delinquency Survey; and Bank Rate Monitor.

Household consumer debt levels
rose again (to 21.24% of disposable
personal income last November),
after remaining stable since the beginning of 1996. This renewed acceleration in household debt burdens is all the more striking when
viewed against the backdrop of a
domestic personal saving rate that
turned negative, the only time this
has occurred since the figure was
first calculated.
Such trends concern many ana-

lysts because personal consumption expenditures account for
nearly two-thirds of the GDP. As
a result, the story goes, if household accounts get too far out of balance, consumption growth may
taper off and pull the economy into
a recession.
Beyond the raw debt numbers,
however, other indicators of household financial distress do not appear
to foreshadow impending doom.
For example, after rising dramati-

cally through the middle part of the
decade, delinquency rates on various types of consumer and mortgage debt have held steady or even
fallen since 1996. Similarly, the
growth in personal bankruptcy
filings and credit card charge-off
rates that was so notable beginning
in 1994 has slowed over the past
two years.
In addition, the steady decline of
mortgage rates since early 1997, not
(continued on next page)

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Household Financial Conditions (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Ratio of total consumer credit to disposable personal income.
b. Annualized percentage change.
NOTE: All data are four-quarter moving averages of quarter-over-quarter changes.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and American Bankruptcy Institute.

to mention the dramatic drop in
average credit card rates over last
year, has served to lower the overall fraction of household income
needed to service these higher debt
levels. As a consequence, households may rationally desire to hold
higher debt balances than they
did during periods of higher
interest rates.
A more fundamental reason to
question the above story about the
danger of high debt burdens is that
it assumes a causal link between
debt levels and real economic vari-

ables that doesn’t appear to exist. In
particular, those who are concerned
about increases in the debt-toincome ratio implicitly assume that
debt burdens either cause or predict
future consumption expenditures.
Historical experience, however,
calls this assumption into question.
In fact, changes in real economic
variables such as personal consumption expenditures, durable goods
consumption, and GDP typically
precede changes in the debt-toincome ratio by as much as two or
three quarters. In other words,

changes in consumption output
tend to predict changes in consumer debt levels, not the other
way around.
An alternative story can be told
to demonstrate the reasonableness
of such a pattern. When households experience a negative shock
to their incomes, the debt-to-income level naturally rises for two
reasons: First, of course, is the direct effect of lower disposable personal incomes. Simultaneously,
however, households may increase
(continued on next page)

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Household Financial Conditions (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

a. Mean response of banks using the following scale: 1 = tightened considerably, 2 = tightened somewhat, 3 = remained basically unchanged, 4 = eased
somewhat, and 5 = eased considerably.
b. Total domestic assets over $15 billion.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices.

their indebtedness in order to
smooth their consumption patterns,
if they perceive the shock to be
temporary. Such smoothing is not
complete, however, so that consumption ex-penditures, particularly for dur-ables, decline in the
face of this income shock. As a result, the real economic variables of
interest decline in advance of, not
following, a decline in household
debt levels. Most importantly, by
the time we observe changes in
debt levels that might portend
lower economic growth, that lower
growth already has occurred.

Additional insight into household
financial conditions can be gleaned
from the Federal Reserve’s quarterly
Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey
on Bank Lending Practices. According to the latest survey, conducted
last month, the trend toward tighter
loan standards that has prevailed
over the last three years for credit
card lending and other consumer
loans appears to be moderating,
while mortgage loan standards continue their steady track.
The same patterns are evident in
the changing terms of credit card

loans. Although credit limits and interest rate spreads are slightly less
favorable than they have been in the
past (due primarily to the influence
of large banks), minimum payment
requirements and other credit card
terms are virtually unchanged.
Despite this tightening of standards, senior loan officers continue
to report a strong and growing willingness to make consumer installment loans. Taken together, these
trends suggest that creditworthy borrowers are having little trouble in
gaining access to credit.

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Trade Deficits

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Increased concerns about the
widening U.S. trade deficit can
be understood by examining the
1998:IIIQ data on international
transactions from different perspectives. The increased gap between
imports and exports of goods, services, and income may reflect a relative increase in the disposable income of U.S. citizens, or an
increased attractiveness of investing
in the U.S. On the other hand, it
could be seen as the U.S. economy’s increased vulnerability to
withdrawals of foreign funds.
Net capital inflow, the increase in
foreign holdings in the U.S., continues to exceed net capital outflow.

However, the accounting requirement that a current-account deficit
must be balanced by capital flow
does not mean that the currentaccount deficit causes the capital
flow — the sequence could be reversed. The form taken by the inflow
might be important in this regard.
Direct foreign investment (DFI) in
the U.S., which involves ownership
control rather than portfolio design,
now exceeds U.S. DFI abroad. Fluctuations in DFI have been much
more moderate than those shown by
other components of capital flow,
suggesting that at least part of the increased net capital inflow will not
quickly reverse direction.

A country relying on capital inflow may see it turn to outflow unless the capital is invested wisely. In
addition, since the services provided
by capital imply payments to the
lenders, a long period of net capital
inflow might lead to an increase in
the burden of such payments. The
most recent data show an increase
in the excess of payments on foreign
assets in the U.S. over income receipts on U.S. assets abroad. However, the debt burden facing the U.S.
does not approach the levels typically found in countries that subsequently experience significant net
capital outflow.

19
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Brazil

FRB Cleveland • February 1999

SOURCES: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; International Monetary Fund, Direction of Trade Statistics; and Morgan Stanley Capital International.

On January 13, Brazil devalued its
currency, the real, creating further
turmoil in world financial markets.
By January 22, the real had fallen
29% despite large expenditures of
dollar reserves by Brazil’s central
bank. It was unclear whether
planned fiscal reforms would be sufficient to slow the currency’s fall, and
reliance on further interest rate increases might not be credible given
their probable negative effects on
the Brazilian economy.
The decline in the value of the real
and the weakening of Brazil’s economy are concerns for its trading partners. In particular, Argentina main-

tains the value of its currency against
the U.S. dollar. The real’s decline
against the dollar increases the cost
to Brazil of Argentinian exports. Although the U.S. accounts for the
largest share of Brazil’s trade (21%),
Brazil is Argentina’s largest partner
(26%). Argentina already has begun
to consider cutting some import
taxes to lessen the impact on industries that depend on Brazilian trade.
Other Latin American economies
could be influenced as well. Commerce between Brazil and Argentina
accounts for most of the trade within
Mercosur, the South American trading bloc that also includes Paraguay

and Uruguay. The continued fragility of the Mexican banking system
and the peso’s weakness in 1998
suggest that the decline of the real
could affect Mexico significantly.
Mexico has little trade with either
Brazil or Argentina, but Brazil’s
problems could hamper the economic growth of other countries
which in turn would reduce their
trade with Mexico. Or a pure contagion effect could occur whereby investors pull back from an entire
group of countries. To date, however, there is little evidence of significant consequences for Mexico.