View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

r
e
b
m
t e
p
e
S
In t h i s i s s u e :

C o m p a r a t iv e A d v a n t a g e a n d th e
C h a n g in g C o m p o s it io n o f
U . S. O u t p u t , E x p o rts, a n d

The

P arad o x

D is tr ic t

of

B u s in e s s




Bank

Im p o r t s

"R e se rv e s"

C o n d it io n s

C

o m

a n d

p a r a t i v e

t h

e

C

o m

E

x p o r t s ,

by

John

C

d v a n t a g e

h a n g i n g

p o s i t i o n

E.

A

a n d

o f

I m

U . S . O

p

o

u

t p

u

t ,

r t s

L e im o n e

In 1971, the U nited States experienced a m erchandise trade deficit for the first
time in this century, greatly intensifying concern over the deterioration in the
m erchandise trade position. This concern stem s from w idespread
belief that the U nited States needs a large m erchandise trade surplus to
achieve balance o f paym ents equilibrium .
Econom ists and policym akers have pointed to the U. S. inflationary
surge since 1965 and the overvaluation of the do llar as m ajor culprits in
the disappearance o f the trade surplus. But recently, som e eco nom ists
have begun to suspect that structural changes in the e c o n o m y have also
contributed to this situation. Som e adherents o f this view have even begun
to question the need for a large, perm anent U. S. m erchandise trade surplus.1
In citing structural changes, they note that the share o f national ou tpu t
originatin g in g o o d s-p ro d u c in g sectors— agriculture, m ining, and m anufactur­
ing— has been shrinking, but the share o f service activities has been
expanding. From this they hypothesize that the U. S. m ay be lo sin g its
com parative advantage in g o o d s but gain in g one in services. Consequently,
one w o u ld expect the m erchandise trade balance, over the lo n g run, to
trend from surplus to deficit and the surplus on services trade to expand
unless inflationary pressures or controls on trade and capital distort these
long-run tendencies.
The idea that services m ay provide a gro w in g trade surplus m ay surprise those
w h o think of barber shops and laundries as typical service industries. But the
share o f such labor-intensive services in national ou tpu t has been declin in g.2
Instead, services' share o f total output has expanded because o f the
grow th o f private and governm ental services heavily dep end ent u po n educators,
scientists, adm inistrators, and other high ly skilled and educated persons.
It is the grow th o f these services, w hich provide m ajor sources o f new
kn ow le dge and te ch n olo gy for increasing productivity, that som e econom ists
have begun to associate with the possibility of an ex pan ding surplus on
services trade.
Yet g o o d s w ho se produ ction is heavily dep end ent u po n te ch n o lo gy and
highly skilled personnel have also increased their o u tpu t share even as the
share o f total go o d s o utput has shrunk. Such g o o d s have m aintained a

Monthly Review,

V ol. L V III, N o. 9. Free su b scrip tio n an d ad d itio n a l c o p ie s availab le
u p o n request to the Research D ep artm e nt, Federal Reserve Bank o f Atlanta,
Atlanta, G e o rg ia 30303.

134



SEPTEMBER 1973, M O N T H L Y RE V IEW

substantial trade surplus despite deterioration in
the overall m erchandise trade position.3
Therefore, broad structural shifts from g o o d s to
services w ithin o u tpu t and trade cloak com plex
structural changes in m any sm aller co m pone nts
of go o d s and services.
To appraise the hypothesis o f ch an gin g
com parative advantage, this article exam ines
the structural changes in U. S. exports and
im ports of g o o d s and services and their inter­
relationship w ith structural changes in U. S. output
between 1958 and 1971. This tim e fram e permits
a com parison of trends du ring the relatively
noninflationary 1958-1964 environm ent with
1965-1971, m arked by strong inflationary pressures
and increasing overvaluation o f the dollar. The
article first analyzes broad structural changes,
h igh ligh tin g the role of services in output and
trade. It then proposes a hypothetical fram ew ork
c o m b in in g elem ents of com parative advantage
and e c o n o m ic developm ent theories to explain
structural changes and linkages between output
and trade. Finally, the article analyzes detailed
sectoral trends within the context of this fram e­
w ork to uncover som e m ajor influences underlying
the structural changes in U. S. output and trade.
Structural Trends
Services' share in national output rose from a p ­
proxim ately 54 percent in 1950 to 64 percent in
1971.4 In contrast, output shares o riginating
in m anufacturing, agriculture, and m in in g have
trended dow nw ard, and that of construction
has rem ained stable (Chart I).5
Services accou nt for approxim ately one-third
of total im ports and exports.6 M oreover, between
1958 and 1965, the net balance on service trade
m oved steadily from a deficit equal to .15 percent
of national output to a surplus equal to .43
percent. Thus, in 1965, services constituted nearly
one-third of the total surplus on go o d s and services
(Chart II). In contrast, the surplus on m erchandise
trade (agricultural, mineral, and m anufactured
goods) fo llow ed no discernible trend d u ring this
period. After 1965, however, the balances o f both
m erchandise and service trade d ro pp ed off sharply
relative to output.
These com parison s suggest that the traditional
focus on m erchandise trade alone has been too
narrow to adequately interpret the forces
underlying U. S. trading strength. Furthermore, the
upsurge in net service exports through 1965, in
contrast to the erratic trend of net m erchandise
exports, supports the hypothesis that the U. S.
trade balance is b e c o m in g m ore service-oriented.
The sharp declines in both m erchandise and
service trade positions after 1965, as im ports
surged, suggest that inflationary pressures and
overvaluation of the dollar severely distorted
these long-run trends.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ATLANTA




CHART I

National Output by Sectoral Shares
Services

Constr.

Mining
’6 5
Note: All

g u r e s a r e in c u r r e n t d o lla r s .

’7 0

N a t io n a l o u tp u t is d e fin e d in t e x t.

Despite parallel shifts from go o d s to services
in both output and trade, trends in trade have
not paralleled trends in output shares. For
instance, the balance of agricultural trade m oved
from deficit to surplus and the m inerals trade
deficit narrowed, relative to national output,
between 1958 and 1971, although the output shares
of both sectors declined. These diverse trends
suggest that linkages between o utput and trade
are too com plex to be derived from co m paring
trends in broad sectors of o utput and trade. Hence,
forces underlying structural changes in both output
and trade m ust be analyzed before the hypothesis
that the U. S. trade position is b e c o m in g m ore
service-oriented can be fully evaluated.
Relationships Between Production and Trade
Econom ists have traditionally linked output and
trade through the theory of com parative advantage.
A c c ord in g to this theory, each area or nation tends
to specialize in the production of those go o d s and
services that it can create with greatest efficiency

CHART II
Sectoral Trade Balances, 1958-1971
°/o

o f n a tio n a l o u tp u t

Total Services

%

1.0

o f n a tio n a l o u tp u t

Total Goods

135

(i.e., in w hich it has a com parative advantage). In
the m odern version of the theory, differences in
com parative advantage stem from differences
between regions or nations in their mix of
productive inputs. For example, if a nation possesses
a higher capital to labor ratio than other countries,
it (1) tends to specialize in p rod u cin g capitalintensive g o o d s and services and (2) exports
these products for labor-intensive imports.
In recent years, econom ists have attem pted to
expand the traditional categories o f capital and
labor to include physical capital (e.g., machinery),
unskilled labor, hum an capital (investm ent in
education and training in specialized skills),
te chn ology (i.e., application of new kn ow le dge
to create new products or to produce old go o d s
and services m ore efficiently), econom ies of
scale,7 and natural resources.
D e m a n d patterns also play an essential role in
determ ining the equilibrium mix of production,
exports, and im ports am o n g nations. In fact, large
differences in dem an d patterns, m ore typically
present between nations of w idely differing
per capita incom e levels, m ay occasion trade
patterns opp osite to those predicted by com parative
advantage.8
O v e r time, national econom ies experience
contin u ou s and broadly sim ilar shifts in the
structure of output that are related to changes in
both dem and patterns and the mix of productive
inputs.9 These changes, in turn, bring about
changes in a nation's trade pattern.10 (Differences
am o n g nations in tim ing and pace m ake specializa­
tion and trade possible.)
Thus, nations at early stages of eco n o m ic
deve lopm en t are strongly oriented toward
agriculture, m anufacture o f sim ple co nsum p tio n
goods, and retail trade, w hich satisfy basic
dem ands for food, shelter, and clothing. These
first tw o activities depend heavily upon natural
resources, and all three use relatively unskilled
labor. A s countries develop, trade becom es m ore
extensive and m ore rou ndabou t production
m ethods emerge. C onsequently, m ining, transporta­
tion, and industries processing raw materials for
other industries begin to expand their share of
output. These sectors typically require heavy
investm ent in physical capital and experience
increasing eco nom ies of scale.
A t m ore advanced levels of developm ent,
consum ers— fin ding it easier to satisfy basic needs
in terms of food, shelter, and clothin g— dem and
a w ider variety of m ore sophisticated
g o o d s and services. Produ cin g sectors also search
for increasing efficiency through m ore m odern
eq uip m e nt and im proved organization. Thus,
business and professional services and m anufactur­
ing industries p ro d u cin g new, highly sophisticated
go o d s contribute an increasing proportion to total
output. These sectors use highly skilled and

136



educated w orkers and te ch n o lo gy and produce
these inputs for other sectors of the econom y.
In sum, changes in the mix of productive inputs
play a significant role in ch a n gin g the structure
of output. Thus, national eco nom ies typically
m ove from produ ction using raw materials and
unskilled labor tow ard produ ction characterized
by eco no m ies of scale and intensive use of physical
capital and, finally, tow ard activities that use
hum an capital and te ch n o lo gy intensively and
produce them for other sectors. C h an ge s in the
com position of d em an d as per capita incom es
rise also interact w ith changes in the mix of p ro ­
ductive inputs to produ ce changes in the structure
of output. How ever, the im portance of dem and
shifts versus input shifts in b rin gin g abou t structural
o utput changes are not w ell understood. Even
less appreciated is the role dem an d shifts play
in brin ging about changes in the mix o f productive
inputs them selves (e.g., changes in the saving rate
on capital form ation, changes in the dem an d for
education on the d eve lo pm en t o f hum an capital
and technology, and changes in the dem an d for
leisure on the sup ply o f labor).
This fram ew ork suggests that the highly d e ­
veloped U. S. e c o n o m y sh ou ld be increasingly
oriented tow ard the produ ction and export of
business and professional services and tow ard
sophisticated c onsum e r g o o d s and capital e q u ip ­
ment produ ced by techn ology-in ten sive m anu fac­
turing industries. Sim ilarly, g o o d s and services
heavily dependent upon natural resources or
unskilled labor sh ou ld decline in relative
im p o rta n c e w ithin output and exports. But
im ports m ay also becom e m ore service- and less
go ods-o riented because of shifts in the c o m p o si­
tion of dem and. Hence, w hile the theory o f c o m ­
parative advantage im plies that sectors increasing
their output shares sh ou ld trend tow ard a trade
surplus and contracting sectors sh ou ld trend tow ard
deficit, the uneven pace of shifts in the co m p o sitio n
of dem an d m ay contradict this expectation for
som e sectors. C h an ge in the mix o f productive
inputs and c o m p ositio n of dem an d in U. S.
trading partners m ay also strongly influence trends
in U. S. trading patterns.
In p u t M ix , D e m a n d C o m p o sitio n , and
Structural C h a n g e
Let us n ow analyze trends of U. S. o u tpu t and trade
in individual sectors w ithin the context o f changes
in mix of productive inputs and in co m p o sitio n of
dem and. (All trends are expressed relative to
output in order to abstract from the influence of
the total e c o n o m y's grow th. For example, although
a sector's im ports m ay be g ro w in g in absolute
terms, these im ports w ill exhibit a d e c lin in g trend
relative to national o utput if the rate of grow th is
less than that of total dom estic output.)

SEPTEMBER 1973, M O N T H L Y REVIEW

CHART III
Agriculture
Agriculture's share of total output has declined
largely because consum ers spend a shrinking
proportion of their incom es on foo d as their
incom es rise. The dow ntrend in agricultural im ports
also reflects this behavior, although U. S. barriers
against im ports o f certain agricultural products
(e.g., beef and tom atoes), m ay have contributed.
But the shrinking im portance of noncom petitive
c o m m oditie s (especially coffee and cocoa) w ithin
total agricultural im ports suggests that dem and
shifts ou tw eighed trade barriers in determ ining
this trend.
The gro w in g relative scarcity o f the traditional
agricultural inputs, labor and land, w ithin the mix
of U. S. productive inputs has also contributed to
agriculture's declin in g share in total output and has
u ndou btedly dam pen ed agricultural exports.
(Significantly, the United States has agricultural
deficits with Latin Am erica, Australia and N ew
Zealand, and Africa, areas with a relatively greater
abundance o f land and/or labor.) M oreover, land
and labor used in agriculture have been attracted
to other sectors paying higher returns on their use.
U. S. farmers have adopted new production
m ethods that substitute technologically advanced
eq uip m e nt and techniques, im proved m anagem ent,
and large scale operations for labor and land.11
These changes have slow ed the relative dow ntrend
in agricultural exports and, helped by sales of
agricultural products under various governm ental
program s (e.g., PL 480 sales to less-developed
nations), eventually permitted a surplus in
agricultural trade to em erge.12

M inerals
The depletion of m any mineral deposits du ring
e co n o m ic grow th and, in recent years,
environm ental concerns have raised costs and
restrained U. S. mineral production. Yet mineral
export grow th has kept up with grow th in total
output because of the very large U. S. share in
glob al deposits of copper, phosphate rock, sulfur,
and coal. These four co m m o ditie s account for the
bulk o f U. S. mineral exports.
M in in g of these com m odities, especially coal and
sulfur, is technology-intensive. In recent years,
coal has also benefited from increasing
econo m ies o f scale. Nevertheless, mineral exports
have consistently fallen short of mineral im ports
because of the depletion of other U. S. natural
resources and the large dom estic dem and for
petroleum and natural gas, w hich dom inate total
U. S. mineral production.
Im port quotas, particularly on petroleum , have
u ndou btedly suppressed mineral imports,
although recent and prospective changes
in U. S. energy policies m ay reverse this
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ATLANTA




137

trend. Yet shifts in the co m po sitio n of dem an d may
have also dam pen ed mineral im ports and
production. Thus, sophisticated go o d s and services,
the m ost rapidly gro w in g output sectors, rely less
heavily upon raw materials in creating value added
than som e of the older go o d s sectors. M oreover,
energy consum ption, w hich is heavily dependent
upon mineral fuels, has trended d o w n w ard relative
to G N P since 1947.13 The decline in output shares
of utilities and transportation services, accounting
for about one-half of gross energy c o n su m p ­
tion,14 also im plies that dem and for mineral fuels
has been declin in g relative to total dem and.
M an u factu rin g
Trends in m anufacturing can be better understood
by gro u p in g together m anufactured g o o d s of
sim ilar production and dem and characteristics—
sim ple consum er goods, interm ediate goods, and
fabricated metal goods. Sim ple consum er g o o d s 15
industries process raw materials satisfying basic
consum er needs of food, clothing, and shelter.
Their output norm ally depends heavily upon low skilled labor but only to a lim ited extent upon
econom ies of scale or new technology.16 Interm edi­
ate industries also process raw materials but sell the
bulk of their output to other producers. They
typically require heavy investm ents in plant and
eq uip m ent (physical capital) and tend to benefit
from substantial internal econom ies of scale. M etalfabricating industries produce sophisticated go o d s
that satisfy rapidly rising dem ands for recreation,
travel, education, and leisure or provide capital
inputs to other industries. The m anufacture of these

go o d s requires large inputs o f hum an capital and
te chn ology and relies less on physical capital and
econom ies o f scale than interm ediate industries.
The steadily d e clin in g trend in sim ple consum er
g o o d s ' share of national output (Chart IV) and their
persistent trade deficit (Chart V) suggest a
com parative disadvantage stem m ing from relatively
intensive use of raw materials and unskilled labor.
The tendency for consum ers to spend less of their
bu dget on sim ple consum e r g o o d s as incom es
rise has undo u bte dly d am pen ed ou tpu t grow th and
accounted for a stable trend in sim ple consum er
go o d s im ports until the outbreak of inflation in
1965. Thereafter, such im ports accelerated in
response to excess dom estic dem and, substantially
w id e n in g the trade deficit for these goods.
The share of interm ediate g o o d s in o u tp u t
has also declined, though m ore irregularly
than sim ple consum er goods. Im ports and exports
from 1958 to 1964 fluctuated around a flat trend
and were roughly in balance. This pattern suggests
a slow ly em ergin g com parative disadvantage
stem m ing from a rising scarcity of dom estic raw
materials partially offset by e co n o m ie s of scale and
intensive use o f physical capital. In addition, the
stable level of im ports until 1965 and the slow ly
declin in g share of output suggest that dem an d for
interm ediate go o d s has grow n m oderately less
than total dem and. The sharp rise in im ports and
equally sharp decline in output share after 1965
reflect an increasing substitution of im ports for
dom estic production in response to surgin g excess
dem an d in the econom y.
The trade surplus and rising trends for exports
and output shares (except du rin g recessions) for
m etal-fabricated products suggest a strong U. S.
com parative advantage in these goods, w hose
productive processes dep end heavily upon hum an
capital and technology. The rising trends for
im ports and output also im ply above-average
grow th of dem an d for these products. But ac­
celerating im ports after 1965 resulted in a decline
in the trade balance o f fabricated metal products.
M oreover, accelerating imports, by substituting for
dom estic production, m ay have contributed to
the sharp dow nturn in this sector's share o f d o ­
m estic output after 1968.
Services
Evaluating the forces u nderlying trends in service
output and trade present num erou s difficulties.
Problem s o f m easuring o u tpu t are c o m p o u n d e d by
substantial differences between service ou tpu t and
service trade classification schem es. Nevertheless,
w e have attem pted a breakout and co m pariso n of
service co m p on e n ts w hich, though crude,
suggest that service output and trade patterns
change in response to c o m m o n su p p ly and dem and
influences m uch like g o o d s-p ro d u c in g sectors.

138




SEPTEMBER 1973, M O N T H L Y REVIEW

CH A RT V

Trends in Exports, Imports, and Trade Balances
for Mfg. Components
%

of n a tio n a l o utp u t

Sim ple Consumer

- 1.0
Im p orts

E x p o rts

Intermediate
Im p o rts

E x p o rts

+
■ 0

2.4

The expansion in services' domestic output share
from 1958 onward stems from growth in both
private and state and local services,
plus an upsurge in Federal services
after 1965 (Chart VI). The expansion in private
services derives entirely from professional and
technical services (i.e., educational, legal,
miscellaneous professional, miscellaneous business,
medical and health, and nonprofit organizations).
Output shares of other private services (i.e., repair,
personal, private household, lodging, and entertain­
ment services) remained stable or declined. These
latter are very labor-intensive but utilize
relatively little human capital.17
Educational services account for approximately
two-thirds of the expansion in state and local
output18 and, currently, for more than 40 percent of
state and local expenditures. General government,
civilian safety, welfare administration, and health
and medical services make up most of the remain­
ing expansion in that sector. In sum, the expansion
of both private and state and local governments'
services stems from services that use human capital
and/or technology intensively in their production
processes and provide the main source for adding
to the stock of these inputs.
A growing body of opinion, supported by
limited evidence, holds that fees and royalties and
direct investment earnings in trade accounts include
payments for a wide variety of services similar to
professional and technical services which swell
the services' output share.19 (Some service
exports only incorporate indirectly domestically
produced services. For example, educational

2.0
1.6

CHA RT VI

Trends in Components of Services
%

1.2

of n a tio n a l outp u t

.8
.4

1.8
1.4

1.0
.6
.2

•I

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK O F ATLANTA




139

services provide the hum an capital and tech n ology
essential for generating fees and royalties and
returns on direct investment, but educational
services directly exported are prob ab ly quite
small.) The large and gro w in g surplus on these
services (classified here as technical services) was
responsible for the bulk o f the overall surplus on
services trade from 1960 onw ard (Chart V II).

CHA RT VII

Trends in Exports, Imports, and Trade Balances
for Service Components
% of n a tio n a l o utp u t

Hence, the contribution o f technical services to the
grow th o f service o utput and exports and the large
trade surplus for this sector strongly support the
hypothesis that the United States has a significant
and gro w in g com parative advantage in services
utilizing large prop ortions o f hum an capital and
te ch n o logy in their mix o f productive inputs.

.8
.4

0

G overnm ental restraints on foreign direct
investm ent of U. S. corporations m ay have
d am pen ed this com parative advantage. Thus,
technical services exports flattened out du ring the
m id-Sixties w hen such controls were first im posed.
The renewed uptrend o f these exports in the early
Seventies is consistent w ith som e relaxation of
restraints.
The pattern of Federal services in output
and trade overw h elm ingly reflects the
vagaries in the dem an d for military services (i.e.,
these trends are relatively independent of the
mix o f productive inputs used to produ ce military
services). M ilitary expenditures declined relative
to output from 1958 to 1965 as "c o ld w a r"
hostilities abated but began rising after
1965 in response to the Vietnam conflict. The
Federal G o vern m e nt's share o f output m oved
correspondingly. M ilitary expenditures have
ranged from 80 to 85 percent o f Federal
expenditures on g o o d s and services and dom inate
exports and im ports o f governm ental services as
well. The proportion o f Federal nonm ilitary
expenditures to dom estic output has rem ained
stable, although their co m p o sitio n has changed.
The trend in military sp e n d in g abroad (imports)
and consequently the deficit for this sector
closely paralleled the pattern of the G overn m e nt's
share in total output (i.e., declin in g from 1958
through 1965, then rising in response to the
acceleration of Vietnam hostilities).
In this article, w e have assum ed that returns on
foreign financial assets and paym ents on financial
liabilities to foreigners im plicitly include a su b ­
stantial c o m p o n e n t o f paym ents for financial
services and, therefore, respond to the sam e
dem and and sup ply forces influencing dom estic
output o f such services. (Governm ental receipts
and paym ents on foreign assets and liabilities
are included in these services.)
Financial services are relatively labor-intensive
and use relatively less physical capital (excluding
real estate) and hum an capital than m anufacturing.
How ever, the U. S. reputation for possessing
one of the largest, m ost efficient financial systems

140



.8
.4

0

Trans.
.4
Ex p o rts
B a la n c e

‘'■ ' ■ ■ ■ ■ ■ m

Travel

i a

T

g

i

+
0

im p o rts

.4
Ex p o rts

+
0

U U U U IJ 1 T U 1 J U U U U u u
B a la n c e

’60

'65

’70

SEPTEMBER 1973, M O N T H L Y REVIEW

in the w orld im plies substantial external econom ies
of scale.
The net surplus of financial services until the late
Sixties suggests a U. S. com parative advantage,
perhaps based on external eco no m ies o f scale.
The sudden contraction of this surplus after
1965 and the appearance of a deficit in 1969 largely
reflect the inflationary b o o m after 1965 w hich
swelled U. S. credit dem an ds and induced
substantial capital inflow s from abroad. A s a result
of paym ents to foreigners for use of these funds,
financial service im ports surged dramatically.
Recycling o f U. S. dom estic funds via the Eurodollar
market because o f Regulation Q interest ceilings
added to paym ents to foreigners. In essence, R egu la­
tion Q frustrated the dom estic production of
financial interm ediation services and further ex­
panded dom estic dem and for such services from
abroad.20
By constraining exports, governm ental regulations
m ay have also contributed to the deterioration of
the balance of financial services. Thus, c o in cid in g
with the im position o f the Interest Equalization
Tax on U. S. purchases o f foreign securities
and the Volu n tary Foreign C redit Restraint Program,
w hich constrained the increase of U. S.
com m ercial bank financial claim s on foreigners in
the mid-Sixties, the grow th rate of returns on
foreign portfolio investm ents (exports) slowed.
Transportation services claim a sm all and
shrinking share o f dom estic output. Exports have
m aintained a flat trend relative to output, but a
slow ly rising im port level has open ed up a sm all
deficit suggesting a slow ly em ergin g U. S.
com parative disadvantage in transportation
services. The sector is characterized by heavy
investm ents in physical capital, econom ies
of scale, and an indirect dependence on mineral
resources via fuel consum ption. The contraction
in share of total output and the lim ited rise of
im ports also im ply that dom estic dem and for
transportation services has grow n relatively slowly.
The rising level of travel im ports reflects gro w in g
Am erican expenditures on travel abroad as incom es
rise. The nearly equal rise in travel exports
indicates that foreign dem and for travel in the
United States has also grow n m ore rapidly than
dom estic output. Nevertheless, the deficit in this
c o m p o n e n t in relation to the overall level of trade
im plies a strong U. S. com parative disadvantage
rooted in the labor intensity of travel-related
services. The contraction of the output share of
travel-related services— hotels, retail trade,
and personal services— tends to bear out this
inference.21

from the m id-Sixties onw ard, the analysis of
patterns o f change in the structure of U. S. output
and trade in this study supports the hypothesis
of a long-run shift in U. S. com parative advantage
from go o d s to services. Nevertheless, this
conclu sion by itself is m isle adin g since it overlooks
the com plex set of changes in patterns of output
and trade that have resulted from a ch an gin g mix
o f productive factors and, to a lesser extent,
shifts in the com po sitio n o f total dem and.
Thus, services that utilize and reproduce hum an
capital and te chn ology account for the gro w in g
surplus in service trade and the expansion of
services w ithin dom estic output. G o o d s relying
heavily upon the use of hum an capital and
technology, m ainly m etal-using m anufactured
goods, have also increased their share of dom estic
output and m aintained a strong trade surplus.
In contrast, g o o d s and services relying heavily
upon inputs o f raw materials or labor have tended
to d w in d le in relative im portance within dom estic
output and to register trade deficits. M inerals,
sim ple m anufactured consum p tion goods, w holesale
and retail trade, and som e private services fall
into this group. Sectors characterized by heavy
investm ents in physical capital and eco no m ies of
scale, especially interm ediate m anufactured g o o d s
and transportation services, have declined
som ew hat m ore slow ly in relative im portance
within dom estic output and have tended to
develop sm all trade deficits.22
O n the other hand, dem and for military services
rather than com parative advantage has determ ined
trends in the share o f Federal G o vern m e nt services
in total output and the trade deficit in governm ent
services. M oreover, after 1965, the acceleration in
U. S. dem an d for military services sim ultaneously
exaggerated the expansion of output and im ports
of services, thereby distorting the longer-run p o si­
tive relationship between the expansion o f service
output and of the trade surplus in services.
Trends in agricultural output and trade
m eanw hile have reflected shifts in both dem and
and com parative advantage. C h ange s in dem and
away from raw agricultural products have resulted
in the declin in g relative im portance of agricultural
output and imports. But a substitution of physical
capital, technology, and econo m ies of scale for
traditional inputs o f land and labor has slow ed
the relative decline of agricultural exports and
resulted in a persistent surplus position in the Sixties
for the first time since the early Twentieth Century.
How ever, serious distortions in these long-run
trends after 1965 resulted in a deterioration in
the overall trade balance, affecting prim arily

C o n c lu sio n s and Im plications

the balances for m anufacturing and services.
First, the acceleration in Vietnam -related military

Taking into account distortions introduced by
cum ulative inflation and overvaluation of the dollar

expenditures sw elled service im ports dramatically.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ATLANTA




Second, inflationary credit dem an ds generated in

141

the U. S. by the sudden expansion o f military
expenditures and retention of Regulation Q further
expanded service im ports through an en suing rise
of interest paym ents to foreigners. Finally, U. S.
exchange controls dam pen ed the export grow th
of financial, technical, and professional service
exports. The dim in ish in g surplus on m anufacturing
trade, reflecting a sharp deterioration in the trade
balance for all three com ponents, apparently
stem m ed from the cum ulative im pact of inflationary
pressures after 1965 and the overvaluation of
the dollar.
Realignm ents of exchange rates in the past three
years and the prospective term ination of U. S.
restrictions on capital ou tflow s should help reduce
these distortions and perm it long-run trends to

reassert themselves. How ever, since ec o n o m ic
adjustm ents from these realignm ents are far from
com plete, several years m ust pass before the
explanatory hypothesis put forth in this article
can be fully tested.
The patterns of output and trade exam ined here
im ply that international adjustm ent involves m ore
than m onetary and fiscal policies to control
aggregate dem and. Eco n om ic policies m ust also
accom m odate structural adjustm ents in trade that
stem from o n g o in g shifts in the patterns of
dem and for g o o d s a n d services and in the mix of
productive factors w ithin dom estic econom ies.
Thus, international adjustm ent cann ot be achieved
independently o f m easures that facilitate internal
resource adjustm ent to these sh ifts.*

FOOTNOTES
'See Lawrence B. Krause, "Trade Policy for the Seventies,"
Columbia Journal of World Business, January-February 1971;
Robert A. Bennett, "Roosa Sees U. S. Economy in Major Shift,"
American Banker, November 18, 1971; and Robert E. Lipsey, "The
Current International Competitive Position of the United States,"
The Conference Board Record, April, 1972.
-Throughout this article, national output is defined as total
national income less the rest of the world component as shown
in relevant issues of the U. S. Department of Commerce, Survey
of Current Business. National income is the value of final goods
and services, less capital depreciation, indirect business taxes,
and certain other "nonincome" charges. To obtain the contribu­
tion to national income from a specific economic sector, we
must add what is left after deducting from the total value of
sales of each firm in that sector the amount of the above
charges, plus purchases of goods and services from other firms.
In contrast, exports and imports are classified according to the
total value of output actually sold in international commerce by
a specific industry. For example, in addition to the value added
by the textile firms themselves, the value of textiles exported
includes the value of fibers, transportation, etc., purchased by
the textile industry in order to produce the exported product.
8Peter G. Peterson, The United States in the Changing World
Economy, Council on International Economic Policy, December
27, 1971, Washington, D. C.
Mn contrast, services claimed only 42 percent of GNP in final
demand terms in 1971. These figures differ because a large
portion of net output of service industries becomes input to
goods-producing industries and is included in the value of goods
reaching final demand.
5lt should be pointed out that national income and its components
deflated by the GNP deflator show that the share of national
output originating in manufacturing has increased during the
Sixties. Nevertheless, the presumption of underestimation of real
product in the services sector, stemming from very difficult
methodological and data problems involved in measuring many
types of services, raises serious doubts about the validity of using
deflated rather than current dollar measures as a better indicator
of the trend in manufacturing's share of total output. (See
Martin L. Marimont, "Measuring Real Output for Industries
Providing Services: OBE Concepts and Methods," in Production
and Productivity in the Service Industries, Victor R. Fuchs, ed.,
National Bureau of Economic Research [New York and London,
1969].) Moreover, the increasing proportion of white-collar
workers in total manufacturing employment (many of whom
perform tasks similar to those performed by workers in the
business and professional service industries) suggests that a
growing proportion of manufacturing output, whether measured
on a deflated or current dollar basis, incorporates indirectly an
expanding volume of services.
“Commodity exports and imports are classified according to the
U. S. Standard Industrial Classification basis as are the detailed
industry sectors for national income. Commodity trade figures on
this basis are only available from 1958 onward, although

142



commodity trade on the Standard International Trade Classifica­
tion goes back for many years. For the years 1958 through 1970,
data were taken from the U. S. Department of Commerce,
U. S. Commodity Exports and Imports as Related to Output, for
selected years. Data for 1971 were taken from the U. S.
Bureau of the Census U. S. Exports of Domestic Merchandise,
SIC-Based Products and Area, Report FT 610, 1971 Annual, and
U. S. Imports for Consumption and General Imports, SIC-Based
Products and Area, Report FT 210, 1971 Annual. Service exports
and imports are derived from U. S. Department of Commerce
balance of payments data in relevant issues of the Survey of
Current Business and do not conform to the Standard Industrial
Classification.
Economies of scale may be of several types. Internal economies
result when a plant or firm is able to reduce unit costs of
production by expanding output. External economies result when
costs are reduced because of an expansion of the industry, the
reduction in transport costs associated with the spatial concen­
tration of producers and markets, or the growth of specialized
services accompanying local expansion of output. External
economies of scale tend to be closely associated with urbaniza­
tion. Most empirical studies that take into account scalar
economies only attempt measurement of internal economies
of scale.
sSee H. Robert Heller, International Trade: Theory and Empirical
Evidence (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey; Prentice Hall, Inc.,
1968), chapters 4 and 5.
"See, for example, the works of Simon Kuznets, especially
"Quantitative Aspects of the Economic Growth of Nations,"
Part II, Part III, and Part VII in selected issues of Economic
Development and Cultural Change and Hollis B. Chenery,
"Patterns of Industrial Growth," American Economic Review,
September, 1960, pp. 624-654.
' “Evidence relating changes in goods output to changes in the
composition of merchandise trade may be found in Simon
Kuznets, "Quantitative Aspects of the Economic Growth of
Nations: Part X. Level and Structure of Foreign Trade: Long-Term
Trends," Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 15,
No. 2, Part II, January, 1967, and Alfred Maizels, Industrial Growth
and World Trade (Cambridge, England; The University
Press, 1963).
"F or a description of this complex process in selected regions of
the southern United States, see William H. Nicholls, "Indus­
trialization, Factor Markets, and Agricultural Development,"
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 69 (August, 1961), pp. 319340, and references cited therein.
12The balance on crude foodstuffs began registering persistent
deficits in 1909. See John M. Letiche, Balance of Payments and
Economic Growth (New York, Augustine M. Kelly, 1967). The
concept of agricultural trade in this article, while predominantly
consisting of crude foodstuffs, also includes nonfood, raw
agricultural commodities. By way of comparison, the Department
of Commerce end use classification of agricultural trade, which
includes some processed food products, shows a mostly negative

SEPTEMBER 1973, M O N T H L Y REVIEW

tendency from 1923 until 1960, followed by a persistent surplus
thereafter. See William H. Branson and Helen B. Junz, "Trends
in U. S. Trade and Comparative Advantage," Brookings Paper on
Economic Activity, No. 2, 1971.

state and local governments' shares in national income. However,
we have made inferences about the composition of these services
from the functional distribution of governmental expenditures
on goods and services.

,3This downtrend is measured by the ratio of gross energy con­
sumption (in thousands of B.T.U.'s) per dollar of 1958 Gross
National Product. Actually, this downtrend was interrupted by a
sharp increase in energy consumption between 1967 and 1970.
However, the ratio dropped again in 1971 and is projected to
continue dropping until the year 2000. See Walter G. Dupree,
Jr., and James A. West, United States Energy Through the Year
2000, U. S. Department of the Interior, December, 1972, pp. 6
and 13.

19The nature of fees and royalties strongly suggests an intensive
use of human capital. Thus, they include payments for sale of
intangible property rights (patents, techniques, processes,
formulae, designs, trademarks, copyrights, franchises,
manufacturing rights, etc.) and professional, administrative, and
management services, and rental of tangible property. (This
description is from the U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau
of Economic Analysis, Survey of Current Business, June, 1971,
pp. 51-52.) Earnings on direct investments may well include
disguised payments for many of these same or related services.
Thus, a recent U. S. Tariff Commission study points out that
numerous factors may distort a rational allocation of foreign
investment related revenues between technical services and
earnings on investments. The study also provides evidence of a
positive relationship between the rate of growth of foreign direct
investment and the technological intensity of U. S. multinational
corporations. See U. S. Senate, Committee on Finance,
Implications of Multinational Firms for World Trade and
Investment and for U. S. Trade and Labor, (Washington, 1973),
Chapter VI, "Technology, R & D, and the Multinational
Firms," pp. 550-604.

14lbid., p. 7.
1!!Simple consumer goods consist of the two-digit SIC categories
of food, tobacco, textiles, apparel, furniture, printing, rubber,
and miscellaneous manufacturing. Intermediate goods consist of
lumber and wood, paper, chemicals, petroleum refining, stone,
clay and glass, and rubber and plastics. Fabricated metal goods
consist of metal fabricating, nonelectrical machinery, electrical
machinery and equipment, transportation equipment and
ordnance, and instrument industries.
16Evidence on the consumer orientation and relative factor
intensities with regard to capital, human capital, technology, and
internal economies of scale of manufacturing industries for
two- and three-digit SIC-based categories of manufacturing may
be found in G. C. Hufbauer, "The Impact of National
Characteristics & Technology on the Commodity Composition of
Trade in Manufactured Goods" and in The Technology Factor in
International Trade, Raymond Vernon, ed., National Bureau of
Economic Research, (New York, 1970), pp. 212-223.
17This assertion is based upon the proportion of professional,
technical, and kindred workers to total employed workers for
these industries. These data may be obtained from the U. S.
Bureau of the Census, Occupation by Industry 1970, Table 1. In
this article, all references to human capital intensity for service
industries are based on these data.
18National income statistics do not provide a breakout of the
different component services that make up either Federal or

-°Private payments on financial instruments (imports) declined
dramatically in 1971 but were partially offset by skyrocketing
payments on U. S. Government liabilities to foreigners. This shift
basically reflects the movement of dollars from private to central
bank hands as speculative pressures against the dollar mounted
in foreign exchange markets.
21Other private services show a small but rising trade surplus.
However, the heterogeneity of services in this component (which
includes insurance, communications, and consulting services as
well as payments related to diplomatic and other miscellaneous
services) precludes any meaningful inferences about underlying
demand and supply forces.
“ Evidence of a negative relationship between net commodity
exports and the ratio of physical capital to labor may be found in
Branson and Junz, op. cit., p. 328.

August 15, 1973
BANK OF ST. JOHN A N D BRANCHES

Reserve, Louisiana
Began to remit at par.

August 21, 1973

B an k
A n n o u n ce m e n ts

CENTRAL BANK OF SOUTH DA YT O N A

South Daytona, Florida
Opened for business as a par-remitting nonmember.
Officers: Fred Sinclair, president; Walter D. Compton,
vice president and cashier. Capital, $600,000; surplus and
other funds, $400,000.

August 1, 1973
FIRST G EO RG IA BANK

August 22, 1973

Atlanta, Georgia

Tallahassee, Florida

Admitted to membership in the Federal Reserve System
as a merger of the First Georgia Bank, Atlanta, Georgia,
and the Bank of Fulton County, East Point, Georgia.

Opened for business as a member. Officers: Edward K.
Walker, chairman; Jerry L. McDaniel, Jr., president;
Michael M. Fields, vice president; Lucy J. Tacot, cashier.

August 1, 1973

August 22, 1973

THE GULF NATIO NA L BANK

N O R T H W O O D BANK OF WEST PALM BEACH

BR O W A R D NATIO NA L BANK OF PLANTATION

West Palm Beach, Florida

Plantation, Florida

Opened for business as a par-remitting nonmember.
Officers: C. Robert Stock, president; William A. Lord,
vice president; Betty Jean Kidder, cashier. Capital,
$960,000; surplus and other funds, $484,000.

Opened for business as a member. Officers: Robert B.
Lochrie, chairman; Terrence E. Reilly, president; Carl W.
Cross, cashier. Capital, $300,000; surplus and other funds,
$300,000.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ATLANTA




143

T
o f

by

h e
B

P a r a d o x
a n k

W illia m

N.

" R

Cox,

e s e r v e s "

III

In accounting, "re se rve s" are funds set aside for future use, as a corporation
typically sets aside funds for paying taxes or replacing w o rn -o u t equipm ent.
In military tactics, "reserves" are troops deliberately held out o f the front
line to meet a break-through or exploit an opening.
In national defense, "reserves" are trained civilians w h o can be called to
military service in an em ergency.
In each o f these contexts, the m eaning o f "re se rve s" is consistent and clear:
They constitute a backstop, a stock o f additional resources held for
contingencies, a precaution against running out. W e m ight expect, therefore,
that "reserves" w o u ld serve a sim ilar function in the context of m odern
banking. Like all businesses faced with uncertainty, banks d o h old additional
resources for contingencies, especially the contin gen cy o f w idespread
w ithdraw als of custom er deposits du ring a brief period. W h e th e r the deposits
are w ithdraw n by a transfer o f currency through the teller's w in d o w or a
transfer o f funds to another bank, the bank still has to m ake paym ent. In the
extreme and unusual case w hen paym ent cannot be made, the bank fails.
To provide for the contin gen cy of large unexpected w ithdraw als, every bank
holds additional resources in readiness.
But there is a paradox here. The assets w e have com e to call "b a n k reserves"
d o n o t serve as additional resources held to pay off w ithdraw als and to protect
against bank failure, at least for the m ost part. O n the other side of the paradox,
the additional resources banks d o h old to meet w ithdraw als— their reserves in
a functional sense— are not usually called "b a n k reserves." So "b a n k reserves"
do not serve as a true reserve, but other resources do. This paradox raises
m any questions, som e of w hich are answ ered below.
If "b a n k reserves" aren't really reserves in the sense o f b e in g extra resources
held for use in contingencies, then w hat are they?
A m ore descriptive term m ight be "im m o b iliz e d assets." By law and
regulation, each m em ber bank m ust dep osit en o ugh funds with its regional
Federal Reserve Bank to equal specified prop ortions of the deposits custom ers
hold with the bank itself.1 The funds deposited at the Fed are thus assets
w hich the bank cannot lend to custom ers or invest in securities. They are
im m ob ilized in the sense that banks cannot invest them elsew here at a profit.
D o e s this m ean that "re se rv e " balances dep osite d w ith the Fed are useless
to the bank except for satisfying the regulatory requirem ents?
N o t necessarily. For instance, banks often settle debts a m o n g them selves—
debts that arise from interbank clearing of checks, transfers o f funds through
the Fed's wire system, etc.— by accepting credits to or a llo w in g charges
against their "re se rve " accounts. This and other considerations im ply that
banks w o u ld m aintain w ork in g balances at the Fed even in the absence of
"re se rve " requirements, so that som e of the required "re se rv e " balances
serve a dual purpose as far as the dep ositin g bank is concerned.
1Each bank's currency holdings, or vault cash, also count toward meeting "reserve" requirements.
Nonmember banks must meet somewhat similar requirements imposed by state banking
authorities, but not in the form of deposits with the Fed.

144



SEPTEMBER 1973, M O N T H L Y REVIEW

The "reserve b a la n c e s" are available, then, in the
sense that one bank can pay another by askin g the
Fed to transfer funds from its "re se rv e " account
to another. Right?
Right. In this sense, the Fed is a bank for banks.
For that matter, a m em ber could ask the Fed to
clean out the account and deliver the proceeds in
currency, if it w anted to.
If the fu n ds a bank deposits w ith the Fed are
available in this way, then w hy are the funds
im m ob iliz e d ? W h y cannot a bank use the
"re se rv e " fu n ds as true reserves for contingencies?
The funds are technically available, in the sense
that a bank can draw on its "re se rve " account.
But the funds used to meet Fed reserve require­
m ents are effectively im m ob ilized because if the
bank draw s them out,2 it thereby fails to meet the
reserve requirements established under the Federal
Reserve Act. This is illegal.3
But the level o f each bank's law ful required
reserves varies w ith the level of the bank's
deposits, d o e s it not?
Yes, that's correct.
So w hen a ban k's deposits fall, then the bank's
reserve requirem ent w o u ld fall too, leavin g som e of
the reserve deposits n o longer im m ob ilized. True?
True in part. U nder ou r system 's fractional
reserve requirements, a m em ber bank w o u ld
typically be required to im m ob ilize 10 cents at the
Fed for each dollar o f dem and deposits (checking
accou nt balances). So if a dollar in deposits is
w ithdraw n by a custom er, 10 cents is indeed "freed
u p " by the reduced reserve requirements. But to
pay off a custom er, the bank has to co m e up with
m ore than just 10 cents on the dollar; it has to
com e up with the w ho le dollar. "R e se rv e " balances
at the Fed, in this case, are o nly 10-percent reserves
in the sense of being m obilizable to meet such
deposit w ithdrawals. The bank m ust lo o k so m e ­
w here else for the other 90 cents.
W o u ld it be correct to say, then, that bank "r e ­
serves" held at the Fed are not there to protect the
b an kin g custom er, then?
Except for the 10 cents on the dollar, that is
correct.4
2This is true except in the peculiar case where the bank converts
reserve balances into vault cash.
3Very occasionally, a bank fails to meet its reserve requirements
at the Fed for a week or two. It then comes under administrative
scrutiny and pays a penalty interest rate on the amount of
its deficiency.
'And except in the eschatological sense. If a bank fails, its
assets including “ reserves" are distributed among its depositors
and other creditors. So "reserves" do not protect much against
failure, but they do have some value if failure occurs, similar
to a bank's capital and surplus.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ATLANTA




Then w hat does serve as a true reserve for banks
if not the "b a n k reserves" w e have been discu ssing?
This is the other side of the paradox. W h a t
resources does a bank have to meet custom er
dem ands for w ithdraw als? Each bank has three
lines of defense. First, the bank can draw on its
liquid assets, in clu d in g reserve-account balances
at the Fed held in excess of requirements, inclu ding
the bank's ow n deposits at other banks, and in­
c lu d in g readily m arketable short-term investm ent
securities and loans. Second, each bank has lines
of credit against w hich it can borrow : from other
banks in the form of interbank loans, from the
pu blic in the form o f interest-bearing certificates
of deposit, and, in the case o f m em ber banks,
from the Fed through the so-called discou nt
w indow . The third line of defense, the m ost fu n d a­
mental, is the com bination of m anagem ent
prudence, regulatory exam inations of that prudence,
and, ultimately, deposit insurance from the F D IC .
N o w let's g o back a bit. If bank "re se rve s" held
on deposit at the Fed are not truly reserves in the
sense of protecting the bank or the bank custom er,
w hat d o they d o ?
They serve another function, that of providin g
the Federal Reserve with the m eans of controlling
the overall level of bank deposits and credit.5
But if bank "re se rve s" aren't really reserves in
the usual sense of that w ord, then w hy are they
called reserves?
Basically because today's "re se rve " balances at
the Fed are the direct institutional descendants of
earlier form s of reserves— form s w hich did indeed
function as reserves in the usual sense of the word.
Before the C ivil W ar, for example, bank notes
circulated as m oney m uch as bank deposits do to­
day. The m ore reputable banks assured the circula­
tion of their notes as m oney by standing ready to
convert them into go ld coin or other w ell-esteem ed
notes, m uch as a bank today stands ready to convert
its deposits into currency or credits at another
bank. To assure this convertibility, the m ore rep­
utable antebellum banks, therefore, held in reserve
stocks of go ld coin (called specie) or notes issued
by other banks. The relationship between the level
of such reserve stocks and the am oun t of the bank's
notes ou tstan din g w as determ ined not by law, but
by prudence. Safer banks had higher ratios of
reserves to bank notes, w hich tended to m ake their
notes m ore acceptable to the public.6 ■
“See "Controlling Money with Bank Reserves," this Review, April
1973. By controlling the amount of reserves available to member
banks as a group and by controlling the reserve-to-deposit ratios
each member bank must meet, the Fed can limit the total
deposits in the banking system. Competition among the banks
impels them to issue deposits up to this limit.
“This sort of arrangement was not peculiar to pre-Civil War
American banking; it has been traced back to European
financial institutions in the Fifteenth Century.

145

S i x t h

D i s t r i c t

S t a t i s t i c s

S e a s o n a l l y A d ju s t e d
(A ll d a ta a re in d e x e s, u n le s s in d ic a t e d o th e r w ise .)

L ate st Month

One
Month
Ago

Two
M onths
Ago

One
Y ear
Ago

SIX T H D IS T R IC T

July
Ju ne
Ju ne
June

162
180
189
191

160
164
239
184

158
166
153
183

146
135
151
138

Ju ly
Ju ly

673
615

661r
570r

679
564

590
494

July
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
July
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
July
Ju ly
July
Ju ly
July
Ju ly
Ju ly
July
July
Ju ly
Ju ly

125
114
112
101
110
111
111
124
107
117
111
120
111
127
142
108
129
132
122
132
136
134
100
134
86

125
114
112
102
111
111
111
123
107
117
110
120
111
127
141
108
129
131
122
131
136
134
99
132
84

125
114
112
103
110
110
111
123
107
116
110
120
110
126
139
106
129
132
123
131
135
134
102
131
86

121
111
111
102
108
110
110
119
105
112
108
115
109
119
130
107
124
125
118
126
130
130
100
126
86

Ju ly

3.7

3.8

3.8

4.0

Ju ly
July
July
Ju ly
Ju ly
Dec.
June
Aug.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.
Apr.

1.8
40.8
242
281
203
188
84
114
292
244
188
288
297
223
164
306
349
200
191
207
232
289
445
770
454

1.8
40.7
275
308
242
187
80
115
291
242
188
284
294
223
164
307
349
200
191
207
234
285
436
772
459

1.7
40.6
203
276
131
186
79
114
289
239
186
282
287
222
162
306
348
200
191
207
231
283
436
778
453

2.4
41.1
196
257
136
168
86
126
269
234
185
266
290
215
164
299
311
193
183
185
200
267
398
650
413

Ju ly
Ju ly

238
223

234
221

231
216

184
170

Ju ly
July
Ju ly

198
175
246

195
173
236

194
171
234

169
150
190

F IN A N C E AND BAN KIN G
Lo an s*
All M em ber B a n k s .........................
Large B a n k s ........................................
Deposits*
All M ember B a n k s ..............................
Large B a n k s ........................................
B an k D e b its*/**
...................................

M anufacturing

Ju ly
Ju n e

158
205

160
224

155
209

145
145

Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly

115
113
116
118
72

115
112
116
115
70

115
112
116
117
80

112
110
113
112
75

Payrolls

Nonfarm Em ploym ent . . . .
M anufacturing
.........................
N onm anufacturing
. . . .
C o n s t r u c t i o n .........................
Farm E m p lo y m e n t .........................
U nem ploym ent Rate
(P ercent of Work Force) . .
Avg. W eekly H rs. in Mfg. (Hrs.)

4.3
41.4

4.3
40.5

4.4
40.8

Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly

219
190
214

214
186
205

213
185
194

178
165
168

. July
June

164
197

161
214

156
149

145
159

.
,
.
.

Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly

144
121
148
179
114

142
120
146
178
103

141
118
145
177
105

134
115
137
156
104

. Ju ly
Ju ly

2.7
40.9

2.8
40.9

2.8
40.8

3.7
41.7

July
Ju ly
Ju ly

268
230
284

263
224
271r

259
224
267

201
191
222

160
174

154
178

156
185

145
117

Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly

121
109
127
126
82

122
109
128
126
81

122
109
128
126
86

119
107
124
126
78

Ju ly
Ju ly

3.8
40.6

3.7
39.7

3.8
40.4

3.9
40.7

Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly

239
185
261

232
182
264

231
183
261

181
152
201

Ju ly
Ju ne

149
159

147
234

143
143

138
122

Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly

113
104
115
93
75

113
104
114
92
76

114
105
115
97
76

111
104
113
92
83

Ju ly
Ju ly

5.6
42.0

6.2
41.6

6.0
4 1.4

5.9
42.3

Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly

214
172
192

214
173
187

211
169
175

161
156
153

Ju ly
Ju n e

181
202

182
118

178
205

165
156

Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly

121
126
119
110
83

121
126
119
109
81

122
126
120
113
82

119
123
116
112
91

FIN A N C E AND BAN KIN G
Member B an k L o a n s ....................
Member B an k D eposits . . . .
B ank D eb its**
..............................

M anufacturing P a y r o l l s ..............................Ju ly
Farm C a sh R e c e i p t s ...................................June
EM P LO YM EN T
Nonfarm Em ploym ent . . . .
M anufacturing
.........................
N o n m a n u f a c tu r in g ....................
C o n s t r u c t i o n .........................
Farm E m p lo y m e n t .........................
U n em ploym ent Rate
(P ercent of Work Force) . .
Avg. W eekly Hrs. in Mfg. (H rs.)
F IN A N C E AND BAN KIN G
M em ber B an k L o a n s ....................
M em ber B an k D ep osits
. . .
..............................
B an k D eb its**
L O U IS IA N A

IN COM E
M anufacturin g Pa yro lls
. . .
Farm C a sh R e c e i p t s ....................
EM P LO Y M E N T
Nonfarm Em p loym en t . . . .
M anufacturing
.........................
N o n m a n u f a c tu r in g ....................
C o n s t r u c t i o n .........................
Farm E m p lo y m e n t .........................
Unem ploym ent R ate
(P erce n t of Work Force) . .
Avg. W eekly H rs. in Mfg. (Hrs.)
F IN A N C E AND BAN KIN G
M em ber B an k Lo an s* . . . .
M em ber B an k D ep osits* . . .
B an k D e b its*/**
.........................
M IS S IS S IP P I

M anufacturing P a yro lls . . . .
Farm C a sh R e c e i p t s ....................
EM P LO Y M E N T

E M P LO Y M E N T




4.3
40.6

EM P LO YM EN T

IN CO M E

146

Ju ly
Ju ly

Member Bank L o a n s ....................
Member B an k Deposits . . . .
Bank D eb its**
..............................

ALABAMA

Nonfarm E m p l o y m e n t .........................
M anufacturin g
...................................
N o n m a n u f a c tu rin g ..............................
C o n s t r u c t i o n ...................................
Farm E m p lo y m e n t ...................................

One
Y ea r
Ago

F IN A N C E AND BAN KIN G

IN CO M E
M anufacturing P a yro lls
....................
Farm C a sh R e c e i p t s ..............................

Two
Months
Ago

IN COM E

EM P LO YM EN T AND PR O D U CTIO N
Nonfarm E m p l o y m e n t ..............................
M anufacturing
........................................
Nondurable G o o d s ..............................
F o o d .......................................................
T e x t i l e s .............................................
Apparel
........................................
P aper
.............................................
P rinting and P u b lish in g . .
C h e m i c a l s ........................................
D urable G o o d s ...................................
Lbr., Wood Prods., Furn. & Fix .
Stone, C lay, and G la ss . . . .
Prim ary M e t a l s .........................
F ab ricated M e t a l s .........................
M a c h i n e r y ...................................
Transportation Equipm ent
Nonm anufacturin g
.........................
C o n s t r u c t i o n ..............................
Transportation
.........................
T r a d e .............................................
F in ., ins., and real est. . . .
S e r v i c e s ........................................
Fed eral G overnm ent . . . .
Sta te and Local Governm ent.
Farm E m p lo y m e n t ...................................
U nem ploym ent Rate
(P ercent of Work Force) . . . .
Insured U nem ploym ent
(P ercent of Cov. E m p . ) .........................
Avg. W eekly Hrs. in Mfg. (Hrs.) . .
C onstruction C o n t r a c t s * .........................
R e s i d e n t i a l ..................................................
All O t h e r .......................................................
E le ctric Power Production**
. . .
Cotton C o n s u m p t i o n * * .........................
Petroleum P r o d u c t i o n * * ....................
M anufacturing Production
. . . .
Nondurable G o o d s ..............................
Food
.............................................
T e x tile s
........................................
Apparel
........................................
Pap er .............................................
Printing and Pu b lish ing . .
C h e m i c a l s ...................................
D urable G o o d s ...................................
Lum b er and W o o d ....................
F u rn itu re and F ix tu re s
. .
Stone, C lay , and G la s s . . .
P rim ary M e t a l s .........................
Fab ricated M e t a l s ....................
N o n electrical M achinery . .
E le ctrica l M achinery . . . .
Transp o rtatio n Equipm ent

One
Month
Ago

U nem ploym ent Rate
(P ercent of Work Force) . .
Avg. W eekly Hrs. in Mfg. (H rs.)

IN CO M E AND SP E N D IN G
M anufacturing P a y r o l l s ..............................
Farm C a sh R e c e i p t s ...................................
C r o p s ............................................................
Livesto ck
..................................................
Instalm en t Credit at B a n k s*/1 (Mil. $)
New Lo an s ..................................................
R epaym en ts
.............................................

Latest Month

SEPTEMBER 1973, M O N T H L Y REVIEW

L ate st Month

One
Month
Ago

Two
M onths
Ago

One
Y ea r
Ago

Ju ly
Ju ly

4.4
40.4

40.7

40.3

41.1

Ju ly
Ju ly
Ju ly

225
193
227

195
219

217

181

163
252

164
159

Late st Month

O ne
Month
Ago

Tw o
M onths
Ago

One
Y ea r
Ago

EMPLOYMENT

U n em ploym ent R ate
(P erce n t of Work Force) . .
Avg. W eekly H rs. in Mfg. (H rs.)

Nonfarm Em ploym ent . . . .
M anufacturing
.........................
N o n m a n u f a c tu rin g ....................
C o n s t r u c t i o n .........................
Farm E m p lo y m e n t .........................
U nem ploym ent Rate
(P ercent of Work Force) . .
Avg. W eekly H rs. in Mfg. (H rs.)

F IN A N C E AND BAN KIN G
M em ber B an k L o an s*
M em ber B an k D eposits*
B an k D e b its*/**
. . .

.
.
.
.
.

. . July
. . Ju ly
. . Ju ly
. . Ju ly
. . Ju ly

123
115
128
121
93

124
116
128
121
93

124
116
128
122
84

119
112
123
120
88

.
.

. July
. Ju ly

3.2
40.8

3.0
40.5

2.9
40.6

3.7
40.8

Member B an k Lo a n s* . . . . . .
Member B an k Deposits* . . . . .
B an k D e b it s * / * * .............................. . .

. Ju ly
. July
. Ju ly

221
182
191

219
178
198

214
178
183

180
163
161

.
.

TEN N ESSEE
FIN A N C E AND B AN KIN G
M anufacturin g P a y r o l l s .........................July
Farm C a sh R e c e i p t s ...................................June

165

202

states

147
156
**D a ily average b asis

fP relim in a ry data

i-Revised

N.A. Not ava ilab le

Note: Indexes for bank debits, construction contracts, cotton consumption, employment, farm cash receipts, loans, petroleum
production, and payrolls: 1967 = 100. All other indexes: 1957-59=100.
S o u rces: M anufacturing production estim a ted by th is Bank; nonfarm , mfg. and nonmfg. em p., mfg. payro lls and hours, and unem p., U .S . Dept, of Labor and cooperating
state ag e n cie s; cotton consum ption, U .S. B ureau of C e n su s; construction co n tracts, F . W. Dodge Div., M cGraw-Hill Inform ation Sy stem s Co.; petrol, prod., U .S . B ure au of
M ines; ind ustria l use of ele c. power, Fed. Power Com m .; farm ca sh receipts and farm em p., U.S.D .A . Other indexes based on data co llected by th is B an k. All indexes
ca lcu la te d by th is B ank.
'D ata benchm arked to Ju n e 1971 Report of Condition

D e b i t s

t o

D e m

a n d

D e p o s i t

A c c o u n t s

In s u r e d C o m m e r c ia l B a n k s in th e S ix t h D is tr ic t
(In T h o u s a n d s o f D o lla r s )
P ercen t Change

P ercent Change

Ju ly
1973
From
July
1972

July
1973

Ju ne Ju ly
1973 1972

Bartow -LakelandW inter Haven
Daytona B ea ch
Ft. LauderdaleHollywood
. . .
Ft. M yers . . . .
G a in e sv ille
. . .
J a ck so n v ille . . . .
MelbourneTitusville-Cocoa
M iami
....................
O r l a n d o ....................
P ensaco la .
. .
Sa raso ta
. . . .
T a lla h a sse e
. . .
Tam pa-St. Pete
.
W. Palm B ea ch
.
Albany
....................
A tlanta
..................
Augusta
. . . .
Colum bus
.
Macon
....................
Sa van nah . . .
.
Alexandria
Baton Rouge
Lafayette
. .
Lak e C h a rle s
New O rleans

.
.
. .

Biloxi-Gulfport
Ja ckso n
. .

.
.

Chattanooga
Knoxville
.
N ash ville
.

.

.
.
.

. . .
. . .
. . .

.

Ju n e
1973
From

1973
from
1972

3,662,288
95,059
345,964
1,030,921
658,327
219,626

3,323,085
100,427
330,191
1,035,244
577,406
210,117

2,769,381
81,190
257,365
866,423
503,880
161,626

+ 10
- 5
+ 5
- 0
+ 14
+ 5

+32
+ 17
+ 34
+ 19
+31
+ 36

+21
+ 18
+ 19
+ 14
+ 22
+ 27

806,763
469,924

716,103
347,569

591,631
329,470

+ 13
+ 36

+ 36
+ 43

+ 26
+ 25

1,837,522
288,132
241,684
3,856,659

1,776,008
308,846
241,649
3,641,502

1,466,863
213,535
191,272
3,118,999

+
+
+

3
7
0
6

+ 25
+ 35
+ 26
+ 24

+ 17
+ 35
+ 20
+ 22

427,911
6,979,296
1,563,379
437,262
520,392
855,923
3,930,396
1,234,521

446,998
6,418,014
1,473,773
432,957
502,901
763,134
3,812,678
1,141,515

341,191
4,998,964
1,192,727
371,511
332,951
604,157
2,909,793
853,817

- 4
+ 9
+ 6
+ 1
+ 3
+ 12
+ 3
+ 8

+ 25
+ 40
+ 31
+ 18
+ 56
+ 42
+ 35
+ 44

+ 27
+ 28
+ 22
+ 11
+ 49
+ 44
+ 25
+ 37

187,176
15,280,487
520,411
431,569
540,315
537,783

194,594
15,184,118
496,861
406,285
515,173
504,621

162,706
10,667,057
409,416
363,273
453,096
420,169

+
+
+
+
+

4
1
5
6
5
7

+ 15
+ 43
+ 27
+ 19
+ 19
+ 28

+ 19
+41
+ 18
+ 11
+ 18
+ 19

259,919
1,413,581
276,126
227,204
4,420,809

225,932
1,295,321
254,304
212,866
4,086,837

208,285
1,093,787
226,914
195,154
3,330,676

+ 15
+ 9
+ 9
+ 7
+ 8

+ 25
+ 29
+ 22
+ 16
+33

+ 20
+ 13
+ 21
+ 9
+ 12

280,701
1,466,436

268,126
1,390,882

215,913
1,098,534

+ 5
+ 5

+ 30
+ 33

+ 23
+25

1,286,820
949,133
3,182,193

1,210,253
846,598
3,141,170

945,746
759,538
2,667,549

+ 6
+ 12
+ 1

+36
+ 25
+ 19

+21
+ 20
+ 20

5

+ 11

+ 15

OTH ER C E N T E R S
Anniston
. .

Ju ne
1973

Ju ly
1972

1973
from
1972

Ju ly
1973

June
1973

180,955
74,841

175,124
71,148

119,906
58,121

+ 3
+ 5

+ 51
+ 29

+ 31
+ 28

168,488
70,210
194,952
40,542r
988,644
1,808,967

129,056
57,611
141,522
37,471 r
735,602
1,406,729

+ 11
+ 7
+ 3
+ 9
+ 11
+ 1

+ 45
+31
+ 42
+ 18 r
+ 49
+ 30

+ 31
+ 26
+ 34
+ 19 r
+ 38
+ 19

164,506
102,883
166,700
19,409
141,130
72,296
39,793
56,790
142,880
98,963

162,501
96,591
179,908
22,667
126,714
65,919
47,522
67,223
139,004
94,583

148,519
90,595
148,890
22,815
105,615
51,566
31,350
47,869
123,286
84,468

+ 2
+ 7
- 7
-1 4
+ 11
+ 10
-1 6
-1 6
+ 3
+ 4

+ 11
+ 14
+ 12
-1 5
+ 34
+ 40
+ 27.
+ 19
+ 16
+ 17

+ 13
+ 21
+ 18
+ 2
+ 29
+ 23
+ 25
+ 43
+ 16
+ 13

18,942
11,131
95,192
62,917
28,092
38,353

16,546
10,882
77,054
53,163
25,472
38,504

14,149
8,490
60,550
49,341
15,218
31,902

+ 14
+ 2
+24
+ 18
+ 10
- 0

+ 34
+ 31
+ 57
+ 28
+ 85
+ 20

+ 5
+ 25
+ 36
+ 13
+ 59
+ 13

.
.

137,797
76,050
137,548
53,515

133,233
67,402
113,730
51,280

114,921
64,920
102,733
47,764

+ 3
+ 13
+21
+ 4

+ 19
+ 17
+ 34
+ 12

+ 22
+ 20
+ 19
+ 6

.
.

139,059
78,368
46,981

139,563
67,691
38,019

131,110
59,088
37,556

- 0
+ 16
+24

+ 6
+ 37
+ 25

+ 18
+ 24
+ 6

B ristol
. . . .
Johnson City
Kingsport . . .

116,492
188,371
259,987

114,982
166,638
254,935

116,145
146,029
216,010

+ 1
+ 13
+ 2

+ 0
+ 29
+ 20

- 0
+ 16
+17

Dothan
Selm a

STAN DARD M ETRO PO LITA N
ST A T IST IC A L A R E A S **
Birm ingham
. . .
G adsden
. . . .
H untsville
. . .
M o b i l e .................... .
Montgomery . . .
T uscalo o sa
. . .

Y ea r

Y ea r
to

. . . .
. . . .

B radenton
. .
Monroe County
O cala
. . . .
St. Augustine
St. Petersburg .
Tam pa
. . . .
Athens
.
B runsw ick
Dalton
.
Elberton
G a in e sv ille
Griffin
.
LaG range
Newnan
Rome
.
Valdosta

. . .
.
. . .
. .
.
. . .
. .
. .
. . .
. .

Abbeville
. .
B un kie
. . . .
Ham mond
.
New Iberia
.
Plaquem ine .
Thibodaux
.
H attiesburg
.
Laurel
. . . .
Meridian
. .
Natchez
. .
PascagoulaMoss Point
V icksb urg
.
Yazoo C ity
.

strict

Total

Alabam a
.
Florida
Georgia
. .
L o u isia n a 1 .
M issis sip p i1
T e n n e sse e 1

.

.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.

.

. .
. .
. .
. .
. .
. .

.
.

186,613
75,188
200,084
44,187
1,097,947
1,824,458

. 74,993,722

71,494,120r 57,084,222r + 5

+31

+ 26

8,604,741
. 25,892,208
21,152,663
7,913,681
3,201,718
. 8,228,711

6,625,552
8,040,573
24,459,076r 19,556,779r
20,877,609
15,632,055
6,078,048
7,284,519
2,504,236
2,994,069
7,838,274
6,687,552

+ 30
+ 32
+ 35
+ 30
+ 28
+ 23

+ 20
+ 26
+ 34
+ 22
+ 20
+ 19

+
+
+
+
+
+

7
6
1
9
7
5

1 District portion only
r-Revised
Fig u re s for som e areas differ sligh tly from p relim inary figures published in "B a n k Debits and Deposit T urnover" by Board of G overnors of the Federal R eserve System .
" C o n f o rm s to SM SA definitions a s of Decem ber 31, 1972.

FEDERAL RESERVE BAN K OF ATLANTA




147

D i s t r i c t

B u s i n e s s

C o n d i t i o n s

Signs o f co n tin u in g m oderation in the e c o n o m y's gro w th rate inclu ded slackenin g gro w th in ban k loans,
slo w in g construction activity and retail sales, and cutbacks in agricultural produ ction. H ow ever, a further
decline in the u n em p loym en t rate, sustained c o n su m e r bo rrow in g, and rising farm cash receipts indicated
sources o f c o n tin u in g strength.
Bank le n d in g contin u ed to m oderate, particularly

decline

in

soybean

prices

in

July

offset

gains

at the sm aller banks. A t the larger District banks,

throu ghou t the livestock sector. Lower feed prices

business loans, sluggish in recent m onths, strength­

checked the rise in prices paid by farmers. Cash

ened slightly in July w hile real estate loans were

receipts through the first half o f 1973 sh ow ed a

noticeably

one-fifth

weak.

Total

deposit

grow th,

running

slightly behind the pace of previous m onths, re­
m ained
large

strong,

C D 's ,

with

tim e

acco u nting

deposits,

for the

bu lk

particularly
of

current

gain

over

last

year's

level,

althou gh

Florida's gain w as m oderated by low er citrus prices.
Recent forecasts indicate substantial

increases

in

soybean and rice produ ction in 1973, but p ro d u c ­

growth. O n A u g u st 16, this Bank raised its discou nt

tion of peanuts and cotton w ill be dow n. Indicated
broiler production is d o w n 8 percent from a year

rate from 7 to

ago and even m ore in Georgia.

7

V 2 percent. By late A ugust, the prim e

rate at m ost District banks had increased to 93A
percent.
There were signs o f softness in the construction

N e w c o nsum e r instalm ent loan s rem ained at high
levels in all categories. How ever, large repaym ents

sector, th o u gh the value o f construction contract
aw ards and construction em p lo ym en t rem ain w ell

of previously incurred debt resulted in July's total
credit ou tstan din g b ein g the sm allest in 24 m onths.
Retail sales of autos and other co nsum e r g o o d s

above levels recorded a year ago. How ever, c o n ­

tapered off slightly but were substantially higher

struction e m ploym ent w as dow n slightly from early-

than the co m parable year-ago level.

1973

levels.

Residential

aw ards

rem ained

near

historic high levels, but the residential sector w as
beset by rising rates on construction and perm anent
loans, as deposit inflow s at thrift institutions slow ed
dramatically.
Prices received by farmers declined in July for

A contin u ed expansion in lab or d e m a n d n u d ge d
the u n em p lo ym en t rate d o w n to 3.7 percent in July.
Em ploym ent inched upw ard, w ith the gains centered
in non m anu facturin g industries.

Food processing,

textiles, apparel, and chem icals were the o n ly in­
dustries

recording

job

declines.

Factory

hours

the first tim e in several m onths, but prelim inary

changed little; a strike-related decline in A la b am a

data indicate another sharp increase in August. A

w as largely offset by gains in other states.

N o te : D ata o n w h ic h st a te m e n t s a r e b a s e d h a v e b e e n a d ju s te d w h e n e v e r p o s s i b l e to e lim in a te s e a s o n a l

148




in flu e n c e s.

SEPTEMBER 1973, M O N T H L Y REVIEW