View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Credit Derivatives: Where's the Risk?
Paula Tkac
Economic Review, Vol. 92, No. 4, 2007
Tkac is an economist and associate policy adviser in the Atlanta Fed's research department. The following text is adapted slightly from an interview with Tkac recorded
shortly after the Atlanta Fed's 2007 Financial Markets Conference, "Credit Derivatives: Where's the Risk?" held May 14–16. The interview is part of the Atlanta Fed's
Research Insights podcast series. To listen to this podcast or to subscribe to any of the Atlanta Fed podcast series, visit www.frbatlanta.org and click "Podcasts" on the home
page.
Moderator: Welcome to Research Insights, a podcast from the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. Our topic today is credit derivatives. . . . Our first question is, What are
credit derivatives?
Tkac: . . . Credit derivatives are a relatively recent financial innovation that effectively shifts credit risk, or the risk of default, from one party to another. The vast majority of
credit derivatives are actually known as credit default swaps, and I think it might help if I give you a simple example.
[S]uppose you want a bond, issued by a major corporation, such as GM or IBM. You're exposed to credit risk in the sense that if the corporation defaults on its bond payment,
your bond decreases in value or becomes worthless. A credit default swap allows you to transfer this credit risk to another market participant for a price. Essentially, you pay
a yearly fee to your counterparty, and they agree to pay you the par value of the debt in the case of default. Credit default swaps can also be written on sovereign debt of a
nation, baskets of corporate bonds, indexes of debt-issuing corporations, and even tranches of these indexes. The market has grown rapidly in the past decade or so and
has gotten increasingly complex as we've moved ahead.
Moderator: . . . Why do credit derivatives matter to financial markets?
Tkac: . . . I think the first reason is, as I mentioned, the large growth in the market. As of 1997, there was $180 billion in credit default swaps traded. That ballooned to over
$20 trillion in 2006, so the sheer magnitude of the trade in these instruments reflects the value of this innovation to market participants but also causes us to want to look at
them a little more closely.
I should mention [that] the major participants are banks, hedge funds, and insurance companies. Conceptually, any innovation like this that unbundles risk allows these risks
to be priced more efficiently. This [efficiency] allows participants to hedge and allows capital to flow more freely to its highest-valued use [and thus] has great benefits not only
for financial markets but for our economy more generally.
However, there are some concerns or potential for what we call "systemic risk"—the risk of spillovers of any kind of adverse event in this market to the larger financial market.
The reasons that there are some concerns are, one, that these contracts are largely bilateral. They're under the radar. They're agreed to by two individual counterparties, not
regulated through any exchanges. They involve a large notional amount. That means the value of the credit default swaps being traded out there is some fourteen to
eighteen times the value of the underlying bonds on which these instruments are written. In addition, the participation of hedge funds causes some concern because, again,
hedge funds largely operate under the regulatory radar, and so we're never certain from a policy perspective exactly what risks are being taken and whether they're being
effectively monitored.
Finally, this market has largely been untested. We've been through a very positive credit environment recently, and we don't really know what will happen if there is a major
credit event on a large scale and how that might ripple through the financial system
Moderator: . . . [Y]ou just got back from the Atlanta Fed Financial Markets Conference. Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke spoke there. There were other participants including
policymakers, academics, and market participants. What were some of the main points that were raised at this year's conference?
Tkac: [W]e spent a lot of time talking about both the risk management and, at individual firm level, the important things that market participants need to do to manage and
evaluate their risk when trading these instruments. But [we also discussed] the risks at the systemic or macro level in terms of understanding the integrity and stability of the
financial system and how credit derivatives and credit default swaps play into those concerns. [T]wo points that I would like to mention as probably most important coming out
of the conference [are], first, [that] we heard from many practitioners and policymakers about the role of financial market participants themselves in monitoring and evaluating
and managing their own risk—not only the risks of the instruments that they're holding, but importantly, for systemic reasons, the risk of their counterparties and their potential
distress. So, when you trade with another . . . entity [that] has distress or losses and can shut down and can't meet [its] obligations, that may spill over onto your concerns,
and that's where we worry about this domino effect being more pervasive.
So . . . what we heard was that each individual market participant has a great incentive to evaluate and monitor and manage [his] own risk and exposure, and this is a
powerful market-centered force to help us in constraining the potential for systemic risk. And indeed the industry itself has taken steps to improve back-office clearing and
settlement, to move to auction and cash-based settlement, away from the physical delivery of bonds. All of these contribute to the integrity and stability of the market for
credit derivatives.
Second, I'd like to reference Chairman Bernanke's remarks. He spoke more generally and brought up, I think, some very important points about regulating financial
innovations such as credit derivatives. He noted that consistency and a principlesbased paradigm for the regulation of innovations is important for achieving three public
policy objectives: financial stability, investor protection, and market integrity. This [approach] is in contrast to a more rules-based approach or an ad hoc approach, which
might regulate each instrument as it becomes available. As we all know, regulating in a rule-based fashion only encourages market participants to innovate and behave in
response to those rules in ways [that are] sometimes . . . adverse to the initial policy objective. So Chairman Bernanke's remarks, I think, provide a good roadmap going
forward as the market continues to innovate.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Credit Derivatives:
An Overview
DAVID MENGLE
The author is the head of research at the International Swaps and Derivatives Association.
This paper was presented at the Atlanta Fed’s 2007 Financial Markets Conference, “Credit
Derivatives: Where’s the Risk?” held May 14–16.

derivative is a bilateral agreement that shifts risk from one party to another; its
value is derived from the value of an underlying price, rate, index, or financial
instrument. A credit derivative is an agreement designed explicitly to shift credit risk
between the parties; its value is derived from the credit performance of one or more
corporations, sovereign entities, or debt obligations.
Credit derivatives arose in response to demand by financial institutions, mainly
banks, for a means of hedging and diversifying credit risks similar to those already
used for interest rate and currency risks. But credit derivatives also have grown in
response to demands for low-cost means of taking on credit exposure. The result has
been that credit has gradually changed from an illiquid risk that was not considered
suitable for trading to a risk that can be traded much the same as others.
This paper begins with a description of credit default swaps, total return swaps, and
asset swaps and then focuses on the mechanics and risks of credit default swaps. The
paper then describes the market for credit default swaps and how it evolved and provides an overview of pricing and the risk-management role of the dealer. Next, the discussion considers the costs and benefits of credit derivatives and outlines some recent
policy issues. The conclusion considers the possible future direction of the market.

A

How Credit Derivatives Work
The vast majority of credit derivatives take the form of the credit default swap
(CDS), which is a contractual agreement to transfer the default risk of one or more
reference entities from one party to the other (Figure 1). One party, the protection
buyer, pays a periodic fee to the other party, the protection seller, during the term
of the CDS. If the reference entity defaults or declares bankruptcy or another credit
event occurs, the protection seller is obligated to compensate the protection buyer
for the loss by means of a specified settlement procedure. The protection buyer is
entitled to protection on a specified face value, referred to in this paper as the

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

1

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 1
Credit Default Swap

XX basis points per annum

Protection buyer

Protection seller
Default payment

Reference entity

notional amount, of reference entity debt. The reference entity is not a party to the
contract, and the buyer or seller need not obtain the reference entity’s consent to
enter into a CDS.
Risks associated with credit default swaps. In contrast to interest rate swaps
but similar to options, the risks assumed in a credit default swap by the protection
buyer and protection seller are not symmetrical. The protection buyer effectively takes
on a short position in the credit risk of the reference entity, which thereby relieves the
buyer of exposure to default.1 By giving up reference entity credit risk, the buyer effectively gives up the opportunity to profit from exposure to the reference entity. In
return, the buyer takes on (1) counterparty default exposure to simultaneous default
by the reference entity and the protection seller (“double default”) and (2) counterparty replacement risk of default by the protection seller only. In addition, the protection buyer takes on basis risk to the extent that the reference entity specified in the
CDS does not precisely match the hedged asset. A bank hedging a loan, for example,
might buy protection on a bond issued by the borrower instead of negotiating a more
customized, and potentially less liquid, CDS linked directly to the loan. Another example would be a bank using a CDS with a five-year maturity to hedge a loan with four
years to maturity. Again, the reason for doing so is liquidity, although as CDS markets
expand the concentration of liquidity in specific maturities should lessen.
The protection seller, in contrast, takes on a long position in the credit risk of the
reference entity, which is essentially the same as the default risk taken on when lending directly to the reference entity. The main difference between the two is the need to
fund a loan but not a sale of protection. The protection seller also takes on counterparty risk because the seller will lose expected premium income if the buyer defaults.
One exception to the above risk allocation is the funded CDS (also called a creditlinked note), in which the protection seller lends the notional amount to the protection buyer in order to secure performance in the event of default. In a funded CDS
the protection buyer is relieved of counterparty exposure to the protection seller, but
the seller now has exposure to the buyer along with exposure to the reference entity.
In order to reduce the seller’s exposure to the buyer, the parties sometimes establish

2

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

a bankruptcy-remote entity, known as a special-purpose vehicle, that stands between
the two parties and is independent of default by the protection buyer.
CDS mechanics. The reference entity is the party on which protection is written.
For the simplest (single-name) form of CDS, the reference entity is an individual corporation or government. If a corporate reference entity is taken over by another, the
protection typically shifts to the acquiring entity. If a reference entity de-merges or
spins off a subsidiary, CDS market participants have developed a set of criteria, known
as successor provisions, for determining the new reference entities.
A CDS with two or more—usually between three and ten—reference entities is
known as a basket CDS. In the most common form of basket CDS, the first-to-default
CDS, the protection seller compensates the buyer for losses associated with the first
entity in the basket to default, after which the swap terminates and provides no further protection. CDS referencing more than ten entities are sometimes referred to
as portfolio products. Such products are generally used in connection with synthetic
securitizations, in which a CDS transfers credit risk of loans or bonds to collateralized debt obligation (CDO) note holders in lieu of a true sale of the assets as in a cash
securitization (Choudhry 2004).
A major source of credit derivatives growth since 2004 has been the index CDS, in
which the reference entity is an index of as many as 125 corporate entities. An index
CDS offers protection on all entities in the index, and each entity has an equal share of
the notional amount. The two main indices are the CDX index, consisting of 125 North
American investment-grade firms, and the iTraxx index, consisting of 125 euro-based
firms, mainly investment grade. In addition, indices exist for North American subinvestment-grade firms, for European firms that have been downgraded from investment grade, and for regions such as Japan and Asia excluding Japan. If a firm included
in the index defaults, the protection buyer is compensated for the loss and then the
CDS notional amount is reduced by the defaulting firm’s pro rata share. In addition to
CDS on indices, market participants can buy or sell protection on tranches of indices—
that is, on a specific level of losses on an agreed notional amount of an underlying
index. For example, an investor can sell protection on the 3–7 percent tranche of the
CDX Investment Grade Index with a notional amount of $100 million, which means the
investor could be required to compensate a protection buyer for losses on the index in
excess of $3 million but not beyond $7 million, for a maximum of $4 million.
Recent innovations in CDS have extended protection to reference obligations
instead of entities. CDS on asset-backed securities (ABS), for example, provide protection against credit events on securitized assets, usually securitized home equity
lines of credit. In addition, CDS can specify CDO notes as reference obligations.
Finally, loan CDS can reference leveraged loans to a specific entity.
With regard to credit events, the confirmation of a CDS deal specifies a standard
set of events that must occur before the protection seller compensates the buyer for
losses; the parties to the deal decide which of those events to include and which to
exclude. Which events are chosen varies according to the type of reference entity.
First, the most commonly included credit event is failure to pay. Second, bankruptcy
is a credit event for corporate reference entities but not for sovereign entities. Third,
restructuring, which refers to actions such as coupon reduction or maturity extension undertaken in lieu of default, is generally included as a credit event for corporate entities. Restructuring is sometimes referred to as a “soft” credit event because,
1. Credit traders in fact refer to bought protection as a short position in the reference entity and to
sold protection as a long position.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

3

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

in contrast to failure to pay or bankruptcy, it is not always clear what constitutes a
restructuring that should trigger compensation. Fourth, repudiation or moratorium
provides for compensation after specified actions of a government reference entity
and is generally relevant only to emerging market reference entities. Finally, obligation
acceleration and obligation default, which refer to technical defaults such as violation
of a bond covenant, are rarely included.
The third feature of a CDS, the settlement method, refers to the means by which
the protection seller compensates the buyer in the event of default. The two types of
settlement are physical settlement and
cash settlement. If a credit event triggers a
In contrast to interest rate swaps but simiCDS with physical settlement, the proteclar to options, the risks assumed in a credit
tion buyer delivers to the protection seller
default swap by the protection buyer and
the defaulted debt of the reference entity
with a face value equal to the notional
protection seller are not symmetrical.
amount specified in the CDS. In return, the
protection seller pays the par value—that is, the face amount—of the debt. If the
event occurs in a CDS with cash settlement, an auction of the defaulted bonds takes
place to determine the postdefault market value. Once this value is determined, the
protection seller pays the buyer the difference between the par value, which is equal
to the CDS notional amount, and the postdefault market value. Physical settlement
was the standard settlement method for most CDS until 2005 but is being replaced by
cash settlement for reasons that will be discussed in a later section.
The last major feature of a credit default swap is the premium, commonly known
as the CDS spread; this feature will be discussed in more detail in a later section. The
spread is essentially the internal rate of return that equates the expected premium
flows over the life of the swap to the expected loss if a default occurs at various dates.
The buyer and seller agree on the spread on the trade date, and the spread remains
constant for the life of the CDS; the only exception is a constant maturity CDS, in
which the credit spread is reset periodically to the current market level. The CDS
spread is quoted as an annual premium, such as 1 percent or 100 basis points per
annum, but is actually paid in quarterly installments during the year.
Transaction mechanics. In the early stages of a trading relationship, the contracting parties conduct credit analyses of each other and negotiate the terms of the
agreement under which future transactions will take place. For over-the-counter
(OTC) derivatives, including credit derivatives, the most commonly used agreement
is the International Swaps and Derivatives Association (ISDA) Master Agreement.
The agreement includes terms that the parties wish to include in all future transactions—for example, governing law, covenants, and so on. Once the parties execute
the agreement, it serves as the contract under which all future OTC derivative deals
take place. Each deal is evidenced by a confirmation, which contains the terms of the
individual transaction such as reference entity, maturity, premium, notional amount,
credit events, settlement method, and other transaction-specific terms. The terms of
the confirmation in turn draw from the ISDA definitions pertaining to the product;
for CDS, the relevant definitions are the 2003 ISDA Credit Derivatives Definitions.
Execution of a deal involves negotiating the deal terms, which as mentioned above
are listed in the confirmation. The generation of the confirmation is of particular importance because both parties must agree on the same terms; if they do not specify precisely the identity of the reference entity, for example, a protection buyer could claim
that the entity defaulted, but the payer could refuse payment because the entity
described in the confirmation is not identical to the one that defaulted. In most trans-

4

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 2
Total Return Swap

LIBOR +
X basis points
Total return
receiver

Funding cost
(<
– LIBOR)
Total return
payer

TR of reference
obligation

Reference
obligation
TR of reference
obligation

Total return swap

Total return (TR) = interest + fees ± (appreciation/depreciation) – default losses

actions, market participants will choose from a standard menu of contract terms that
have been developed collectively by ISDA member firms. As in all OTC derivatives,
however, the parties are free to negotiate terms that differ from market standards.
Following the execution of the trade, the parties will monitor for occurrence of
credit events. In addition, the parties will also have to amend trades to account for
succession events in which the reference entity changes form as mentioned previously. Finally, if a credit event occurs, the parties settle the CDS obligations according
to procedures set forth in the ISDA documentation.
Other credit derivatives. The credit default swap in various forms accounts
for the vast majority of credit derivatives activity. Three related products deserve
mention, however.
First, a total return swap transfers the total economic performance of a reference
obligation from one party (total return payer) to the other (total return receiver). In
contrast to a credit default swap, the total return swap transfers market risk along
with credit risk. As a result, a credit event is not necessary for payment to occur
between the parties.
A total return swap works as follows (Figure 2). The total return payer normally
owns the reference obligation and agrees to pay the total return on the reference
obligation to the receiver. The total return is generally equal to interest plus fees plus
the appreciation or depreciation of the reference obligation. The total return receiver,
for its part, will pay a money market rate, usually LIBOR (London Interbank Offered
Rate), plus a negotiated spread, which is generally independent of the reference obligation performance. The spread is generally bounded by funding costs: The upper
bound is the receiver’s cost of funding, and the lower bound is the payer’s cost of
funding the reference obligation. If a credit event or a major decline in market value
occurs, the total return will become negative, so the receiver will end up compensating the payer. The end result of a total return swap is that the total return payer is
relieved of economic exposure to the reference obligation but has taken on counterparty exposure to the total return receiver. The most common total return receivers
are hedge funds seeking exposure to the reference obligation on terms more favorable

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 3
Asset Swap

LIBOR
Money
market

6.30%
Investor

LIBOR + 0.85%

Corporate
note (5-year)

6.30%

Dealer

Assume that
5-year U.S. dollar interest rate swap rate = 5.45%
Par bond coupon = 6.30%
⇒ Asset swap spread = 0.85%

than by funding a direct purchase of the obligation; this tactic is sometimes known
as “renting the balance sheet” of the total return payer, which is normally a wellcapitalized institution such as a bank.
In addition to total return swaps, asset swaps are sometimes classified as credit
derivatives although they are in fact interest rate derivatives. Whatever their classification, they are relevant to credit derivatives because they are related by arbitrage to
credit default swaps. An asset swap combines a fixed-rate bond or note with an interest
rate swap (Figure 3). The party that owns the bond pays the coupon into an interest rate
swap with a similar maturity to the bond. Because the bond coupon is typically larger
than the current swap rate for that maturity, the LIBOR leg of the floating rate swap is
increased by a spread equal to the difference between the underlying bond coupon
rate and the interest rate swap rate prevailing on the trade date. Because the interest rate
swap effectively strips out the interest rate risk of the bond, the bondholder is left
mainly with the credit risk of the bond (along with some counterparty credit risk on the
swap). The asset swap spread compensates the bondholder for the credit risk; for
this reason, the asset swap spread should be related by arbitrage to the credit default
swap spread. This relationship will be discussed in more detail in the section on pricing.
One last type of credit derivative is the credit spread option, which gives the
buyer the right but not the obligation to pay or receive a specified credit spread for
a given period. Such products were never more than 5 percent of notional amounts
outstanding and are now about 1 percent (British Bankers Association [BBA] 2006),
so they are of mainly historical interest. Credit spread options appear to have given
way to swaptions on CDS, which give the buyer the right but not the obligation to buy
(put swaption) or sell (call swaption) CDS protection.
In the remainder of this paper, credit derivatives and credit default swaps will
mean the same thing unless otherwise specified.

The Market for Credit Derivatives
According to the BBA (2006), the notional amount outstanding of credit derivatives
has grown from $180 billion in 1997 to over $20 trillion in 2006 (Figure 4). Other sur-

6

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 4
Growth of Credit Derivatives
50,000
45,000

BBA
ISDA

40,000

$U.S. billion

35,000
30,000
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

Notional amounts outstanding

Sources: BBA (2006); ISDA Market Surveys, 2001–07

veys report higher numbers. ISDA, for example, began collecting CDS notional
amounts in 2001 and reports growth from $632 billion in 2001 to over $45 trillion by
midyear 2007; annual growth has exceeded 100 percent from 2004 through 2006 but
slowed to 75 percent by mid-2007. And the Bank for International Settlements, which
began collecting comprehensive statistics in 2004, reports growth of notional amount
from $6.4 trillion at the end of 2004 to almost $43 trillion as of June 2007 (BIS 2007).
Average notional amounts for individual deals range from $10 million to $20 million
for North American investment-grade credits and are about €10 million for European
investment-grade credits; sub-investment-grade credits have notionals that average
about half the amounts for investment grade (JPMorgan Chase 2006). The most liquid
maturities center on five years, but liquidity is increasing for shorter maturities and
for longer maturities out to ten years (BBA 2006).
Table 1 shows the credit derivative breakdown by product type. According to the
BBA, CDS on indices have recently passed CDS on single names as the dominant
product type (BBA 2006). Single-name CDS, which were 38 percent of notional
amount outstanding in 1999, grew to as high as 51 percent in 2004 and are 33 percent
as of 2006. CDS linked to indices and to tranches of indices have grown from virtually
nothing in 2003 to 38 percent of outstandings. Finally, CDS referencing portfolios of
names in synthetic securitization transactions have declined slightly from 18 percent
in 2000 to just over 16 percent in 2006. The “others” category includes total return
swaps and asset swaps, which are now less than 6 percent of outstandings; in 2000,
in contrast, total return swaps were 11 percent of outstanding amounts, and asset
swaps were 12 percent (BBA 2002).
Tables 2 and 3 show the breakdown of market participants by type. Banks and
securities firms were dominant in 2000, at 81 percent of protection buyers and 63 percent of protection sellers. By 2006, they had declined in importance to 59 percent
of buyers and 44 percent of sellers. Recent data distinguish between banks’ trading

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

7

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table 1
Credit Derivative Product Mix
2000

2002

2004

2006

38
6
—
—
—
—
10
5
—
—
41

45
6
—
—
—
—
8
5
—
—
36

51
4
9
2
6
10
6
2
1
1
8

33
2
30
8
4
13
3
1
0
1
6

Single-name credit default swaps
Basket products
Full index trades
Tranched index trades
Synthetic CDOs—fully funded
Synthetic CDOs—partially funded
Credit-linked notes (funded CDS)
Credit spread options
Equity-linked credit products
Swaptions
Others
Source: BBA (2006)

activities and credit portfolio management activities: Trading activities are roughly
balanced between buying and selling protection while credit portfolio managers
appear more likely to hedge by buying protection than to seek diversification through
selling protection. Insurance companies tend to be active as sellers of protection;
they were 23 percent of sellers in 2000 but dropped to 17 percent by 2006. The
most significant change has been in the importance of hedge funds, which tend to
function as both buyers and sellers: In 2000, hedge funds were 3 percent of buyers
and 5 percent of sellers but by 2006 had grown to 28 percent of buyers and 32 percent of sellers.
Table 4 shows the most common CDS counterparties—essentially, the most
active dealers in the market—from 2003 through 2006. Table 5 shows the most common reference entities for single-name CDS, both by deal count and by underlying
notional amount, as of year-end 2006 (Fitch Ratings 2007).
Evolution of the market. Smithson (2003) identified three stages in the evolution of credit derivatives activity. The first, “defensive” stage, during the late 1980s
and early 1990s, was characterized by ad hoc attempts by banks to lay off some of
their credit exposures. In addition, products such as securitized asset swaps bore
some resemblance to credit default swaps in that they paid investors a credit spread
while providing for delivery of the underlying asset to the investor in the event of a
default (Cilia 1996).
Stage two, which began about 1991 and lasted through the mid-to-late 1990s,
saw the emergence of an intermediated market, in which dealers applied derivatives
technology to the transfer of credit risk while investors entered the markets to seek
exposure to credit risk (Spinner 1997). Examples of dealer applications of derivative
technology include two transactions by Bankers Trust (Das 2006, 269–70). The first
involved a total return swap with another bank client seeking to free up credit lines
with a major client. The swap enabled the bank to pass its credit risk to Bankers
Trust, which in turn hedged its risk by selling the client’s bonds short. The second
transaction involved a funded first-to-default CDS on several Japanese client banks,
against which Bankers Trust had substantial credit exposure in the form of in-themoney options. Although defensive in nature from Bankers Trust’s viewpoint, the

8

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table 2
Buyers of Protection by Institution Type
Type of institution

2000

2002

2004

2006

67
—
—
7

59
39
20
6
2
2
2
28
2
2
2
1

Banks (including securities firms)
Banks—trading activities
Banks—loan portfolio
Insurers
Monoline insurers

81
—
—
7
—

73
—
—
6
3*

Reinsurers
Other insurance companies
Hedge funds
Pension funds
Mutual funds
Corporates
Other

—
—
3
1
1
6
1

3
12
1
2
4
2

2
3
2
16
3
3
3
1

2002

2004

2006

54
—
—
20
10
7
3
15
4
4
2
1

44
35
9
17
8
4
5
32
4
3
1
1

*Monoline insurers and reinsurers combined
Source: BBA (2006)

Table 3
Sellers of Protection by Institution Type
Type of institution
Banks (including securities firms)
Banks—trading activities
Banks—loan portfolio
Insurers
Monoline insurers
Reinsurers
Other insurance companies
Hedge funds
Pension funds
Mutual funds
Corporates
Other

2000
63
—
—
23
—
—
—
5
3
2
3
1

55
—
—
33
21*
12
5
2
3
2
0

*Monoline insurers and reinsurers combined
Source: BBA (2006)

transaction appealed to investors seeking yield enhancement by buying the creditlinked notes issued by Bankers Trust.
Another innovation during this phase was the synthetic securitization structure.
Synthetic securitization represented the extension of credit derivatives to structured
finance, that is, to the combining of derivatives with cash instruments or with other
derivatives to attain a desired exposure. The first synthetic securitization transactions
included the Glacier transaction, developed by SBC Warburg (now UBS), and the Bistro
transaction, developed by J.P. Morgan (now JPMorgan Chase). Glacier was a funded
structure, in which SBC transferred to investors the entire credit risk of approximately $1.75 billion of loans by means of credit-linked notes. Bistro, in contrast, was

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table 4
Twenty Largest CDS Counterparties, 2003–06
2003

2004

2005

2006

JPMorgan Chase

Deutsche Bank

Morgan Stanley

Morgan Stanley

Deutsche Bank

Morgan Stanley

Deutsche Bank

Deutsche Bank

Goldman Sachs

Goldman Sachs

Goldman Sachs

Goldman Sachs

Morgan Stanley

JPMorgan Chase

JPMorgan Chase

JPMorgan Chase

Merrill Lynch

Merrill Lynch

UBS

Barclays

CSFB

CSFB

Lehman Brothers

UBS

UBS

Lehman Brothers

Barclays

Lehman Brothers

Lehman Brothers

Merrill Lynch

Citigroup

Credit Suisse

Citigroup

Citigroup

CSFB

Merrill Lynch

Bear Stearns

Bear Stearns

BNP Paribas

BNP Paribas

Commerzbank

Barclays

Merrill Lynch

ABN Amro

BNP Paribas

BNP Paribas

Bear Stearns

Bear Stearns

Bank of America

Bank of America

Bank of America

Citigroup

Dresdner

Dresdner

Dresdner

Société Générale

ABN Amro

HSBC

ABN Amro

HSBC

Société Générale

Commerzbank

HSBC

Dresdner

AIG

Royal Bank of Scotland

Société Générale

Bank of America

Barclays

Société Générale

Calyon

Royal Bank of Scotland

Toronto Dominion

ABN Amro

Royal Bank of Scotland

Calyon

Calyon

Toronto Dominion

AIG

CIBC

Source: Fitch Ratings (various years)

a partially funded structure, in which Morgan transferred to investors approximately
10 percent of the credit risk by means of a credit default swap while retaining any
loss beyond that in the form of a “super-senior” tranche (Choudhry 2004). Although
the transactions appear defensive from UBS and Morgan’s point of view, they also
appealed to investors seeking exposure to credit risk.
Investors benefited from the above second-stage innovations in at least two
ways. First, investors could attain exposure to loans, which had previously been out
of reach becaue of the lack of a credit processing infrastructure among buy-side
firms. Second, investors could attain exposure to credit risk without having to accept
exposure to interest rate risk as well; asset swaps were an early means of attaining
such exposure.
The third stage saw the maturing of credit derivatives from a new product into
one resembling other forms of derivatives. Single-name credit default swaps emerged
during this period as the “vanilla,” or generic, credit derivatives product, while structured finance groups combined credit derivatives into “arbitrage” CDO packages
geared to investor demands. Major financial regulators issued guidance for the regulatory capital treatment of credit derivatives, which served to clarify the constraints
under which the emerging market would operate. Further, ISDA in 1999 issued a set
of standard credit derivatives definitions for use in connection with the ISDA Master
Agreement. Finally, dealers began warehousing risks and running hedged and diversified portfolios of credit derivatives.

10

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table 5
Top Reference Entities, Gross Protection Bought and Sold, Year-End 2006
Largest by count

Largest by volume

Protection sold

Protection bought

Protection sold

Protection bought

1

General Motors/GMAC

General Motors/GMAC

General Motors/GMAC

General Motors/GMAC

2

DaimlerChrysler

DaimlerChrysler

Brazil

Brazil

3

Telecom Italia

Ford Motor Corp./
Ford Motor Credit

DaimlerChrysler

DaimlerChrysler

4

Italy

France Telecom

Ford Motor Corp./
Ford Motor Credit

France Telecom

5

Deutsche Telekom

Telecom Italia

Turkey

Turkey

6

Ford Motor Corp./
Ford Motor Credit

Telefonica

Telecom Italia

Ford Motor Corp./
Ford Motor Credit

7

Brazil

Brazil

Russia

Telecom Italia

8

Telefonica

Deutsche Telekom

France Telecom

Deutsche Telecom

9

France Telecom

Italy

Deutsche Telecom

Russia

10

Russia

Volkswagen

Telefonica

Telefonica

11

BT Group

Russia

United Mexican States

AT&T

12

Fannie Mae

Time Warner

BT Group

BT Group

13

General Electric/GECC

Turkey

Italy

AIG

14

Spain

Argentina

AT&T

Volkswagen

15

Turkey

BT Group

General Electric/GECC

General Electric/GECC

16

Portugal

General Electric/GECC

AIG

Gazprom

17

United Mexican States

Altria Group

Fannie Mae

Banco Santander
Central Hispano

18

France

Bombardier

Altria Group

Safeway

19

Germany

Merrill Lynch

KPN

United Mexican States

20

Altria Group

Philippines

Vodafone

Altria Group

21

Deutsche Bank

United Mexican States

Portugal Telecom

Argentina

22

Merrill Lynch

AIG

VNU

KPN

23

Gazprom

Bayer

Safeway

Venezuela

24

Time Warner

Citigroup

Gazprom

AXA

25

Volkswagen

Clear Channel

Venezuela

Supervalu

Source: Fitch Ratings (2007)

During this stage, the market encountered a series of challenges that led to calls
for further refinement to the documentation. One such problem was restructuring.
The 1999 definitions included debt restructuring—that is, actions such as lowering
coupon or extending maturity—as a credit event triggering payment under a CDS.
The definition was put to the test with the restructuring in 2000 of loans to Conseco.
Banks agreed to extend the maturity of Conseco’s senior secured loans in return for
higher coupon and collateral; protection was thereby triggered on about $2 billion of
CDS. Protection buyers then took advantage of an embedded “cheapest to deliver”
option in CDS by delivering long-dated senior unsecured bonds, which were deeply

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

11

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

discounted—worth about 40 cents on the dollar—relative to the restructured loans,
which were worth over 90 cents on the dollar. Protection sellers ended up absorbing
losses that were greater than those incurred by protection buyers, which led many
protection sellers to question the workability of including restructuring. The problem
was complicated further by the insistence by some regulators that CDS cover restructuring for a CDS hedge to qualify for capital relief. The result, arrived at through
ISDA committee efforts, was a set of modWith the new ISDA credit derivatives defiifications to the definition of restructuring
that placed some limits on deliverable bond
nitions in place, dealers in 2003 began to
maturity and therefore on the cheapesttrade according to certain standardized
to-deliver option.
practices that went beyond those adopted
Another problem involved apportioning
credit protection when a reference
for other OTC derivatives.
entity de-merges or spins off part of its
activities into new entities. The problem arose in the United Kingdom in 2000, when
National Power de-merged into two companies; one company inherited 56 percent of
National Power’s obligations, and the other held the rest. The problem was to determine the new reference entity for CDS referencing National Power, but the 1999 definitions did not provide sufficient guidance to assure the market that courts would
agree on the outcome. The result was to develop a set of detailed “successor” provisions, which provided quantitative thresholds for such cases.
Yet another problem was debt moratoriums or repudiations in emerging markets.
During the Argentine debt crisis of 2002, there were several changes of government,
involving a succession of officials who made threats regarding debt repudiation. The
problem arose that, under the 1999 definitions, it was possible to declare a repudiation credit event following a statement by a government official even if in the end the
government did not fail to pay its obligations. To reduce the risk of declaring a credit
event prematurely, ISDA developed more stringent criteria for such an event.
The foregoing problems led ISDA to issue in 2003 a new set of credit derivatives
definitions. At this point, one can add a fourth stage to those cataloged by Smithson,
namely, the development of a liquid market. With the new ISDA credit derivatives
definitions in place, dealers in 2003 began to trade according to certain standardized
practices—standard settlement dates, for example—that went beyond those adopted
for other OTC derivatives. Further, index trading began on a large scale in 2004 and
grew rapidly. The wide acceptance of index trading at that time was in part the result
of the merger of the iBoxx and Trac-x credit indices into iTraxx for Europe and CDX
for North America. The mergers provided market participants with a single index,
subject to transparent rules and a high degree of standardization, for each major
market. At the same time, dealers took deliberate measures to promote liquidity in
index trading; such measures included developing master confirmations, committing
to quote tight bid-offer spreads, and allowing investors to trade out of an old index
and “roll” into the new one at mid-market spreads. Index trading was more appealing
to investors than single-name trading because indices provide diversified exposure
instead of concentrating it on one name. The results went well beyond expectations:
According to one survey, index product growth was 900 percent in 2005 (Fitch
Ratings 2006).
This last stage saw the entry of hedge funds on a large scale as both buyers and
sellers (Tables 2 and 3). Hedge funds use credit derivatives in a variety of ways. First,
hedge funds use credit derivatives in their convertible bond arbitrage activities to strip
out unwanted credit risk. Second, hedge funds can buy and sell protection to profit

12

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

from perceived mispricing. Finally, hedge funds engage in basis trading between
credit default swaps and assets swaps on cash bonds. All these activities serve to
increase liquidity, price discovery, and efficiency in the market.

Pricing, Valuation, and Risk Management
CDS pricing and valuation. The premium for a credit default swap is commonly
known as a CDS spread and is quoted as an annual percentage in basis points of the
notional amount. Although quoted as an annual percentage, protection buyers actually
pay the spread on a quarterly basis, that is, in four installments per year. Further, in
contrast to other OTC derivatives, CDS have standard payment dates, namely, March
20, June 20, September 20, and December 20; these standard payment dates also
serve as standard maturity dates. CDS transacted prior to a standard payment date
are subject to a “stub” period up to the first standard payment date and follow the
standard schedule afterwards. A CDS with a five-year maturity agreed on May 1, 2007,
for example, would become effective on May 2 with the accrued premium due on
June 20; subsequent payments would occur on regular dates until maturity on June
20, 2012. If the spread for a distressed credit is sufficiently high, the CDS will trade
“up front”—that is, the buyer will pay the present value of the excess of the premium
over 500 basis points at the beginning of the trade and pay 500 basis points per annum
for the life of the swap (Taksler 2007, 44).
There are two basic ways of determining a CDS spread, namely, from asset swap
spreads and from calculation of expected CDS cash flows. Assets swaps, which were
described in a preceding section and shown in Figure 3, are related to credit default
swaps because both products serve to unbundle credit risk. In an asset swap, an
investor purchases a reference entity’s cash bond—preferably priced at par—and
pays the bond coupon into an interest rate swap of the same maturity. As mentioned
previously, the swap counterparty adjusts the LIBOR leg of the swap for the difference between the bond coupon rate and the par swap rate for the same maturity;
the difference is known as the asset swap spread and compensates the investor for the
default risk on the bond.
The asset swap spread performs essentially the same function as a CDS spread,
so the two should be related by arbitrage. If CDS spreads are low relative to asset
swap spreads, for example, a dealer or investor could buy an asset-swapped bond
and offset it by buying protection (equivalent to selling the reference entity short)
and locking in a profit. Such arbitrage should lead to convergence between CDS
spreads and asset swap spreads (narrowing of the basis). Arbitrage in the other
direction is not as straightforward, however: If CDS spreads are higher than asset
swap spreads, arbitrage requires selling protection (long the credit) and selling the
bond short. Shorting a bond is often not feasible, however, and will depend crucially
on the liquidity of the underlying bond market.
The possibility of arbitrage between CDS and asset swaps will nonetheless tend
to reduce the basis between the two rates. But other factors are also at work to keep
the rates from converging (Choudhry 2006). Supply and demand factors might affect
the price of CDS relative to bonds in several ways. Structured finance activity, for
example, might lead to sales of protection to fund CDO notes, thereby driving down
CDS spreads relative to bonds. Similarly, investors with high funding costs might prefer to take on credit risk by selling protection rather than by purchasing bonds
financed by borrowing, again driving spreads down relative to bond yields. And in the
other direction, a bond trading below par will tend to push CDS spreads higher relative to bond yields. The reason is that a protection seller pays out the difference

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

13

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

between par value and postdefault price, while an investor who bought the bond
below par has lost only the difference between the below-par purchase price and the
postdefault price. The result of the above factors is that, even if asset swap spreads
will not in most cases converge to CDS spreads, they are a reasonable starting point
for calculating the spread.
As an alternative to relying on asset swap spreads, CDS pricing models seek to
calculate CDS spreads by calculating expected cash flows. In such models, the CDS
spread is an internal rate of return that equates present value of expected premium
payments to present value of expected loss payments; that is
PV(expected spread payments) = PV(expected
default losses), where
n
Σ
DCF
PV(expected spread payments) = Spread
×
i × PSi × PVi (N) and
n
i=1
Σ [(PSi–1 – PSi) × PVi(N)]
PV(expected default losses) = LGD × i=1
using the following notation:
Spread = fixed CDS spread;
DCFi = day count fraction relevant to period i;
PSi = survival probability, that is, probability of no default from inception to period i;
PVi(.) = present value operator for period i;
N = notional amount of CDS protection;
LGD = loss rate given default, equal to (1 – recovery rate), assumed fixed; and
PSi–1 – PSi = PDi = probability of default in period i.
Solving the model involves calculating the spread that equates net present value
to zero—that is, an internal rate of return—under an assumed LGD. The survival and
default probabilities come from outside the model; alternatively, market spreads can
be used to calculate implied probabilities of default under an assumed LGD. For simplicity, the above equations ignore accrued spread, which in the event of default
would be payable by the buyer to the seller for the fraction of the period from the last
premium payment date to the default date.
After inception, the value of the CDS will depend mostly on changes in credit
quality as reflected in current credit spreads. Given that the CDS spread for a transaction remains fixed, the mark-to-market value of the CDS will be equal to the present
value of the spread differences over the life of the CDS, taking account of survival
probabilities and, again, ignoring the accrued premium. Letting Spread0 equal the
CDS spread fixed at inception and Spreadi equal the current market spread, markto-market value from the buyer’s point of view is
n

Σ DCFi × PSi × PVi(N).
MTMi = (Spreadi – Spread0) × i=1
If the buyer were to unwind at this point (to be discussed in the section on novations),
the above equation represents the amount payable to the buyer.2
Just as difficulties exist using asset swap spreads, problems are associated with
models such as that described above. A major difficulty is that the model requires
that one assume an LGD and furnish exogenous probabilities of default to calculate
an implied CDS spread. Alternatively, one could use the current market CDS spread
to calculate an implied probability of default, but doing so would still require assuming an LGD. Assumptions regarding recoveries therefore are important to CDS pricing
and valuation. In practice, market participants can model the effect of alternative

14

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

LGD assumptions and can set aside reserves against differences in assumptions
(JPMorgan Chase 2006, 92–93; Chaplin 2005, 105).
Risk management. The purpose of a derivatives dealer, along with making a twoway market, is to earn profits by managing the risk of a portfolio of derivatives. For
credit derivatives, the risk management function is similar in form to that for other
types of derivatives. When a dealer takes on risk from a client, the dealer typically
hedges the risk but might elect to leave some of the risk uncovered. The willingness
of dealers to leave some risks uncovered—that is, to speculate—adds liquidity to the
market but requires close management.
Typically, however, dealers hedge their risks in some manner. Most simply, a dealer
might offset the risk of a new deal against that of other clients. Further, the dealer might
hedge the risk of a deal in the underlying market, that is, the cash bond market; for
that reason, credit derivatives and corporate bond risks are often managed together.
Finally, a dealer might choose to offset risks by means of offsetting transactions with
other dealers; this is a primary function of the interdealer market.
In the early stages of credit derivatives as described above, risk management
essentially consisted of laying off one’s own risks. As the market developed into a twosided market, dealers assumed the role of intermediaries between buyers and sellers,
taking on the basis risk between the two. In these early stages of development, dealers tended to hedge new transactions with offsetting cash market positions to the
extent feasible or else with offsetting transactions.
As the market has developed, additional hedging alternatives have become available. The growth of index CDS, for example, has increased the flexibility of dealers
in their risk-management activities. After the advent of widely traded index CDS,
market liquidity increased significantly, and new market participants entered both as
buyers and sellers. In such an environment, the business has evolved into a “flow”
business: that is, traders tend to remain “flat” by buying and selling continually
instead of by taking large open long or short positions. But trading desks also can use
index CDS to hedge their single-name CDS. For example, on any given day spreads
tend to move in the same direction, so index swaps might be a reasonable hedge of a
diversified single-name CDS portfolio; as with other hedges, the dealer would assume
and manage the basis risk between the two.3
Along with the market risks of their deal portfolios and the accompanying basis
risks, dealers manage a host of other risks. First, counterparty credit risk is a major
component of all OTC derivatives activity. Counterparty risk management begins
with ISDA or other relevant transaction documentation, followed by measurement of
both current exposure and potential losses if default were to occur in the future and
finally by collateralization of net exposures. Second, dealers manage such risks as
time decay, in which deals lose value as they approach maturity. Finally, dealers manage model risks, which are associated with the simplifying assumptions as well as
unidentified errors in pricing models; to anticipate the possibility of model deficiencies, dealers calculate potential losses from modeling errors and set aside reserves to
cover them (Chaplin 2005, 100–106).
One unique aspect of credit derivatives activity compared with other OTC derivatives is liquidity management. Credit derivatives are characterized by a higher degree
of standardization than are other forms of OTC derivatives, although the standard
2. For a more detailed practitioner-oriented discussion of CDS pricing, see Chaplin (2005).
3. This type of hedging is roughly equivalent to hedging interest rate swaps with Treasury bonds or
an equity portfolio with S&P 500 futures.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

15

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

terms are not mandatory as in exchange-traded futures. As noted above, CDS involve
standard payment and maturity dates. Further, each type of reference entity involves
a standard set of credit events and other terms. Standard terms facilitate trading by
simplifying negotiation and tasks such as unwinds; they also make it easier for market
participants to engage in arbitrage between CDS indices and underlying names.
Credit derivatives participants have adopted a higher degree of standardization
because credit risk is different from other underlying risks. Unlike interest rate swaps,
in which the various risks of a customized transaction can be isolated by traders and
offset in liquid underlying money and currency markets, credit default swaps involve
“lumpy” credit risks that do not lend themselves to decomposition. Standardization
is therefore a substitute for decomposition. Yet despite the higher degree of standardization, CDS retain their essential nature as OTC rather than standardized transactions: Parties to CDS deals remain free to diverge from the market standard and to
customize transactions to whatever extent they agree.

Benefits and Costs of Credit Derivatives
Benefits. Credit derivatives emerged in response to two long-standing problems in
banking. First, lending operated under the handicap that hedging credit risk was seldom, if ever, feasible. In financial terms, the problem was that taking a short position
in credit was not generally feasible. Although selling a corporate bond short is theoretically possible, many borrowers do not have liquid debt outstanding, so borrowing
for a short sale is often not feasible. As a result, if a credit deteriorates, a lender can
do little to protect itself prior to default other than taking collateral, which might not
be effective in many distressed cases, or by selling the loan, which normally requires
the consent of the borrower.
A second problem was diversification of credit risk. Financial economists have
long noted the benefits of applying a portfolio approach to loans by means of diversification (Flannery 1985), but practical considerations made diversification difficult
to achieve. Relationship considerations, for example, posed an obstacle to diversifying by deliberately reducing exposure to major clients. Further, the statistical properties of credit risk—that is, non-normality of loss distributions and the resulting
effect of specification errors in determining losses in the tail of the distributions—
suggest that a truly diversified loan portfolio requires a significantly larger number of
credits than would an equity or bond portfolio (Smithson 2003, 34–38). Given such
obstacles, the only practical way to diversify a lending business was to grow to a large
size by means of acquiring other banks.
Buying protection by means of credit derivatives provides solutions to both of the
foregoing problems. By allowing banks to take a short credit position, credit derivatives enable banks to hedge their exposure to credit losses. A major benefit is that,
in contrast to loan sales, CDS do not require consent of the reference entity. As a
result, lenders also have a solution to the second problem, diversification. By hedging selectively, a bank can reduce its exposure to certain entities, thereby attaining
its diversification objective without jeopardizing the client relationship.
Another benefit to the protection buyer is the ability to act on a negative credit
view. If an investor believes that the market is overly optimistic about a reference
entity’s prospects, for example, the investor can buy protection now in anticipation
of deterioration. If the investor’s view turns out to be correct, the investor can
unwind the transaction at a profit by selling protection on the entity. Such speculative activity has the beneficial effect of adding liquidity to the market and of increasing the quality of price discovery (International Monetary Fund [IMF] 2006, chap. 2).

16

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Market participants can also use CDS to engage in arbitrage between markets. In
convertible bond arbitrage, for example, an investor buys a convertible bond in which
the embedded equity option is underpriced, uses an asset swap to hedge out the
interest rate risk, and then buys credit protection to hedge out the credit risk. The
investor is then left with a pure equity exposure, which is the object of the arbitrage.
With regard to sellers of protection, credit derivatives enable market participants to
attain exposure in the form of a long credit position. A financial institution seeking
to diversify its credit exposure might, for
Unlike interest rate swaps, in which risks
example, sell CDS protection as an alternacan be isolated and offset in liquid undertive to making loans or buying bonds. This
alternative is especially helpful to institulying money and currency markets,
tions that seek credit exposure but lack the
credit default swaps involve “lumpy”
legal infrastructure for lending; it is also
credit risks that do not lend themselves
helpful to banks seeking to diversify their
loan portfolios but lacking direct relationto decomposition.
ships with desired credits. Further, selling
protection allows an investor with a high cost of funding to take on credit exposure
without incurring the cost of funding. It is important in such cases that the investor
realizes that the exposure to losses is the same as if it were lending directly.
The ability to sell protection also allows market participants to act on a view that
a reference entity’s credit quality will improve. In this case, the investor would sell
protection now in the hope of unwinding it later by purchasing it at a lower price. As
mentioned above, such activity adds liquidity to the market and increases the quality
of price discovery.
Another benefit of credit derivatives is that they add transparency to credit markets (Kroszner 2007). Prior to the existence of credit derivatives, determining a price
for credit risk was difficult, and no accepted benchmark existed for credit risk. As
credit derivatives become more liquid and cover a wider range of entities, however,
lenders and investors will be able to compare pricing of cash instruments such as
bonds and loans with credit derivatives. Further, investors will be able to engage in
relative value trades between markets, which will lead to further improvements
in efficiency and price discovery.
At a higher level, economic stability stands to benefit from the ability to transfer
credit risk by buying and selling protection. As with other derivatives, the cost of risk
transfer is reduced, so risk is dispersed more widely into deeper markets. The result
is that economic shocks should have less effect than was the case prior to the existence of derivatives. Several objections can be made to such an argument, however,
and these will be considered in the next section.
Costs. It is often argued that the flip side of wider and deeper risk transfer is that,
instead of exerting a stabilizing influence on markets, it is potentially destabilizing
because it transfers risk from participants that specialize in credit risk (that is, banks)
to participants with less experience in managing credit risk—for example, insurers
and hedge funds (“Risky business” 2005, for example). In addition, there is the danger that anything used to disperse risk can also be used by investors seeking yield
enhancement to concentrate risk. Finally, these new institutions generally fall outside
the regulatory reach of agencies that oversee various aspects of the credit markets.
Such arguments have weaknesses, however. While it is true that banks traditionally specialize in managing credit risk, for example, it is also true that traditional lending has tended to concentrate credit exposures in a narrow class of institutions,
namely, commercial banks. Further, one could argue that nonbank institutions might

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

17

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

in many cases have liability structures that are more suitable than those of banks for
bearing credit risks (IMF 2006, chap. 2). But even if one were to accept the questionable argument that nonbank investors are inevitably less skilled than banks at
managing credit risk, it would also be the case that credit losses would have less
effect on any one institution than was the case when credit was limited mostly to
banks. Finally, the argument that credit derivatives increase overall risks by transferring credit risk outside strictly regulated institutions makes an implicit assumption
that government regulation automatically leads to more prudent risk-taking. But this
argument ignores the potential moral hazard associated with such an assumption.
Indeed, because less regulated institutions are less likely to be protected by an official
safety net, such institutions are likely to have substantial incentives to identify, measure, and manage credit exposures (Kroszner 2007).
Another commonly cited cost of credit derivatives is that they reduce incentives
for lenders to analyze and monitor credit quality because they now have the ability
to off-load credit risk (Jackson 2007, for example). The result is a decrease in overall credit quality. Again, there are weaknesses to such arguments, mainly that hedging is not costless. As is true with other risks, when one hedges away a risk, one also
hedges away the opportunity to profit. A possible exception to this rule would be systematic underpricing of CDS protection relative to loan risk, for which no evidence
exists. Another possible exception is a “lemons” argument that lenders use collateralized debt obligations to off-load risks to protection sellers, although one would
expect that such a practice, if widespread, would induce CDO note buyers to build
expectations of higher losses into the price of the credit protection they provide. Yet
another exception would be lenders’ possessing inside information about credit quality, on which they could act by buying underpriced protection. This issue has already
received extensive attention by the financial industry (Joint Market Practices Forum
2003), however, and one would not expect such activity to be a systematic feature of
credit derivatives markets.
A corollary to the argument that lenders with access to credit protection are
indifferent to risk is that credit derivatives, as do other forms of risk transfer,
inevitably involve a moral hazard effect that leads to higher risk overall (Plender
2006). In other words, risk reduction at the individual entity level can mean higher
risk at the system level. Such an argument has an element of plausibility in that, when
market participants are able to hedge certain risks, they are able to increase the
amount of risks they take overall. But even if firms do take on more risk than before,
one could argue that, as long as firms do not take on excessive amounts of risk, the
system is in fact safer because the individual institutions that hedge are less vulnerable to market shocks.

Recent Credit Derivatives Policy Issues
Novations and operational backlogs. The entry of hedge funds and other
investors into credit derivatives has been an important factor in the development of
CDS market liquidity and efficiency. Such investors enter primarily to take positions.
As described above, an investor who believes protection on a reference entity is
underpriced can buy protection in anticipation that spreads will widen; if the view
turns out to be correct, the fund reverses the transaction at a profit. Similarly, a fund
that believes that a distressed credit’s prospects will improve could sell protection in
the hope of unwinding at a profit if the improvement occurs.
In order to understand the novations problem, one must understand how OTC
derivatives trade. OTC derivatives do not trade in the same way as securities, that is,

18

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

by means of transfer of ownership. Instead, they trade “synthetically” by three different means, each of which involves payment by one party to the other of a transaction’s
mark-to-market value. First, the parties can agree to a termination (or tear-up), under
which they agree to extinguish the original obligation following payment. Second, one
party can enter into an offsetting transaction, which leaves the original transaction in
place but effectively cancels out its economic effect. Finally, a party can enter into a
novation, also known as an assignment, under which the party (transferor) transfers its
rights and obligations under the transaction to a third party (transferee) in exchange
for a payment. Following the novation, the parties to the transaction are the transferee
and the remaining party. The ISDA Master Agreement requires a transferor to obtain
prior written consent from the remaining party before a novation takes place.
Until relatively recently, novations were relatively infrequent; the usual method
of exiting a transaction was an offsetting transaction. But as hedge funds have
become more active in CDS, novations have become increasingly common. Investors,
and especially hedge funds, tend to prefer to unwind through novation rather than
through offset because they are reluctant to incur credit exposure and the resulting
need to post collateral on the offsetting swap.4 And they generally prefer novation to
termination because termination limits unwind possibilities to the original counterparty and can provide insights into trading strategies to the counterparty. As a result,
novations increased, especially as index trading grew; one estimate placed novations
at 40 percent of trade volume as of 2005 (CRMPG II 2005).
Novations became a problem because of participants’ failure to follow established
procedure. First, a hedge fund wishing to step out of a transaction via novation might
not obtain prior consent from the remaining party. Second, the transferee might not
verify that the transferor had obtained clearance. Finally, the remaining party, which
might not have been aware of the novation until the first payment date following,
might later back-date its books to the novation date and simply change the counterparty name. The finger pointing went further: When dealers complained that investors
had failed to obtain consent, investors countered that remaining parties had given
consent but had failed to transmit the necessary information to the back office in a
timely manner. Although novations in such cases did not typically lead to significant
adverse credit exposures for dealers—transferees are virtually always dealers and
therefore better capitalized than the hedge fund transferors—they did present substantial operational problems in the form of confirmation backlogs.
The industry was aware of the problem. ISDA addressed the issue in 2004 by developing novation definitions, a standard novation confirmation, and a best-practices
statement. Regulators were also aware of the problem and in some cases expressed
concern publicly (Evans 2005). A solution did not ensue, however, because of competitive pressures and the lack of incentive to act alone. On the one hand, dealers were
aware of the problem and would benefit if all parties to novations followed established
procedures. But on the other hand, refusing to agree to novations if procedures were
not followed would lead to losing potentially profitable business to those dealers that
did not insist on proper procedures. The industry consequently found itself in a “prisoners’ dilemma” situation in which each party would benefit from adhering to proper
procedures but had no means of knowing whether other parties would do so as well.
The result was no change, and confirmation backlogs increased.
4. Hedge funds generally post up-front collateral (known as the independent amount) with dealer
counterparties regardless of the direction of exposure. They then post additional collateral to
cover subsequent variations in exposure.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

19

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

During August 2005, however, Federal Reserve Bank of New York President
Timothy Geithner invited fourteen major credit derivative dealers to a meeting to discuss CDS operations issues, with particular attention to confirmation backlogs. At the
meeting, which occurred the following month, the dealers agreed to reduce backlogs
and to report their progress periodically.
The effort to reduce backlogs led to increased efforts within ISDA to complete a
solution to the novations issue. The solution, known as the ISDA Novation Protocol,
was announced just before the New York Fed meeting in September (Raisler and
Teigland-Hunt 2006). The protocol entailed
extensive negotiation between dealers,
The entry of hedge funds and other
hedge funds, and other participants and
investors into credit derivatives has been
specified a set of explicit duties for the
parties to a novation. Under the protocol,
an important factor in the development
parties wishing to act as transferees are
of CDS market liquidity and efficiency.
required to obtain prior consent but are now
able to do so electronically. If the remaining party provides consent prior to 6 PM New York time, the novation is complete; the
remaining party can respond by email. If the remaining party does not provide consent prior to 6 PM, the transferor and transferee enter into an offsetting transaction
that obtains a similar economic result to the novation.
Market participants were given a deadline to sign on to the ISDA Novation
Protocol; dealers agreed not to transact novations with parties that did not agree. In
order to provide assurance that remaining parties would respond promptly to novation requests, dealers committed to specific standards for responding by the deadlines in the protocol. The result has been considered a success: 2,000 parties signed
on to the original Novation Protocol, and almost 190 entities have signed on to a
version designed for new participants.
Initial assessments of the protocol have been favorable. These assessments have
corresponded to reports that the industry has made considerable progress in reducing confirmation backlogs and increasing overall operational efficiency. According to
the New York Fed, by September 2006 the fourteen largest dealers had reduced the
number of all confirmations outstanding by 70 percent and of confirmations outstanding past thirty days by 85 percent. Further, the dealers had doubled the share of
trades confirmed electronically to 80 percent of total trade volume (Federal Reserve
Bank of New York 2006).
The case of novations demonstrates that collective action problems can threaten
the feasibility of private sector efforts but that thoughtful regulatory action can facilitate a solution. Although all parties had an interest in a solution, none believed the
other side was willing to take the necessary steps. Further, competitive considerations made dealers reluctant to exert pressure on one of their most active client groups.
The regulatory intervention provided sufficient cover for dealers to insist on adherence by their clients. In this case, a relatively light touch by a regulator was sufficient
to bring about a solution.
CDS settlement following credit events. As mentioned earlier, credit derivative index trades have been the major factor in recent growth in credit derivatives.
The result of this growth was a new challenge, namely, that the amount of credit protection outstanding is far greater than the supply of underlying debt that could be
delivered if a credit event were to occur. The problem manifested itself in a series of
corporate bankruptcies in the North American auto parts companies (Collins & Aikman,
Delphi, Dana, and Dura), airlines (Delta and Northwest), and power companies

20

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

(Calpine). Because of the expanded interest in credit derivatives caused by the introduction of indices, the amount of credit derivatives outstanding was in some cases
reported to be as much as ten times the amount of bonds actually available to settle
trades when a credit event occurs. This imbalance called into question the ability of
the industry to achieve traditional physical settlement in an orderly manner, which
led to calls by industry participants to substitute cash settlement for physical settlement for index trades.
The problem was that existing CDS contracts called for physical settlement after
credit events. In addition, current documentation provides that the cash settlement
will be determined by dealer poll by each dealer, which was not considered feasible
given the large number of market participants that would be trying to buy deliverable
debt at the same time. With regard to the first problem, counterparties are free to
substitute cash for physical settlement if they so agree, but doing so on a large scale
could require bilateral negotiations between each pair of counterparties. Further,
developing an alternative to the dealer poll required a collective industry solution.
The solution proposed by ISDA was that firms move to cash settlement by means of
a protocol that allows market participants to amend their contracts on a multilateral
basis rather than engaging in bilateral negotiations. In essence, market participants
can agree to industrywide and standardized amendments to their contracts. Parties
that agree to be bound by the protocol’s terms effectively amend their credit derivative contracts without negotiating directly with other firms. In addition, the protocol
provided an alternative means by which a cash settlement price could be determined.
The protocol in this case allowed market participants to shift from physical settlement to cash settlement using a price generated in an auction for the defaulted
bonds. In the first protocol, held in May 2005 for auto parts supplier Collins &
Aikman, there was a single deliverable obligation. The next protocol addressed the
bankruptcy filings of U.S. airlines Delta and Northwest, which offered multiple
deliverable obligations. Delphi, another auto parts company, was a particularly
challenging one as the volume of trades on the name was high: Merrill Lynch and
Fitch Ratings estimated that there was $28 billion of exposure on this name but
only $2.2 billion par value of bonds available and $3 billion in loans outstanding
(Fitch Ratings 2005).
Experience with subsequent credit events has led to what appears to be a longterm solution. First, although cash settlement will be the standard, institutions will
have the option to settle physically with their dealers if they so choose. Second, the
cash settlement protocol will, unlike the early versions, apply to both index and
single-name CDS as well as other products such as swaptions. Third, the new system,
following further experience, will be incorporated into the next set of credit derivatives definitions.

Remaining Issues
In considering the future of credit derivatives, two subjects come to mind. The first
is the potential for further innovation and growth of credit derivatives. The second is
the possibility that credit derivatives might evolve into a standardized, exchangetraded product.
Growth and innovation could occur along several dimensions. One dimension is
type of contract. There have been some variations on the CDS such as credit swaptions and constant-maturity credit default swaps, but the CDS has proved to be an
adaptable product and is unlikely to be displaced. To the extent that product innovation occurs, it is likely to take the form of structured finance applications tailored

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

21

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

to investor demands for tailored exposures. An example of such a product is the single
tranche CDO, which provides investors with exposure to credit risk through a customized CDS portfolio.
Another dimension is type of risk. Until recently, CDS were written on entities or
groups of entities. But recent innovations have extended CDS protection to obligations
instead of industries. CDS on asset-backed securities, for example, have enabled
investors to access securitized risks without having to make a direct investment. As
a result, supply constraints are less of a factor. Other examples include CDS on leveraged loans and on preferred stock, which
again reference financial instruments of a
Growth and innovation of credit derivaparticular type.
tives could occur along several dimensions:
Yet another dimension is new market
participants.
The major new entrant has
type of contract, type of risk, and new
been hedge funds. Whether there are other
market participants.
significant entrants waiting in the wings is
not clear, however. Tables 2 and 3 suggest
that mutual funds and pension funds have shown some growth, but prudential
restrictions on allowable risks might continue to limit the role of such buy-side firms.
Second, retail investors might begin to participate, but the history of over-thecounter derivatives, which have remained overwhelmingly wholesale in nature, suggests that retail investors are unlikely to be a major factor. If retail investors do show
an appetite for credit investing, they will likely participate through banks and securities firms that serve as intermediaries. A third possibility is that regional banks will
increasingly participate in the market, possibly by selling protection as a means of
diversifying their portfolios. As Tables 2 and 3 show, however, bank portfolio managers are significantly more likely to use credit derivatives to shed credit risk than to
take on credit risk.
A final possibility is that nonfinancial corporations might enter the market as they
have for interest rate, currency, and commodity derivatives, but so far they have not
done so in any significant way (Smithson and Mengle 2006). In the early days of credit
derivatives, corporations were considered a potential source of business because of
credit risks embedded in corporate balance sheets as receivables and supplier relationships. Further, corporate credit exposures could be a natural hedge for dealers’
exposures to investors and would help dealers balance their CDS portfolios at low
cost. Corporate activity did not materialize, however, largely because of basis risks:
The nature of corporate exposures is difficult to match with a specific amount of protection and possibly on a specific reference entity.
With regard to the evolution of credit default swaps into standardized, exchangetraded futures contracts, several projects are under way as of this writing. First, futures
on the iTraxx Europe credit index began trading on Eurex on March 27, 2007. The
product is based on a five-year index with a fixed income; a new contract will be issued
every six months. The contract will be cash settled, with the payout based on the ISDA
CDS settlement auction. Second, the Chicago Mercantile Exchange is developing a
futures contract on single-name credit default swaps. Contracts will be written on three
reference entities chosen by the exchange. If a credit event occurs, the contracts will
have a fixed recovery rate. The CME is also developing an index contract. Third, the
Chicago Board Options Exchange is developing a credit default option, which involves
an up-front payment and a binary payout of $100,000 per contract if a credit event
occurs. Finally, the Chicago Board of Trade and Euronext.Liffe are each planning
futures contracts based on a credit index, but details are not yet available.

22

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

The arguments for exchange-traded credit derivatives products are similar to
those for other types of derivatives. First, exchanges could provide enhanced liquidity and price discovery by means of standardization and centralized trading. Second,
by making the exchange clearinghouse the counterparty to each trade and by imposing universal margin requirements, credit futures could provide a means of reducing
counterparty credit risk to users. Finally, credit derivatives might in some cases provide a means for dealers to hedge their exposures as they do for interest rate, commodity, and equity derivatives.
Whether CDS trading migrates to exchanges will depend largely on the degree of
substitutability between over-the-counter CDS and the new credit futures products.
At the same time, whether CDS and credit futures will share the same complementarities that they have in other markets is not clear. With regard to substitutability,
OTC derivatives and futures compete to some degree as substitutes but, on closer
examination, tend to appeal to different groups of users. If investors perceive the
CDS market as being insufficiently liquid, or if counterparty risk is a major consideration, then some volume might move to the exchanges. But index CDS appear to
have attained a high degree of liquidity already, so whether they will be motivated to
abandon dealers for exchanges is not yet clear.
With regard to complementarity, it is not apparent that futures would provide the
same hedging and price discovery function that they do for other over-the-counter
derivatives. Given the degree of standardization of CDS, dealers are apparently able
to trade balanced books without significant residual risks that need to be laid off on
exchanges. Further, dealers might not find price discovery information for a small
number of selected reference entities to be particularly useful. Still, if credit futures
attract significant liquidity, dealers might seek to incorporate the price information
into their risk management activities.
It is possible, however, that credit derivatives have already evolved into a mature
product and that future growth will resemble that of interest rate and other derivatives. That is, products will become increasingly commoditized but will also become
known to a wider range of users. The past ten years have seen credit evolving from
a largely illiquid product into an increasingly tradable product in which risks are
managed in the same way as other market risks. Perhaps the next ten years will see
the spread of this new credit risk management technology more deeply and widely
into the financial system.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

23

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

REFERENCES
Bank for International Settlements (BIS). 2007.
Triennial and semiannual surveys on positions in
global over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives markets
at end-June 2007, November.

Flannery, Mark. 1985. A portfolio view of loan selection and pricing. In Handbook for banking strategy,
edited by Robert A. Eisenbeis and Richard C. Aspinwall.
New York: John Wiley and Sons.

British Bankers Association (BBA). 2002. BBA credit
derivatives report 2001/2002. London: BBA Enterprises Ltd.

International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2006. Global
financial stability report, April.

———. 2006. BBA credit derivatives report 2006.
London: BBA Enterprises Ltd.
Chaplin, Geoff. 2005. Credit derivatives: Risk management, trading and investing. West Sussex, U.K.:
Wiley.
Choudhry, Moorad. 2004. Structured credit products:
Credit derivatives and synthetic securitisation.
Singapore: Wiley.
———. 2006. The credit default swap basis. New
York: Bloomberg Press.
Cilia, Joseph. 1996. Product summary: Asset swaps.
Financial Markets Unit, Supervision and Regulation,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, August.
Counterparty Risk Management Policy Group (CRMPG)
II. 2005. Toward greater financial stability: A private
sector perspective, July.
Das, Satyajit. 2006. Traders, guns, and money.
Harlow, U.K.: Pearson.
Evans, Gay Huey. 2005. Operations and risk management in credit derivatives markets. CEO Letter,
Financial Services Authority, February.
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 2006. Statement
regarding progress in credit derivatives markets,
September 27.
Fitch Ratings. 2005. Delphi, credit derivatives, and
bond trading behavior after a bankruptcy filing,
November 28.
———. 2006. Global credit derivatives survey: Indices
dominate growth as banks’ risk position shifts,
September 21.
———. 2007. CDx Survey, July 16.

24

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

Jackson, Tony. 2007. Derivative risk threatens private
equity. Financial Times, February 26.
Joint Market Practices Forum. 2003. Statement of principles and recommendations regarding the handling of
material nonpublic information by credit market participants. International Association of Credit Portfolio
Managers, International Swaps and Derivatives Association, Loan Sales and Trading Association, and the Bond
Market Association.
JPMorgan Chase. 2006. Credit derivatives handbook.
Corporate Quantitative Research, December.
Kroszner, Randall. 2007. Recent innovations in credit
markets. Credit Markets Symposium, Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond, March 22.
Plender, John. 2006. The credit business is more perilous than ever. Financial Times, October 13.
Raisler, Kenneth, and Lauren Teigland-Hunt. 2006. How
ISDA took on the confirmations backlog. International
Financial Law Review, February.
Risky business. 2005. Economist, August 18.
Smithson, Charles. 2003. Credit portfolio management. Hoboken, N.J.: Wiley.
Smithson, Charles, and David Mengle. 2006. The
promise of credit derivatives in nonfinancial corporations (and why it’s failed to materialize). Journal of
Applied Corporate Finance 18, no. 4:54–60.
Spinner, Karen. 1997. Building the credit derivatives
infrastructure. Derivatives Strategy, Credit Derivatives Supplement, June.
Taksler, Glen. 2007. Credit default swap primer,
2d ed. Debt research, Bank of America, January 5.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Credit Derivatives and
Risk Management
MICHAEL S. GIBSON
Gibson is a deputy associate director in the Division of Research and Statistics at the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. He thanks Patrick Fleming and Ankur Rughani
for excellent research assistance and Michael Gordy, Pat Parkinson, Matt Pritsker, and Pat
White for comments on an earlier draft. This paper was presented at the Atlanta Fed’s 2007
Financial Markets Conference, “Credit Derivatives: Where’s the Risk?” held May 14–16.

he growth of credit derivatives suggests that market participants find them useful for risk management. Figure 1 shows the growth trajectory for credit derivatives from two surveys of derivatives dealers: the International Swaps and Derivatives
Association (ISDA) Market Survey, which goes back to 2001, and the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) semiannual derivatives statistics (2007), which go back
to 2004. The BIS survey is more accurate because it adjusts for double counting of
interdealer trades, but both surveys show a similar pattern of rapid growth. Notional
amounts of credit derivatives outstanding have roughly doubled each year for the
past five years.
Credit derivatives have been used by a wide variety of market participants. No
single data source provides definitive information on the activity of different types of
market participants, but combining several available data sources provides a relatively clear picture. I will refer to three data sources: the BIS semiannual derivative
statistics (2007), a report on credit risk transfer by the Joint Forum (BIS 2005a), and
the surveys by Fitch Ratings (2006).
All three data sources measure activity in the credit derivatives market with
notional amounts. Notional amounts are often not a good measure of the credit risk
that is actually transferred in a particular transaction. However, notional amounts
are relatively easy data to collect, and for this reason they are the most common
data reported. I will present the notional amount data while keeping their limitations
in mind.
The most comprehensive data source is the BIS semiannual derivative statistics
(BIS 2007). About fifty-five dealers contribute to this survey, which breaks out credit
derivative notional amounts by the type of counterparty. Table 1 shows these data for
December 2006. The largest category is reporting dealers, reflecting the interdealer
nature of the market. In any dealer market, dealers rely on interdealer trading to adjust
their risk profiles in response to trading flows from end users. According to dealers,

T

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

25

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 1
Notional Amounts of Credit Derivatives Outstanding
40,000
35,000
30,000
ISDA Market Survey
$U.S. billion

25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
BIS semiannual derivative statistics

5,000
0
2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

Source: ISDA, BIS

only 5 to 10 percent of their notional amount of derivatives represents hedges of their
own credit exposures; the balance reflects interdealer trading and accommodation
of customer demands (BIS 2005a, 16).
Banks and security firms that are not reporting dealers make up one-fifth of the
total. Some of this percentage captures nondealer banks investing on their own account
in credit derivatives. Some likely captures banks acting as fiduciaries for private
banking or high-net-worth investors. The category of “other financial institutions”
includes hedge funds, pension funds, and special-purpose vehicles and makes up
another fifth of the total. Many structured credit products, including collateralized
debt obligations (CDOs), make use of special-purpose vehicles. Hedge funds are active
traders but tend to maintain their positions for a short amount of time; their share of
trading volume would likely be larger than their share of notional amounts outstanding. This category is the fastest-growing among the nonreporting dealer categories.
Insurance firms account for a small portion of outstanding notional amounts, around
1 percent, but are notable for their one-sided participation as net sellers of credit
protection to dealers. Of course, exactly how much risk transfer those data represent
is unclear, given that notional amounts cannot be equated with risk.
The Joint Forum report, which relied on surveys by Fitch Ratings and Standard
and Poor’s, also noted that insurance and financial guaranty firms were net sellers of
credit protection, along with European banks (BIS 2005a). Banks overall used credit
derivatives to shed credit risk. At the banks that took on credit risk with credit derivatives, exposures taken on with credit derivatives were only 2–6 percent of exposures
from traditional lending. Large banks tended to be net buyers of credit protection.
Fitch Ratings has repeated its survey annually. The most recent survey, done in
2006, confirmed the broad outlines of the patterns discussed above (Fitch Ratings 2006).
Insurance and financial guaranty firms remain net sellers of credit protection, mainly
through portfolio credit derivatives, a category that includes synthetic CDOs, credit
default swap indexes, and credit index tranches. While banks as a group remain

26

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table 1
BIS Semiannual Derivatives Statistics, December 2006 (Notional Amounts, $Billions)
Type of counterparty

Dealer bought protection
from counterparty

Dealer sold protection
to counterparty

Total (adjusted for
double counting)

Reporting dealers
Nonreporting banks and security firms
Other financial institutions
Nonfinancial institutions
Insurance and financial guaranty firms

16,044
2,928
2,826
561
211

16,165
2,758
2,824
530
95

16,104
5,686
5,650
1,091
306

Total

22,571

22,372

28,838

Source: BIS (2007, table 4)

net buyers of credit protection according to Fitch’s data, Fitch noted a shift in its most
recent survey. Some individual banks, as well as German banks as a group, shifted to
net sellers of credit protection via derivatives. One possibility is that these banks are
relying more on securitization, rather than derivatives, to shed credit risk. Fitch also
noted that firms responding to its survey reported having sold $377 billion of notional
amount of credit protection more than they bought. Firms not reporting to the survey,
including hedge funds, asset managers, and pension funds, must be shedding this
$377 billion of notional credit risk.

Market Participants Using Credit Derivatives for Risk Management
Clearly, market participants are finding credit derivatives to be useful tools for risk
management to support such rapid growth. To dig deeper into the usefulness of credit
derivatives for risk management, I discuss how they are used by three types of market
participants: commercial banks, investment banks, and investors.
Commercial banks. Commercial banks use credit derivatives to tailor their credit
risk exposure. Broadly speaking, they shed credit risk via credit derivatives. Banks
have used credit derivatives and other means of credit risk transfer, such as securitizations, to shed risk in several areas of their credit portfolio, including large corporate
loans, loans to smaller companies, and counterparty credit risk on over-the-counter
(OTC) derivatives. Banks use single-name credit default swaps (CDS) to shed the
credit risk of issuers to whom they have a large exposure. Banks can transfer the credit
risk of a portfolio of exposures to investors via securitization transactions, such as
collateralized loan obligations (CLOs).
The Joint Forum (BIS 2005a), reporting on interviews held in 2004 with about
sixty market participants, found that the largest commercial banks had shed a material, but small, amount of credit risk via credit derivatives, mainly to their large,
investment-grade corporate customers. The Joint Forum also reported that a number of commercial banks had scaled back their credit hedging activity.
However, these conclusions may no longer hold. The amount of credit risk shed
by banks may be rising, and hedging has spread to categories of credit risk beyond
investment-grade corporate loans. A number of banks, mainly European, have undertaken large hedging transactions in the past couple of years. Table 2 reports several
recent hedging transactions by large banks. These transactions are larger and more
numerous than what had been reported at the time of the Joint Forum survey. In
total, these transactions represent the equivalent of $88 billion notional amount of

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

27

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

Date

Bank

Name of deal

Cash or synthetic?

Collateral

Amount

June 2005

ABN Amro

Amstel 2005

Synthetic

Corporate loans

EUR 10 bil

December 2005

ABN Amro

Smile 2005

Synthetic

Dutch SME loans

EUR 6.75 bil

November 2006

ABN Amro

Amstel 2006

Synthetic

Corporate loans

EUR 10 bil

December 2006

ABN Amro

Amstel SCO

Synthetic

Counterparty exposures
on derivatives

EUR 7 bil

February 2007

ABN Amro

Smile Securitization 2007

Cash

Dutch SME loans

EUR 4.9 bil

December 2005

Barclays

Gracechurch Corporate
Loans Series 2005-1

Synthetic

UK midsize corporates

GBP 5 bil

January 2007

Barclays

Gracechurch Corporate
Loans 20071

Synthetic

UK SME loans

GBP 3.5 bil

February 2007

Credit Suisse

Clock Finance

Synthetic

Swiss SME loans

CHF 4.8 bil

July 2005

Deutsche Bank

GATE SME CLO

Synthetic

SME loans

EUR 1.5 bil

June 2006/
February 2007

Deutsche Bank

Craft EM CLO

Synthetic

Emerging market loans, bonds,
and counterparty exposures

USD 500m/1 bil

February 2007

HSBC Trinkaus

HEAT 3

Cash

SME loans

EUR 314 mil

November 2005

HSBC

Metrix Funding

Cash

Corporate loans

GBP 2 bil

November 2006

HSBC

Metrix Securities

Synthetic

Corporate loans

GBP 2 bil

November 2006

Mizuho

n/a

Synthetic

Non-Japanese large corporate loans

JPY 560 bil

October 2006

SocGen

Atlas III

Synthetic

Corporate loans

EUR 2.8 bil

November 2006

UBS

n/a

Bilateral swap

High-yield corporate loans

USD 600 mil

Note: “SME” stands for small and medium-sized enterprises.
Source: Company and rating agency reports and financial press

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

28

Table 2
Recent Hedging Transactions by Large Banks

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table 3
Hedging Done with Credit Default Swaps
Date

Bank

Year-end 2006
Year-end 2006
Year-end 2006
2006 Q1

Bank of America
Citigroup
JPMorgan Chase
Société Générale

Credit exposure before
hedging (billions)

Amount of hedging
reported (billions)

Exposure hedged
(percent)

USD 618
USD 633
USD 631
EUR 60

USD 8
USD 93
USD 51
EUR 15

1
15
8
25

Source: For U.S. banks, 2006 annual reports; for Société Générale, “Safety first,” Risk, August 2006

credit risk shed by eight large international banks over 2005–07.1 In many of these
transactions, and in contrast to similar transactions in the late 1990s, the issuing bank
sold off the first-loss equity tranche of the credit risk. The categories of credit risk shed
include not only loans to large corporates but also loans to small and medium-sized
enterprises, loans to emerging markets, and counterparty exposure on derivatives. Most
transactions listed in the table are synthetic, using credit derivatives to transfer risk
off the balance sheet.
Table 3 shows reported amounts of CDS hedging by the three largest U.S. commercial bank holding companies, as reported in their 2006 annual reports, and by one
European bank, as reported in the financial press. (Only U.S. banking organizations
appear to disclose CDS hedging in their annual reports.) For this admittedly small
sample, the average percentage of credit risk hedged appears to be larger than that
reported by the Joint Forum.
Several reasons could explain why commercial banks appear to be hedging more
of their credit risk than they were in 2004. First, credit spreads are at low levels,
reducing the cost of hedging. Second, accounting changes in Europe have made it
possible for banks to carry loans at fair value, reducing the conflict that was perceived between the accounting treatment of credit derivatives and their use in risk
management (BIS 2005a, 11). Third, the Basel 2 capital accord will align regulatory
capital charges more closely with actual credit risks and will allow greater recognition of hedging.
Investment banks. An investment bank can use credit derivatives to manage
the risk it incurs when underwriting securities. An underwriter assumes credit risk
for the short time period between taking the risk onto its own books and selling it into
the market. By virtue of the growth of credit derivatives, the underwriter might then
be able to hedge some of that credit risk more easily.
Nonagency residential mortgage-backed securities (RMBS) have been a rapidly
growing market for securities underwriting in recent years. In 2006, $574 billion of
securities were underwritten and issued in this segment, up from less than $100 billion in 2000 (SIFMA 2007b). The increase in issuance volume would naturally lead to
a rise in credit risk borne by underwriters because underwriters must warehouse residential mortgage loans on their books during the time it takes to assemble a pool
large enough to launch a securitization. Underwriters must find a way to cope with
the potential increase in credit risk, which, given the numbers cited above, might be
1. According to global CDO market issuance data reported by the Securities Industry and Financial
Markets Association (SIFMA) (2007a), $107 billion of balance-sheet CDOs were issued in 2005–06.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

29

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

so large as to discourage them, at the margin, from taking on additional underwriting
business. One way for underwriters to cope with such a potential increase in credit
risk is to hedge more of it.
New credit derivative instruments appear to be useful to underwriters who want
to hedge the risk of a residential mortgage loan warehouse. Beginning in mid-2004,
dealers began to trade credit default swaps
on asset-backed securities (referred to as
Banks have used credit derivatives and
ABS CDS). By year-end 2005, Fitch Ratings
other means of credit risk transfer, such as
(2006, 2) put the size of the ABS CDS
securitizations, to shed risk in several areas market at $495 billion in notional amount
outstanding and growing rapidly.2 An underof their credit portfolio.
writer can use an ABS CDS to buy credit
protection on an RMBS with similar characteristics to the loans in its warehouse. The performance of the ABS CDS should
roughly offset the performance of the warehouse loans.
As is typical of successful and liquid new markets, there appears to be a healthy
balance of supply and demand of credit risk in the ABS CDS market. In addition to
underwriters seeking to hedge warehouse loans, asset managers with a negative view
on the housing sector are also natural buyers of credit protection on RMBS. Investors
seeking exposure to the RMBS market, including CDOs, are natural sellers of credit
protection. ABS CDS have proved to be relatively liquid compared to the markets for
individual RMBS. Using ABS CDS on large, recently issued RMBS, dealers created an
index called the ABX.HE, which can be used to trade the credit risk of a pool of twenty
RMBS deals. Of course, if sellers of credit protection become scarce because of a
weaker-than-expected housing market, the ABS CDS and ABX.HE markets could see
much of their recent liquidity dry up, and underwriters would lose a useful tool for
credit risk management.
Investors. Investors are the third group that uses credit derivatives for risk management. An investor can use credit derivatives to align its credit risk exposure with
its desired credit risk profile. Credit derivatives can be more flexible and less expensive than transacting in cash securities. The surveys cited earlier show that insurers
are an important class of investors that use credit derivatives. However, other fixedincome asset managers, including hedge funds, also participate in the market. Most
observers agree that of the three groups, demand from investors is most responsible
for spurring the growth of the credit derivatives market.
“Investors” are a heterogeneous group, and they participate in the credit derivatives market in different ways. Some are “buy and hold” investors that seek to earn a
return from a broad exposure to issuers of fixed-income securities, and others are
“active traders” that seek to earn a return by predicting short-term price movements
better than other market participants. The advantages of credit derivatives as a riskmanagement tool are different for the two groups.
Traditionally, insurance companies and pension funds have been thought of as
buy-and-hold investors, and hedge funds have been thought of as active traders. But
the distinctions between different types of asset managers are becoming increasingly
blurred. A given asset manager may place some assets in a buy-and-hold index strategy, some with an in-house team of active traders, and the remainder with external
managers who could pursue either type of strategy.
Buy and hold. Suppose a buy-and-hold investor develops a negative view about
a particular sector—for example, telecom. Consider an investor that does not use
credit derivatives. It can only rebalance its portfolio away from telecom issuers by

30

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table 4
Alternative Scenarios Faced by an “Active Trader”

Scenario
1. XYZ defaults
2. XYZ credit spread falls by 10 basis points at all maturities
3. XYZ credit spread increases by 10 basis points at all maturities

Change in market value
Sell $10MM
Buy $10MM
at ten years
at five years
Deliver bonds
+$76,347
–$76,347

Receive bonds
–$43,837
+$43,837

Net

Zero
+$32,510
–$32,510

Source: Bloomberg page CDSW, using a BBB spread curve as of April 16, 2007

selling some of the telecom bonds it holds. Secondary markets for corporate bonds
are notably illiquid for seasoned issues, so the transaction cost of selling seasoned
telecom bonds will be high. The investor’s best option for replacing the telecom
bonds will be newly issued bonds, which have low transaction costs because they are
relatively liquid. However, the particular bonds that happen to be issued at a given
time may be influenced by the particular trends in the market at that time, such as
which sectors are undergoing leveraged buyouts, and may not be exactly the replacements that the investor is looking for.
Now consider an investor that does use credit derivatives. This investor can shift
its exposure away from telecom issuers by buying credit protection on telecom
issuers using credit default swaps. The bid-ask spread is generally lower for credit
default swaps than for corporate bonds, and the difference is larger when the bonds
are seasoned. To replace the telecom exposures, this investor can sell credit protection on other, nontelecom issuers or simply sell credit protection on a credit default
swap index.
Active trader. Now consider an investor that is an active trader with a view that,
over the next three months, Issuer XYZ’s credit risk standing will improve and its
credit spreads will tighten. One obvious trade based on such a view is to buy one of
Issuer XYZ’s bonds or sell credit protection on Issuer XYZ with a single-name credit
default swap. However, buying a bond or selling credit protection exposes the
investor to the risk that Issuer XYZ defaults, a risk the investor may not want to take.
As mentioned above, one benefit of credit derivatives is that an investor can use
them to take a customized exposure to particular components of credit risk, such as
spread risk, default risk, recovery risk, or correlation risk. In this example, the
investor wants to be exposed to the spread risk of Issuer XYZ but not default risk.
To achieve this goal, suppose that the investor sells $10 million notional amount
of credit protection on Issuer XYZ with a ten-year maturity and buys $10 million
notional amount of credit protection on Issuer XYZ with a five-year maturity. These
two positions have the same $10 million exposure to default risk, but the longer
maturity position has a greater sensitivity to credit spreads (higher credit duration).
Table 4 shows what happens in three different scenarios. Scenario 1 shows what
happens if Issuer XYZ defaults. The investor will receive $10 million face value of Issuer
XYZ’s bonds on the five-year CDS and will deliver $10 million face value of bonds on
2. While the asset-backed securities market includes securities backed by a range of collateral,
including credit card loans and auto loans, nearly all ABS CDS contracts reference RMBS or commercial mortgage-backed securities.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

31

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

the ten-year CDS. Clearly, such a trade is
hedged against the default of Issuer XYZ
within the next five years.
Scenarios 2 and 3 show what happens
Tranche
Five-year
Ten-year
when Issuer XYZ’s credit spread curve narrows or widens at all maturities in a paral0–3 percent
500 + 9.98%
500 + 40.85%
lel shift. As expected, in scenario 2, the
up-front
up-front
issuer gains on net when the credit spread
3–6 percent
46
334
narrows, and the opposite occurs in sce6–9 percent
13
88
nario 3 when the credit spread widens. Of
9–12 percent
6
39
course, credit spread curves do not always
12–22 percent
2
13
shift in parallel, and an additional risk of
Index
23
43
this trade (not shown in the table) is that
Source: www.creditfixings.com
the credit spread curve steepens.
Without credit derivatives, such a trade
would
only be possible if Issuer XYZ hapTable 6
pened
to have bonds outstanding with
Deltas on iTraxx Europe Tranches
five-year
and ten-year maturities and if the
on March 1, 2007
investor could borrow a bond to establish a
Tranche
Five-year
Ten-year
short position. While the stars may align on
occasion for both of these conditions to be
0–3 percent
27.5
13
satisfied, a liquid credit derivatives market
3–6 percent
4
11
clearly offers more possibilities for cus6–9 percent
1.25
4.25
tomizing risk exposures along these lines.
9–12 percent
0.6
2.1
Credit index tranches. Credit index
12–22 percent
0.2
0.8
tranches
are another example of how credit
Index
1
1
derivatives can produce different riskSource: www.creditfixings.com
return trade-offs. A credit index such as
CDX (in North America) or iTraxx (in
Europe) is a liquid product that provides exposure to a broad segment of the credit
derivatives market. Credit index tranches take the risk of a credit index and divide it
into pieces with different seniority. Because these tranches on credit indexes are
standardized, they are relatively liquid compared to other tranched credit products,
which are usually customized on a one-off basis. Table 5 shows the tranches for the
iTraxx Europe index, along with the spreads on each tranche at the five- and ten-year
maturities as of March 1, 2007. The spread represents the cost paid by a buyer of
credit protection.
Understanding the relative risk of credit index tranches is difficult but is obviously important for investors who are choosing the risk and return of their investment
portfolio. A common way that market participants compare the risk of different
tranches is to use a model to compute the relative size of the position in the underlying index that would have the same sensitivity to a small movement in the index
credit spread as the tranche. This measure is called “delta,” and, by construction,
the delta of a position in the index equals one. Delta can be seen as a measure of
the tranche’s leverage.
Table 6 shows the deltas of the iTraxx tranches. The deltas themselves purport to measure the risk of a tranche relative to a position in the index. One can
also use deltas to compare the risk of different tranches. For example, at the fiveyear maturity, the 3–6 percent tranche is twenty times riskier than the 12–22 percent tranche.
Table 5
Spreads on iTraxx Europe Tranches on
March 1, 2007 (Basis Points per Annum)

32

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table 7
Market Spreads and Expected Weighted Average Spreads on
iTraxx Europe Tranches on March 1, 2007 (Basis Points per Annum)
Five-year
Tranche
3–6 percent
6–9 percent
9–12 percent
12–22 percent
Index

Ten-year

Market

Expected

Market

Expected

46
13
6
2
23

45.5
12.8
5.8
2
22.9

334
88
39
13
43

289
84
38
12.9
42.2

Source: Author's calculations

However, delta only measures one dimension of a tranche’s risk: exposure to
credit spread risk. Other dimensions of risk, such as default risk, may give a different
sense of the relative risk of different tranches. In the field of derivatives pricing, the
risk and return of different positions that are exposed to the same single underlying
risk factor must satisfy the formula
expected excess return
= a constant.
risk
This idea underpins the Black-Scholes formula and many other asset-pricing models.
I will apply this idea to get a back-of-the-envelope sense of the relative default
risk of iTraxx tranches. Defaults among names in the iTraxx Europe index correspond
to the single underlying risk factor of the theory. The 0–3 percent tranche is quite
sensitive to the timing of defaults, in addition to the number of defaults, so it does
not fit the assumption of exposure to a single risk factor, and I therefore omit it from
this analysis.
I compute the expected excess return on each tranche as the expected weighted
average spread less the expected default loss. Each of these is measured in basis
points per annum. To compute the expected weighted average spread per annum, I
start with the market spreads from Table 5. The spread actually received is less than
the market spread because the spread is paid on the remaining balance outstanding
on the tranche, which can be reduced when defaults hit the tranche. Using the singlefactor Gaussian copula model of Gibson (2004), I use single-name CDS spreads on the
125 names that make up the iTraxx Europe index to compute the probability distribution of defaults on the index. This calculation assumes a flat correlation of 15 percent across all names. Using this market-implied probability distribution of defaults,
Table 7 shows the expected weighted average spread on each tranche from Table 5,
along with the market spread.
I compute the expected default loss using the same model of Gibson (2004) and
the same flat correlation of 15 percent, but I use historical default probabilities for
each credit in the index based on its credit rating and assume a constant recovery
rate on defaulted issuers of 40 percent.3 The expected default losses for each tranche
are shown in Table 8.
3. Historical default probabilities are taken from Moody’s Investors Service (2007, exhibit 26).

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

33

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Subtracting the expected default loss in
Table 8 from the expected weighted average spread in Table 7 gives the expected
excess return for each tranche. This calcuTranche
Five-year
Ten-year
lation is the concept in the numerator of
the above formula. Using the formula,
3–6 percent
29
73
the ratio of expected excess return for
6–9 percent
3.2
14
two tranches of the same maturity
9–12 percent
0.5
3
should equal the ratio of risk for the two
12–22 percent
0.03
0.3
tranches. Dividing the expected excess
Index
15
16
return of each tranche by the expected
Source: Author's calculations
excess return of the index gives a relative
ranking of the risk of the tranches, similar
to the concept of delta introduced above.
Table 9
Table 9 shows the result of my backRelative Risk of iTraxx Europe Tranches on
of-the-envelope calculation to compare
March 1, 2007 (Risk of Underlying Index = 1)
the sensitivity to default risk of the iTraxx
Tranche
Five-year
Ten-year
tranches. Perhaps it is comforting that
when one compares Table 9 with the deltas
3–6 percent
2.0
8.1
in Table 6, the two independent risk mea6–9 percent
1.2
2.6
sures agree on which tranches are more or
9–12 percent
0.7
1.3
less risky than the index (that is, which
12–22 percent
0.3
0.5
have a relative risk greater or less than
Index
1
1
one). However, the actual numbers in the
two tables differ by quite a bit in some
Source: Author's calculations
cases. For example, according to Table 6,
the 3–6 percent five-year tranche is four
times riskier than the index, while according to Table 9, it is only twice as risky.
The conclusion from this discussion of the risk of credit index tranches is that,
while they broaden the range of risk-return choices that investors have available in
the credit markets, they also pose a challenge to understand the various dimensions
of risk they are exposed to. I now turn to a more general discussion of the riskmanagement challenges posed by credit derivatives.
Table 8
Expected Default Loss on iTraxx Europe Tranches
on March 1, 2007 (Basis Points per Annum)

Credit Derivatives and Risk-Management Challenges
The first half of this paper has shown how commercial banks, investment banks, and
investors use credit derivatives for managing credit risk. However, credit derivatives
pose risk-management challenges of their own. In the second half of the paper, I discuss five of these challenges.
Credit risk. One fundamental reality of credit derivatives is that they do not
eliminate credit risk. They merely shift it around. As a result, when the credit cycle
turns and default rates rise, someone, somewhere, will lose money. Consider Figure 2,
which shows global speculative grade default rates since 1980. Clearly, no one should be
surprised if, when the credit cycle turns, the speculative grade default rate hits 10 percent, which is what it hit in 1990–91 and in 2001.
Although credit derivatives cannot eliminate losses from credit risk, they can
transform credit risk in intricate ways that may not be easy to understand. This issue
does not arise with single-name credit default swaps, where the exposure is nearly
identical to that of a corporate bond, or with credit default swap indexes, where the
exposure is nearly identical to that of a portfolio of corporate bonds. But where complex

34

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 2
Speculative Grade Default Rate
12

10

Percent

8

6

4

2

0
1980 1982 1984 1986

1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000

2002 2004 2006

Source: Moody’s Investors Service (2007, exhibit 21)

credit derivatives such as CDO tranches are concerned, a legitimate risk-management
issue may develop.
Do market participants understand their exposures to credit risk that they have
taken on with complex credit derivatives? Given the breadth of market participants
who are active in the credit derivative market, there is no definitive way to answer
this question.
However, we can point to evidence from the last credit cycle that some market
participants did not fully understand the exposures they had from their participation
in the credit derivatives market. In 2001, American Express “lost hundreds of millions
of dollars on investments in collateralized debt obligations.”4 The chief executive
officer of American Express was quoted as saying he “did not comprehend the risk”
of its CDO holdings. The U.K. bank Abbey National was reported to have suffered
“disastrous losses in its high-yield portfolio, including CDOs”5 and, as a result, to have
liquidated its wholesale credit portfolio, including selling off $8 billion of CDO tranches
in 2003 (Lucas, Goodman, and Fabozzi 2006, 383). In both cases, the banks were
reported to have retained first-loss tranches of CDOs they had underwritten. And
first-loss tranches naturally contain a great deal of credit risk.
CDO investors, too, naturally suffered losses in the 2001–02 credit cycle. But
since many investors do not account for their investments on a mark-to-market basis
or may not make detailed accounting statements public, less information was made
available in the public domain about these losses. According to reports in the financial
media, dealers commonly restructured CDO tranches that were exposed to troubled
issuers. Credit risk would have manifested itself in a decline in the mark-to-market
value of such a tranche. The dealer could replace a troubled issuer in the CDO’s reference portfolio with a less risky issuer. The mark-to-market loss would be “paid for”
4. See Financial Times, “Out of depth in the collateralized debt pool,” July 22, 2001.
5. See Euromoney, “Market dislocation boosts CDO trading,” April 2003.

35

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

by lowering the coupon that the investor would receive on the CDO tranche for the
remaining life of the deal.6
This brief review of the experience in the last credit cycle of 2001–02 reinforces
the point that credit derivatives do not eliminate losses from credit risk. These
lessons that I have reviewed here are certainly no secret to participants in the credit
markets, many of whom had first-hand experience of living through that credit cycle.
Given the rapid growth of the credit derivatives market, it may be fortunate that
one of the most widely used complex credit derivative structures, the CDO tranche, is
a mature product has already been through
Although credit derivatives cannot eliminate a stressful credit cycle. This experience
should contribute to financial stability durlosses from credit risk, they can transform
ing the next credit cycle, whenever that
credit risk in intricate ways that may not be may come to pass.
Of course, new flavors of CDOs will
easy to understand.
always present new challenges. One relatively new product is a CDO using assetbacked securities for collateral instead of corporate debt. In 2006, 60 percent of CDO
issuance used asset-backed securities as collateral (SIFMA 2007a). These CDOs
transfer the credit risk of asset-backed securities, primarily RMBS. Given the slowing
growth of house prices in recent months, credit risk in the RMBS sector is likely to
be increasing.
Counterparty risk. Counterparty risk is the risk that the counterparty to a
credit derivative contract will default and not pay what is owed under the contract.
For credit derivatives, as with other OTC derivatives, counterparty risk is an important risk that needs to be managed. Given the growing role of hedge funds in the
credit derivatives market, counterparty risk is becoming even more prominent, since
hedge funds generally are among a dealer’s riskier counterparties.
In many cases, dealers use collateral to reduce counterparty risk. According to the
2006 ISDA Margin Survey, 63 percent of all counterparty risk exposure on credit
derivatives is currently collateralized by large dealers. For hedge fund counterparties,
a larger share is likely to be covered by collateral since dealers nearly universally
require hedge fund counterparties to post collateral to cover current credit exposures.
However, despite the widespread use of collateral and margin, some important riskmanagement challenges are associated with counterparty risk on credit derivatives. One
challenge is simply measuring the exposures on complex credit derivatives. One of the
key measures of counterparty risk is potential future exposure. Potential future exposure takes into account the possible future moves in credit spreads or future defaults
that could create a larger credit exposure if the market moves in the dealer’s favor. This
potentially larger credit exposure is something that is already present in the current
derivative contract and therefore should be measured like any other credit exposure.
Market participants are aware of not only the need to measure potential future
exposure on complex credit derivatives but also the difficulties in measuring it. As
one article by a practitioner puts it, “unfortunately, models that can estimate [counterparty risk exposure] exactly are hard to build and calibrate” (Pugachevsky 2006,
372). That article describes a technique to approximately measure counterparty risk
exposure on synthetic CDO tranches, defining counterparty risk exposure as the
amount that would be expected to be lost if the counterparty defaults in the future.
In a stylized example of CDO tranches with a notional amount of $5 million, the article estimates the counterparty risk exposure to be around $50,000, or 1 percent of
notional. Certainly that seems like a material amount of counterparty risk.

36

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

According to an estimate from www.creditflux.com, there were $450 billion of
synthetic CDO tranches and $1.7 trillion of credit index tranches traded in 2006. One
percent of this roughly $2.2 trillion in notional amount would total $22 billion in counterparty risk exposure, the amount that dealers would collectively expect to lose if
all their CDO counterparties simultaneously defaulted. If two-thirds of that is collateralized, dealers in aggregate would have roughly $7 billion in uncollateralized counterparty risk exposure currently in their portfolios, before accounting for hedging.
These figures are certainly only a very rough approximation of the order of magnitude of the counterparty risk created by complex credit derivatives. In particular, the
actual loss from counterparty default could well be larger than the expected loss.
And, of course, any counterparty credit exposure amount should be compared with
a dealer’s capital that is available to absorb potential losses.7 All told, it appears that
counterparty risk should be a material concern of participants in the credit derivatives market.
Model risk. Complex credit derivatives require complex models for valuation
and hedging. While a few complex credit derivatives, such as credit index tranches,
are traded in liquid markets with some price transparency, most are not. Products
without a liquid market are referred to as “mark-to-model.” The risk of loss due to a
flawed model is known as model risk.8
Model risk materialized in the market for tranched credit derivatives in May
2005.9 Following the downgrade of General Motors to below-investment-grade status,
the market prices of some credit index tranches moved in ways that would be considered as either extremely implausible or impossible, according to the way certain
models were being used for valuation and risk management at that time. For example,
in the first week of May 2005, the credit spread on the CDX.NA.IG index widened,
signaling higher credit risk, but the spread on the 3–7 percent mezzanine tranche
tightened, signaling lower credit risk. Market commentary attributed this to an imbalance of market liquidity in the mezzanine tranche market. In some cases the models
themselves were not the problem, but models were being used in a way that gave
false confidence about the effectiveness of hedging strategies.
In fairness to those who build models for a living, it has to be said that the flaws
that were revealed by the May 2005 episode were not a surprise to many model
builders. Even before May 2005, modelers were documenting the flaws of the standard
6. One example of such a report appeared in Risk magazine in September 2004: “By autumn 2002,
all the talk in the structured credit community was about restructuring. Investors were increasingly looking for resilience in the ratings of their holdings. In its public CDO ratings, Moody’s began
explicitly mentioning the removal of WorldCom from portfolios as a reason for ratings upgrades.
“But such new-found resilience comes at a price. Although some claim it is a cheaper option
than selling an entire CDO tranche, restructuring is by definition an expensive process, involving
the unwinding of distressed default swap positions and replacing them with stronger credits at
tighter spreads. And that process is likely to mean wider bid/offer spreads for investors” (Dunbar
2004, 32).
7. For comparison, the three largest U.S. bank holding companies each had over $75 billion in tier 1
capital in 2006.
8. Rebonato (2001) provides the following more complete definition of model risk: “Model risk is the
risk of occurrence at a given point in time (today or in the future) of a significant difference
between the mark-to-model value of a complex and/or illiquid instrument held on or off the balance sheet of a financial institution and the price at which the same instrument is revealed to have
traded in the market—by brokers’ quotes or reliable intelligence of third-party market transactions—after the appropriate provisions have been taken into account.”
9. The International Monetary Fund (2005, 21–23) describes the episode.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

37

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

model used for tranched credit products, the Gaussian copula model. As one paper
published in 2004 noted, “despite the popularity of the Gaussian copula model, there are
clear and valid questions over its theoretical foundations” (Gregory and Laurent 2004).
Of course, any model is only an approximation of reality, and model improvement
must be a continuous process for products as new as tranched credit derivatives. In
the two years since the May 2005 episode, research into alternatives to the Gaussian
copula model has exploded. While eventually this research is likely to lead to better
models and a reduced level of model risk for complex credit derivatives, there could
be a long wait until that occurs. For the
foreseeable future, those who trade comMarket participants are aware of not only
plex credit derivatives will need to pay
the need to measure potential future expocareful attention to measuring and managing their exposure to model risk.
sure on complex credit derivatives but also
Rating agency risk. Rating agencies
the difficulties in measuring it.
play an important role in the credit derivatives market. As noted in a recent central
bank research report, the structured finance market, including the credit derivatives
market, relies heavily on ratings (BIS 2005b). Given the complex nature of many
credit derivatives, many investors rely on rating agencies to assess the credit risk of
a particular transaction. However, according to that report, large institutional investors
do not rely solely on ratings for making investment decisions.
The debate over the role of rating agencies in the market for complex credit
derivatives has two sides. One side argues that rating agencies are fully transparent
in the methodologies they use to rate synthetic CDOs. They publish detailed criteria
reports that are available to the general public without charge, and in some cases
they allow their models to be freely downloaded. They implicitly acknowledge that
their ratings of structured finance transactions are fundamentally different than their
ratings of corporate debt, for example, by compiling and publishing separate default
and migration statistics for the two groups, rather than pooling them into a single
group. This approach should discourage investors from treating an AAA rating on a
structured credit derivative exactly like an AAA rating on a corporate bond.
The other side of the debate argues that the one-dimensional nature of traditional
credit ratings makes them insufficient for comparing the risk of corporate debt and
structured credit derivatives and that using the same rating scale for the two is misleading. While the expected loss or probability of default of a BBB-rated corporate
bond and a BBB-rated synthetic CDO tranche may be the same, their risk differs
materially in other important dimensions. For example, synthetic CDO tranches are
much more sensitive to the credit cycle, or to business cycle risk, than a portfolio of
similarly rated corporate debt (Gibson 2004). Calculations reported in Gibson (2004)
show the expected loss measured as a percent of notional amount on a stylized mezzanine CDO tranche in a recession could be eight times larger than on a portfolio of
corporate bonds.
The tranches of the iTraxx index, discussed in detail in the first half of this paper,
can also be used to illustrate some of the points about rating agency risk. A credit rating provides a third way to look at the relative risk of the various tranches. Table 10
reproduces the two relative risk measures introduced above along with the ratings
associated with each ten-year maturity tranche from one rating agency. In several
ways, the ratings give a quite different message about the relative risk of various
tranches. According to the rating, the 6–9 percent tranche is less risky, rated A, than
the index itself, rated A–/BBB+. But the other two risk measures consider that tranche

38

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

to be at least twice as risky as the index.
Table 10
Various Relative Risk Measures for iTraxx Europe
The tranche’s spread of 88 basis points is
Tranches at Ten-Year Maturity on March 1, 2007
twice as high as the index’s spread of 43
basis points. Comparing the ratings of the
Spread risk Default risk
6–9 percent and 9–12 percent tranches
Tranche
(Table 6)
(Table 9)
Rating
shows a large difference between an AAA
rating and an A rating. In terms of histori3–6 percent
11
8.1
B+
cal default probability for corporate bonds,
6–9 percent
4.25
2.6
A
an A rating has roughly ten times higher
9–12 percent
2.1
1.3
AAA
default probability than AAA over a ten12–22 percent
0.8
0.5
AAA
Index
1
1
A–/BBB+
year horizon. Yet the other two risk measures consider the 6–9 percent tranche to
Source: Author's calculations; ratings from Fitch Ratings as of
be roughly twice as risky as the 9–12 perSeptember 20, 2006
cent tranche. And it seems particularly odd
that the 9–12 and 12–22 percent tranches
can be rated the same when no scenario exists in which the 12–22 percent tranches
takes a single dollar of loss without the 9–12 percent tranche losing its entire principal amount. Without taking a stand on which risk measure is better or worse, it seems
clear that relying on a rating to tell the entire story of the risk on a tranched credit
derivative product is a bad idea.
Settlement risk. When an issuer defaults, credit derivatives that reference the
issuer’s debt must be settled. Traditionally, settlement in the CDS market was based
on physical delivery by the protection buyer of the referenced issuer’s debt securities
in exchange for par. Physical settlement is the natural settlement mechanism when
a CDS is used to hedge the credit risk of owning a bond. Cash settlement is less desirable in that situation because the value of owning the bond of the defaulted issuer
may diverge from the cash settlement price on a CDS, reducing the effectiveness of
the hedge.
As the credit derivative market has grown, it has become common for the notional
amount of CDS outstanding referencing a particular issuer to be larger than the face
value of the issuer’s bonds outstanding. In October 2005, Delphi Corporation defaulted
with $2 billion of deliverable bonds and approximately $28 billion of credit derivatives
outstanding. Because settlement must occur within a fixed time period after a default,
a single bond can be used (and reused) for settlement of CDS only so many times.
The potential exists for an artificial scarcity of the bonds of defaulted issuers that are
needed for CDS settlement, driving up the price of the bonds. In the worst case, if
the protection buyer cannot obtain the bonds it needs to settle its contracts by the
deadline, the contract expires worthless. This situation has the potential to affect the
price of CDS in advance of a default, making CDS less useful as hedges and distorting the price signals that the CDS provides to the market.
Since the growth of the credit derivatives market shows no signs of slowing down,
settlement risk is likely to continue to increase as long as physical settlement is the
standard in CDS contracts. Market participants are certainly aware of the issue and
are working on a solution. In the wake of the Delphi default, dealers rushed to organize a cash settlement auction in which more than 570 counterparties participated.
Although all participants in the credit derivatives market have a broad interest in
seeing the market function well, their interests may diverge in a settlement situation
when some are protection buyers, some are protection sellers, some would probably
prefer physical settlement, and some would prefer cash settlement. Getting marketwide agreement on an auction mechanism may not be easy, especially when the

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

39

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

agreement is made after the default occurs. Moreover, the example of the European
auctions of mobile-phone licenses reinforced the basic fact that differences in auction design can lead to vast differences in outcomes (Klemperer 2002).
The auction mechanism that was used for the Delphi auction in November 2005
has been tweaked since then to discourage gaming and to encourage broader participation. In the most recent large default in the CDS market, Dura Automotive
Systems in late 2006, the most recent auction mechanism was tested and seemed to
work well. However, each auction is an ad hoc process that must be quickly agreed
to following a default. Settlement risk will still be high until the auction settlement
mechanism is incorporated into standard CDS documentation and is tested in actual
defaults, including some in less benign market environments.

Conclusion
I have documented the striking growth of credit derivatives, from nearly nothing a
decade ago to tens of trillions of dollars in notional amounts outstanding at the end
of last year. Driving this growth, market participants—including commercial banks,
investment banks, and investors—appear to find a variety of credit derivative products to be useful for their own risk-management purposes. I discussed a number of
the ways that credit derivatives can be useful for risk management. At the same time,
credit derivatives are posing some significant risk-management challenges. Many of
these challenges reflect the immaturity of the credit derivatives market. For the
credit derivatives market to develop and mature, market participants must address
these risk management challenges.

40

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

REFERENCES
Bank for International Settlements (BIS). 2005a.
Credit risk transfer. The Joint Forum, March.
<www.bis.org/publ/joint13.pdf> (November 2, 2007).

———. 2006. ISDA margin survey 2006.
<www.isda.org/c_and_a/pdf/ISDA-Margin-Survey2006.pdf> (November 27, 2007).

———. 2005b. The role of ratings in structured
finance: Issues and implications. Committee on the
Global Financial System Publication No. 23, January.
<www.bis.org/publ/cgfs23.pdf> (November 2, 2007).

Klemperer, Paul. 2002. How (not) to run auctions: The
European 3G telecom auctions. European Economic
Review 46, nos. 4–5:829–45.

———. 2007. OTC derivatives market activity in
the second half of 2006. Monetary and Economic
Department, May. <www.bis.org/publ/otc_hy0705.pdf>
(November 2, 2007).
Dunbar, Nicholas. 2004. Seduced by CDOs. Risk
(September): 38–44.
Fitch Ratings. 2006. Global credit derivatives survey:
Indices dominate growth as banks’ risk position
shifts, September 21.
Gibson, Michael S. 2004. Understanding the risk of
synthetic CDOs. Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, Finance and Economics Discussion
Series 2004-36, July. <www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/
feds/2004/200436/200436pap.pdf> (November 2, 2007).
Gregory, Jon, and Jean-Paul Laurent. 2004. In the core
of correlation. Risk (October): 87–91.
International Monetary Fund. 2005. Global Financial
Stability Report: Market Developments and Issues.
September. <www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/GFSR/
2005/02/index.htm> (November 2, 2007).

Lucas, Douglas J., Laurie S. Goodman, and Frank J.
Fabozzi. 2006. Collateralized debt obligations:
Structures and analysis, 2d ed. Hoboken, N.J.:
John Wiley & Sons.
Moody’s Investors Service. 2007. Corporate default
and recovery rates, 1920–2006.
Pugachevsky, Dmitry. 2006. Pricing counterparty risk
in unfunded synthetic CDO tranches. In Counterparty
Credit Risk Modeling, edited by Michael Pykhtin.
London: Risk Books.
Rebonato, Riccardo. 2001. Managing model risk. In
Mastering risk—volume 2: Applications, edited by
Carol Alexander. London: Financial Times/Prentice Hall.
Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association
(SIFMA). 2007a. Global CDO Market Issuance Data.
<www.sifma.org/research/pdf/SIFMA_CDOIssuanceData
2007q2.pdf> (November 2, 2007).
———. 2007b. Research Quarterly, February.
<www.sifma.org/research/pdf/Research_Quarterly_
0207.pdf> (November 2, 2007).

International Swaps and Derivatives Association
(ISDA). Various years. ISDA Market Survey historical
data. <www.isda.org/statistics/historical.html>
(November 27, 2007).

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

41

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Credit Derivatives, Macro
Risks, and Systemic Risks
TIM WEITHERS
The author is associate director of the Master of Science Program in Financial Mathematics
at the University of Chicago. The author thanks Jerry Dwyer for the invitation to write the
paper, conference discussants Dick Berner and Nigel Jenkinson and moderator Charlie
Plosser for valuable insights, conference coordinator Jess Palazzolo and the staff at the
Atlanta Fed for making the presentation a genuine pleasure, and Lynn Foley for editorial
assistance. He thanks Bill Sullivan, Sanjeev Karkhanis, and Joe Bonin at UBS; Mark Hurley
at JP Morgan; and William Y. Chan at Credit Suisse for comments on earlier drafts. He
acknowledges the support of Niels Nygaard, director of the Program in Financial Mathematics at the University of Chicago; Regenstein Library at the University of Chicago; and
the Social Science Library at Yale University. This paper was presented at the Atlanta Fed’s
2007 Financial Markets Conference, “Credit Derivatives: Where’s the Risk?” held May 14–16.

n the early to mid-1990s, derivatives received a great deal of negative publicity in the
popular media. Several unfortunate incidents ultimately led Gastineau and Kritzman
(1996), in the revised edition of their Dictionary of Financial Risk Management, to
define a derivative as, “in the financial press, anything that loses money.”
The proximate causes of these derivatives disasters were a variety of factors:
Metalgesellschaft experienced a cash flow mismatch between long-term over-thecounter (OTC) forward contracts and marked-to-market short-term exchange-traded
futures; Gibson Greeting was encouraged to enter into complex, and probably inappropriate, financial transactions that it apparently didn’t fully understand; Procter &
Gamble and Robert Citron of Orange County assumed significant investment risk,
exacerbated by a “surprise” interest rate hike; Barings Bank employed a rogue trader
who was able to engage in fraud because of the lack of institutional risk control; and,
of course, just about everything went wrong at Long-Term Capital Management
(LTCM). Many of these incidents were highlighted prominently soon thereafter in
books with titles such as Derivatives: The Wild Beast of Finance (Steinherr 1998).
At least one market participant (an investment bank) felt that the label “derivatives” was so detrimental that it renamed its offerings “risk management products.”
Many remain skeptical of the value that derivatives can provide; one hedge fund manager, speaking to a group of summer MBA interns at an investment bank in New York
a couple of years ago, when asked if he used options as part of his investment strategy, replied, “I don’t go to that crack house.”
The (interest rate) swap market has been around for only about twenty-five
years, yet it is one of the largest and, arguably, one of the most important and successful financial markets in the world. Credit derivatives are much newer, having
been first publicly introduced by the International Swaps and Derivatives Association
(ISDA) in 1992 but not broadly traded until after the standardization of the documentation in 1999.1

I

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

43

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

What about “credit”? The origin of the word, as our classics scholars know, comes
from the Latin—proximately from creditum (meaning “loan”) and ultimately stemming from credere (to entrust) and credo (I believe), which, for our purposes, is
what every bank or lender does (in terms of expecting to be paid back with interest)
and, more generally, what every counterparty expects (in terms of performance)
when entering into an OTC derivative contract. There is nothing new about lending
and borrowing, though Grant (1992) has chronicled the alleged long-term relaxation,
and accompanying deterioration, of credit practices in the United States. Chacko et al.
(2006) go one step further—identifying credit risk as a disease: “It makes you uneasy,
queasy, almost to the point of nausea. Well, we are here to inform you that you have
just been infected with the Credit Risk virus. And you won’t be cured until the money
is safely returned. In the modern world, this is a virus as ordinary as the common cold”
(3). Ryan and Risk (2006) refer to the “predicament” relating to credit derivatives as
“akin to battling a rare disease” (at least rare thus far). Others have used expressions
like “contagious” and “cancerous growths” in their descriptions of these instruments.
What happens when you combine wild beasts with some ubiquitous, virulent
pathogen? Avian flu? No, credit derivatives! Who wouldn’t be scared?
When the topic for this session was first proposed, the distinction between macro
risks and systemic risks initially struck me as quite different. I would like to address the
first (on which, I believe, there has been a fair amount of both academic and practitioner research and to which I will dedicate only something of an overview) and then
transition to the second set of risks (which, I believe, constitutes the actual issues
relevant for the policy discussions to be subsequently addressed here).

Credit Derivatives and Macro Risks
When one thinks of macro risks, what come to mind are exposures to changes in
those aggregate or fundamental economic factors that could affect the economy as a
whole in general or the financial markets and the banking sector in particular.
Before considering the macro risks that might affect the credit markets, a distinction should be drawn—one that I heard made by a credit derivative market maker
a few years ago. He pointed out that, while trading credit derivatives is surely trading credit, there is a difference between trading the market’s perception of credit (as
realized in corporate and some sovereign bond spreads) and trading “real” credit. By
real credit he meant trading instruments that are triggered not by the possible likelihood of bankruptcy; not by changes in default probabilities, recovery rates, or credit
ratings or by changes in those ratings; and not by any other circumstances that may
influence the market price of credit risk in any particular name but by the actual act
of filing for bankruptcy, by missing payments on borrowed money, by debt repudiation or moratorium, or by restructuring under financial duress—in other words, trading
instruments that kick in when one comes to not believe in some institution’s ability
and willingness to repay debt. Of course, one would like to think that there is a fairly
close correlation between these two types of credits and that the marketplace would
respond by providing financial capital to what is perceived to be a potentially rewarding arbitrage strategy between the two (capital structure arbitrage having been one
of the faster growing of the hedge fund strategies out there). But the distinction
between real credit and perceived credit is not trivial, as most commonly seen
reflected in the presence (or absence) of total returns swaps for corporate securities
in (from) the catalogue of credit derivatives.2
What’s in a name? Insurance or derivative? One of the fundamental reasons
for the success (or, at least, the popularity) of credit derivatives is their ability to sep-

44

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

arate the hedging or acquisition of credit risk from the traditional vehicles that have
allowed a position in credit (that is, bonds and loans). Credit derivatives are often
likened to “financial credit insurance” (and, indeed, they have been referred to in
that manner and certainly can be utilized in that way),3 even if the NAIC (National
Association of Insurance Commissioners) constantly reminds derivative salespeople
(and their compliance departments) that they cannot market derivatives as insurance, which is a unique product, separate from financial contracts: swaps, forwards,
futures, and options.4
Obviously, investment banks that have lending relationships with corporates and
sovereigns welcome the ability to lay off credit risk without the consent, or even the
knowledge, of their counterparties. This lending goes to the very heart of relationship
banking. Moreover, thanks to credit derivatives, these banks have embraced the relaxation of capital requirements previously imposed on the traditional lending businesses.
Consideration of macro risks for credit derivatives raises three issues. The first
is whether the ability to lay off credit risk has influenced the activities associated
with bank lending or capital market issuance practices. The second is whether
1. See Skinner (2005). Also see Neal and Rolph (1999), who wrote, “Estimates from industry sources
suggest the credit derivatives market has grown from virtually nothing in 1993” (3). A very entertaining article (Tett 2006a) gives some insights into the development of the credit derivative market.
2. Nelken (1999) notes, “There is considerable uncertainty in the market about when an instrument
is a credit derivative and when it is not. One definition of a CD [credit derivative] is any contract
whose economic performance is primarily linked to the credit performance of the underlying asset.
This definition would technically rule out TR [total return] swaps, because their performance is
only partially linked to the credit quality of the underlying and is mostly linked to the market risk
of the underlying” (173).
3. Skinner (2005) says, “Credit default swaps . . . are actually default insurance” (280). Nelken (1999)
notes that “a credit derivative works very much like an insurance policy. . . . The credit swap market
is very similar to the insurance and reinsurance markets” (5). Goodman (2001) argues that “credit
default swaps are really quite simple—they are conceptually similar to insurance policies” (144).
And Anson (1999) states, “This type of swap may be properly classified as credit insurance, and the
swap premium paid by the investor may be classified as an insurance premium. The dealer has
literally ‘insured’ the investor against any credit losses on the referenced asset” (44).
4. In a March 16, 2007, e-mail message to me from Matti Peltonen, Chief Risk Management Specialist,
New York State Insurance Department, Peltonen cites a letter, dated April 30, 2002, written by
James Everett, Capital Markets Counsel, New York State Insurance Department, providing the
department’s legal interpretation in response to an inquiry asking whether credit default swaps
constitute insurance. Peltonen notes in his e-mail: “The New York Insurance Department (NYID)
consistently finds that derivative contracts are not insurance contracts as long as the payments
due under the contracts are not dependent on proving an actual loss. For example, in considering
catastrophe options (cat options) that provide for payment in the event of a specified natural disaster (such as a hurricane or major storm), the NYID stated that cat options were not insurance
contracts. A cat option purchaser did not need to be injured by the event or prove it had suffered
a loss from the event. In reaching this conclusion, the NYID distinguished between a ‘derivative
product,’ which transfers risk without regard to an actual loss, and ‘insurance,’ which only transfers the risk of a purchaser’s actual loss.”
This distinction is not to be taken lightly. Risk Transfer (May 26, 2004) informs us: “If a derivative contract were found to be an insurance policy, the derivative could only be sold by a licensed
insurance broker. Thus a derivative counterparty that is not so licensed—one ultimately found to
have been selling an insurance policy—would be acting unlawfully. In California, this would be a
misdemeanour. In Connecticut, fines, imprisonment, or both can be imposed for acting ‘as an
insurance producer’ without a license. Under Delaware law, a Delaware corporation can lose its
‘charter’ to do business if it acts ‘as an insurer’ without a ‘certificate of authority’ to conduct an
insurance business.”

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

45

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

macroeconomic factors might act as catalysts in initiating widespread credit crises
and their associated implications for credit derivative markets. The third is whether
the greater dispersion of credit risk in the economy among a broader class of firms,
investors, and institutions is a positive and stabilizing development.
Credit derivatives and lending behavior: Moral hazard? The first question
asks whether lending practices have changed in light of the new credit risk management products. This question addresses the ability to lend, the willingness to lend,
and possibly the degree of thoroughness contained in the process of due diligence
that has typically attended most bank lending activities. We tend to use the expression “moral hazard” technically to refer to a situation in which an additional or heightened risk arises because of the presence of a contract or mitigating arrangement,
which subsequently causes one of the naturally risk-averse parties involved to relax
its behavior with respect to its efforts to avoid a negative underlying outcome. The
prototypical example of a market instance of this phenomenon is, not surprisingly,
insurance; for example, a homeowner who possesses fire insurance may reduce her
actions and expenditures to keep her domicile free from circumstances that might
cause inadvertent combustion. Gladwell summarized this problem nicely:
Insurance can have the paradoxical effect of producing risky and wasteful behavior. Economists spend a great deal of time thinking about such moral hazard for
good reason. Insurance is an attempt to make human life safer and more secure.
But, if those efforts can backfire and produce riskier behavior, providing insurance
becomes a much more complicated and problematic endeavor. (2005, 2)

Have banks really become less cautious in their lending behavior? A number of
factors make this question more of a discussion point than a well-posed question in
search of a definitive answer: Recent advances in banking deregulation, the Basel
Accords, modernization of financial markets, the evolving role of financial institutions,
consolidation in the banking (especially the investment banking) industry, heightened competition, collapsing spreads, innovative products, and new technology all
add noise to the question at hand.
That said, Nout Wellink, President of Netherlands Bank and Chairman of the Basel
Committee on Banking Supervision, properly pointed out in February 2007: “The role
of banks as the ultimate holders of credit assets has become less important. . . . We are
therefore witnessing a fundamental change in the business of banking from buy and
hold strategies to so-called ‘originate-to-distribute’ models” (2007).
There have been claims that the current state of credit markets has been altered by
the existence and infusion of credit derivatives. More specifically, it has been posited
that traditional lenders have become less concerned with the accurate credit quality
assessment of their borrowers because the lenders, through the use of credit derivatives, will no longer be the ones “holding the bag” when the ultimate creditors “cease
to believe.” Plender tells us,
If the real worry is systemic risk, a more fundamental threat comes from the
change in the structure of the banking industry whereby credit risk is packaged
into tradeable IOUs or hedged via credit derivatives and shunted off bank balance
sheets. Yet . . . moral hazard . . . complete with the marked decline in risk premiums
and in lending standards, is the story of credit markets this decade. The mechanics of moral hazard in the exponentially growing newer financial markets entail
the destruction of the old relationship between banker and borrower. This is

46

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

because banks no longer retain the credit risk in much of their lending. They originate and distribute; and where the intention is to distribute, the lender is
inevitably less bothered about loan quality. (2006)

With the recent events in the subprime lending market (which, I believe, have little to do with credit derivatives), one could argue that this situation may have resulted
simply from a turn in the credit cycle and housing market and might attach no greater
significance than that. The ability to minimize financial fluctuations and lessen price
volatility is typically not included among the benefits associated with free markets. Was
the unprecedented level of subprime lending a result of a change in the market’s
appetite for credit risk, a reflection of the influx of ready, new investors into this area,
or simply an error on the part of those who assessed the risks in this case? Those who
sing the praises of free markets usually assert that, while markets are not always
correct and can frequently be “wrong,” they are generally not stupid.
There may be a more subtle dynamic at work in this context. Whalen reports,
In the age of derivatives-enabled structured finance, the term “private equity” has
become passé. Nearly every financial buyer deal we see coming to market involves
a large degree of debt finance, regardless of the type of sponsor. Looking at the
staggering numbers for public and private bond issuance in 2006, measured in the
trillions of dollars, it seems clear to us, at least, that OTC derivatives and kindred
structures like collateralized debt obligations [CDO] are driving a process whereby
assets are being packaged and sold at prices that understate the true economic
risk. (2007)

One last thought: Knowing that insurance is available is quite different from having a policy “in hand”; it is not wise to wait until flames are coming from the roof to
seek an insurance quote. The issue of liquidity will be explored later.
Debt: The big picture. Currently, the United States is seriously in debt. On an
aggregate level, U.S. households “owe,” on average, 122 percent of their net income.
National debt is ready to top $9 trillion (and this amount does not include future
Social Security and future Medicare liabilities). Corporate debt is at an all-time high;
business-sector and financial-sector debt exceeds $23 trillion. Moreover, the United
States is relying on significant amounts of foreign funding. By the end of the third
quarter of 2006, the United States had borrowed in excess of $860 billion (around 6.5
percent of gross domestic product [GDP]) from abroad to finance its expenditures,
and BusinessWeek predicts more than 6 percent GDP growth in 2007. Overall, the
debt of the United States was estimated (at the end of 2006) at $48.4 trillion. The
question that begs answering is whether any changes have occurred in the banking
system, lending markets, regulatory framework, or institutional landscape to warrant
this explosion in credit risk. The presence of credit derivatives is probably more a
reflection of an attempt to manage credit risk than a manifestation of the spread of
this credit disease.
Macro risks and contagion. The second macro issue is the extent of the potential impact of changes in the credit cycle and the ability of the system and the market participants to handle such changes. By analogy, if the government were to put
something into the water that drove the death rate to zero, the life insurance business, one would think, would become extremely stable and relatively uninteresting;
no one, or at least no one who knew what was in the water, would subsequently refer
to this industry as risky. Insurance companies would collect the premiums and never

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

47

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

need to make a payout. If there were no bankruptcies, defaults, repudiations, or need
for restructuring, credit markets (and credit derivative contracts in particular) would
be dull and uninteresting. In the end, it will be credit events that test these products,
contracts, markets, and institutions.
If credit derivatives are triggered by credit events, then, on a macro scale, we
might want to consider what tends to influence the incidence of these events. Neal
and Rolph tell us,
Credit risk is influenced by both business cycles and firm-specific events. Credit
risk typically declines during economic expansions because strong earnings keep
overall default rates low. Credit risk increases during economic contractions
because earnings deteriorate, making it more difficult to repay loans or make bond
payments. Firm-specific credit risk is unrelated to business cycles. (1999, 5)

Credit derivative modeling will be looked at in more detail later, but some credit
models have incorporated aggregate economic variables as potential explanatory
drivers of credit conditions. For example, Das (2005) identifies the model developed
by McKinsey and Company (under Tom Wilson) as one in which macro variables play
a primary role: “The model focuses on the risk of a credit portfolio explicitly linking
credit default and credit migration behaviour to the macro-economic factors that are
major drivers of the credit quality of the portfolio” (590). Although one might think
that inclusion of these macro variables could enhance/improve credit analysis, Das
informs us that “in practice, the increasingly favoured models are reduced form
models” (590).
There is no shortage of academic or practitioner research attempting to identify
and evaluate those discernable variables that influence the number and severity of
bankruptcies, defaults, and so on. While it is intuitive that economic downturns would
generally coincide with the incidence of credit events, we can ask what macroeconomic factors in particular are the most significant in that context.
Ed Altman (a professor of finance at New York University’s Stern School of Business
and one of the foremost authorities on credit, bankruptcy, and defaults) and other
academic researchers have incorporated various macro factors into their credit models and analyses and have attempted to evaluate the importance of those variables.
These factors have included the level of interest rates, leverage, inflation, unemployment, aggregate measures of indebtedness, nominal and real GDP growth rates,
changes in those growth rates, savings rates, liquidity premiums, the ratio of highyield debt to total debt outstanding, returns (and changes in returns) of aggregate
equity indices, and, in a few cases (see Frye 2000 and Gordy 2000), a single systematic factor referred to as “the state of the economy.” The inclusion of these factors is
intended to capture the drivers of the probability of default and/or the recovery rate
(or, conversely, loss given default) in the event of bankruptcy/default. In some
instances, these variables are examined in conjunction with a number of other firmspecific factors such as industry or sector or geography as well as more traditional
credit indicators like the degree of corporate leverage, the ratio of free operating
cash flow to total debt, and EBIT or EBITDA (earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization) interest coverage multiples.
Interestingly, in examining the empirical importance of macroeconomic variables
that have been recognized as statistically significant in the work of others, Altman et
al. (2003) find that these variables add little in terms of explanatory power or incremental statistical significance.5

48

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

The open state of this research is reflected in the current work of Professor John
Binder (2006) of the University of Illinois–Chicago, who has recently found a counterintuitive positive empirical relationship between probability of default and recovery
rates. Furthermore, in a recent telephone conversation I had with a senior risk manager at a large, high-profile hedge fund, the manager articulated an unsolicited belief
in support of the notion that default probabilities and recovery rates (on bank debt,
at any rate) should be expected to exhibit a positive relationship.
To summarize: If the level of interest rates, the state of the credit cycle, the dummy
variable acting as a proxy for boom or recession, or any of the macro variables included
in these credit studies proved likely to announce or even trigger widespread defaults,
then we might consider these macro risks
Macro risks are exposures to changes in
as a potential source of systemic risk.
Perhaps less ambitiously, consider the
those aggregate or fundamental economic
heretofore generally accepted negative
factors that could affect the economy in
relationship between probabilities of default
general or financial markets and the bankand recovery rates. If the deterioration of
the economy serves as the single driving
ing sector in particular.
factor (raising default probabilities and
reducing recovery rates), then this deterioration could potentially, on an economywide
basis, trigger credit derivatives and simultaneously generate systemic risk in the banking and financial sectors. The lack of unambiguous significance in the literature of
aggregate macro phenomena on credit (and credit events in particular), viewed in conjunction with standard firm-specific characteristics, tends to mitigate our immediate
and urgent concern with macroeconomic risks per se as a source of systemic risk via
the conduit of the credit derivatives markets. But the likelihood of a macro event as a
catalyst for triggering credit derivatives certainly remains a possibility.
One final aspect of the macro relationship to credit involves what Lucas and others have referred to as “policy rules” (and the associated critique of attempting to
estimate relationships econometrically when the behaviors of market participants
change with changes in policy regime). While this consideration may serve to challenge the weak statistical significance in the empirical studies of macro variables and
credit events, what it really introduces is the notion that Federal Reserve and governmental policies (in particular, monetary and credit policies) themselves respond
to the myriad economic data and financial considerations discussed at each Federal
Open Market Committee meeting. While that relationship may be obvious enough, it
raises the issue of whether policy action itself may trigger a series of credit events.
After all, if it were not for the unexpected tightening of interest rates in 1994, the
first interest rate hike since 1989, there never would have been a Procter & Gamble
derivative fiasco or an Orange County bankruptcy.
Before leaving this section, I would like to quote Ed Altman’s conjecture that we
may be navigating in a new and heretofore unexplored world of credit. One fact that
he pointed out is that the U.S. high-yield market had less then $10 billion notional
outstanding in 1978, whereas currently there is over $1 trillion outstanding—exceptional growth by any standard. Furthermore,
5. Altman et al. (2003) note: “Macro variables are added in columns 7–10; we are somewhat surprised
by the low contributions of these variables since there are several models that have been constructed that utilize macro-variables, apparently significantly, in explaining annual default rates”
(16). They also observe: “Macro variables—as before—tend to have no evident effect on BDR (the
weighted average default rate on bonds in the high yield bond market)” (19).

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

49

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

the (junk) market is not dominated by fallen angels, despite GM and Ford’s inclusion in 2005, but by newly issued non-investment grade securities. . . . In addition,
the U.S. has seen a substantial rise in the size of the syndicated loan market.
Syndicated lending has risen more than 60% in the last three years and rose to
total outstandings of $1.5 trillion in 2005. The growth in this sector has been
paced by more risky leveraged loans. Leveraged loans . . . are now estimated to be
about $500 billion, or about one-third of the syndicated loan market in the U.S.
These higher risk and return loans are increasingly being financed by non-bank
institutions, such as CLO (collateralized loan obligation) hedge funds. While large
banks typically arrange these highly leveraged syndicated loans, in recent years
more than three-quarters of the funds have been provided by non-bank institutions. . . . As is readily apparent from examining the history of high-yield bonds,
however, markets are dynamic and constantly shifting. And there are times when
even the most carefully constructed and tested forecasting models can be off the
mark. The last few years has been one such period. Given the unique environment
in the credit markets during the last several years, which has been fueled by massive liquidity and the advent of new participants like hedge funds, it is worth asking whether historically based estimates of default probabilities and recovery rates
are still relevant. (Altman 2006, 2-6)

The next section provides more discussion on hedge funds and who is taking on
this mushrooming credit risk.

Concern with Credit Derivatives from Market Professionals
Concern has been articulated from many quarters about the rapidly expanding market in credit derivatives. With nearly $35 trillion notional outstanding and annual
growth rates that have ranged between 40 percent and 160 percent, credit derivatives
easily qualify as one of the most quickly developing product areas within the capital
markets. The explosive growth in credit derivatives in recent years (in terms of face
amount outstanding, trading volume, and the sheer variety of products available) has
raised questions about many facets of this phenomenon. Like any new market, credit
derivatives have experienced some growing pains (and I will mention a few of the
problems that have arisen), but most of the anxiety that has been voiced centers on
three aspects of this market:
1. the sheer size of the notional outstanding (and, more importantly, the fact that
the face amounts being traded in many names—independent of the added volume
via credit indices—are integer multiples of the current notionals outstanding in
that name’s debt [bonds and loans]);
2. the increasing involvement of the hedge fund community in this market; and
3. the operational backlogs and issues surrounding confirmations, clearing, and
settlement.
Credit derivative notional versus underlying outstanding debt. Currently,
in the auto industry alone, primarily at General Motors and Ford, the notional outstanding in credit default swaps (alone) is estimated to be fourteen to eighteen times
higher than the underlying bonds, notes, and loans. Gillian Tett, the capital markets
editor at the Financial Times, tells us that, in the overall market, “the total size of the
CDS [credit default swap] universe is now believed to be 10 times bigger than the
total pool of underlying cash bonds” (2006b).

50

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

What would happen if “something went wrong”? What do we even mean by “wrong”?
For some in this market, a credit event could be interpreted as “something gone right.”
Nevertheless, concern about the size of this market should not be underestimated.
Gerry Curtis, a distinguished investment adviser based in Boston, recently noted
the following:
Possibly a bigger source of risk (than the issuance of low quality debt securities)
is the sale of credit default swaps to buyers who do not own the bonds that are
insured. There are many bond issues outstanding in which the amount of credit
default swaps is substantially greater than the amount of bonds outstanding. If the
issuer defaults on the bonds, the loss to the seller of the credit default swap is
many times greater than the premium received by the seller. The favorable default
rate on junk bonds in 2005 and 2006 has enhanced the willingness of buyers to
purchase “junk” bonds and/or sell credit default swaps. (2007)

This sentiment has been echoed by many other traditional institutional asset
managers who are wary of what credit derivatives might do to their portfolios and
markets. Part of the concern seems to stem from a general belief that credit default
swaps, which originally played a useful role in hedging default risk associated with
debt issuance, have been carried to excess and are now vehicles for speculation and
counterproductive.
There is absolutely no scarcity of negative sentiment regarding credit derivatives,
as illustrated by article titles such as “Somebody Turn On the Lights” (Mayer 1999),
“Credit Derivatives Trigger Near System Meltdown” (Dodd 2005), and “[Credit] Derivatives Will Collapse the World’s Financial System” (Jeffolie 2006). By some measures,
Lyndon LaRouche’s admonition that “the amount of indebtedness outstanding is
greater than could ever be repaid, so the system is hopelessly bankrupt” (Gallagher
2007) appears discerning and contemplative by comparison (and is only slightly less
disturbing than Gallagher identifying LaRouche as a “leading economist”). On the topic
of this rhetoric, I agree with Partnoy and Skeel (2006a), who write, “Unfortunately,
opinion on the credit derivatives issue is polarized between alarmists who oppose financial innovation and supporters who naïvely embrace it.” Let’s examine what has gone
wrong and could go wrong as a result of the volume mismatch.
Historically, the credit default swap market has been primarily a physically settled
market. By that, I mean that upon exercise (following the declaration of a credit event),
the buyer of credit protection would deliver acceptable debt (as in a previously agreedupon range of bonds and/or loans) or deliverables in exchange for the face value of
that debt (with little in the way of variations from par). For securities that are already
distressed, the typical quote would involve points up front in addition to the periodic
credit default swap premium (where that premium is quoted in terms of basis points
per annum for any fixed horizon—five years being the most common as well as the
de facto default tenor—and typically paid quarterly).
The point is that, if there are multiples of the underlying debt being traded in the
credit default swap market, then it would seem obvious that physical settlement
could be problematic. There is at least the potential for a bottleneck. When Argentina
defaulted in January 2002, the major broker-dealers got together to net all the trades
before the securities ultimately traded hands; as in the past, an orderly capital markets settlement occurred following this credit event (as opposed to the protracted
cross-border legal proceedings that have accompanied sovereign defaults). For the
most part, the primary credit derivative dealers are the large global investment banks;

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

51

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

in most of the recent industry polls (BBA [British Bankers Association], ISDA, Fitch,
Risk), banks account for around 55 percent of credit derivative buying and 40 percent of credit derivative selling. These figures are not surprising because banks often
act as the market makers and intermediate counterparties in this product area. That
said, in the case of Argentina, it took an unusual proactive measure on the part of the
banks and dealers to ensure a smooth settlement; without this coordinated action,
there could have been a problem.
Why not move to cash settlement? Would that not eliminate the possible squeeze
scenario? There have actually been instances in which, upon the occurrence of credit
events, the outstanding debt has traded up (as it needed to be acquired to be subsequently delivered). For example, when Delphi entered bankruptcy, its debt, which
had been trading around 57 cents on the dollar, traded up, peaking at 71 cents before
ultimately falling back to around 60 cents.
Many of the academic texts suggest that cash settlement of credit derivatives has
not only been possible but common. These books are wrong (or at least “more wrong”
in the case of the United States, as opposed to Europe, where cash settlement is
more common). Even credit index documentation (and it is in the indices that cash
settlement makes the most sense), when last I looked, indicated physical settlement
on the term sheets.
The reason for the staunch resistance to cash settlement (where the payout
would be based on the difference between face value and market value) hinges on
the process for the determination of what market value really is. In the past, with other
products, recourse to polling a number of other market makers and broker-dealers
and then possibly averaging the quotes (midmarket or otherwise) would serve to
determine the unwind cash flow. So what had been the objection to cash settlement
for credit derivatives (and it had been a large one)? One Morgan, for example, may feel
singularly uncomfortable if another Morgan (which may have positions in that name’s
debt and/or the credit derivatives themselves) is a significant contributing factor in
the broker poll. Physical settlement, then, avoids valuation disagreements and the
need for market polls.
This overarching concern with the notional imbalances has led to concerns along
these lines:
With more credit derivatives being traded than bonds available, a default by GM
could spark panic buying of the company’s bonds, driving up prices. The contracts
would be worthless if prices rose to 100 cents on the dollar because investors would
have to pay the same amount for the bonds as they received in payouts. ‘The current method has the potential to significantly distort the economics of the trade,’
says James Batterman, an analyst at Fitch Ratings in New York. ‘There are no limits
on the amount of derivatives exposure vis-à-vis deliverables.’ (Hamish Risk 2006)

To be blunt, I have to question Risk’s use of the word “worthless” (or at least ask
for clarification “to whom?”); I would replace his use of “investors” with “speculators”; and as for the use of the expression “the economics of the trade,” I think the
economics speak for themselves.
Another concern after a bankruptcy or default, not unrelated to the necessity of
a broker poll or some other process for the determination of market value, is the likely
loss of liquidity in the securities of the affected debtor. Thin markets tend to make
people uncomfortable about taking, for example, the last traded price as a market
consensus, and, following credit events, even if the debt continues to trade, it is often

52

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

accompanied by spotty markets. Some have argued that the downgrade of the autos
(which was not a credit event in and of itself) was not such a tremendous shock but
that the significant market impact resulted from the institutional response—as bond
funds, whose prospectuses require they hold investment-grade paper, scrambled to
dump Ford and GM and sought other investment opportunities.
The credit derivative market has responded to the credit-derivative-notional-versusunderlying-debt mismatch and the issues related to polling by developing a process
that seems to meet the needs of market participants: an auction. Going forward, with
credit events, the broker-dealers (supported by Creditex and Mark-It Partners and in
line with ISDA protocol) will participate in an actual auction (not just a polling)
through which the investment banks will provide inside markets, market orders, limit
orders, and automated electronic trades and arrive at a final settlement price. If one
Morgan thought the other Morgan was too low on his valuation for the defaulted debt,
the first Morgan could express his belief by buying it in that market (voting with his
dollars as it were), independent of credit derivative positions. This process has
already been successfully implemented for Calpine, Collins & Aikman, Dana, Delphi,
Delta, Dura, and Northwest Airlines over the last couple of years, has been supported
and embraced by the dealer community (contributing members include ABN Amro,
Bank of America, Barclays, Bear Stearns, BNP Paribas, Citigroup, Commerzbank,
Credit Suisse, Deutsche Bank, Dresdner, Goldman Sachs, HSBC, JP Morgan, Lehman,
Merrill Lynch, Morgan Stanley, Royal Bank of Scotland, Société Générale, and UBS),
and has recently (February 2007) been extended to electronic tradable tranche fixings for credit indices (see Markit 2007).
This auction process now allows for the cash settlement of credit default swaps
following a credit event (making the derivative/underlying debt imbalance something
of a nonissue as well as making the invariably uncomfortable polling unnecessary)
and should help allay fears about the sheer number and notional magnitude of these
derivatives being traded.
Many market professionals remain largely unfamiliar with the specifics of these
contracts:
However, for a CDS (credit default swap) contract to be valid, it needs to be
backed up by some tangible bonds in the marketplace (even if far smaller in size).
Usually that is not a problem, since few companies are debt free. But if corporate
events occur which prompt a company to withdraw its bonds—such as a merger—
this can suddenly make CDS contracts worthless. . . . For the CDS market is now
so monstrously large that the behaviour of the derivatives is exerting an increasingly large impact on the cash market. The tail, as they say, is wagging the dog.
(Tett 2006b)

There are actually well-defined protocols for such corporate activities as mergers,
acquisitions, spin-offs, and other corporate actions called succession events (which I
will not go into here).
I will offer one last thought on underlying mismatches before leaving this topic
(as it is one of the main sources of concern regarding credit derivatives). There are
a number of (very successful and important) derivative contracts that cover underlyings that themselves are relatively small, illiquid, not traded, or even nonexistent as
a stand-alone asset. Dozens of instances come to mind. The Treasury bond futures
contracts are on a notional 6 percent (semiannual) coupon twenty-year U.S.
Treasury bond; there is no such thing (and even if, by chance, there were today, there

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

53

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

wouldn’t be tomorrow). What’s made this contract particularly interesting is (1) the
fact that it has been, and continues to be, physically settled (giving rise to lists of
eligible-for-delivery securities, conversion factors, cheapest-to-deliver instruments,
embedded options, etc.) and (2) the fact that the U.S. Treasury stopped issuing
bonds for a time. While the futures contracts never stopped trading (though deliverables always did remain) and while a large portion of the volume of trade has shifted
to the ten-year Treasury note futures contract, there is no reason why bond futures,
The reason for the staunch resistance to
in principle and in practice, could not
cash settlement of credit derivatives hinges
trade even if there were no deliverables.
on the process for the determination of
CMTs (constant-maturity Treasuries) also
qualify by this criteria. Eurodollar futures,
what market value really is.
the most actively traded futures contract
in the world, are cash-settled three-month LIBOR futures (and they have their own
quirks), but they are nominally on ninety-day deposits (which the Chicago
Mercantile Exchange will never make or take). The S&P 500 derivatives complex
(futures and options on the futures at the Merc and options on the Chicago Board
Options Exchange [CBOE]) pay off based on where the underlying stocks close; we
once claimed that there was no S&P 500 cash product, but exchange-traded funds
(SPDRs or ticker “SPY”) have mitigated that assertion. VIX derivatives traded on the
CBOE are contracts that have payoffs based on the implied volatility as determined
by several option quotes. OTC variance swaps also have payoffs based on actual
volatility (in this case, usually the non-detrended historical variance of returns).
There is no variance (per se as an asset) that trades, but no one worries about the
settlement of these contracts. Nondeliverable forwards (NDFs) on Chinese yuan or
renminbi have paid off without involving the underlying currency, and the foreign
exchange (FX) market, the largest market of them all, generally trades on an order
of magnitude forty times larger than the volume associated with the entire global
value of international trade; if excessive volume or speculation were reasons to terminate trading in a product, FX would be the first to go.
Of course, with every derivative (be it a future, forward, swap, or option), for every
seller, there’s a buyer, and for every buyer, there’s a seller. While I am decidedly not of
the opinion that derivatives are zero-sum instruments, I understand the statement
that “risk is neither created nor destroyed, just repackaged and redistributed.” Given
the propagation of derivatives in general and the growth of credit derivatives in particular (and recognizing that many of these OTC trades are leveraged), there are those
who think their existence adds risk to the marketplace. Risk is a two-edged sword.
Whether one gets long a credit name by buying its corporate bonds or selling credit
protection via a credit default swap, the major difference is funding (and therefore
leverage). If this fact sounds odd, consider that, far and away, the most common equity
derivative strategy is selling puts—synthetically; this overlay strategy, which involves
buying (or owning) the underlying stock and writing (or selling) calls against that long
stock position, is most often referred to as a buy-write or covered-call or covered-write
(or over-write). Many consider this strategy to be a low-risk investment play. Most
would consider naked put selling, though, to be extremely risky. The primary difference between these two strategies is basically funding. So why would someone prefer
one strategy over the other? That’s a good question.
By the way, in 2003 the size of the OTC credit derivative market topped the size
of the entire OTC equity derivative market (Banks, Glantz, and Siegel 2007, table 1.2),
and this ratio now stands at around five.

54

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Hedge funds and credit derivatives. Although hedge funds have been involved
in some of the larger derivative disasters (I once heard someone on a trading floor say,
“Long Term Capital Management,” to which someone else interjected, “They were neither. They didn’t last long and apparently didn’t manage their capital very well either.”),
many hedge funds understand the risks of derivatives (and credit derivatives in particular) well, use them responsibly and effectively, and provide support and depth to a
market dealing in risks that were once concentrated in the banking industry.
Independent of the ongoing trend that continues to see flows into hedge funds,
they command under 3 percent of global investable wealth (around $1.25 trillion).
Although any statement that begins with the words “every hedge fund” is likely false
(given the range of strategies employed by the myriad hedge funds out there today),
most do indeed “hedge.” The most common hedge fund strategies continue to be
equity long-short. This approach might involve, for example, going long General
Motors stock and short Ford stock. While there are many ways to get market neutral,
the main idea is that if the market goes up or down, you’re okay if you’re simultaneously long and short; if the auto sector goes up or down, you’re covered (because you’re
long and short). This strategy bases its returns on the specific overperformance/
underperformance in the chosen pair of securities. Variants of this strategy typically
do not involve very high leverage (either using borrowing to magnify one’s positions or
using derivatives to command greater positions than the cash market would provide).
Typically, greater leverage is employed in risk arbitrage (that is, merger or takeover
strategies) and in convertible bond arbitrage (buying convertible corporate debt,
hedging the equity risk by shorting the corporation’s stock, and turning the exposure
into a volatility trade). The one strategy that usually involves larger degrees of leverage is fixed income arbitrage; LTCM (which was, after all, primarily a fixed income
hedge fund) told its investors that it intended to lever its positions twenty to twentyfive times (that is, for every $1 they received, they were going to take on $20 to $25
of risk). That said, it’s been argued that one of the most problematic aspects of the
LTCM debacle is the ease with which the firm was able to lever its positions and access
financial resources from the major banks. In that regard, I think the banks have
learned their lesson. Nevertheless, Alex Ineichen (2001), a world-class authority on
hedge funds, has argued that, “many of LTCM’s strategies would have worked if they
could have held onto their assets for some months longer” (7).
Many hedge funds use credit derivatives to lay off risk. Consider one of those convertible arbitrage funds (buying convertible bonds and selling stock). If the funds
want to strip out the credit risk of these bonds (which they own), they could pay so
many basis points per annum to know that, worst case, they have the right to sell this
debt for its face value. On the other hand, some hedge funds are engaged in more
sophisticated strategies (for example, buying five-year credit protection on Ford and
selling five-year credit protection on General Motors—with no intention of holding
this trade for five years). Unlike buying straight corporate debt and attempting to
short another corporate bond (thus tying up financial capital), doing two credit
default swaps may give the hedge fund exactly the exposure it would like (with only
a net capital charge or net margining on the part of its counterparty/counterparties).
Chilcote (2006) reports that “hedge funds lost hundreds of millions of dollars, owing
to their exposure to derivative contracts and the downgrading of General Motors’ and
Ford’s debt in May” (1). One need only hear this assertion to raise the obvious question, If the hedge funds lost, then who won?
Chilcote goes on to characterize “hedge funds . . . that specialize in credit-default
swaps” as “secretive.” Louis Moore Bacon is one of the grand old men of the hedge

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

55

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

fund industry (and credited with an extremely impressive track record at Moore
Capital). Bacon, at a Hedge Fund Symposium in London in 2000, identified what he
called the five warning signs for hedge funds: (1) size (getting too big and exhausting the available investment opportunities within one’s area of expertise—and beyond
some point morphing from being one of the hunter-gatherers to “becoming the
game”), (2) leverage (taking on too much risk), (3) transparency (in tremendously
understated fashion, Ineichen [2001] tells us, “Full transparency of current positions is commercially unwise.”), (4) funding (asset and liability mismatches), and
(5) hubris (what Lowenstein [2000, 89] has identified as potentially the most dangerous “Greek” of all). Perhaps the greatest detriment to hedge funds today is their
association with LTCM (where all five of the above factors came into play in a significant and negative way). At any rate, many hedge funds are understandably reluctant
to disclose their positions. Not only is this their stock in trade (that is, their security
selection process, hedging techniques, valuation models, portfolio construction
methods), but hedge funds know that a market participant with deeper pockets
could trade against them.
This scenario is not just the creation of the paranoia of a few hedge fund managers;
it is probably far more likely to occur than one would think. Take the case of Amaranth
Advisors LLC (a large hedge fund that was based in Greenwich, Connecticut).
Amaranth apparently got into trouble in the fall of 2006 with losing positions in energy
derivatives, though it did utilize what it referred to as a multistrategy approach and
traded convertible bonds as well as other instruments. Amaranth’s typical leverage
ranged between 6 and 8.
The Wall Street Journal reported the following (after Amaranth’s $6 billion loss):
Hedge funds are among Wall Street’s biggest customers, and the Street gives them
red carpet treatment as the fees roll in. But the Amaranth case shows how Wall
Street dealt with a fund after it had traded its way into a deep hole. Information
the fund revealed about its holdings as it grasped for a lifeline let other commoditymarket players, Wall Street firms included, exploit its positions. As they drove prices
relentlessly against Amaranth, its losses swelled, and instead of facing a big but
possibly survivable setback, it collapsed. (Davis, Zuckerman, and Sender 2007;
also see Stoyeck 2007)

There were disturbingly similar allegations in the case of LTCM.
If someone were to claim that hedge funds constitute a major source of systemic
risk, the natural place to start looking for it would be with the investment banks.
None of the investment banks or securities houses, to my knowledge, have complained about the fact that around half of all trades on the New York Stock Exchange
are done by hedge funds. Furthermore, don’t hold your breath—many of the larger
investment banks are generating 15 percent, 20 percent, 25 percent or more of their
revenues from hedge funds. This revenue is not surprising because many hedge
funds trade very actively and opportunistically. In principle, the investment banks, as
prime brokers, clearing agents, and flow trading counterparties, should be in an excellent position to properly assess a hedge fund’s credit risk and charge/margin for market exigencies, but there is at least the potential for a perceived conflict of interest.
Moreover, Thomas F. Huertas, director of the Financial Services Authority (FSA)
in London, has shared his further concerns, as far as margining goes, with Risk magazine regarding the issues of rehypothecation, cross-margining, and the geographic
and legal access to capital.

56

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Blaming hedge funds in general for market disasters is like blaming well-fed vultures for dead animals; while the two are often seen together, it doesn’t mean that
one is the cause of the other. Contrary to what seems to be the norm, Alan Greenspan
(2005) has praised the ability of hedge funds to make the financial markets more efficient, to bring some contrarian balance in times of overly enthusiastic exuberance,
and to provide needed liquidity to markets, especially in turbulent market scenarios.
In situations in which hedge funds have gotten into trouble, we should ultimately
look for the real source of the problem (which may have been nothing more sinister
than a bad investment or a strategy gone awry). Although it was felt at the time that
LTCM required a Fed-orchestrated bailout for the good of the financial system as a
whole, subsequent hedge funds have gone away with little in the way of concern that
the banking system or financial markets (national or global) might be at risk or in
peril. Furthermore, LTCM was atypical (particularly at the time) in its size; it was far
and away the largest hedge fund at that time (based on assets under management).
It’s seldom pointed out that LTCM returned financial capital to investors as investment/
trading opportunities in the market waned. With regard to the exceptional events
surrounding LTCM, I’d like to quote one authority:
The primary mechanism for regulating excessive leverage and other aspects of
risk-taking in a market economy is the discipline provided by creditors, counterparties, and investors. In the LTCM episode, unfortunately, market discipline
broke down. LTCM received generous terms from the banks and broker-dealers
that provided credit and served as counterparties, even though LTCM took exceptional risks. Investors, perhaps awed by the reputations of LTCM’s principals, did
not ask sufficiently tough questions about the risks that were being taken to generate the high returns. Together with the admittedly extraordinary market conditions of August 1998, these risk-management lapses were an important source of
the LTCM crisis. (Bernanke 2006)

(One can only wonder whether LTCM would be around today if they had utilized
credit derivatives as part of their arbitrage strategy.)
The demise of Amaranth is an excellent counterpoint. There was no furor in the
financial press (at least, not until the role of the investment banks started to become
better understood); there was no talk of a government-sponsored bail-out; and the
possibility of collateral damage or systemic risk never even seemed to have been
mentioned. Moreover, no one blamed derivatives for this implosion. Amaranth was
a hedge fund (but at least part of its portfolio was assumed by another large hedge
fund). There were certainly losses, but no former employees appeared on television lamenting the loss of their retirement savings. Maybe we’re getting it right. Or,
at any rate, bashing hedge funds just because they are hedge funds seems to be losing popularity.
Having worked at UBS, I believe I have some insight into the investment banks’
point of view. Alarm bells would surely be tolling if a bank knew that every hedge fund
had on exactly the same trade(s); this sort of concentration of risk (gone wrong) may
have repercussions for hedge funds’ banking counterparties—even if the klumpenrisk (the individual net exposure of the broker-dealer to a particular entity) is nominally managed to be small. In essence, if every hedge fund were doing the same thing,
although booked as separate institutional relationships, it would be nothing more than
a multiple-counterparty LTCM scenario. The job of credit risk control for hedge funds
has to be one of the more challenging roles at an investment bank today.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

57

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

This systemic danger (of hedge funds taking on similar positions) has not gone
unnoticed. The European Central Bank (ECB) has warned,
The increasingly similar positioning of individual hedge funds within broad hedge
fund investment strategies is another major risk for financial stability which warrants close monitoring despite the essential lack of any possible remedies. This
risk is further magnified by evidence that broad hedge fund investment strategies
have also become increasingly correlated, thereby further increasing the potential
adverse effects of disorderly exits from crowded trades. (2006, 142)6

The influx of financial capital into hedge funds, in conjunction with the concentration
of trading strategies in this universe, probably explains the recent less-than-stellar
industry performance.
To say that hedge funds have been under tremendous, continual, ongoing scrutiny
would be an understatement. The question is whether (and how) regulatory intermediation would help. Greenspan spoke at an IMF Conference in Beijing in June 2005
on hedge funds; Risk magazine reported as follows:
Greenspan said (beyond his belief that some market participants were taking on
“risks for which their compensation is inadequate,” that the hedge fund industry
had expanded too quickly and should temporarily shrink, and that CDO returns
were destined to be disappointing in the near term) he was not particularly concerned that this may have a negative impact on financial stability, as long as banks
and other lenders are managing their credit risks effectively. (2005, 10)

In other words, for those who qualify as eligible investors in hedge funds, laissez faire,
and as for the investment banks that are the ultimate risk watchdogs, watch your
credit risk! As Juvenal asks, though, “Quis custodiet ipsos custodes?” (Who will guard
the guardians?)
I’d like to make one last point about hedge funds and credit derivatives. Philippe
Jorion (2005), a recognized authority on risk management (both market risk and
credit risk), reports an interesting (and possibly surprising) fact about the use of
credit derivatives by hedge finds (based on a 2003 BBA survey): “Hedge funds and
securities firms . . . are fairly balanced, each with about 16% of protection buyers and
sellers” (546).
This statement makes you wonder where the credit risk is going, then, doesn’t it?
Operational risks. When I first entered the financial world, it was with a proprietary option trading firm based in Chicago known as O’Connor and Associates. At
the time, much of its trading took place on exchange floors (in Chicago and around
the world). O’Connor was recognized as being among the best at what it did (and
what it claimed to understand, better than anyone else, was risk management). For
an O’Connor trader, there was one ultimate cardinal sin—not knowing your position.
It is this unpardonable offense, for the world of credit derivatives generally, that has
led to well-warranted criticism and ill-informed hysteria.
Greenspan, over the years, has been among the staunchest defenders of derivatives, claiming that they reallocate risk into the hands of those who are best capable
to take on, to warehouse, and to dynamically manage those risks. In 1999 Greenspan
said, “By far the most significant event in finance during the past decade has been
the extraordinary development and expansion of financial derivatives. . . . These
instruments enhance the ability to differentiate risk and allocate it to those investors

58

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

most able and willing to take it . . . a process that has undoubtedly improved national
productivity growth and standards of living” (1999).
There are also those at the other end of the spectrum. Indeed, there have been
some interesting articles comparing and contrasting the thoughts and beliefs of Alan
Greenspan and Warren Buffett on this topic since both have been outspoken on the
uses and value of these instruments (see Weinberg 2003). For those who have not
been following these discussions, Buffett has labeled derivatives “financial weapons
of mass destruction.” It’s been said that much of what Buffett has claimed is disingenuous because he has used derivatives himself, but he does make an important
point to be revisited later.
It is interesting, then, to hear of not only a criticism of derivatives from Greenspan
but to hear of a Federal Reserve intervention (back in September 15, 2005) ordering
a group of credit derivatives dealers “to get their act together” on the heels of a revelation that significant unprocessed credit derivative trades were outstanding—the
cardinal sin. How can one manage risk if one doesn’t know what the risks are? And
how can one know what the risks are if one doesn’t know what one’s positions are?
Timothy Geithner, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, last year
touched on (and reiterated) this potential problem:
These concerns . . . suggest the need for greater caution by financial institutions
in several important areas. . . . It is very important that the major dealers make the
investments necessary to improve the operational infrastructure that underpins
the credit derivatives and broader OTC derivatives markets. Operational risk and
infrastructure failures have played a prominent role in past financial crises, and
the infrastructure weaknesses that have characterized the credit derivatives markets since their inception are an ongoing source of concern. (2006, 3)

Since the September 15, 2005, castigations (which reflected concerns originally
articulated in June 1999 on the heels of the LTCM disaster),7 the industry has worked
diligently to reduce those trade backlogs and expedite the processing, confirmation,
and settlement of credit derivatives. Originally, the fourteen banks agreed, among
other things, to cut the number of unsigned trades by 70 percent before July 2006.
Not only was that goal exceeded,8 but in 2005 the larger credit derivative traders
reduced the average confirmation lag from twenty-three days to sixteen days.
The FSA (the U.K. financial regulatory authority) in their Financial Risk
Outlook 2006 wrote,
Credit derivatives provide a valuable mechanism through which financial market
participants can manage their credit risk, bringing together those who wish to
reduce credit exposures with those who are prepared to increase them. The market
6. This sentiment was also contained in the International Monetary Fund’s annual report (2005),
which suggested that there might be a meltdown in the credit derivatives market if all the investors
were to “run for the exit at the same time.”
7. These concerns were outlined in a document known as “Improving Counterparty Risk
Management Practice,” put out by the Counterparty Risk Management Policy Group under the
direction of Gerald Corrigan and Stephen G. Thieke and then updated and reissued, again by
Corrigan, in July 2005 with the title “Toward Greater Financial Stability—A Private Sector
Perspective,” addressing current topics of concern.
8. “Credit derivative dealers have reduced a backlog in processing trades by more than 80%, more
than their target, an industry trade association said” (Credit derivative banks 2006).

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

59

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

has continued to grow at a rapid pace and firms such as hedge funds have become
increasingly important, as both buyers and sellers of these instruments. Operational
and legal risks may arise if the market is unable to keep up with this growth.
Without confirmation that a trade has taken place, parties to the transaction
are exposed to legal and financial uncertainty. If a credit event occurs while a
credit-derivative transaction remains unconfirmed, doubt as to its legal validity
and contractual responsibilities could prevent the transaction from being executed.
This uncertainty could create liquidity problems and act as an accelerant in a
financial crisis. (2006, 15)

Similarly, Platt (2006) tells us, “The rapid growth in global credit derivatives is
putting stress on settlement systems and operational controls, despite significant
progress in clearing a big backlog of unconfirmed trades.” Although improvements
are reassuring, this concern over the recent rapid growth points to the possibility of
a catalyst for a systemwide breakdown. It is neither the instruments themselves nor
the fact that hedge funds are increasingly involved in credit derivatives that constitutes the greatest concern. Operational risk is certainly a well-founded consideration
on its own.
Some initiatives have been proposed that could act to mitigate some of the operational risks. For one thing, the European exchange Eurex started trading futures
on the iTraxx index at the end of March 2007. These futures behave like the credit
default swaps that trade over the counter but with the exchange counterparty support (reducing counterparty risk), with much more transparent pricing, and with the
associated daily mark-to-market margining. The Chicago Mercantile Exchange has
also reported its intention to list credit event futures contracts (originally targeted
for first quarter 2007, revised to a June 17, 2007, start date) and, as usual, the
CBOE is close behind. As is not uncommon, given the rivalry between the OTC
market and the exchanges, the banks initially declined to participate in trading
these exchange-listed contracts, one head of credit trading in London calling the
contracts flawed.

So What Are the Risks?
Early problems. Mention was made of glitches in the development of credit derivative products and markets. There are some classic errors that were made early on in
this market’s history (many of which have achieved almost folklore status). In one
instance, namely Anderson, credit protection was sold and bought on a company that
turned out to be a parent/holding corporation that did not have any outstanding debt.
In essence, there were no deliverables. This sort of slip has been addressed, among
other safeguards, by the creation of the REDs (Reference Entity Database Service),
which is intended to eliminate any ambiguity regarding the precise legal names of
counterparties (that may have similarly labeled affiliates or possibly unrelated but
close-sounding names) and which links a particular name to a specific debt issue. For
the purposes of, say, a credit default swap, this service ensures that the credit being
traded is properly identified. For the record, what one is buying/selling protection on,
in terms of the institution and the level of debt (for example, senior unsecured) referenced, may differ from the deliverables in the case of a credit event—obviously an
issue, but hardly a source of systemic risk.
A facet of this market that is often not discussed is the bilateral nature of a credit
default swap. Reference has been made to these contracts as options—specifically
put options on debt. A credit default swap (CDS), though, is a swap (not an option)

60

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

and can be triggered by either the buyer of protection (which is what most of us think
of) or the seller of protection. One might ask why a protection seller would trigger a
CDS when that action would result in his/her receiving defaulted debt that is trading,
say, 70 cents on the dollar. The answer is that there are a number of reasons why a
protection seller may wish to do this. Perhaps the most important (particularly in the
early days before the standardization of the documentation, or “standard docs”)
involved the need for a market maker who had, say, sold protection for 45 basis
points and then purchased it, from another counterparty, for 42 basis points (if this
trade is not assigned) to ensure that there was not a substantive difference between
the debt that was being received and the debt that was required for delivery (which,
at some point, involves a notice of physical settlement—a letter indicating the
specifics of the debt that is going to be proffered). If the market were to continue
with physical settlement, this procedure could pose a systematic concern, but, in
light of the new auction process (and accompanying cash settlement), is not a cause
for a systemic breakdown.
Conseco. Because of its landmark nature, let me very briefly review the Conseco
case. In September 2000, Conseco (an insurer, lender, and financial services company
based in Indiana) found itself in financial difficulty. It had acquired a home lender
known as Green Tree Financial, which made mobile home loans; unlike most home
equity loans, where the value of the home tends to rise, this often is not the case with
mobile homes. Conseco, therefore, experienced an urgent need for financing and,
through its bankers (Bank of America and Chase Manhattan), was able to renegotiate
its debt. Officially, this renegotiation constituted a credit event (under the category
of restructuring). It was alleged that at least one of the banks, having bought credit
protection on Conseco, subsequently triggered credit default swaps. Moreover, since
there was not a bankruptcy (in which the majority of debt might have traded pari
passu) because Conseco was still a viable business, there remained a credit term
structure. Longer-dated Conseco debt was trading 68 cents on the dollar (whereas
the extended fifteen-month loan was trading 92 cents on the dollar). Those who had
bought protection and chose to exercise obviously delivered the longer-dated debt.
The subsequent clarification of exactly what constitutes restructuring, who may
“call” the credit event, and what may be delivered (leading to the definition of modified restructuring, or “Mod R,” which requires the deliverable to be like the protection traded) reflects some of the growing pains associated with the credit derivative
marketplace.
Credit risk models. It has long been known that credit risk is not an easy nut to
crack (read, “concept to model”). Anyone who has ever traded options, for example,
knows that the Black-Scholes formula does not precisely fit the real world, but for
European-style options on non-dividend paying stocks, it works fairly well. There are
a great many quotes along the following lines: “Models are to be used, but not to be
believed,” “All models are wrong” and “I’ll take a good trader over a great model any
day.” Nevertheless, models have their uses. Why is modeling credit risk so difficult?
As far back as 1999 (the year of the publication of the first comprehensive, standardized ISDA credit derivative documentation), Phelan and Alexander concisely
summarized what they perceived to be the primary impediments to developing a
framework for evaluating credit risk:
Credit risk is more difficult to model than market risk for several reasons. First,
the lack of a liquid market makes it difficult—or impossible—to price credit risk
for a specific obligor and tenor. Second, true default probabilities in the market

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

61

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

cannot be observed. Users must determine these probabilities by either inferring
default rates based on observed historical experience of the public credit ratings,
using a model such as KMV’s Credit Monitor, or determining the default rate
through a subjective credit approval process. Third, default correlations are quite
difficult to observe or measure, making it hard to aggregate credit risk. And
fourth, to calculate the equity/capital cushion, it is necessary to estimate the tail
risk probabilities of asymmetric, fat tailed loss distributions. (1999)

There are some substantive difficulties listed here.
Jorion (2005) tells us in his Financial Risk Managers Handbook, “Risk management starts with the pricing of assets” (3). Theoretical valuation is the key to
understanding and managing risk.
It is no surprise that when one looks at aggregate market data on credit derivatives broken down by market participant (whether from BBA, Risk, ISDA, or Fitch),
it appears that banks/dealers account for about half of the buying and half of the selling. In short, the market makers are probably acting as market makers. When I was
at UBS, it drew a distinction between what it called “flow business” and “structured
business”—the former being primarily a market-making operation or market conduit
and the latter generating trades that would likely not be backed-to-back (even if they
were ultimately hedged using more standardized credit products). If a market maker
is running a matched book, the removal of one link in the settlement chain should not
be particularly problematic (and certainly shouldn’t bring down a systemic cataclysm).
For that reason, as long as the dealers properly manage their credit risk (in the sense
of counterparty collateralization and risk capital), one would think a credit event—
even on a big name like GM—wouldn’t start a meltdown. One hedge fund trader once
lamented that one of the large banks kept asking him to share his positions (which
he was adamant he would not do); the trader indicated that he was more than willing to incur capital charges and margining based on his direct exposures to that bank
but that he would not disclose his portfolio to that institution; as mentioned earlier,
this sort of reluctance on the part of most hedge funds to share their positions is
understandable. In one of the less cogent articles suggesting that credit derivatives
might result in the systemic breakdown of the financial markets, Chilcote (2006)
noted that “Long-Term Capital management did not disclose its risk or positions to
investors or counterparties” (1). This observation runs counter to the criticisms of
former LTCM principals who claim, in their search to find a source of financial support to allow them to weather the Russian debt crisis, that they were taken advantage of by the larger banks once their positions had become known.
Back to valuation, why is credit risk so difficult? When we consider credit events,
we are talking about low-likelihood, tail probabilities (which are often recognized as
particularly unstable). James (1999) told us, “there is no robust way of finding the fair
value of a credit derivative” (1). Partnoy and Skeel (2006b) go one step further; with
regard to credit derivatives, they write, “The mathematical precision of the models is
illusory” and “If the mathematical models have serious limitations, how could they
support a multi-trillion dollar industry?” One of the most difficult modeling issues
involves the portfolio risk management of credit risk. At issue is the determination of
the correlation between defaults, a consideration particularly important in tranched
products (such as synthetic collateralized debt obligations and first-to-default structured products). One hears credit risk modelers talk about such things as fat tails,
copulas (elliptical, Archimedean, extreme value, Clayton’s, Frank’s, Gumbel’s), and
conditional correlation coefficients. Unfortunately, our intuition, in the context of

62

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

credit derivatives, often fails. For example, financial theory typically advocates the
benefits of portfolio diversification, but, as those familiar with first-to-default products
understand, a diversified credit pool is not a good thing for the investor.9
The autos: What went wrong? The automobile manufacturer downgrade in
2005 surprised some investors, who lost money and, at first, did not understand why.
Let’s look at this event in a bit more detail.
On May 5, 2005, Standard and Poor’s, the credit rating agency, downgraded Ford
one notch to BB+ and GM two notches to BB (these moves signifying a change in
their debt ratings from investment grade to subinvestment grade or “junk”).
Although S&P had given anticipatory hints
Blaming hedge funds in general for market
that these downgrades were possibly to be
expected, the market response was immedisasters is like blaming well-fed vultures
diate and chaotic.
for dead animals; while the two are often
By the date of the downgrade, many
seen together, it doesn’t mean that one is the
hedge funds were engaged in capital structure arbitrage on the automakers. This arbicause of the other.
trage often involved trading debt versus
equity or one level of debt (such as senior unsecured) versus another level of debt
(such as junior subordinated). One trade that many hedge funds used was a long
bond and short stock position; the idea was that if the automakers did poorly, the
ability to recoup something on the debt was relatively high (given that some recovery value on the bonds was to be expected), whereas if the company went under, the
equity would likely be worthless. Many hedge funds, instead of buying the bonds,
effectively got long the auto credit risk (synthetically) by selling protection through
credit default swaps and then short sold the stock (or effectively got short by purchasing equity put options). What could go wrong?
After the downgrade, the price of protection skyrocketed. On their credit trade,
hedge funds had a mark-to-market loss. One would think the equity (being subordinate to the debt in case of distress or impending bankruptcy) would lead the bonds,
and this presumption is reasonable. But, at that time, in a very public way, an opportunistic corporate raider named Kirk Kerkorian suggested that he might want to
acquire a large block (28 million shares) of GM stock at $31 per share (a 13 percent
premium over the previous closing price). GM equity took off (causing those who
were short the stock—or long the equity puts—to experience a mark-to-market
loss); for those using stock as a hedge for their credit derivatives, they lost on their
hedge too.
There were other trades that hedge funds had on that also blew up. We have not
gotten into the details of some of the more structured index credit derivatives, but
some hedge funds traded tranches of portfolios of credit risk. In selling protection on
the equity tranche (which isn’t equity at all, but debt—though, like equity, this tranche
experiences the first losses) and hedging by buying protection on the mezzanine
tranche (which takes the next hit) of various structured credit derivatives, essentially
these investors were entering into a correlation trade. In the case of the automakers
in May 2005, what we saw was a case of correlation gone wrong. The impact on Ford
and GM was huge, but other corporate spreads were essentially unchanged. The
price of protection on the equity tranche tripled, rising from 16 percent to 50 percent, whereas the mezzanine tranche was unaffected.
9. Any reader interested in the underlying mathematics is directed, as a first step, to Malevergne and
Sornette (2006).

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

63

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Liquidity. One of Warren Buffett’s
favorite similes goes something like this:
Derivatives are like hell—easy to enter
February 23, 2005
May 15, 2007
and almost impossible to exit.
Although this characterization may be
GMAC
225–235
GMAC
166–170
glib, it touches a nerve. Liquidity does conGM
285–295
GM
430–435
stitute a systemic concern. There are difFord
230–240
Ford
544–549
ferent definitions and, therefore, measures
IBM
12–22
Boeing
8–12
of liquidity, but in this context, it refers to
HPQ
20–30
Dow
31–34
the ability to trade continuously in markets
Lehman
22–27
Citi
9–11
made up of several competing dealers with
reasonable two-sided bid-offer spreads
Note: Spreads are shown in basis points.
offering conventional trading volumes.
There is grave concern that if a number of
names simultaneously experienced credit events, the system would grind to a halt.
On this count, although one usually thinks of the large investment banks as the
market makers, hedge funds may actually prove helpful. Dodd (2006) tells us, “The
OTC market in credit derivatives is often cited as a case in point where hedge funds
play a critical role in market liquidity. Indeed it is likely the case that market depth
and bid-ask spreads are improved by the participation of hedge funds.”
One of the simpler (and arguably wanting) measures of liquidity is the bid-ask
spread. Incorporated into that basis point differential (quoted annually for standard
five-year protection) is a reflection of the number of market participants, the evolving
transparency and convergence of valuation, the willingness of the dealers to broker
credit risk, the reduction of market maker edge, and the general competitiveness of
this area. The table shows a few representative examples of how this bid-ask spread
has changed over the past couple of years. Based on these market quotes, the bid-ask
spread has tightened (reflecting competition, market participation, and market liquidity) from around 10 basis points in 2005 to a range of 2 to 5 basis points in 2007.
Perhaps of greater concern regarding liquidity, though, would be the response of
the broker-dealer community—either in their unilateral response to simultaneous largescale credit events or in the treatment of their counterparties under such a scenario.
Of course, two-sided trade flow is the lifeblood of a market maker; without that flow,
the best a trader can hope for is to dynamically manage his risks as they accumulate—and this point brings us back to hedging, modeling, and valuation.
Small number of dealers. In 2004, 81 percent of credit derivatives bought and
75 percent of credit derivatives sold were accounted for by only fifteen large banks.
When the New York Fed summoned the credit derivatives dealers on September 15,
2005 (to admonish them for their operational shortcomings in credit derivatives), only
fourteen institutions were present. The most recent Fitch Global Credit Derivatives
Survey (September 21, 2006) reports that the top ten institutions make up 66 percent
of the volume in credit derivatives. Even that figure may be misleading since the
majority of the volume in credit derivative trading is done by four counterparties: JP
Morgan, Morgan Stanley, Deutschebank, and Goldman Sachs.
While the small number of dealers involves industrial organization, it bemoans the
fact that a large percentage of the volume of credit derivative trading is concentrated
in the hands of a relatively few dealers.
Greenspan admits, “One development that gives me and others some pause is the
decline in the number of major derivatives dealers and its potential implications for
market liquidity and for concentration of counterparty credit risk” (2003).

Table
Tightening of the Bid-Ask Spread over Time

64

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

There is no doubt that an unexpected departure of any one of these primary
dealers would have very negative repercussions on the credit derivatives market.
But, not to be dismissive, in light of the fact that credit derivatives account for only
about 7 percent of the OTC derivatives volume and cognizant that all these banks are
major players in most of the OTC derivatives markets, a number of market participants would probably have more to worry about than credit derivatives.
Legal risk. At the end of the day, credit derivatives are almost exclusively unique
bilateral OTC contracts and, as such, are only as good as the contractual documentation the attorneys draft. This fact explains the preponderance of lawyers on and
around credit derivative desks.
In the world of derivatives, some still remember a trade (an interest rate swap
contract) entered into by the local U.K. municipal authorities of Hammersmith &
Fulham; when interest rates moved against the municipal government’s position,
they sought (and eventually obtained from the House of Lords) a formal judgment
ordering the nullification of the transaction as illegal.
In the world of credit derivatives, a number of issues have ended up in court.
Most recently, Bear Stearns bought protection from Aon on a Philippine corporate
backed by a government agency. Aon then bought protection from Société Générale
on the Republic of the Philippines.
When the Philippine agency withdrew its backing of the Philippine corporate, this
withdrawal constituted a credit event on the Bear Stearns-Aon CDS but did not trigger the Aon-Soc Gen CDS. The 2nd U.S. Circuit Court upheld the content of the
respective contracts, lending support to the process and providing additional confidence in the use of standard documentation.
An incredibly disturbing statistic highlights the importance of maintaining proper
legal documentation: A September 2004 Fitch report indicated that in some 14 percent of credit derivative claims, there have been subsequent legal proceedings. “In some
instances, the disputes have involved assertions that one of the parties breached
fiduciary duties owed to its counterparty, the risks associated with the transaction
were not adequately disclosed, or the transaction was not suitable for the counterparty.” Caveat vendor! (Seller beware!)
Insider trading. Allegations of insider trading have even been made in the credit
derivatives market from both the practitioner community (Joint Market Practices
Forum 2003; Credit default swaps 2006) and the academic community (Acharya and
Johnson 2005). Insider trading rules are well defined for “securities,” but OTC
credit derivatives formally fall outside their purview. What this consideration really
speaks to is the potential for material nonpublic information flow within the larger
broker-dealers.
And, really, after consideration of all these risks, what is the worst that could
happen? Stephen Ross tells us,
As a general rule, regulatory and legislative activity follows any period of financial
tragedy, and, however well intentioned, its statutes are often structured in some
haste and as much in response to the drama of the events as to the logic. Not
unexpectedly, they usually take the form of prohibiting certain activities that were
held up by the media as grotesque examples of abuse, and rarely do they take
account of the reality that the cure might be worse than the disease. . . . What is
remarkable is not the failures, but rather how exceptional they are and how well
the market system seems to work overall. (2000)

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

65

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Conclusion
The mission of the Federal Reserve System falls into four categories (my emphasis
added):
•

•

•
•

conducting the nation’s monetary policy by influencing the monetary and credit
conditions in the economy in pursuit of maximum employment, stable prices,
and moderate long-term interest rates;
supervising and regulating banking institutions to ensure the safety and
soundness of the nation’s banking and financial system and to protect the
credit rights of consumers;
maintaining the stability of the financial system and containing systemic
risk that may arise in financial markets;
providing financial services to depository institutions, the U.S. government, and
foreign official institutions, including playing a major role in operating the nation’s
payment system. (BOGFRS 2005, 1)

There is no doubt that credit derivatives affect at least three of these duties in a
significant way. The probability of systemic risk in the banking industry stemming
from macroeconomic events related to credit derivatives is probably much lower than
in the past because of the dissemination of default risk among a broader investor
base. This claim may not be true, though, of the insurance industry (“insurance companies account for only 1% of protection buyers versus 20% of protection sellers”
[Jorion 2005, 523]). For the financial system as a whole—recognizing that hedge
funds, on balance, supply and demand comparable magnitudes of credit derivatives
to and from the market—hedge funds would appear to provide a buffer for traditional
lending institutions. One caveat is the potential for concentration risk if hedge funds
all end up taking on the same (losing) positions.
The distribution of risk has its downside, though, in terms of control. Some may
recall the days when the Fed targeted the money supply. Because banks were so
clever at creating money substitutes (regardless of the various definitions of money:
M1, M2, M3b), eventually the Fed simply gave up attempting to control or target the
monetary aggregates. One wonders whether there is an analogue at work with the
control of credit risk (through credit derivatives).
The impressive growth of the marketplace for credit derivatives speaks for itself.
Recent developments in the settlement procedure, reductions in operational risks, and
other advances to improve the clearing, transparency, and liquidity of the market bode
well for the continued success of these products. Nevertheless, potential concerns still
remain: These include moral hazard associated with the due diligence responsibilities
of those involved in the debt origination process; the relatively small number of large
broker-dealers; potential conflicts of interest (given the role of the banks as hedge fund
counterparties in conjunction with their traditional role in a lending/credit function); the
ability to manage credit/counterparty risk; the challenges associated with modeling and
hedging the more complex of the credit derivatives; liquidity; and, as always, legal risks.
Considering catastrophic or systemic risks brings to mind a quote from Donald
Rumsfeld:
As we know, there are known knowns; there are things we know we know. We also
know there are known unknowns; that is to say we know there are some things we
do not know. But there are also unknown unknowns—the ones we don’t know we
don’t know. (U.S. Department of Defense 2002)

66

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Here is one last conjecture for a potential source of systemic credit risk. Donald
Perry wrote:
A hot topic of debate has been the financial shock that precipitated the stock market crash of 1929. Following that decline there was increasing unemployment,
business bankruptcy, bank failure and deflation. Similar conditions are being mirrored today. . . . We have the largest debt bubble in history at a time when there is
growing business failure and unemployment. As continuing growth in debt and
the derivatives market weaken the US and world financial condition, some have
wondered what future shock could precipitate a massive economic collapse similar to 1929? . . . There is speculation that the shock may come from the combination of Iraq war costs, increasing terrorism, tax cuts, unemployment, weakening
pricing power, and travel aversion. Whatever the merits to such speculations, a
more sobering shock appears to be on its way. I am referring to Severe Acute
Respiratory Syndrome (SARS), an infectious disease that originated in southern
China around November of last year and can result in a type of fatal pneumonia. . . .
Although I am not a financial expert, I wonder if this disease may become the needle
or ‘shock’ that could pop the debt and derivative bubbles. (2003)

Will avian flu, after all, be the final straw?

REFERENCES
Acharya, Viral V., and Timothy C. Johnson. 2005.
Insider trading in credit derivatives. London Business
School. Social Science Research Network Working
Paper, May.

Binder, John J. 2006. The expected recovery rate and
the probability of default on high yield debt. College of
Business Administration, University of Illinois–Chicago
Working Paper, December.

Altman, Edward I. 2006. Are historically based default
and recovery models in the high yield and distressed
debt markets still revelant in today’s credit environment?
New York University, Salomon Center, Stern School of
Business Special Report, October.

Board of Governors of the Federal System (BOGFRS).
2005. The Federal Reserve System: Purposes and
functions. Washington, D.C.

Altman, Edward I., Brooks Brady, Andrea Resti, and
Andrea Sironi. 2003. The link between default and
recovery rates: Theory, empirical evidence, and implications. New York University, Stern School of Business,
Finance Working Paper FIN-03-006, March.
Anson, Mark J.P. 1999. Credit derivatives. New Hope,
Pa.: Frank J. Fabozzi Associates.
Bacon, Louis Moore. 2000. Can institutions afford to
ignore hedge funds? Keynote speech, 2000 Hedge
Fund Symposium, London, April 27.
Banks, Erik, Morton Glantz, and Paul Siegel. 2007.
Credit derivatives: Techniques to manage credit risk
for financial professionals. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2006. Hedge funds and systemic
risk. Speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta’s
2006 Financial Markets Conference, Sea Island, Georgia,
May 16. <www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/
2006/200605162/default.htm>.

Chacko, George, Anders Sjoman, Hideto Motohashi,
and Vincent Dessain. 2006. Credit derivatives: A
primer on credit risk, modeling, and instruments.
Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Wharton/Pearson Education.
Chilcote, Edward. 2006. Credit derivatives and financial
fragility. The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College,
Policy Note 2006/1, January.
Credit default swaps may incite regulators. 2006.
Bloomberg, October 10.
Credit derivative banks cut trade backlog by 80%, adding
$17 trillion in risk. 2006. False Flag News, July 26.
Curtis, Gerry. 2007. Views from the sidelines #55,
January 29.
Das, Satyajit. 2005. Credit derivatives: CDOs and
structured credit products, 3d ed. Hoboken, N.J.:
John Wiley & Sons.
Davis, Ann, Gregory Zuckerman, and Henny Sender.
2007. Amid Amaranth’s crisis, other players profited.
Wall Street Journal, January 30.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

67

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Dodd, Randall. 2005. Credit derivatives trigger near
system meltdown, Special Policy Brief 26. Derivatives
Study Center, Financial Policy Forum, August 5.
———. 2006. On the hedge fund question: A program
of reckless complacency, Special Policy Brief 29.
Derivatives Study Center, Financial Policy Forum,
October 30.
European Central Bank. 2006. Financial Stability
Review (June).
Financial Services Authority. 2006. Financial Risk
Outlook 2006.
Frye, John. 2000. Collateral damage. Risk (April):
91–94.
Gallagher, Paul. 2007. The global financial system is
burning at both ends. Global Research (March 18).
Gastineau, Gary L., and Mark P. Kritzman. 1996. The
dictionary of financial risk management, revised
ed. Summit, N.J.: Frank J. Fabozzi Associates.
Geithner, Timothy F. 2006. Implications of growth in
credit derivatives for financial stability. Remarks at the
Third Credit Risk Conference—New York University
Stern School of Business, May 16.
Gladwell, Malcolm. 2005. The moral-hazard myth. The
New Yorker (August 29): 2.
Goodman, Laurie S. 2001. Synthetic CDOs. In Investing
in collateralized debt obligations, edited by Frank J.
Fabozzi and Laurie S. Goodman. Hoboken, N.J.: John
Wiley & Sons.
Gordy, Michael B. 2000. Credit VaR models and risk
bucket capital rules: A reconciliation. Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System working paper.
Grant, James. 1992. Money of the mind: Borrowing
and lending in America from the Civil War to
Michael Milken. New York: Farrar Straus Giroux.
Greenspan, Alan. 1999. Financial derivatives. Remarks
to the Futures Industry Association Meeting, Boca
Raton, Florida, March 19.
———. 2003. Remarks on corporate governance at the
2003 Conference on Bank Structure and Competition,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, May 8.
———. 2005. Risk transfer and financial stability.
Remarks at the 41st Annual Conference on Bank
Structure, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, May 5.

Jeffolie. 2006. Derivatives will collapse the world’s financial system. iTulip.com, March 17.
Joint Market Practices Forum. 2003. Principles and
recommendations regarding the handling of material
nonpublic information by credit market participants.
October.
Jorion, Philippe. 2005. Financial Risk Manager
Handbook, 3d ed. Hoboken, N.J.: Wiley–Finance.
Lowenstein, Roger. 2000. When genius failed: The
rise and fall of Long-Term Capital Management.
New York: Random House.
Malevergne, Yannick, and Didier Sornette. 2006.
Extreme financial risks: From dependence to risk
management. The Netherlands: Springer.
Markit. 2007. Creditex, Markit successfully complete
first electronic tradeable tranche fixings. Press release,
February 5. <http://markit.com/marketing/press_releases.
php?date=05Feb2007>.
Mayer, Martin. 1999. Somebody turn on the lights.
Derivatives Strategy (November).
Neal, Robert S., and Douglas S. Rolph. 1999. An introduction to credit derivatives. In Handbook of credit
derivatives, edited by Jack Clark Francis, Joyce A.
Frost, and J. Gregg Whittaker. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Nelken, Israel. 1999. Implementing credit derivatives:
Strategies and techniques for using credit derivatives in risk management. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Partnoy, Frank, and David Skeel. 2006a. Credit derivatives play a dangerous game. Financial Times (July 17).
———. 2006b. The promises and perils of credit
derivatives. University of San Diego School of Law
Legal Studies Research Paper No. 07-74.
Perry, Donald. 2003. A needle to pop the debt and
derivatives bubble. May 5.
Phelan, Ken, and Colin Alexander. 1999. Different
strokes. Risk Credit Risk Supplement (October).
Platt, Gordon. 2006. Growth in credit derivatives putting
stress on controls, despite progress in clearing trade
backlog. Global Finance (November).
Plender, John. 2006. The credit business is more perilous than ever. Financial Times.com (October 13).
Risk. 2005. Greenspan warns of investor backlash.
(July): 10.

Ineichen, Alexander. 2001. The myth of hedge funds.
Journal of Global Financial Markets (Winter 2001):
34–46.

Risk, Hamish. 2006. GM bankruptcy risk exposes default
swap imbalance (Update 1). Bloomberg.com (March 14).

International Monetary Fund. 2005. Annual report.
April 6.

Ross, Stephen A. 2000. Forensic finance. Presentation
at Risk 2000, Boston, June 13–14.

James, Jessica. 1999. Credit derivatives: How much
should they cost? Risk (October).

Ryan, Jennifer, and Hamish Risk. 2006. Credit default
swap market whipsawed by Verison (Update 1).
Bloomberg.com (August 8).

68

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Skinner, Frank. 2005. Pricing and hedging interest
and credit risk sensitive instruments. Burlington,
Mass.: Elsevier Butterworth-Heinemann.
Steinherr, Alfred. 1998. Derivatives: The wild beast
of finance. Hoboken, N.J.: John Wiley & Sons.
Stoyeck, Richard. 2007. Amaranth hedge fund collapse—friendly banker becomes PREDATOR. ezinearticles.com (February 3).

U.S. Department of Defense. 2002. DoD News Briefing—
Secretary Rumsfeld and Gen. Myers, February 12.
<www.defenselink.mil/transcripts/transcript.aspx?
transcriptid=2636>.
Weinberg, Ari. 2003. The great derivatives smackdown.
Forbes.com (May 9).

Tett, Gillian. 2006a. The dream machine: Invention of
credit derivatives. Financial Times (March 24).

Wellink, Nout. 2007. Risk management and financial
stability—Basel II and beyond. Delivered at the GARP
Eighth Annual Risk Management Convention and
Exhibition, New York City, February 27. <www.bis.org/
review/r070228a.pdf>.

———. 2006b. Lessons for CDS investors. Financial
Times.com (November 2).

Whalen, Christopher. 2007. Credit derivatives, moral
hazard and systemic risk. Seeking Alpha (January 30).

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Fourth Quarter 2007

69